54
6. Production Literature: Pindyck und Rubinfeld, Chapter 6 Varian, Chapter 18

6. Production - Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaften · ... Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 3 | Introduction •In this chapter, we will focus on the supply side. ... • The

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

6. Production

Literature:

Pindyck und Rubinfeld, Chapter 6

Varian, Chapter 18

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 2 |

Chapter Outline

• Production Technology

• Production with One Input Variable (Labor)

• Production with Two Input Variables

• Returns to Scale

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 3 |

Introduction

• In this chapter, we will focus on the supply side.

• Theory of the firm:

– How does a firm minimize costs or maximize profits with

regard to its production decisions?

– How do costs vary with production?

– Characteristics of market supply.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 4 |

The Technology of Production

• The production process

– The combination of inputs or production factors required

to produce a certain level of output.

• Factors of Production

– Labor

– Material

– Capital

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 5 |

The Technology of Production

• The Production function

– Function showing the highest output that a firm can

produce for each specified combination of inputs.

– Describes what is technically feasible when the firm

operates efficiently, i.e., when the firm uses each

combination of inputs as efficiently as possible.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 6 |

The Technology of Production

• A production function with a given technology of two inputs

is as follows:

Q = F(K,L)

Q = Output, K = Capital, L = Labor

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 7 |

Production with One Variable Input (Labor)

Amount Amount Total Average Marginal

of Labor (L) of Capital (K) Output (Q) Product Product

0 10 0 --- ---

1 10 10 10 10

2 10 30 15 20

3 10 60 20 30

4 10 80 20 20

5 10 95 19 15

6 10 108 18 13

7 10 112 16 4

8 10 112 14 0

9 10 108 12 -4

10 10 100 10 -8

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 8 |

Production with One Variable Input (Labor)

• Note that

1) with each additional unit of labor, the quantity (Q)

produced increases, reaches a maximum, and then

decreases.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 9 |

Production with One Variable Input (Labor)

• Note that

2) The average product of labor ( ), initially

increases with each additional unit of labor until

reaching a global maximum after which it decreases

with each additional unit of labor.

L

Output QAP

Labor input L

LAP

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 10 |

Production with One Variable Input (Labor)

• Note that

3) The marginal product of labor ( ), the additional

output produced with each additional unit of labor,

increases rapidly and later decreases and becomes

negative.

( , )L

Output Q F L KMP orLLlaborinput

LMP

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 11 |

Production with One Variable Input (Labor)

Total Product

A: tangent to the total product

curve with slope = MP (20)

B: slope of 0B = AP (20)

C: slope of 0C= MP & AP

Labor per month

Output

per

month

60

112

0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1

A

B

C

D

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 12 |

Production with One Variable Input (Labor)

Average Product

8

10

20

Output

per

month

0 2 3 4 5 6 7 9 10 1

30

E

Marginal Product

Note

To the left of E, MP > AP, and AP is increasing.

To the right of E, MP < AP, and AP is decreasing.

At point E, MP = AP, and AP is at its maximum.

Labor per month

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 13 |

Production with One Variable Input (Labor)

• The principle that as the quantity of

an input increases while other inputs remain fixed,

the resulting additions to output (marginal output) will

eventually began to decrease with each additional

unit of the respective input.

The Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns

2

2

( , )0

F K LL

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 14 |

Production with One Variable Input (Labor)

• If labor input is low, MP increases due to

specialization.

• If labor input is high, MP decreases due to inefficiency.

The Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 15 |

The Effect of Technological Improvement

Labor per time period

Output per time

period

50

100

0 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 1

A

O1

C

O3

O2

B

Even though any given

production process

exhibits diminishing

returns to labor,

labor productivity

(output per unit of labor)

can increase if there

are improvements in

technology.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 16 |

Malthus and the food crisis

• Malthus predicted that as both the marginal and average

productivity of labor fell and there were more mouths to

feed, mass hunger and starvation would result.

• Why was Malthus’ prediction wrong?

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 17 |

Index of World Food Production per Capita

1948-1952 100

1960 115

1970 123

1980 128

1990 138

1995 140

2001 161

Year Index

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 18 |

Malthus and the food crisis

• The data shows that increases in production exceeded population growth.

• Malthus did not take technological improvements into account.

• Over the past century, technological improvements have dramatically altered food production in most countries (including developing countries, e.g., India).

• As a result, the average product of labor and total food

production have increased.

• Therefore, technological improvements can create

surpluses and reduce prices.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 19 |

Malthus and the food crisis

• Question:

– Why does hunger remain a severe problem in some areas

of the world?

