50
A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality Chad Jones and Jihee Kim A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 1

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

A Schumpeterian Model of

Top Income Inequality

Chad Jones and Jihee Kim

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 1

Page 2: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Top Income Inequality in the United States and France

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 20100%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

Year

Income share of top 0.1 percent

United States

France

Source: World Top Incomes Database (Alvaredo, Atkinson, Piketty, Saez)

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 2

Page 3: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Related literature

• Empirics: Piketty and Saez (2003), Aghion et al (2015),Guvenen-Kaplan-Song (2015) and many more

• Rent Seeking: Piketty, Saez, and Stantcheva (2011) andRothschild and Scheuer (2011)

• Finance: Philippon-Reshef (2009), Bell-Van Reenen (2010)

• Not just finance: Bakija-Cole-Heim (2010), Kaplan-Rauh

• Pareto-generating mechanisms: Gabaix (1999, 2009),Luttmer (2007, 2010), Reed (2001). GLLM (2015).

• Use Pareto to get growth: Kortum (1997), Lucas and Moll(2013), Perla and Tonetti (2013).

• Pareto wealth distribution: Benhabib-Bisin-Zhu (2011), Nirei(2009), Moll (2012), Piketty-Saez (2012), Piketty-Zucman(2014), Aoki-Nirei (2015)

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 3

Page 4: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Outline

• Facts from World Top Incomes Database

• Simple model

• Full model

• Empirical work using IRS public use panel tax returns

• Numerical examples

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 4

Page 5: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Top Income Inequality around the World

2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 182

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

22

Australia

Canada

Denmark

France

Ireland

Italy Japan

Mauritius

New ZealandNorway

Singapore

Spain

Sweden

Switzerland

United States

Top 1% share, 1980−82

Top 1% share, 2006−08

45−degree line

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 5

Page 6: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

The Composition of the Top 0.1 Percent Income Share

Year

Top 0.1 percent income share

Wages and Salaries

Businessincome

Capital income

Capital gains

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 20100%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

14%

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 6

Page 7: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

The Pareto Nature of Labor Income

$0 $500k $1.0m $1.5m $2.0m $2.5m $3.0m1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

Wage income cutoff, z

Income ratio: Mean( y | y>z ) / z

2005

1980

Equals 1

1−ηif Pareto...

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 7

Page 8: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Pareto Distributions

Pr [Y > y] =

(y

y0

)−ξ

• Let S(p) = share of income going to the top p percentiles,

and η ≡ 1/ξ be a measure of Pareto inequality:

S(p) =

(100

p

)η−1

If η = 1/2, then share to Top 1% is 100−1/2 ≈ .10

If η = 3/4, then share to Top 1% is 100−1/4 ≈ .32

• Fractal: Let S(a) = share of 10a’s income going to top a:

S(a) = 10η−1

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 8

Page 9: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Fractal Inequality Shares in the United States

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 201015

20

25

30

35

40

45

S(1)

S(.1)

S(.01)

Year

Fractal shares (percent)

From 20% in 1970 to 35% in 2010

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 9

Page 10: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

The Power-Law Inequality Exponent η, United States

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 20100.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

0.45

0.5

0.55

0.6

0.65

η(1)

η(.1)

η(.01)

Year

1 + log10

(top share)

η rises from .33 in 1970 to .55 in 2010

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 10

Page 11: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Skill-Biased Technical Change?

• Let xi = skill and w = wage per unit skill

yi = wxαi

• If Pr [xi > x] = x−1/ηx , then

Pr [yi > y] =( y

w

)−1/ηy

where ηy = αηx

• That is yi is Pareto with inequality parameter ηy

SBTC (↑ w) shifts distribution right but ηy unchanged.

↑α would raise Pareto inequality...

This paper: why is x ∼ Pareto, and why ↑α

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 11

Page 12: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

A Simple Model

Cantelli (1921), Steindl (1965), Gabaix (2009)

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 12

Page 13: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Key Idea: Exponential growth w/ death ⇒ Pareto

TIME

INCOME

Initial

Creative

destructionExponential

growth

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 13

Page 14: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Simple Model for Intuition

• Exponential growth often leads to a Pareto distribution.

• Entrepreneurs

New entrepreneur (“top earner”) earns y0

Income after x years of experience:

y(x) = y0eµx

• Poisson “replacement” process at rate δ

Stationary distribution of experience is exponential

Pr [Experience > x] = e−δx

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 14

Page 15: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

What fraction of people have income greater than y?

