22
OCCASIONAL PAPER Adopting the Euro in Central Europe Challenges of the Next Step in European Integration Susan Schadler, Paulo Drummond, Louis Kuijs, Zuzana Murgasova, and Rachel van Elkan 234 INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND Washington DC 2005

Adopting the Euro in Central Europe - World Banksiteresources.worldbank.org/INTTOPCONF6/Resources/2057292... · Adopting the Euro in Central Europe ... How Do the CECs Stack Up on

  • Upload
    doanbao

  • View
    216

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

O C C A S I O N A L PA P E R

Adopting the Euro in Central EuropeChallenges of the Next Step

in European Integration

Susan Schadler, Paulo Drummond, Louis Kuijs,Zuzana Murgasova, and Rachel van Elkan

234

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

Washington DC

2005

234

Adopting the Euro in Central EuropeChallenges of the Next Step in European Integration

234

Ado

pting the Euro

in Central E

urope:C

hallenges of the N

ext Step in E

uropean Integratio

n2005

O C C A S I O N A L PA P E R 234

Adopting the Euro in Central EuropeChallenges of the Next Step

in European Integration

Susan Schadler, Paulo Drummond, Louis Kuijs,Zuzana Murgasova, and Rachel van Elkan

INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND

Washington DC

2005

© 2005 International Monetary Fund

Production: IMF Multimedia Services DivisionFigures: Theodore F. Peters, Jr.

Cataloging-in-Publication Data

Price: US$25.00(US$22.00 to full-time faculty members and

students at universities and colleges)

Please send orders to:International Monetary Fund, Publication Services

700 19th Street, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20431, U.S.A.Tel.: (202) 623-7430 Telefax: (202) 623-7201

E-mail: [email protected]: http://www.imf.org

recycled paper

Adopting the euro in Central Europe : challenges of the next step in Europeanintegration / Susan Schadler . . . [et al.]—Washington, D.C.: InternationalMonetary Fund, 2005.

p. cm.—(Occasional paper, ISSN 0251-6365) ; 234

Includes bibliographical references.

ISBN 1-58906-350-3

1. Euro—Europe, Central. 2. Europe, Central—Economic integration.3. Economic and Monetary Union. 4. Monetary policy—Europe, Central.I. Schadler, Susan. II. Occasional paper (International Monetary Fund) ; no. 234

HG925.A36 2004

Preface ix

Abbreviations xi

I Overview and Policy Conclusions 1

Scope of the Study 1A Framework for Decisions on the Timing of Euro Adoption 2Long-Term Benefits and Costs 2What Do the CECs Bring to Euro Adoption? 4Requirements for Successful Participation in EMU 5The Maastricht Criteria and ERM2 6Strategies for Meeting the Maastricht Criteria 8

II Assessing the Long-Run Benefits of Euro Adoption 12

Gains from Trade 12Beyond Trade: Benefits on Income and Investment 16

III Long-Term Costs of Losing Monetary Policy 18

How Do the CECs Stack Up on the OCA Criteria? 19How Useful Is the Exchange Rate as a Shock Absorber? 28What Do General Equilibrium Models Say? 33Appendix 3.1. Cluster Analysis 36Appendix 3.2. Output Response to Shocks Under Different

Exchange Rate Regimes—Graphical Analysis 37

IV What Do the CECs Bring to Euro Adoption? 40

Income Gap 40Economic Size 40Capital-Labor Ratios 40Capital Inflows 40Investment 41Real Appreciations 41Inflation 41Financial Sectors 41Fiscal Deficits 42Unemployment 42Appendix 4.1. Measuring Balassa-Samuelson Effects 42

V Vulnerabilities During Euro Adoption 47

Getting the Parities Right 47Capital Account Volatility 48Credit Booms: Risks and Responses 56

Contents

iii

iv

Macroeconomic Booms 70Appendix 5.1. Methods of Exchange Rate Assessment 73Appendix 5.2. Estimating Credit Behavior in the Euro Area 79

VI Institutional Arrangements for Entering ERM2 and Adopting the Euro 83

The Path Toward Euro Adoption 83ERM2: Rules and Questions 84

VII Strategies for Euro Adoption 86

Taming Fiscal Deficits 86Controlling Inflation While Stabilizing the Exchange Rate:

Will It Be Possible? 100Choosing Parities 104Monetary Policy Frameworks 108Appendix 7.1. Estimation of the Impact on Growth of Fiscal

and Monetary Policy 116

Acting Chair’s Concluding Remarks, Executive Board Seminar,February 18, 2004 123

Bibliography 126

Boxes

1.1. The Core and Noncore in Pre-Euro Europe 21.2. How Large Are Balassa-Samuelson Effects in the CECs? 51.3. Exchange Rate Criterion 72.1. Staying Out of the Euro—Rationale and Perceived Benefits

and Costs 133.1. The Wage Curve for the CECs 24

Figure in Box 3.1:Changes in Real Unit Labor Cost and Unemployment Rate,

1995–2002 243.2. Classification and Identification of Shocks in the Mundell-

Flemming (MF) Model 315.1. Hungary—Experience with Increased Exchange Rate Volatility 55

Figure in Box 5.1:Hungary: Nominal Exchange Rate 55

5.2. Estimation of Credit-to-GDP Ratios 645.3. Harnessing Macroeconomic and Credit Booms—Stylized

Facts in the Noncore EMU Countries 74Figure in Box 5.3:Selected Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Macroeconomic

Developments 747.1. Calculating Prudent Structural Fiscal Deficits 88

Table in Box 7.1:Cyclical Sensitivity of Fiscal Deficits and Prudent Fiscal Buffers 88

7.2. Empirical Estimates of Short-Term Fiscal Multipliers 907.3. Accounting for Pension Reform—The Current Debate in Context 1017.4. Greece: Setting and Adjusting the ERM Central Parity 107

Figure in Box 7.4:Greece: Exchange Rate and Interest Rate 107

CONTENTS

7.5. Foreign Exchange Intervention: Desirability,Effectiveness, and Feasibility 113

7.6. The Success of Hard Pegs in the Baltics 119

Tables

2.1. CECs: Potential Long-Run Increases in Trade and Per Capita Output Following Euro Adoption 15

3.1. CECs and Euro-Area Countries: Correlations of Shocks with the Euro Area 20

3.2. CECs and Euro-Area Countries: Correlations of Indicators of Economic Activity with Germany 21

3.3. CECs and Euro-Area Countries: Manufacturing Intraindustry Trade 22

3.4. CECs: Sectoral Distribution of Employment and GDP, 2001 233.5. CECs and Euro-Area Countries: Manufacturing

Asymmetry Indicator 233.6. CECs and Selected Euro-Area Countries: International

Investment Positions (IIPs), 2002 243.7. CECs and Selected EU Countries: Overall Strictness of

Employment Protection Legislation 253.8. CECs and Euro-Area Countries: Clusters and Underlying

Components of Susceptibility Indicators 273.9. CECs and Euro-Area Countries: Clusters and Underlying

Components of Susceptibility and Adaptability Indicators 283.10. CECs and Euro-Area Countries: Clusters and Underlying

Components of Susceptibility, Adaptability, and Interest Rate Indicators 29

3.11. CECs: Sources of Variance in Exchange Rates and Output 323.12. Cluster Analysis Variables 384.1. CPI-Based Real Appreciation and Estimated

Contribution of the B-S Effect for the 1990s 414.2. Labor Market Characteristics 425.1. CECs and Noncore Euro-Area Countries:

Convergence and Interest Differentials 545.2. Selected Noncore Euro-Area Countries:

Banking Sector Indicators, 1997–2003 615.3. Credit-to-GDP Ratios in the CECs and Noncore Euro-Area

