11-Saif-Tag_02

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/2/2019 11-Saif-Tag_02

    1/18

    Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 1, No. 1 (1991),pp . 49-66

    RISK AVER SION, MORAL HAZARDAND FINAN CIAL ISLAMIZATION POLICY

    Seif I . TA G EL-DINRiyadh , Saudi Arabia

    1. IntroductionAmong the major challenges facing the advocates of Islamic economicreforms, is the issue of Islamizing the financial systems of modern Muslimsocieties. The fundamental Islamic norm that any form of promised returnto financial capital is usury and hence prohibited, presents the Islamic systemas being purely equity-based. However, the historical experience and familiar-ity with state-supported debt instruments, which are securely embedded inbanking and financial systems, have created some misgivings in Muslim

    societies about the economic feasibility of the recent Islamization initiatives.Such misgivings lead to the apprehension that elimination of interest-baseddebt and complete reliance on risk-bearing equities, could adversely affectthe supply of investible funds leading to loss of efficiency in the financialsystem and retardation of economic growth prospects. Although that is oneof the most popular arguments raised against the replacement of debt institu-tion by an interest-free system, it has no firm theoretical basis in the literature.The issue was never a serious concern to the Western pioneers of economictheory.In the absence of a standard analytical formulation of such a view, we shallconsider an indirect implication of the mean variance portfolio choice theory,which establishes a Pareto optimal status for the Capital Market Line (CML)through utility analysis of risk-aversion. The CML stands for the institutionof lending and borrowing among the risk-averse investors, at an assumedrisk-free interest rate. It has been shown that the removal of the CML depre-sses the welfare positions of all participants, who would move towards lowerequilibria positions with purely risk-bearing securities. This indirect implica-tion is perhaps the most solid analytical exposition to be encountered in theliterature, in support of the view that elimination of debt finance could bringforth efficiency 1osses.l It is worth mentioning here that the approach adoptedby Naqvi (1986) in support of the same view relies on a rather ad-hoc mean-var-iance analysis of risk-aversion, as it makes no reference to the standard ap-proach. Similarly, Masud (1989) took no notice of the above-mentionedtheoretical implication of the mean-variance portfolio choice theory.

  • 8/2/2019 11-Saif-Tag_02

    2/18

    Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. 1, N o. 1He rather, proposed a counter theorem to demonstrate that risk-aversion onthe supply side does not matter if there is sufficient scope for risk-diversifica-tion in the market. Alternatively, he offered a thesis of 'moral hazards' toexplain the dominance of debt finance in real life. Despite the interestingchange in emphasis from the commonly held views about the influence ofrisk-aversion, the moral hazard thesis indirectly contributes to the belief thatthere are powerful behavioural norms which lead to the prevalence of debtinstitution in actual practice. It implies that the policy of Islamization is 'costly'in the sense that if a society chooses to Islamize its financial system, it wouldhave to bear a 'deadweight loss' in terms of necessary information costs toguard against the 'moral hazard' problem.

    The main objective of this paper is to critically examine the analytical basisof the proposition that removal of interest-based finance is harmful to theprocess of supplying investible funds. The possible harmful effects are eitherdue to the risk-averse nature of fund suppliers, as indirectly implied by themean-variance portfolio choice theory, or due to the 'moral hazard' problemhighlighted by Masud. We will examine both of these approaches in this paper.

    In the next section, we start with a discussion of the Pareto optimal positionfor the Capital Market Line (CML) as implied by the mean-variance theoryof portfolio choice. The discussion relates mainly to the utility analysis ofrisk-aversion with particular reference to the assumed convex curvature ofthe mean-variance indifference curves which provides support to the existenceof the CML in the Pareto optimal position. We question the theoreticalassertion due to Tobin (1958, 1965, 1974) that these indifference curves arenecessarily convex when investment returns are assumed to be normallydistributed. This discussion involves reference to Feldstein's (1969) criticismof Tobin, to show that he overlooked a crucial point in Tobin's proof ofconvexity - namely, the proof implied perfectly correlated investment returns.We highlight that the assumed convex curvature is only an analyticalconvenience and not a theoretical necessity. Hence, the associated indirectnegative implication for the Islamic system should not be taken too far. Insection three, we discuss the 'moral hazard thesis' and show its irrelevanceto the modern corporate sector and the financial choice in securities markets.The discussion also includes a critical mathematical note about Masud'sTheorem. The final section contains the summary and conclusions.