• Equals fraction with at least x(y) years of experience

x(y) =1

µlog

(y

y0

)

• Therefore

Pr [Income > y] = Pr [Experience > x(y)]

= e−δx(y)

=

(y

y0

)−

δ

µ

• So power law inequality is given by

ηy =µ

δ

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 15

Page 16: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Intuition

• Why does the Pareto result emerge?

Log of income ∝ experience (Exponential growth)

Experience ∼ exponential (Poisson process)

Therefore log income is exponential

⇒ Income ∼ Pareto!

• A Pareto distribution emerges from exponential growthexperienced for an exponentially distributed amount of time.

Full model: endogenize µ and δ and how they change

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 16

Page 17: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Why is experience exponentially distributed?

• Let F (x, t) denote the distribution of experience at time t

• How does it evolve over discrete interval ∆t?

F (x, t+∆t)− F (x, t) = δ∆t(1− F (x, t))︸ ︷︷ ︸

inflow from above x

− [F (x, t)− F (x−∆x, t)]︸ ︷︷ ︸

outflow as top folks age

• Dividing both sides by ∆t = ∆x and taking the limit

∂F (x, t)

∂t= δ(1− F (x, t))−

∂F (x, t)

∂x

• Stationary: F (x) such that∂F (x,t)∂t = 0. Integrating gives the

exponential solution.

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 17

Page 18: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

The Model

– Pareto distribution in partial eqm– GE with exogenous research– Full general equilibrium

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 18

Page 19: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Entrepreneur’s Problem

Choose et to maximize expected discounted utility:

U(c, ℓ) = log c+ β log ℓ

ct = ψtxt

et + ℓt + τ = 1

dxt = µ(et)xtdt+ σxtdBt

µ(e) = φe

x = idiosyncratic productivity of a variety

ψt = determined in GE (grows)

δ = endogenous creative destruction

δ = exogenous destruction

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 19

Page 20: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Entrepreneur’s Problem – HJB Form

• The Bellman equation for the entreprenueur:

ρV (xt, t) = maxet

logψt+ log xt + β log(Ω− et) +E[dV (xt, t)]

dt

+(δ + δ)(V w(t)− V (xt, t))

where Ω ≡ 1− τ

• Note: the “capital gain” term is

E[dV (xt, t)]

dt= µ(et)xtVx(xt, t) +

1

2σ2x2tVxx(xt, t) + Vt(xt, t)

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 20

Page 21: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Solution for Entrepreneur’s Problem

• Equilibrium effort is constant:

e∗ = 1− τ −1

φ· β(ρ+ δ + δ)

• Comparative statics:

↑τ ⇒↓e∗: higher “taxes”

↑φ⇒↑e∗: better technology for converting effort into x

↑δ or δ ⇒↓e∗: more destruction

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 21

Page 22: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Stationary Distribution of Entrepreneur’s Income

• Unit measure of entrepreneurs / varieties

• Displaced in two ways

Exogenous misallocation (δ): new entrepreneur → x0.

Endogenous creative destruction (δ): inherit existingproductivity x.

• Distribution f(x, t) satisfies Kolmogorov forward equation:

∂f(x, t)

∂t= −δf(x, t)−

∂x[µ(e∗)xf(x, t)] +

1

2·∂2

∂x2[σ2x2f(x, t)

]

• Stationary distribution limt→∞ f(x, t) = f(x) solves∂f(x,t)∂t = 0

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 22

Page 23: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

• Guess that f(·) takes the Pareto form f(x) = Cx−ξ−1 ⇒

ξ∗ = −µ∗

σ2+

√(µ∗

σ2

)2

+2 δ

σ2

µ∗ ≡ µ(e∗)−1

2σ2 = φ(1− τ)− β(ρ+ δ∗ + δ)−

1

2σ2

• Power-law inequality is therefore given by

η∗ = 1/ξ∗

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 23

Page 24: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Comparative Statics (given δ∗)

η∗ = 1/ξ∗, ξ∗ = −µ∗

σ2+

√(µ∗

σ2

)2

+2 δ

σ2

µ∗ = φ(1− τ)− β(ρ+ δ∗ + δ)−1

2σ2

• Power-law inequality η∗ increases if

↑φ: better technology for converting effort into x

↓ δ or δ: less destruction

↓ τ : Lower “taxes”

↓ β: Lower utility weight on leisure

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 24

Page 25: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Luttmer and GLLM

• Problems with basic random growth model:

Luttmer (2011): Cannot produce “rockets” like Google orUber

Gabaix, Lasry, Lions, and Moll (2015): Slow transitiondynamics

• Solution from Luttmer/GLLM:

Introduce heterogeneous mean growth rates: e.g. “high”versus “low”

Here: φH > φL with Poisson rate p of transition (H → L)

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 25

Page 26: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Pareto Inequality with Heterogeneous Growth Rates

η∗ = 1/ξH, ξH = −µ∗

H

σ2+

√(µ∗

H

σ2

)2

+2 (δ + p)

σ2

µ∗H= φH(1− τ)− β(ρ+ δ∗ + δ)−

1

2σ2

• This adopts Gabaix, Lasry, Lions, and Moll (2015)

• Why it helps quantitatively:

φH: Fast growth allows for Google / Uber

p: Rate at which high growth types transit to low growth

types raises the speed of convergence = δ + p.

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 26

Page 27: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Growth and Creative Destruction

Final output Y =(∫ 1

0 Yθi di

)1/θ

Production of variety i Yi = γntxαi Li

Resource constraint Lt +Rt + 1 = N , Lt ≡∫ 10 Litdi

Flow rate of innovation nt = λ(1− z)Rt

Creative destruction δt = nt

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 27

Page 28: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Equilibrium with Monopolistic Competition

• Suppose R/L = s where L ≡ N − 1.

• Define X ≡∫ 10 xidi =

x0

1−η . Markup is 1/θ.

Aggregate PF Yt = γntXαL

Wage for L wt = θγntXα

Profits for variety i πit = (1− θ)γntXαL(xi

X

)∝ wt

(xi

X

)

Definition of ψt ψt = (1− θ)γntXα−1L

Note that ↑η has a level effect on output and wages.

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 28

Page 29: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Growth and Inequality in the s case

• Creative destruction and growth

δ∗ = λR = λ(1− z)sL

g∗y = n log γ = λ(1− z)sL log γ

• Does rising top inequality always reflect positive changes?

No! ↑ s (more research) or ↓ z (less innovation blocking)

Raise growth and reduce inequality via ↑creativedestruction.

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 29

Page 30: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Endogenizing Research

and Growth

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 30

Page 31: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Endogenizing s = R/L

• Worker:

ρV w(t) = logwt +dV W (t)

dt

• Researcher:

ρV R(t) = log(mwt) +dV R(t)

dt+ λ

(E[V (x, t)]− V R(t)

)

+ δR(V (x0, t)− V R(t)

)

• Equilibrium: V w(t) = V R(t)

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 31

Page 32: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Stationary equilibrium solution

Drift of log x µ∗H= φH(1− τ)− β(ρ+ δ∗ + δ)− 1

2σ2H

Pareto inequality η∗ = 1/ξ∗, ξ∗ = − µ∗

H

σ2

H

+

√(µ∗

H

σ2

H

)2+ 2 (δ+p)

σ2

H

Creative destruction δ∗ = λ(1− z)s∗L

Growth g∗ = δ∗ log γ

Research allocation V w(s∗) = V R(s∗)

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 32

Page 33: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Varying the x-technology parameter φ

0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.70

0.25

0.50

0.75

1

POWER LAW INEQUALITYGROWTH RATE (PERCENT)

0

1

2

3

4

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 33

Page 34: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Why does ↑φ reduce growth?

• ↑φ⇒↑e∗ ⇒↑µ∗

• Two effects

GE effect: technological improvement ⇒economy moreproductive so higher profits, but also higher wages

Allocative effect: raises Pareto inequality (η), so xi

X is

more dispersed ⇒E log πi/w is lower. Risk averseagents undertake less research.

• Positive level effect raises both profits and wages. Riskierresearch ⇒ lower research and lower long-run growth.

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 34

Page 35: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

How the model works

• ↑φ raises top inequality, but leaves the growth rate of theeconomy unchanged.

Surprising: a “linear differential equation” for x.

• Key: the distribution of x is stationary!

• Higher φ has a positive level effect through higher inequality,raising everyone’s wage.

But growth comes via research, not through x...

Lucas at “micro” level, Romer/AH at “macro” level

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 35

Page 36: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Growth and Inequality

• Growth and inequality tend to move in opposite directions!

• Two reasons

1. Faster growth ⇒more creative destruction

Less time for inequality to grow

Entrepreneurs may work less hard to grow market

2. With greater inequality, research is riskier!

Riskier research ⇒ less research ⇒ lower growth

• Transition dynamics ⇒ambiguous effects on growth inmedium run

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 36

Page 37: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Possible explanations: Rising U.S. Inequality

• Technology (e.g. WWW)

Entrepreneur’s effort is more productive ⇒↑η

Worldwide phenomenon, not just U.S.