Countries, End-2002 625.4. CECs and Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Credit

Developments Relative to Risk Thresholds 685.5. CECs: Banking Sector Indicators, 1997–2003 715.6. CEC Countries: Summary Exchange Rate Assessment, 2003 775.7. Unit Root Tests 815.8. Johansen Cointegration Tests 815.9. Vector Error Correction Estimates 825.10. Weak Exogeneity Tests 827.1. CECs: Cyclical and Structural Fiscal Balances, 2003 877.2. GDP Growth and Its Sources in EMU Countries, 1980–2001 907.3. Southern Euro-Area Countries: Policy Setting and

Growth in the Run-Up to Maastricht 927.4. CECs: Impact of Fiscal Consolidation 937.5. Selected Euro-Area Countries: Contribution of Interest

Payments to Fiscal Adjustment 967.6. CECs: Expected Contribution of Government Long-Term

Interest Rate Convergence to Fiscal Adjustment 98

v

Contents

7.7. CECs: Required Fiscal Adjustment Relative to Estimated 2003 General Government Budget Outturns 98

7.8. Explaining GDP Growth in EMU Countries, 1980–2001:Regressions I–V 120

Figures

3.1. Euro Area and the Czech Republic: Feasible Combinations of Output and Inflation Variability Under Alternative Monetary Policy Arrangements 35

3.2. IS and LM Shocks in an IS-LM Diagram 384.1. CECs: Income Gaps 434.2. CECs: Selected Indicators of Size 434.3. CECs: Estimates of Capital per Worker Relative to Germany 434.4. CECs: Employment in Percent of Working-Age Population 434.5. CECs: Total Net Capital Inflows 444.6. CECs and Selected Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Current

Account Deficits, Investment, and Savings 444.7. CECs: Real Exchange Rates and Their Components 454.8. CECs: Consumer Price Index 454.9. CECs and Selected Euro-Area Countries: Measures of Size of

Financial Markets 464.10. CECs and the European Union: Fiscal Positions and

Demographics, 2003 465.1. CECs and Selected Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Capital

Flows 495.2. CECs and Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Interest Rate

Differentials and Sovereign Ratings Prior to Euro Adoption 525.3. CECs and Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Measures of

Fiscal Convergence 535.4. CECs: Bank Credit to the Private Sector 565.5. Selected Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Bank Credit to the

Private Sector 575.6. Selected Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Components of

Bank Credit 585.7. Selected Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Residential

Price Indices 595.8. Selected Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Real Interest Rates 595.9. Selected Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Banking

Sector Assets and Liabilities 605.10. Euro Area and CECs: Interest Rates on Bank Loans 615.11. CECs: Net Foreign Liabilities, Credit to Private

Sector, and Deposits 635.12. Euro Area: Bank Credit to the Private Sector 655.13. CECs: Real Bank Credit Growth to the Private Sector 665.14. CECs: Baseline Simulations of Bank Credit to

Private Sector 675.15. CECs: Alternative Simulations of Bank Credit to

Private Sector 695.16. Simulated Effect of a 1 Percentage Point Reduction

in Real Interest Rates on Consumption,Investment, and the Current Account 72

5.17. CECs: Real Effective Exchange Rates 765.18. CECs: Ratios of Wage Costs to Value Added 775.19. Euro Area and CECs: PPP Exchange Rate

Ratio and GDP per Capita 77

vi

CONTENTS

5.20. Euro Area and CECs: Market Exchange Rate Compared with the PPP Exchange Rate 78

5.21. CECs: Market Share in Euro-Area Imports 785.22. Error Correction Term 827.1. Noncore Euro-Area Countries and CECs: Fiscal

Situation Before Euro Adoption 917.2. Southern Euro-Area Countries: Policy Mix, External

Setting, and Growth 927.3. CECs and Euro-Area Countries: General Government

Revenue and Expenditure, and per Capita GDP 947.4. Euro Area: Fiscal Adjustment and Its Contributions 977.5. CECs and Noncore Euro-Area Periphery: Inflation

Prior to Euro Adoption 1027.6. Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Inflation Indicators

After Euro Adoption 1037.7. Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Inflation Indicators

Before Euro Adoption 1057.8. CECs and Noncore Euro-Area Countries: Real and

Nominal Bilateral Exchange Rates Prior to Euro Adoption 106

7.9. CECs: Deviations from the Average Exchange Rate 1107.10. Finland and Spain: Interest Rate Differential and

General Government Balance 1117.11. Finland and Spain: Exchange Rates and

Change in Reserves 1127.12. Reserves in the Euro Area, CECs, and Baltic Countries 1147.13. Czech Republic and Poland: Real and Nominal

Effective Exchange Rates 1147.14. Selected Core Euro-Area Countries: Macroeconomic

Developments Prior to Euro Adoption 1167.15. Baltic Countries: Macroeconomic Developments 1177.16. Euro-Area Countries and CECs: Determinants of GDP

Growth and Openness 122

vii

Contents

The following conventions are used in this paper:. . . to indicate that data are not available or not applicable;— to indicate that the figure is zero or less than half the final digit shown;– between years or months (for example, 1991–92 or January–June) to indi-

cate the years or months covered, including the beginning and endingyears or months;

/ between years or months (for example, 1991/92) to indicate a fiscal orfinancial year.

“Billion” means a thousand million; “trillion” means a thousand billion.“Basis points” refer to hundredths of 1 percentage point (for example,

25 basis points are equivalent to 1⁄4 of 1 percentage point).Minor discrepancies between constituent figures and totals are due to

rounding.The term “country,” as used in this paper, does not in all cases refer to a terri-

torial entity that is a state as understood by international law and practice; theterm also covers some territorial entities that are not states, but for which statis-tical data are maintained and provided internationally on a separate and inde-pendent basis.

ix

Upon entry into the European Union (EU), countries become members of the Eco-nomic and Monetary Union (EMU) with a derogation from adopting the euro as theircurrency (that is, each country joining the EU commits to replace its national cur-rency with the euro, but can choose when to request permission to do so). For most ofthese countries, adopting the euro will entail major economic changes. This paper ex-amines likely economic developments and policy challenges for the five former tran-sition countries in central Europe—the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, the SlovakRepublic, and Slovenia—that joined the EU in May 2004, operated independentmonetary policies, but had not yet achieved policy convergence with the rest of theeuro area by that time.

This study was prepared by a team led by Susan Schadler and consisting of PauloDrummond, Louis Kuijs, Zuzana Murgasova, and Rachel van Elkan. The study hasbenefited from comments by various departments of the IMF; staff of the EuropeanCentral Bank (ECB) and the European Commission (EC); participants in a confer-ence on Euro Adoption in Prague in February 2004; and seminars at the NationalBank of Poland, Czech National Bank, and Magyar Nemzeti Bank. Material pre-sented in this study was originally prepared as background for an IMF ExecutiveBoard seminar on euro adoption in February 2004. The cutoff date for data revisionwas April 2004. Since that date, revisions to data for Greece, in particular, were sig-nificant and could influence the conclusions of parts of the study.

The authors are particularly grateful to Indra Mahadewa, Socorro Santayana, andJocelyn Rivera for processing the original text; to Jolanta Stefanska and JehanPanthaki for excellent research assistance; and to Jim McEuen of the External Rela-tions Department, who edited the paper and coordinated the production of the publi-cation. The views in the paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflectthe views of national authorities or IMF Executive Directors.