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 20 |

Production with One Variable Input (Labor)

• Labor Productivity

total outputAverage Productivity

total labor input

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 21 |

Production with One Variable Input (Labor)

• Productivity and the standard of living

– Consumers—in the aggregate—can only increase their

rate of consumption in the long run by increasing the total

amount they produce. Understanding the causes of

productivity growth is an important area of research in

economics.

– Determinants of productivity of labor

Stock of capital

Technological change

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 22 |

Labor Productivity in Developed Countries

1960-1973 4.70 3.98 7.86 2.84 2.29

1974-1982 1.73 2.28 2.29 1.53 0.22

1983-1991 1.50 2.07 2.64 1.57 1.54

1992-2001 0.86 2.10 1.19 1.98 2.00

Annual Growth Rate of Labor (%)

FR D J UK US

$62.461 $66.369 $52.848 $52.499 $75.575

GDP PER CAPITA (IN 2001 US DOLLARS)

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 23 |

Production with Two Variable Inputs

• There is a relationship between production and

productivity.

• Both labor and capital are variable in the long run.

• Analyze isoquants and compare the different combinations

of K & L and the respective quantities produced.

• Do you see similarities to indifference curves?

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 24 |

The Isoquants

• Isoquants show the flexibility that firms have when

making production decisions: they can usually obtain a

particular output by substituting one input for another.

• This information allows the producer to react

effectively to market changes for inputs, e.g., changes

in price, quality, and availability.

Input flexibility

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 25 |

The Isoquants

• Short run:

• Short-run production refers to production that can

be completed when at least one factor of

production is fixed.

• These inputs are called fixed production factors.

• Long run:

– A period of time in which all factors of production and

costs are variable.

The Short and the Long Run

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 26 |

Production with Two Input Variables (L, k)

Labor per year

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5

5

Q1 = 55

The isoquants are derived from the

production function for a quantity

produced of 55, 75, and 90,

respectively.

A

D

B

Q2 = 75

Q3 = 90

C

E

Capital

per year Isoquants

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 27 |

Production with Two Variable Inputs

• Substituting among production factors (inputs):

– Managers need to determine what combination of inputs

to use in order to maximize production.

– Their main concern is the trade-off between inputs.

– The slope of each isoquant gives the trade-off between

two inputs, holding the amount of goods constant.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 28 |

Production with Two Variable Inputs

Substituting among production factors (inputs):

– The marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS):

Ä /Änderung des ArbeitskräfteeinesatzesGRTS - nderung des Kapitaleinsatzes

(for a fixed level )

or

KMRTS QL

dKMRTSdL

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 29 |

Marginal rate of technical substitution

Labor per month

1

2

3

4

1 2 3 4 5

5 Capital

per year Like indifference curves,

isoquants are negatively sloped

and convex.

1

1

1

1

2

1

2/3

1/3

Q1 =55

Q2 =75

Q3 =90

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 30 |

Production with Two Input Variables

1) Increasing labor from 1 to 5 leads to a decrease in MRTS from 2 to 1/3.

2) The diminishing MRTS occurs due to decreasing marginal returns, which implies that isoquants are convex.

3) The MRTS and the marginal product

The result of a change in labor resulting from a

change in the quantity of goods is equal to

L(MP )( L)

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 31 |

Production with Two Input Variables

• Note:

3) The MRTS and the marginal product

• The result of a change in the quantity of

goods resulting from a change in the quantity

of capital is equal to

K(MP )( K)

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 32 |

Production with Two Input Variables

• Note:

3) The MRTS and the marginal product

If quantity is fixed ( ) and labor input

increases, then

L K(MP )( L) (MP )( K) 0

L K(MP ) / (MP ) - ( K / L) MRTS

0Q

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 33 |

Production with Two Input Variables

• Or also

( , ) ( , )0

0L K

L

K

F K L F K LdL dK

L K

MP dL MP dK

MP dK MRTSMP dL

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 34 |

Marginal rate of technical substitution

• Cobb-Douglas-Technology:

ba LK)L,K(FQ

Thus, ba LaK

K

F 1

.LbK

L

F ba 1

and

The marginal rate of technical substitution is

.aL

bK

LaK

LbK

K/F

L/F

dL

dKba

ba

1

1

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 35 |

Isoquants when Inputs are perfect Substitutes

Labor

per month

Capital

per

month

Q1 Q2 Q3

A

B

C

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 36 |

Fixed-proportions production function (perfect complements)

Labor per month

Capital per

month

L1

C1 Q1

Q2

Q3

A

B

C

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 37 |

Example: A Production Function for Wheat

• Farmers must choose between a capital-intensive and

labor-intensive production function.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 38 |

Isoquants describing the Production of Wheat

Labor

(hours per year)

Capital

(machine

hours per

year)

250 500 760 1000

40

80

120

100

90

Output = 13,800 Bushels

per year

A

B 10- K

260 L

Point A is more capital-intensive.