    2. The Risk Aversion Thesis2.1 Necessary Background

    The underlying theoretical framework of the standard mean-variance theoryof portfolio choice relates to an informationally efficient, frictionless financialmarket, with a community of risk-averse investors who maximize the expectedutility of their end of period wealth. The marketable securities are assumedfixed in quantity and perfectly divisible. Investors are price-takers with

  • 8/2/2019 11-Saif-Tag_02

    3/18

    S.Z. Tag El-Din: Risk Aversion. Moral Hazard and Financial Islamization Policyhomogeneous expectations, since information is assumed to be costless andavailable simultaneously to all investors. Finally, returns on securities havea multivariate normal distribution, and a risk-free security exists such thatinvestors may borrow or lend unlimited amounts at the risk-free rate. Anelaborate exposition of the theory is available in any text book on portfolioanalysis and is summarized in Figure 1below. Fama and Miller (1972) providea more formal verification of the equilibrium position, shown in Figure 1.

    Figure (1 )Equilibrium in Financial

    Capital Market

    The risk-free rate

    0 risk (a )

    The basic model consists of three main building blocks: (1)An investmentopportunity set constructed from knowledge of expected returns, and variance1covariance parameters of the marketable securities; (2 ) A set of mean-varianceindifference curves, to characterize the community of risk-averse investors;and (3) A Capital Market Line (CML), which defines all possible portfoliosconsisting of the risk-free security and the market portfolio of risky securities(p). Equilibrium is defined as the point of tangency between CML and theefficiency frontier (EF) of the investment opportunity set. As clearly shownin Figure 1, every investor maximizes expected utility by getting involved inlending and borrowing at the risk-free rate. Particularly, the portfolio holdingsof the more risk-averse (i.e. those with relatively steep indifference curves)are allocated proportionately, between the risk-free security and the riskyportfolio (p).

  • 8/2/2019 11-Saif-Tag_02

    4/18

    Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. I , No. IConsequently, if the debt institution is abolished, the welfare positions ofinvestors worsen. This is shown in Figure 2. Each investor is now maximizing

    expected utility at a lower tangential point with the efficiency frontier (EF),involving only risky securities.

    Figure 12)Welfare losses due to Removall o f CML

    return

    0 risk o

    This brief description reveals how Pareto optimality in the financial marketis lost by the abolition of debt institution (i.e. the CML). In the current debateabout the feasibility of the financial Islamization policy, this theoreticalimplication has led some people to argue that the abolition of debt institutionbrings forth efficiency losses in the financial market. As it appears, the modeldescribes the act of lending and borrowing at interest as a utility enhancingeconomic activity by exploiting convex indifference curves. The convexityproperty implies increasing risk-aversion for all participants in the financialmarket, but this is a questionable property as we shall shortly explain.2.2 A Critical Analysis

    Despite its broad range of critics in the current literature, the mean-variancetheory of portfolio choice gained popularity in the applied field of security

  • 8/2/2019 11-Saif-Tag_02

    5/18

    S.I. Tag El-Din: Risk Aversion, Moral Hazard and Financial Islamization Policyanalysis, mainly due to the computational convenience of this model.Faulhaber and Baumol (1988) consider the portfolio selection model amongthe major innovations in economics. On the other hand, various critics (e.g.Samuelson (1967); Borch (1974); Feldstein (1969); Agnew (1971); and Roll(1977)) have criticized several aspects of the theory. The criticisms of Feldsteinare particularly relevant for our analysis as they relate to the curvature ofmean-variance indifference curves. Feldstein questioned the convex curvespecification utilized by Tobin's theory of liquidity preference as behaviourtowards uncertainty (Tobin: 1958, 1965). In his critical discussion of Tobin'stheory, Feldstein attained two significant results:First, it is not true that the mean variance indifference curves are necessarilyconvex whenever investment returns are assumed to follow any two-parameterprobability distribution. Second, the portfolios formed by combining morethan one security cannot in general be ranked in terms of mean-varianceindifference curves. In other words, an analysis through m and a is not strictlypossible 'unless utility functions are assumed quadratic or probability distribu-tions are severely restricted' (Feldstein: 1969, p. 11). The first finding emergedfrom a critical analysis of Tobin's assertion (Tobin: 1958, 1965) that wheneverinvestment returns follow a two-parameter probability model, m-a indiffer-ence curves are always convex from below.While rejecting the convexity proposition in general, Feldstein acceptedTobin's assertion in case of normally distributed returns, thus remarking,'Although Tobin's proof is correct for normal distribution, for a number ofeconomically interesting distributions the indifference curves are not convex'(Feldstein: 1969, p.5). Tobin (1974), while commenting on the criticisms ofFeldstein and Borch, re-asserted the downward convexity property in case ofnormally distributed returns, and emphasized the analytical convenience ofthe normal distribution in the theory of portfolio analysis.