Preface

xi

ANOVA Analysis of varianceB and K Borghijs and Kuijs (2004)BCPS Bank credit to the private sectorBEER Behavioral equilibrium exchange rateBIS Bank for International SettlementsB-S Balassa-SamuelsonCAP Common Agricultural Policy (EU)CEC Central European countryCEC-H CECs minus HungaryCPI Consumer price indexCUSUM Cumulated sum of recursive residualsEC European Commission (EU)ECB European Central Bank (EU)ECOFIN

Council Council of Economics and Finance Ministers of the EUEFC Economic and Financial Committee (EU)EMU Economic and Monetary Union (EU)ERM/ERM2 Exchange Rate Mechanism (EU)ESA-95 European System of Accounts 1995 (Eurostat, 1996)EU European UnionEurostat Statistical Office of the European Communities (EU)FDI Foreign direct investmentFEER Fundamental equilibrium exchange rateFRER Fundamental real exchange rateFSAP Financial Sector Assessment Program (IMF–World Bank)FSSA Financial System Stability Assessment (IMF)GDP Gross domestic productGEM Global Economic Model (IMF)GFS Government Finance Statistics (IMF)GFSM Government Finance Statistics Manual 2001 (IMF, 2001)GLS Generalized least squaresGMM Generalized matrix of momentsHP Hodrick-PrescottIIP International investment positionIRF Impulse response functionMF Mundell-FlemingMULTIMOD Multiregion Macroeconomic Model (IMF)NATREX Natural real exchange rateOCA Optimum currency areaOECD Organization for Economic Cooperation and DevelopmentOLS Ordinary least squaresPAYG Pay as you goPPP Purchasing power parityREER Real effective exchange rateRER Real exchange rate

Abbreviations

xii

ABBREVIATIONS

SGP Stability and Growth Pact (EU)SITC Standard International Trade ClassificationSNA System of National Accounts 1993 (EC and others, 1993)SVAR Structural VARTEF Taylor efficiency frontierTFP Total factor productivityULC Unit labor costsUN United NationsUNDP United Nations Development ProgramVAR Vector autoregressionVAT Value-added taxVECM Vector error correction modelVSTFF Very short-term financing facility (ECB)WEO World Economic Outlook (IMF)

The first wave of transition countries to join theEuropean Union (EU) are turning their attention

to the next step in their integration with Europe—replacing their national currencies with the euro.Upon accession to the EU, these countries becamemembers of the Economic and Monetary Union (EMU)with a derogation from adopting the euro as theircurrency. As such, each is committed to replacing itsnational currency with the euro but can choose whento request permission to do so. Adopting the eurowill entail major economic changes. Countries willreap the benefits of closer integration with the euroarea and attendant gains for trade, growth, and realconvergence. At the same time, relinquishing mone-tary policy could lead to greater economic volatilityunless adjustment to shocks that are asymmetric withrespect to the euro area occurs efficiently throughother channels—primarily fiscal policy and wageand price flexibility—or the incidence of such shocksis reduced owing to the discipline of the euro-areamacroeconomic policy framework and the eliminationof variable emerging market risk premia.

Decisions on when the transition countries shouldadopt the euro and how they should prepare requirecareful consideration of the substantial differencesbetween them and the existing euro area. For most ofthe transition countries, real convergence—that is,Achieving levels of income and structural economicfeatures similar to euro-area norms—is markedly be-hind that of any existing euro-area members. And forsome, nominal (inflation) and policy (fiscal) conver-gence is as much of a hurdle as it was in the most dif-ficult pre-EMU cases. These initial conditions raisequestions about the balance of benefits and costs, thepolicy prerequisites for a successful experience inthe euro area, and the challenges of meeting theentry tests for the euro area—the Maastricht conver-gence criteria. This study examines these questionsand provides a framework for the IMF’s surveillance.

Scope of the Study

The broad aims of the paper are, first, to identify theconsiderations that will mold the accession countries’

I Overview and Policy Conclusions

strategies for adopting the euro; second, to draw onthe experiences of the existing euro-area members—especially the noncore countries (Box 1.1)—to an-ticipate issues that will arise in the transition coun-tries; and third, to examine vulnerabilities on whichIMF surveillance will need to focus during theprocess of euro adoption. The approach is to use,wherever possible, existing empirical and analyticalwork to draw conclusions; new analysis is under-taken only to fill gaps. Also, while information andviews on individual countries are presented, no effortis made to assess the actual or optimal euro adoptionstrategy for them separately.

The study focuses on the five central Europeancountries (CECs) that now operate independent mon-etary policies and typically have some way to go be-fore they achieve policy convergence with the euro area.These five countries—the Czech Republic, Hungary,Poland, the Slovak Republic, and Slovenia—willneed major changes in their macroeconomic policiesand policy frameworks in the run-up to euro adop-tion. In contrast, the three Baltic countries—Estonia,Latvia, and Lithuania—with far closer policy links tothe euro area, do not face the same kind of challenges.The analysis is solely from the perspective of theCECs rather than the existing euro area. While EUenlargement will entail political and institutionalcomplications for the euro area, the CECs will for along time constitute a small addition in purely economicterms, whether measured in terms of GDP or size offinancial markets.

The plan of the study is as follows. This sectiondraws key points and policy conclusions from the an-alytical work in the rest of the paper. Section II ex-amines the long-run benefits of euro adoption, andSection III the long-run costs of losing the monetarypolicy tool. Section IV provides a snapshot of keycharacteristics of the CECs. Section V examines po-tential vulnerabilities central to the process of euroadoption—risks of setting exchange rate parities atinappropriate levels, volatile capital inflows, andpossible credit and demand booms. Section VI sum-marizes the Maastricht criteria. Section VII considerspreconditions for successful euro adoption and strate-gies for meeting them and the Maastricht criteria.

1

I OVERVIEW AND POLICY CONCLUSIONS

2

tricht criteria, ways of minimizing them, and theoptimal time for bearing them.

These issues are at the heart of this study and willbe addressed in turn.

Long-Term Benefits and Costs

Some estimates of likely gains for growth of tradeand incomes from joining a currency union are star-tlingly large (Section II). A growing literature linksthese to increased trade with other currency union mem-bers feeding into substantial benefits for output growth.Most estimates come from gravity models of bilateraltrade relationships estimated on large panel data sets.The models include a variety of explanatory variablescapturing country size, geography, and institutions, aswell as membership in a currency union. Rose (2002)examines 24 such analyses and finds a pooled estimatethat currency union membership increases trade bysome 85 percent—almost entirely through trade cre-ation rather than trade diversion—with currency unionpartners. This together with an estimate of the impact oftrade on income suggests that euro adoption could po-tentially raise GDP by 18–20 percent over 20 years inmost of the CECs and by 8 percent in Poland.1 How-ever, a number of studies (Persson, 2001; and Tenreyoand Persson, 2001) point to possible upward bias inthese estimates. This bias could arise from samplingunions that involve overwhelmingly poor and/or smallcountries (sampling bias) and from the importance ofexisting trade patterns in the formation of currencyunions themselves (simultaneity bias). Results from re-cent gravity models of the gains from EMU suggesttrade gains of 6–15 percent after only five years of its

Box 1.1. The Core and Noncore in Pre-Euro Europe

While the current EMU countries remained quite diverseduring the early- to mid-1990s, a group of core countries(Austria, Belgium, France, Germany, Luxembourg, andthe Netherlands) had, already by that time, achieved ahigh degree of nominal and real economic convergenceand closely aligned macroeconomic policies. In partic-ular, these countries had maintained their bilateral ex-change rates within narrow bands for an extended pe-riod.

Other EU countries that sought to adopt the euro hadachieved less convergence by the mid-1990s, with

much of their nominal (and even real) convergence tak-ing place later. Thus, inflation was higher (Greece,Portugal, and Spain), fiscal deficits were larger (Italyand Greece), or cyclical positions were less aligned(Finland and Ireland). Many of these late-converging ornoncore countries, therefore, relied on exchange rateframeworks, and adopted monetary policy stances, thatwere significantly different from their counterparts inthe core up to a year before their adoption of the euro.