Point B is more labor-intensive.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 39 |

Isoquants describing the Production of Wheat

• Note

1) For production in A

L = 500 hours and K = 100 machine hours).

2) For production in A

If we increase L to 760 and decrease K to 90, then

𝑀𝑅𝑇𝑆 = −

Δ𝐾

Δ𝐿= −

10

260= 0.04

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 40 |

Isoquants describing the Production of Wheat

• Note

3) MRTS < 1, this means that the cost for labor is less than that of capital, otherwise we would have replaced labor with capital.

4) If labor is costly, then the farmer will substitute labor for more capital (e.g., in the USA).

5) If labor is cheap, then the farmer will substitute his capital for more labor (e.g., in India).

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 41 |

Returns to Scale

• Returns to scale: rate at which output increases as inputs

increase proportionately.

1) Increasing returns to scale: situation in which output

more than doubles when all inputs are doubled.

A larger quantity of goods is associated with lower

costs (cars).

One company is more efficient than many companies

(public utilities).

The distance between the isoquants becomes

smaller.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 42 |

Returns to Scale

Labor (hours)

Capital

(machine

hours)

10

20

30

Increasing returns to scale: the

isoquants move closer together as

inputs increase along line A.

5 10

2

4

0

A

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 43 |

Returns to Scale

2) Constant returns to scale: Situation in which output doubles when all inputs are doubled.

Size does not affect productivity.

There may be a large number of producers.

The distance between the isoquants is constant.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 44 |

Returns to Scale

Labor (hours)

Capital

(machine

hours)

Constant returns to

scale: isoquants are

equally spaced,

since output

increases

proportionally.

10

20

30

15 5 10

2

4

0

A

6

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 45 |

Returns to Scale

3) Decreasing returns to scale: Situation in which output less than doubles when all inputs are doubled.

Efficiency decreases as size increases.

Reduces the firm’s production abilities.

The distance between the isoquants increases.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 46 |

Returns to Scale

Labor (hours)

Capital

(machine

hours)

Decreasing returns to

scale: the distance

between the isoquants

increases.

10

20

30

5 20

2

8

0

A

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 47 |

Returns to Scale: Formula

For an input bundle, (K,L), we have the following:

( , ) ( , )F tK tL tF K L

Then we can say that this function has constant returns to

scale.

Example: t = 2; doubling the input leads to doubling the

output.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 48 |

Returns to Scale: Formula

For an input bundle, (K,L), we have the following:

( , ) ( , )F tK tL tF K L

We can say that this function has increasing returns to

scale.

Example: t = 2; doubling the input leads to more than double

the output.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 49 |

Returns to Scale: Formula

For an input bundle, (K,L), we have the following:

( , ) ( , )F tK tL tF K L

Then we can say that this function has decreasing returns

to scale.

Example: t = 2; doubling the input leads to less than

double the output.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 50 |

Returns to Scale

y = f(x)

x

y

Decreasing returns

to scale

Increasing

returns to scale

A technology can have—locally—different returns to scale.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 51 |

Returns to Scale, Cobb-Douglas

a bQ K L

Cobb-Douglas Production function:

Increase all input quantities proportionately by t:

( ) ( )

.

a b

a b a b

a b a b

a b

tK tL

t t K L

t K L

t Q

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 52 |

Returns to Scale

The Cobb-Douglas Production function is

.LKQ ba

.Qt)tL()tK( baba

The returns to scale of a Cobb-Douglas

technology are constant when a + b = 1,

increasing when a + b > 1, and decreasing when

a + b < 1.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 53 |

Concluding Remarks

• A production function describes the maximum output that a

company can produce given any particular input

combination.

• An isoquant is a curve representing all input combinations

with which a given level of output can be achieved.

| 23.05.2017 | Prof. Dr. Kerstin Schneider| Chair of Public Economics and Business Taxation | Microeconomics| Chapter 6 Slide 54 |

Concluding Remarks

• The average product of labor measures the productivity of

the average unit of labor, whereas the laborer's marginal

product measures the productivity of the last added unit of

labor.

• The law of decreasing marginal returns states that the

marginal product of an input ultimately decreases as its

quantity increases, ceteris paribus.

• Isoquants are always negatively sloped, because the

marginal product of all inputs is positive.