    The downward convexity property of the m-a indifference curves has beenderived by Tobin as a consequence of expected utility maximization wheninvestment returns are normally distributed. This theoretical assertion is bynow, often reported as an accepted text book result.2 In this paper we questionthe validity of this assertion. The issue seems to have been by-passed due tothe more recent developments and theoretical refinements of portfolio theory.Because of many implications of this assertion, the issue deserves anothercritical review. We will attempt to show that even when investment returnsare assumed to be normally distributed, the m-a indifference curves may takea number of possible shapes and not necessarily the convex one. The convexspecification is commonly accepted only as an analytical convenience. It isshown that Tobin's proof of convexity implies pairwise perfectly correlatedinvestment returns in the mean-variance space. Surprisingly this obviousmathematical point went unnoticed by earlier critics.

  • 8/2/2019 11-Saif-Tag_02

    6/18

    Review of Islamic Economics, Vol. I , N o. 12.3 Indifference Curves and Correlated Returns

    T he main po int n oted by Feldstein in his critical discussion of Tobin 's the oryof liquidity preference was that: Not every two-parameter probability modelcan be cast into the standard normal form (i.e. z = (x-m)/o), as implied byTobin's proof for the convexity assertion about m -o indifference curves. T hisclearly explains Feldstein's acceptance of the proof in case of normallydistributed investment returns. H owev er, th e crucial point to no te is that evenin the normal distribution case, the validity of the proof is restricted to thecase where investment return s ar e pairwise perfectly correlated. Th is can beseen from a careful examination of Tobin's proof showing that risk avertors(i.e. th ose with declining marginal utility of m oney incom e) have convex m -oindifference curves (T obin : 1958, pp . 75-6 ). T he proof involves the followingsteps, as explained by Feldstein (1969, p.6).

    (i) Expe cted utility is defined in terms of norm al distribu tion, an d the utilityfunction U(x), asroo

    = U ( m + o z) 0 (z) dzS,where 0(z) is the standard normal density, and the cardinal utility functionfor money income U(x) is assumed to obey the Nueman-Morgensternconsistency axioms of rational choice under uncertainty.

    (ii) Declining marginal utility (i.e. U,, = < o) implies that for every 2 .

    Th us, representing risk aversion.( ii i) Let the two points (m ,o) an d ( m 1 ,a ' ) ie on th e same indifference curvefor an investor, i.e.

    (iv) T h en , from (i),(ii) and (iii), it follows tha t:u{(m+-mf) /2, (o + o' ) /2 ) Z ) > u(m , o )= u ( m l , o l )

    which implies that the indifference curve is convex from below since themidpoint {(m+ m1 )/2, (o + a f )/ 2 ) of th e straight line connecting the two points{ ( m , ~ ) ,m ',o ) lies above the indifference curve which connects these th reepoints. See Figure 3 .

  • 8/2/2019 11-Saif-Tag_02

    7/18

    S.Z. Tag El- Di n: Risk Aversion , Moral Hazard and Financial Islamization P olicy

    Figure (3 )olm'.o") > ulm.o) = u(m' ,o ' )

    return I

    2.3.1 Indeterminacy of the Convexity AssertionIt is immediately noticeable from step (ii) above that the three points{ ( m , ~ ) ;m' + o t ) ; ((m+m1)/2, (o+o1)/2)), correspond to three pair-wise perfectly correlated return variables, (X,Xr and Xu), defined in termsof the same standard normal variable Z, as:

    That is a(X, X') = o(X, X") = o(X1,X ) = 1 (9)from the definition of correlation coefficient, e.g.o(Xt, X) = cov (XI, X) /o to , where cov (X1,X)= o'oOtherwise, if the three points in the (m,o) space stand for independent ornon-perfectly correlated return variables, it will not be possible to maintainstep (ii) which is crucial for the proof. In this case the three return variablesturn out to be:

  • 8/2/2019 11-Saif-Tag_02

    8/18

    Review of Islamic Economics, Vo l. I , N o. 1Where mu= (m+mf)/2; orL(o+a')/2; and the standard normal variates Z,Z1,Z" are pairwise independent or non-perfectly correlated. The determinaterelation of step (ii), which still holds if Z" = (Z+Z1)/2will now be replacedwith the indeterminate relation of the form:

    >U(mlr, a" Z") -(1/2) U(m +a Z)