1This assumes that every 1 percent increase in total trade (as ashare of GDP) raises per capita income by at least 1⁄3 of 1 percent(Frankel and Rose, 2002).

A Framework for Decisions on the Timing of Euro Adoption

Since each new member state is obliged to adoptthe euro at some point, all the issues addressed in thisstudy essentially come down to one basic question:when and how to do it. But the considerations arecomplex and most manageable if broken down intopieces that are as conceptually distinct as possible.There are three broad groupings.

• First, do the long-term benefits of being a euro-area member outweigh the long-term costs?Abstracting from immediate entry require-ments, how much will a country gain from in-creased trade, growth, and policy discipline,and how much will it lose from relinquishingmonetary policy as a stabilization instrument?If net gains are expected to be substantial andcosts unlikely to fall over time, moving with ur-gency to put in place policies necessary for euroadoption would be wise. If the benefits andcosts are balanced and the net gains are likely toimprove over time, a slower approach might bepreferable.

• Second, what policy or institutional changes arerequired to ensure a successful experience in theeuro area? Broadly, these center around changesto enhance economic mechanisms—such aswage and price flexibility and fiscal policy—forabsorbing asymmetric shocks in the absence ofmonetary policy.

• Third, how long will it take to credibly and effi-ciently put needed policies in place and meet theMaastricht criteria? As in any impending regimechange, the run-up to euro adoption carries risksof macroeconomic volatility: a strategy for man-aging them is essential. Also, it is important toidentify costs involved in meeting the Maas-

Long-Term Benefits and Costs

existence (Faruqee, 2004). Whether such trade growth islikely to persist (so that gains over 20 years wouldamount to some 25–75 percent) or to taper off (so thatlong-term gains would be similar to those achieved thusfar) remains to be seen. But taking an average of theseestimates of gains thus far from EMU as a lower bound,euro adoption would raise GDP by some 2 percent over20 years in most of the CECs and by 1 percent in Poland.

One puzzle left unresolved in these models is whatcauses increased trade in a currency union. Elimina-tion of exchange risk is an obvious channel, althoughseparate but concomitant empirical studies of the ef-fect of exchange rate volatility on trade do not unam-biguously support this hypothesis. Most estimationscontrol for membership in free-trade arrangements,so removal of barriers to trade also is not the explana-tion. Presumably, therefore, lower transaction costsand greater competition and transparency of pricesmust play the major role. Also, removing long-termexchange risk should improve the stature of CECs ascompetitive manufacturing platforms and therebypromote foreign direct investment (FDI) in tradables.

Beyond trade creation, euro adoption should pro-duce other, less well researched benefits. These in-clude lower risk premia on borrowing costs and astrong framework for policy discipline. Taking thisbroader range of considerations into account, a studyby the Magyar Nemzeti Bank concludes that euroadoption would add 0.6–0.9 percentage points to av-erage GDP growth in Hungary for 20 years. A sepa-rate study by the National Bank of Poland shows es-timates for Poland at about half this range.

These gains are realized at the expense of relin-quishing monetary policy as a stabilization tool. Thiscost can be assessed in several ways. Through mea-sures such as business cycle correlations, shares of in-traindustry trade in total, and comparisons of sectoralcompositions of output, traditional optimum currencyarea (OCA) criteria capture a country’s susceptibilityto real shocks that are asymmetric to those in the cur-rency union (see Section III, “How Do the CECsStack Up on the OCA Criteria?”). These measuressuggest how often euro-area monetary policy is likelyto be out of sync with the cyclical needs of the CECs.Other OCA criteria focus on the scope for adapting toshocks without monetary policy—especially throughwage and price flexibility, but also through counter-cyclical fiscal policy. A difficulty in assessing OCAcriteria is possible endogeneity, which would makehistory a poor guide. Frankel and Rose (1996) presentevidence that entering a currency union starts pro-cesses that alter the structure of an economy, makingit less susceptible and more adaptable to asymmetricshocks. Krugman and Venables (1996), however, arguethat economic integration creates incentives to exploiteconomies of scale, resulting in greater specializationand exposure to asymmetric shocks. With this debate

3

unresolved, historical data suggest that on OCA crite-ria the CECs are at least as well-suited to euro-areamembership as existing noncore euro-area members.

Also important to assessing the cost of losingmonetary policy independence is the value of theexchange rate as a shock absorber. Concretely, arethe effects on output growth of the most commonshocks a country experiences best countered by ex-change rate changes (real demand shocks) or fluctua-tions in reserves (monetary and financial shocks)?And, given the nature of shocks, have actual ex-change rate movements been effective in absorbingshocks? Empirical work presented in Section III(“How Useful Is the Exchange Rate as a Shock Ab-sorber?”) concludes that the largest share of shocksin the CECs has been monetary or financial in origin;thus, losing the exchange rate instrument may not beparticularly costly if other more efficient adjustmentmechanisms are put in place.

While reassuring that losing the monetary policyinstrument is unlikely to involve large costs, thesefindings do not mean that it is costless. The net costsmust take into account simultaneously the likely sizeand frequency of asymmetric shocks, the costs ofhaving to accept a monetary policy tuned to euro-area-wide rather than national conditions, and thegains from reducing exchange rate risk premia on in-terest rates and eliminating idiosyncratic exchangerate movements unwarranted by fundamentals. Thesefactors were assessed jointly in the Global EconomicModel (GEM), calibrated on the Czech Republic.2The results indicate that, for this calibration—includ-ing, for example, the nature and size of shocks andrisk premia, effectiveness of monetary policy, andwage and price flexibility—the CECs would facesomewhat greater macroeconomic volatility insidethe euro area than outside, assuming monetary policyoutside the union is technically efficient (Section III,“What Do General Equilibrium Models Say?”)3 Thelatter assumption is key: it implies, in contrast to theevidence on the effectiveness of the exchange rate asa shock absorber, that the independent pre-EMUmonetary policy successfully keeps the country onthe schedule of best-possible trade-offs between out-put gap and inflation volatility. Even accepting thisassumption, the predicted difference in volatility be-tween pre- and post-EMU outcomes for plausibleranges of the parameters is small.4

2The GEM is a general equilibrium simulation model with explicitmicro foundations, maintained by the IMF’s Research Department.

3Concretely, the concave frontier of trade-offs between thevolatility of inflation and of the output gap (the Taylor efficiencyfrontier, TEF) is further away from the origin for the country in-side, as compared with the country outside, the euro area.

4Two-thirds of inflation outcomes (output gap outcomes) wouldfall in the range of 1.2–4.8 percent (±2.1 percent of potential)under EMU compared with 1.3–4.7 percent (±1.9 percent of po-tential) under the existing inflation targeting framework.

I OVERVIEW AND POLICY CONCLUSIONS

The balance of the trade-off between gains fortrade and growth and increased volatility is ultimatelya matter of judgment. The GEM does not permit acalibration of the income or consumption equivalentof the costs of volatility—a necessary step for rigor-ous comparison with the benefits for trade and growth.Without such a single metric, interpreting the evi-dence must involve judgments about the trade-offbetween the two. Some see the risks of increasedvolatility in CECs that adopt the euro before greaterreal convergence—and by extension, they argue, syn-chronization of shocks—has been achieved as out-weighing the benefits. Others, however, argue that thepotential benefits to growth are large, and better disci-plined macroeconomic policies might anyway reducevolatility. On balance, provided the CECs adopt struc-tural and fiscal policies strongly geared toward mini-mizing overall economic volatility, our conclusion isthat euro adoption will hasten real convergence, with therisk of at most a modest increase in volatility.

What Do the CECs Bring to Euro Adoption?