Ambiguous effects on U.S. growth (research is riskier!)

• Lower taxes on top incomes

Increase effort by entrepreneur’s ⇒↑η

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 37

Page 38: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Possible explanations: Inequality in France

• Efficiency-reducing explanations

Delayed adoption of good technologies (WWW)

Increased misallocation (killing off entrepreneurs morequickly)

• Efficiency-enhancing explanations

Increased subsidies to research (more creativedestruction)

Reduction in blocking of innovations (more creativedestruction)

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 38

Page 39: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Micro Evidence

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 39

Page 40: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Overview

• Geometric random walk with drift = canonical DGP in theempirical literature on income dynamics.

– Survey by Meghir and Pistaferri (2011)

• The distribution of growth rates for the Top 10% earners

Guvenen, Karahan, Ozkan, Song (2015) for 1995-96

IRS public use panel for 1979–1990 (small sample)

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 40

Page 41: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Growth Rates of Top 10% Incomes, 1995–1996

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 40

1

2

3

4

5

6

1 i

n 1

00:

rise

by a

fac

tor

of

3.0

1 i

n 1

,000:

rise

by a

fac

tor

of

6.8

1 i

n 1

0,0

00:

rise

by a

fac

tor

of

24.6

ANNUAL LOG CHANGE, 1995-96

DENSITY

︷ ︸︸ ︷

⇒ µH

⇒ δ + δ︷ ︸︸ ︷

From Guvenen et al (2015)

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 41

Page 42: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Growth Rates of Top 5% Incomes, 1988–1989

−4 −3 −2 −1 0 1 20

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

Change in log income

Number of observations

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 42

Page 43: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Results

IRS IRS Guvenen et al.Parameter 1979–81 1988–90 1995–96

δ + δ 0.07 ...

σH 0.122 ...

p 0.767 ...

µH 0.244 0.303 0.435

Model: η∗ 0.330 0.398 0.556

Data: η 0.33 0.48 0.55

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 43

Page 44: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Three numerical examples

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 44

Page 45: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Three numerical examples

• The examples

1. Match U.S. inequality 1980–2007 (φ)

2. Match inequality in France (z, p)

3. Match U.S. and French data using taxes (τ)

• Why these are just examples

Identification problem: observe µ but not structuralparameters, e.g. φ and τ

Sequence of steady states, not transition dynamics

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 45

Page 46: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Parameters

• Parameters consistent with IRS panel:

φ ≈ 0.5 ⇒ µH ≈ .3

σH = σL = .122

p = 0.767

q = .504 – 2.5% of top earners are high growth

• Other parameter values

Match U.S. growth of 2% per year and Pareto inequalityin 1980

δ = 0.04 and γ = 1.4 ⇒ δ + δ ≈ 0.10

ρ = 0.03, L = 15, τ = 0, θ = 2/3, β = 1, λ = 0.027, m =0.5, z = 0.20

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 46

Page 47: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Numerical Example: Matching U.S. Inequality

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 20050.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

φH in US rises from 0.385 to 0.568

US Growth

(right scale) US, η

(left scale)

POWER LAW INEQUALITYGROWTH RATE (PERCENT)

1.0

1.5

2.00

2.5

3.0

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 47

Page 48: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Numerical Example: U.S. and France

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 20050.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

p in France rises from 0.89 to 1.09

z in France falls from 0.350 to 0.250

France, η

US, η

POWER LAW INEQUALITYGROWTH RATE (PERCENT)

1.0

1.5

2.00

2.5

3.0

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 48

Page 49: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Numerical Example: Taxes and Inequality

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 20050.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

τ in France falls from 0.395 to 0.250

τ in the U.S. falls from 0.350 to 0.038

France, η

US, η

POWER LAW INEQUALITYGROWTH RATE (PERCENT)

1.0

1.5

2.00

2.5

3.0

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 49

Page 50: A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality · Top Income Inequality in the United States and France 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 0% 2% 4% 6% 8% 10% Year Income share of

Conclusions: Understanding top income inequality

• Information technology / WWW:

Entrepreneurial effort is more productive: ↑φ⇒↑η

Worldwide phenomenon (?)

• Why else might inequality rise by less in France?

Less innovation blocking / more research: raisescreative destruction

Regulations limiting rapid growth: ↑ p and ↓φ

Theory suggests rich connections between:

models of top inequality ↔ micro data on income dynamics

A Schumpeterian Model of Top Income Inequality – p. 50