The profound changes in the CECs during the pastdecade have transformed them into market economiesthat in many respects resemble the euro area. Thesesimilarities are confirmed by the evidence presentedearlier on the OCA criteria—that supply-side shocksand cyclical positions are becoming increasinglysimilar to those in the euro area while labor marketsare at least as flexible as in the euro area. Lookingahead, actions to conform to the acquis communau-taire will increase similarities, particularly in theareas of legal institutions, administrative and regula-tory systems, and, eventually, infrastructure.

Nevertheless, in a number of ways, the CECs havequite distinct macroeconomic characteristics thatwill define their experience within or outside theeuro area for some time to come (Section IV).

• Lower incomes than the euro-area countries. In-comes have been catching up at a moderatepace: annual per capita GDP growth in theCECs has exceeded that in the euro area by anunweighted average of 1.3 percentage pointsover the past five years.

• Low capital bases. Estimates of capital labor ra-tios put them at about 17 percent of the level ofGermany despite employment rates that averageabout 90 percent of the level in Germany. Thismeans that during the catch-up, moderatewages—now about 24 percent of the Germanlevel on average—and large differentials be-tween returns on investment in the CECs andeuro area should persist.

4

• Rising real exchange rates. Traded-goods sectorsare likely to continue to lead productivity growth,giving rise to Balassa-Samuelson (B-S) effects(Box 1.2). These, with other structural influences—such as relatively rapid growth of demand for non-traded goods and price deregulation—should keepinflation on the high side of the euro-area range un-less nominal appreciations occur.

• Large capital inflows. Relatively high returns on investments in the CECs will continue to attractlarge capital inflows, matched by large current ac-count deficits. The inflows will probably continueto have a heavy FDI component, but portfolio in-flows should remain robust as well. Volatility willremain a key risk. Large current account deficitswill be driven by high investment ratios and the de-pressing effects of income growth expectations onpersonal savings.

• Low bank intermediation. Bank credit to the pri-vate sector as of mid-2003 was about one-thirdof the euro-area average. Banks, largely foreign-owned in several of the countries, remain reluc-tant to lend to enterprises but are stepping uplending to households.

• Large general government deficits. ExcludingSlovenia, 2003 deficits are estimated in therange of 31⁄2–61⁄2 percent of GDP. They reflectmoderate revenue ratios but high primary currentexpenditures relative to per capita GDP. Demo-graphic profiles vary: in Slovenia and the Czech Re-public, they rival the worst in the euro area, but inHungary, Poland and the Slovak Republic they aremore favorable than in the euro area.

These characteristics point to the massive chal-lenge and intrinsic vulnerabilities the CECs will faceas they catch up to EU income levels. Joining theeuro area with the right policies in place should be asizable impetus to the catch-up. And the right policiesmust include both measures to more closely align theCECs with the euro area and strategies to addressCECs’ inherent vulnerabilities during the run-up toeuro adoption and afterward. Two specific risks tomacroeconomic stability stand out (see Section V).

• Large capital inflows, by virtue of their size alone,entail risks of volatility and speculative pressureson exchange rates. Moreover, when markets viewwide current account deficits—often the result oflarge inflows—as a signal of vulnerability and pos-sible overvaluation, large inflows can create theirown demise. The predominance of FDI in aggre-gate inflows, generally small derivatives markets,and fundamentally high rates of return on invest-ments in the CECs offer some protection from re-versals. But because CECs will be subject to mar-ket speculation about the euro adoption process as

Requirements for Successful Participation in EMU

well as exogenous contagion and bandwagon ef-fects, capital account volatility is highly probable(Section V, “Capital Account Volatility”). MostCECs have managed such vulnerabilities at least inpart through exchange rate flexibility; this has ex-plicitly shifted risks from exchange rate changes tomarket participants and prevented the authoritiesfrom getting caught on one side of speculativepressures.

• Credit and demand booms are likely to be in theoffing (see Section V, “Credit Booms: Risks andResponses” and “Macroeconomic Booms”). Withactual bank credit substantially below estimatedequilibrium levels, newly privatized foreign-ownedbanks capable of improved risk assessment, andample investment opportunities (including in realestate undervalued by euro-area standards), bothsupply- and demand-side incentives for rapid creditgrowth exist. Relatively strong bank regulation andsupervision offer considerable protection from im-prudence by banks. But rapid credit growth to-gether with falling saving ratios can still produce

5

overheating, high current account deficits, andasset price bubbles.

Requirements for SuccessfulParticipation in EMU

Since participation in EMU entails the loss ofmonetary policy and long-term restrictions on fiscalpolicy, each country must consider the requirementsfor succeeding in this environment. Five elementsseem to be of central importance.

• First, fiscal deficits must be low, and rigidities fromsubsidies and formula-driven social transfers mustbe reduced. Likely persistence of volatile demandand output growth by euro-area standards meansthat prudent debt levels for the CECs—that is, debtlevels that can be serviced without undue strains onthe economy even in slack periods—are probablyno higher than 40–50 percent of GDP. To supportthese moderate debt burdens, given likely develop-ments in real interest rates and potential growth,primary surpluses will be needed. Countries should

Box 1.2. How Large Are Balassa-Samuelson Effects in the CECs?

Catching up to the income levels of more advancedcountries is driven by productivity gains stemmingfrom increases in both capital-labor ratios and total fac-tor productivity. In general, these gains are faster fortradables—which face foreign competition and tend toattract the larger share of technology-intensive foreigndirect investment—than for nontradables. As wages inthe tradables sector rise with productivity they also bidup wages in the nontradables sector. Then, to maintainprofit margins, nontradables’ prices must increase rela-tive to those of tradables. This process is called theBalassa-Samuelson (B-S) effect.

There is strong evidence of B-S effects in transitioncountries, with three main implications.

• First, these effects raise domestic inflation relativeto what it would be without such effects. Thus, for1995–99, Cipriani (2000) finds that productivitygrowth differentials increased the price of non-tradables relative to tradables by between 0.4 per-cent (in the Slovak Republic) and 4.5 percent (inPoland) per year.

• Second, they cause appreciations—though generallyby less than the domestic relative price effects—ofthe CPI-based real exchange rate vis-à-vis an anchorcountry if the productivity growth differential islarger in the catching-up country than in the anchorcountry.1 Kovács (2002) finds that sectoral produc-

1Assuming that traded goods prices are equalized across countries,the size of the real appreciation depends on the cross-country differences

in sectoral productivity growth, shares of nontradables in domestic-consumption baskets, and relative sectoral factor intensities.

tivity differentials add between 1 percent (in Slove-nia) and 2 percent (in Hungary) per year to the CPI-based real exchange rate with Germany. That realappreciations have been larger suggests that otherfactors—such as rapid demand growth, adminis-tered price changes, previous undervaluations, orovershooting—have also been at play.

• Third, depending on the extent of nominal appreci-ations, B-S effects also result in inflation differen-tials between countries. Cipriani finds that B-S con-tributions to the excess of CEC inflation overGerman inflation range from 0.2 percentage pointsfor the Slovak Republic to 1.8 percentage points inthe Czech Republic. Mihaljek and Klau (2003) findeffects over a similar range. These results cannot,however, be extrapolated to determine likely infla-tion differentials once countries limit exchange ratemovements in ERM2 or EMU; this is because esti-mates of B-S contributions to inflation differentialsfrom periods of nominal exchange rate flexibilitywould tend to underpredict B-S induced inflationdifferentials under fixed exchange rates.

The broad conclusion from the many studies on thisissue is that B-S effects on the real exchange rate—andon inflation when nominal exchange rate flexibility iscurtailed in ERM2 or EMU—will probably be on theorder of 1–2 percent per year.

I OVERVIEW AND POLICY CONCLUSIONS

also plan to have overall fiscal deficits that providea buffer relative to the EU’s Stability and GrowthPact (SGP) deficit limit of 3 percent of GDP toallow automatic fiscal stabilizers to operate. At thesame time, fiscal policy will need to be capable ofresponding nimbly to restrain demand in the eventof credit and demand booms.

• Second, wage and price flexibility must be pro-tected where strong and enhanced where weak.For most countries, the record—reflected in thediscussion of the OCA criteria—provides somereassurance: measures of labor market flexibil-ity are at least on a par with the noncore euroarea, although, historically, indexation practicesin Slovenia are an exception. Important, how-ever, is that, while the experiences of the non-core countries in EMU have generally been sat-isfactory, conditions there are not necessarilythe right standard for the CECs, where employ-ment rates are relatively low. In fact, since noquantifiable standards exist, whether wages andprices are sufficiently flexible for successfulparticipation in a currency union is ultimately amatter of judgment.

• Third, synchronization of activity with the euroarea should be strong. Again, without a quantifiablestandard, the appropriate degree of synchronizationis subject to judgment; but the greater the synchro-nization, the less often area-wide monetary policywill be inappropriate for cyclical conditions in theCECs. Here again evidence on the OCA criteria—actual correlations of activity and indirect indica-tors of future correlations—suggests that the CECeconomies are becoming more closely linked withthe euro area.

• Fourth, financial market supervision must be strong.Rapid growth of bank credit to the private sector isalmost inevitable, regardless of euro adoption, asintermediation moves to equilibrium levels. But theeffects of euro adoption on confidence and interestrates may hasten the process. Particularly withoutthe scope for a monetary policy response, effectivebank supervision, alongside fiscal restraint, will bekey in containing the risks of asset price bubblesand overheating. The large presence of foreignbanks in the CECs makes coordination of super-vision with euro-area countries important.

• Fifth, an appropriate level of competitivenessmust be established at the outset of monetaryunion. This must be reflected first in the ERM2(Exchange Rate Mechanism) central parity andlater in the conversion rate agreed jointly with theEuropean Central Bank (ECB), European Com-mission (EC), and other member states. Down-

6

ward price or wage rigidities would make adjust-ment to an overvalued parity difficult and costlyin terms of employment and forgone growth.

The Maastricht Criteria and ERM2

Besides preparing itself for as strong a performanceas possible within EMU, each country must elaborate astrategy to meet the Maastricht criteria (see Section VI).These nominal convergence criteria formally consist offour conditions that must be assessed at a single point intime: (1) year-average inflation that does not exceed bymore than 11⁄2 percentage points that of the “three bestperforming Member States in terms of price stability”;(2) year-average nominal interest rate on the 10-yearbenchmark government bond no more than 2 percent-age points above the average in the same three countries;(3) a fiscal deficit below 3 percent of GDP and publicdebt less than 60 percent of GDP; and (4) trade of acountry’s currency against the euro without severe ten-sions within the “normal fluctuation margins” of the Ex-change Rate Mechanism (ERM2) for at least two years.5Precedents and official statements suggest that exchangerates would almost certainly be deemed stable if they re-mained within a very narrow band (for example, ±21⁄4percent of the central parity), but scope exists for veryshort-term movements below this range when exoge-nous influences are at play and more prolonged move-ments (but still well within 15 percent of parity) above it(Box 1.3). The inflation criterion also leaves room forinterpretation: the three “best performers” in the assess-ments in the late 1990s were the countries with the low-est inflation rates; but, with EMU in place, they mightrather be identified as those with inflation rates closestto the ECB definition of price stability—close to, butbelow, 2 percent.

If countries wish to ensure a successful experiencein EMU, they will want to go beyond the Maastrichtcriteria in several respects. First, structural fiscaldeficits should be reduced well below 3 percent—staff calculations suggest to about 1–2 percent—ofGDP to ensure that debt ratios are contained to pru-dent levels consistent with underlying volatility andthat deficits can be kept within the SGP norms evenin the face of cyclical weakness. Also, budget formu-lation must be flexible enough for fiscal policy toplay a strong stabilizing role. Second, demonstratingwage and price flexibility will be essential, again toensure adequate adjustment in the absence of a na-tional monetary policy. Third, the trend seen in re-

5ERM2 is an arrangement that links the currencies of prospec-tive euro-area members to the euro by establishing a ±15 percentband for exchange rate fluctuations around an agreed central par-ity. The Maastricht exchange rate stability criterion, however, isnot necessarily assessed with respect to this wide band.

The Maastricht Criteria and ERM2

cent years toward greater synchronization of activitywith the euro area must be evidently continuing.

In other respects, however, the Maastricht criteria—specifically the inflation criterion together with the ex-change rate stability criterion—could be overly bindingfor the CECs (see Section VII, “Controlling InflationWhile Stabilizing the Exchange Rate”).

• Whether the inflation criterion can be met in asustainable manner depends on its interpreta-tion. CEC inflation under the common monetarypolicy is likely to be similar to that in the catching-up noncore members—3.4 percent on averageduring 1999–2003. Thus, achieving inflation of11⁄2 percentage points above the rate in the threelowest inflation countries in the EU—some 1.4 percent in 2002—would be tougher thanmost CECs could meet in a sustainable manner.If, however, the standard for the inflation cri-terion were a rate close to the ECB inflationobjective—implying inflation targets of justunder 31⁄2 percent—it should be fully manage-able while sustaining growth at its potential,provided fiscal and structural policies were ap-propriately supportive.

• Meeting the exchange rate stability criterion willchallenge present risk management strategies.

7

Until they enter ERM2, the CECs, with estab-lished records of open capital accounts, can con-tinue to rely on exchange rate flexibility andminimal official intervention in foreign ex-change markets to discourage the private sectorfrom taking excessive unhedged foreign ex-change exposures and protect central banksfrom being caught on one side of speculativepressures. Once in the euro area, the commoncurrency itself will protect from destabilizing ef-fects of capital account volatility. But duringERM2, when free floating will not be possible,choosing an interim monetary framework thatsupports the central parity but also encompassesappropriate risk management features will re-quire careful consideration of the options underERM2.

ERM2 is designed to be a testing ground. The phi-losophy underlying ERM2 is that managing the ex-change rate within a ±15 percent band, which iseventually narrowed to a smaller margin around anannounced central parity, tests policy consistencyand the appropriateness of the central parity as a per-manent rate. In this view, stable exchange marketconditions are essential proof that the central parityis the right rate at which to irrevocably convert to theeuro and that policies are sufficient to support that

Box 1.3. Exchange Rate Criterion

Considerable debate has surrounded the question ofhow the exchange rate stability criterion will be inter-preted for ERM2 participants. Three main pieces of in-formation are relevant.

• First, ERM2 permits exchange rate fluctuationswithin a ±15 percent band around the central parityagainst the euro. This requirement differs from theexchange rate stability criterion, which requires“observation of normal fluctuation margins pro-vided by the exchange rate mechanism of the Euro-pean Monetary System, for at least two years, with-out devaluing against the currency of any otherMember State” (Article 121(I) of the MaastrichtTreaty). In ERM, the exchange rate stability crite-rion was assessed against fluctuation margins of±21⁄4 percent against the median currency (Euro-pean Commission, 2000, Annex D).

• Second, in line with the Maastricht Treaty, prece-dents from ERM indicate that use of a wide uppermargin is possible. Specifically, the Irish pound wason average 4.6 percent above its central parity dur-ing the assessment period, with deviations peakingat almost 11 percent. The Greek drachma was onaverage more than 6 percent above its central parity

during its participation in the ERM/ERM2, and themaximum deviation reached 9 percent. Both centralparities were revalued (by 3 and 31⁄2 percent, re-spectively) shortly before conversion. There werefew tests of flexibility on the lower margin, al-though France was assessed to have met the crite-rion even though it slightly breached 21⁄4 percentbelow parity on two successive days.

• Third, recent official statements reaffirm the valid-ity of these precedents. For example, a senior ECBofficial recently stated that “assessment of the ex-change rate stability against the euro will focus onthe exchange rate being close to the central ratewhile also taking into account factors that mayhave led to an appreciation, in line with what wasdone in the past” (Padoa-Schioppa, 2004).

On balance, a close reading would suggest that ex-change rates would almost certainly be judged stable ifthey remained within ±21⁄4 percent of parity. Appreciationsabove this (but well within 15 percent of the ERM2 band)would be allowed in some cases. Larger deviations wouldalso likely be accepted if they were judged to stem fromevents beyond the authorities’ control.

I OVERVIEW AND POLICY CONCLUSIONS

rate. In addition, the central parity, especially duringthe final approach to euro adoption, will be a center-ing influence on the market.

This perspective contrasts with the view that mon-etary policy frameworks should be instruments ofrisk management in emerging markets. Here, emerg-ing markets are seen as essentially vulnerable to ex-change rate changes through the interaction of twofeatures. First, exchange rates are subject to influ-ences such as contagion, shifts between multipleequilibria, and herd behavior that are distinct fromfundamentals, though not always identifiably so.Second, incentives for building up open foreign ex-change positions (for example, interest rate differen-tials that motivate unhedged foreign currency bor-rowing) mean that exchange rate changes can havelarge destabilizing effects. Monetary policy frame-works need to incorporate an active defense againstthese risks: inflation targeting, where the exchangerate floats, at least potentially, over a wide range, ex-plicitly transfers exchange risk to the private sector;and hard pegs both reduce, by forgoing discretion,and shift risk from the exchange rate to interest rates.In this view, between these “corner solutions” theoptions—especially ones that entail narrow exchangerate bands—provide ambiguous signals about howmarket pressures will be met, do not sufficiently dis-courage open foreign exchange positions, and invitemarket tests of the rate. A challenge for the CECs isto devise monetary policy frameworks that both pro-vide the protection of the “corner solutions” andpermit countries to meet the exchange rate stabilitycriterion.

Strategies for Meeting the Maastricht Criteria

The CECs will need well-planned policy strategiesto meet the Maastricht criteria as they stand (SectionVII). The centerpieces of the policy frameworks willbe fiscal actions and plans, efforts to secure low in-flation while enhancing price and wage flexibility,reasonable central parities, and monetary policyframeworks that embody a strategy for managingmarket risks. These must be coordinated with deci-sions on when to enter ERM2 and how long a stay toplan for.

Fiscal positions will be the bellwether of the seri-ousness of each country’s commitment to adoptingthe euro. Framing targets, demonstrating progresstoward meeting them, and articulating a coherentmedium-term plan will be essential. Targets shouldbe conservative. Calculations of the cyclical sensitiv-ity of each country’s budget and of the recent historyof cyclical swings in growth suggest that countries

8

should aim for a substantial margin—on the order of1–2 percent of GDP—between their deficit targetand the Maastricht ceiling of 3 percent of GDP (seeSection VII, “Taming Fiscal Deficits”). This marginwill ensure that adverse cyclical developments, eitherbefore euro adoption or immediately afterward, do notlead to breaches of the limits of the SGP. It wouldalso be consistent with debt ratios in the range of40–50 percent of GDP, levels that would be safe withthe volatility of revenues and rigidities in expendi-tures that characterize the CECs. Moreover, fiscalpolicy will be a critical defense against unwanted ef-fects of credit and demand booms; deficits willtherefore need to be reined in even more tightly in theevent of these threats to macroeconomic stability.

Attention to the structure of the fiscal adjustmentwill be critical. The short-term effects of the adjust-ment will be depressing, although these are likely tobe at least partially offset by other stimuli, such asrapid credit expansion and/or strong growth of ex-port markets. Most important, however, carefulstructuring of the adjustment will produce longer-term supply-side benefits. A few points illustrate thenature of the adjustment requirement. After account-ing for savings on debt service from interest rateconvergence and the likely net budgetary impact ofEU accession, the primary fiscal adjustment relativeto GDP needed to achieve conservative fiscal positionsis likely to be about 21⁄2–43⁄4 percentage points—insome cases more than the greatest deficit adjustmentof pre-EMU member states.6 This adjustment shouldcome from restraint of current spending—in particu-lar, social transfers (which are large relative to theCECs’ per capita GDP) and subsidies. Calculationsin Section VII suggest that conservative deficit tar-gets could be reached through such expenditure re-straint while leaving tax burdens unchanged and, insome cases, even increasing already low infrastruc-ture spending. Such structural fiscal adjustmentwould also reduce rigidities in future budgeting andimprove efficiency.

Securing low inflation will be a second pillar ofthe strategy (see Section VII, “Controlling InflationWhile Stabilizing the Exchange Rate”). While infla-tion probably cannot be sustained at rates consistentwith the strictest interpretation of the Maastricht in-flation criterion, it will definitely need to be reducedto rates that do not impair competitiveness oncecountries fix exchange rates. Some of the CECs havealready achieved such rates; others have a way to go.In the former, inflation gains need to be aggressivelyprotected; in the latter monetary and fiscal policiesgeared toward reducing inflation might even need tobe supplemented with incomes policies.

6This assessment excludes Slovenia, where deficits are alreadybelow the Maastricht limit.

Strategies for Meeting the Maastricht Criteria

9

Getting the parity right will be another key part ofthe strategy (see Section VII, “Choosing Parities”).The ERM crisis in the early 1990s speaks to the im-portance of avoiding unrealistic parities and respond-ing quickly to signs of misalignment. Estimates ofequilibrium real exchange rates will indicate a rangeof possible rates; decisions on where in the range toset the parity will be part of risk management strate-gies. The adverse effects of getting the central parityand conversion rates too low (inflation and overheat-ing) are likely to be less disruptive than those of get-ting the rate too high (low growth, high unemploy-ment, and the need for price and wage cuts). Shouldmonetary frameworks make use of the wide ERM2bands, two other considerations would come intoplay: first, because tolerance within the exchange ratestability criterion for downside deviations from paritywill be substantially less than that for upside variations,the risks of market tests are greater on the downside;and second, a credible parity even more appreciatedthan the market rate would leave some room for inter-est rates to exceed euro-area levels, helping countriesto constrain inflation and possible rapid creditgrowth.

The fourth part of the strategy will be choosing amonetary framework. Ideally, countries should continueand, in some case even refine, current inflation targetingframeworks until ERM2 entry. After entering ERM2they will need to articulate frameworks that enhance thestabilizing effects of a well-chosen parity, maximize thechances of realizing the exchange rate stability and in-flation criteria, and encompass a strategy for managingrisk (see Section VII, “Monetary Policy Frameworks”).No single framework will be optimal with respect toeach of these considerations. But explicit or implicitcommitments to narrow bands—which would invitemarket tests—would be risky. Because the exchangerate stability criterion effectively rules out continuingcurrent inflation targeting frameworks, two optionswould be consistent with the CECs’ circumstances.

• The option most in the spirit of ERM2 would beexchange rate targeting with wide exchange ratemargins. Here, interest rate and fiscal policieswould aim to stabilize the exchange rate overtime at the central parity, but no explicit or im-plicit bands interior to the ±15 percent ERM2band would be set. Thus, market pressure mightinitially be allowed to move the exchange rate—even quite significantly—but subsequent fiscaland monetary policy adjustments would aim toguide it gradually back toward parity. Direct in-tervention in the foreign exchange market wouldbe minimal so as to avoid any signals of implicitbands. Inflation would be a key secondary ob-jective, but increasingly subordinated to the ex-change rate target if and as the market rate

moved away from parity. This arrangementwould rely on the magnet effect of a well-chosencentral parity when policies are fully consistentwith the parity and the market has clear expecta-tions of a conversion date. Ex ante commitmentto flexibility in interpreting the exchange ratecriterion on both sides of the parity would becritical to establishing the credibility of poten-tial exchange rate variations. Paradoxically, bar-ring exogenous disturbances, these conditionscould well, in the event, produce exchange ratebehavior in line with a relatively narrow inter-pretation of exchange rate stability.

• A hard peg—akin to a currency board arrange-ment—would be worthy of serious considera-tion if the exchange rate stability criterion isexpected to be interpreted narrowly. It wouldclearly signal the authorities’ intentions and, ifcredible, would address vulnerabilities. The pol-icy requirements, however, would be rigorous:before the peg was introduced, the fiscal deficitwould need to be reduced well below the Maas-tricht ceiling, and inflation would need to bebrought into conformity with the Maastricht cri-terion. Then, the credibility of the parity wouldbe strong, risk premia slashed, and interest rateconvergence virtually complete from the outsetof ERM2. A hard peg would, however, abandonany pretense of monetary policy control over in-flation, narrow the options for addressing anyovervaluation or pre-EMU demand boom, andshift the stability/consistency test from the ex-change rate to the interest rate.

In ideal circumstances, these two frameworkswould boil down to the same thing—rigorous macro-economic policies producing stable exchange marketconditions. The essence of the choice concerns thesignal to markets on how the exchange rate will re-spond to exogenous disturbances. Under the hardpeg, interest rates would bear the immediate brunt ofany disturbance, and under the exchange rate targetthe exchange rate would. It is precisely the absenceof such a clear signal that makes the continuum offrameworks between the two—including explicit orimplicit narrow bands—more risky alternatives.

The expected time horizon for the stay in ERM2—while never subject to any guarantees—should alsobe carefully considered. A strong argument exists forsticking to present inflation targeting frameworkswhere they are successful and shifting to a frameworkcompatible with the exchange rate stability criterionfor the minimum stay in ERM2. In this approach,countries would enter ERM2 only at the point whenthe requisite fiscal adjustment was in hand, inflationwas close to the Maastricht criterion, and the authori-ties were confident about the adequacy of wage and

I OVERVIEW AND POLICY CONCLUSIONS

10

price flexibility. This would demonstrate to markets acountry’s policy intentions and increase the likeli-hood that the parity would play a strong centeringrole. Provided policies remained on course and ECand ECB surveillance supported close communica-tion on policies, judgments on the readiness for euroadoption should hold no surprises. Proponents ofERM2 as a testing ground may see this strategy as toorushed to establish the consistency of policies withthe central parity. The essence of a short-stay strategyin ERM2, however, would be decisive implementa-tion of fiscal and structural policies that demonstrateconsistency with the euro area policy framework,thereby bolstering the credibility of monetary policyfocusing on nominal convergence.

Another strategy would be to enter ERM2 well be-fore the two-year assessment period and make use ofthe wide bands while policies are gradually broughtin line with the euro-area policy framework. A clearmonetary framework—both to guide policy deci-sions and provide transparency vis-à-vis markets—would need to be defined. For some countries, a con-tinuation of inflation targeting would probably befeasible within the ±15 percent bands of an agreedcentral parity, although prompt parity changes wouldbe essential if the bands were challenged. Countriesmight, however, want to switch to some form of ex-change rate targeting that also made use of the widemargins, but directed policies toward a medium-termexchange rate target rather than an inflation target.The value of this approach would be in gaining expe-rience with a monetary policy framework that in-cluded a central parity, deviations from which wouldhelp clarify policy inconsistencies.

Such a prolonged stay in ERM2 could entail sig-nificant risks. Specifically, entering ERM2 well be-fore policies suitable for euro adoption were in placecould, by removing the urgency of a clear target datefor euro adoption, slow the mobilization of politicalsupport for needed policy changes. At the same time,without adequate supporting policies, even a wideband could be challenged: inflation targeting could—as it did in 2003 in Hungary—push the exchange rateto the edge of a band; and adhering even loosely to amedium-term exchange rate target, while markets re-mained uncertain about the timing of euro adoption,could invite speculative pressures. Alternatively, ifpolicies could be optimally aligned quickly and cred-ibly, exchange rates would likely be drawn to thecentral parity—barring any exogenous shocks—and lit-tle would be gained from delaying the benefits andsecurity of EMU participation. In essence, enteringERM2 without proper fiscal and structural policiesin place could be risky; but staying in ERM2 withthe right policies in place much beyond the requiredtwo years would unnecessarily delay the benefits ofbeing part of the euro area.

Managing the euro entry process will be a challeng-ing task. An enlarged EMU has the potential for being apositive sum game for existing and prospective mem-bers, in part because it will produce better policies andtherefore more stable conditions for all. But the risks in-herent in such a major regime change are substantial.They can be minimized mainly through good policies inthe candidate countries. In addition, strong surveillanceand timely communications on the part of the EC andECB will play an important role in winning the confi-dence of markets and enhancing countries’ efforts tosustain popular support for their programs.

* * *Several broad policy conclusions can be drawn

from the analysis.

• First, euro adoption is likely to bestow substan-tial net gains on the CECs over the long termand make them stronger, more self-reliant mem-bers of the EU.

• Second, basic requirements for a successful ex-perience in the euro area should be in place priorto euro adoption: activity should be closelyenough aligned with the euro area to minimizerisks that euro-area monetary policy will be in-appropriate to domestic conditions; alternativeadjustment mechanisms to monetary policy—specifically fiscal policy and wage and priceflexibility—must be capable of absorbing shocks;financial market supervision must be exem-plary; and conversion rates must be right.

• Third, while most CECs are in a relatively strongposition vis-à-vis wage and price flexibility andare progressing well on synchronization andbank supervision, fiscal adjustment remains akey challenge.

• Fourth, some specific characteristics of theCECs will present challenges during ERM2 andafterwards. Vulnerability to capital account volatil-ity, real appreciations, and rapid credit and de-mand growth will make the policy requirementsfor a smooth transition rigorous: fiscal adjust-ment prior to ERM2 entry must be substantialand well structured, inflation must be low, cen-tral parities must be set realistically, and mone-tary frameworks during ERM2 must incorporateadequate protection from vulnerability to capitalaccount volatility.

• Fifth, countries need to articulate clear medium-term strategies to prepare themselves for successin the euro area. These must include plans for re-ducing fiscal imbalances so as to contain debt atconservative levels, securing low inflation whileenhancing wage and price flexibility, and furtherstrengthening financial market supervision.

Strategies for Meeting the Maastricht Criteria

11

adoption, a case-by-case approach to the timingof euro adoption will be necessary.

• Finally, once the CECs have put in place strongpolicy programs, the EC and ECB will playvital roles in advising countries on their pro-grams and providing moral support for their ef-forts. Convergence reports and regular consul-tations will offer occasions to reinforce to bothmarkets and the CECs themselves the commit-ment of the euro institutions to this next step inEuropean integration.

• Sixth, medium-term plans should aim to meetthe Maastricht criteria decisively and largelyprior to entering ERM2. Vulnerabilities duringERM2 will be minimized and the anchoring ef-fect of the central parity maximized, if marketexpectations incorporate a credible entry date.Credibility, however, will be directly related tothe strength of measures in place at the time ofERM2 entry.

• Seventh, since each country will need to designand build political support for a strategy for euro