476

0521832985

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

j

Citation preview

  • This page intentionally left blank

  • Nations and Firms in the Global Economy

    This accessible introduction to the world economy and to the theory and practice of

    globalization argues that key topics in international economics cannot be understood

    without a knowledge of international business, and vice versa. It reviews and combines

    insights from both literatures and applies them to real-world issues, clearly explaining

    the main concepts of international economics and business in a uniquely integrated

    approach. Written in a lively and accessible style, this innovative textbook covers all the

    main issues, including international trade, capital mobility, comparative advantage, for-

    eign direct investments, multinational behaviour, financial crises and economic growth.

    It includes carefully selected international examples and case studies, and special interest

    boxes which clearly explain more challenging economic concepts. The companion web-

    site includes additional case studies, exercises and answers to exercises, data, illustrations

    and links to other useful websites.

    Steven Brakman is Professor of International Economics at the University of Groningen.

    Harry Garretsen is Professor of International Economics at the Utrecht School of

    Economics, Utrecht University.

    Charles van Marrewijk is Professor of Economics at Erasmus University Rotterdam.

    Arjen van Witteloostuijn is Professor of International Economics and Business at the

    University of Groningen and Professor of Strategy at the University of Durham.

  • iii

    This book is a remarkable achievement. It covers all the pressing international economic issues

    of our day in an accessible yet thorough manner. The authors adroitly combine illustrative

    data and essential theory to explain the hows and whys of trade and trade liberalisation, the

    delocation of firms and multinational activity, capital flows, currency and financial crises,

    and the role of international organisations such as the IMF and WTO. It is appropriate for

    students without an economics specialisation both at the undergraduate and non-specialists

    graduate level, e.g. MBA and Masters of Public Administration. The facts and real-world feel

    of the book make it interesting as a supplement for specialist students as well.

    Richard Baldwin, Professor of International Economics,

    Graduate Institute of International Studies, Geneva

    International trade and international business have hitherto existed in two separate worlds

    a world of nations and a world of firms in academic teaching and even in research. This

    book gives us a welcome integration of the two at the level of teaching. Students who use it

    will develop a unified vision that will benefit them in their future careers, whether in business,

    government, international institutions, or academic research.

    Avinash K. Dixit, Department of Economics, Princeton University

    This is a fascinating book with a practical approach to international economics that enhances

    our understanding of the globalisation process.

    Hans-Werner Sinn, President of the Ifo Institute for Economic Research, Munich

    This book offers a valuable integration of the economics and business aspects of globalization.

    The integrated approach makes the book a unique and valuable resource for students of

    international economics and business studies.

    Prof. Dr. Joseph Francois, Tinbergen Institute, Rotterdam, and CEPR, London

    Understanding the enormous changes taking place in the world economy requires the per-

    spectives of many different disciplines, of which international economics and international

    business are two of the most relevant. Yet until now these two fields have interacted very

    little. This new text does a superb job of combining the insights of these two complementary

    academic fields. The authors present a lucid overview of theories of international economics,

    with an emphasis on recent contributions such as imperfect competition, multinational cor-

    porations, agglomeration and financial crises. In addition they present a wealth of relevant

    and insightful case-studies from the international business literature which helps bridge the

    gap between theory and reality. Students in a range of courses will benefit from this integra-

    tion of different approaches, and researchers who want an overview of recent work in fields

    outside their own will learn a lot too.

    J. Peter Neary, Department of Economics, University College Dublin

  • Nations and Firms in theGlobal EconomyAn Introduction to International Economics and Business

    Steven Brakman

    Harry Garretsen

    Charles van Marrewijk

    Arjen van Witteloostuijn

  • cambridge university pressCambridge, New York, Melbourne, Madrid, Cape Town, Singapore, So Paulo

    Cambridge University PressThe Edinburgh Building, Cambridge cb2 2ru, UK

    First published in print format

    isbn-13 978-0-521-83298-4

    isbn-13 978-0-521-54057-5

    isbn-13 978-0-511-16099-8

    Steven Brakman, Harry Garretsen, Charles van Marrewijk, Arjen van Witteloostuijn 2006

    2006

    Information on this title: www.cambridge.org/9780521832984

    This publication is in copyright. Subject to statutory exception and to the provision ofrelevant collective licensing agreements, no reproduction of any part may take placewithout the written permission of Cambridge University Press.

    isbn-10 0-511-16099-2

    isbn-10 0-521-83298-5

    isbn-10 0-521-54057-7

    Cambridge University Press has no responsibility for the persistence or accuracy of urlsfor external or third-party internet websites referred to in this publication, and does notguarantee that any content on such websites is, or will remain, accurate or appropriate.

    Published in the United States of America by Cambridge University Press, New York

    www.cambridge.org

    hardback

    eBook (EBL)

    eBook (EBL)

    hardback

  • Contents

    List of figures page xii

    List of tables xv

    List of boxes xviii

    Preface xxi

    Glossary xxv

    Suggested course structure xxviii

    Part I Introduction

    1 The global economy 1

    1.1 Introduction 1

    1.2 A sense of time: the universe and population 4

    1.3 Income levels: GNP and GDP 10

    1.4 What is the global economy? 18

    1.5 Globalization and income 21

    1.6 Globalization and international trade 26

    1.7 Analyzing the global economy 30

    1.8 Conclusions 39

    2 International accounting practices 40

    2.1 Exciting accounting? 40

    2.2 Macro-level accounting: a countrys balance of payments 41

    2.3 Micro-level accounting: a firms annual report 47

    2.4 The importance of distinguishing between micro and macro 55

    2.5 Accounting principles as a platform 56

    Part II Firms, trade and location

    3 Trade and comparative advantage 63

    3.1 Introduction 63

    3.2 Comparative advantage: David Ricardos fundamental insight 64

    3.3 Comparative advantage versus competitiveness 69

    3.4 Comparative advantage: the neo-classical answer 72

    3.5 The closed economy 73

  • viii Contents

    3.6 Open economy international trade: the HeckscherOhlin result 78

    3.7 Factor endowments and competitiveness 80

    3.8 Fragmentation 83

    3.9 Fragmentation: an evaluation 91

    3.10 Conclusions 93

    Appendix: HeckscherOhlin algebra 94

    4 Trade and competitive advantage 96

    4.1 Trade and imperfect competition 96

    4.2 Understanding intra-industry trade: monopoly power 100

    4.3 The trading equilibrium 103

    4.4 Strategic interaction between firms: the AirbusBoeing example 107

    4.5 Monopolistic competition 110

    4.6 Trade with monopolistic competition 113

    4.7 Empirical support for intra-industry trade 116

    4.8 Conclusions 119

    Appendix 4A: strategic interaction: reaction curves 120

    Appendix 4B: derivation of the Helpman equation 124

    5 Firms, location and agglomeration 125

    5.1 Introduction 125

    5.2 Distance in economics 126

    5.3 Geographical economics 130

    5.4 The geographical economics approach: an example 133

    5.5 Geographical economics: a further discussion 136

    5.6 Multinational behaviour 139

    5.7 The boundary of the firm: outsourcing 146

    5.8 Conclusions 151

    Appendix: a more general model of multinational behaviour 152

    Part III Capital, currency and crises

    6 International capital mobility 161

    6.1 Introduction 161

    6.2 Measuring international capital mobility 162

    6.3 Issues about capital mobility 167

    6.4 Determinants, benefits and costs of capital mobility 176

    6.5 Summing up and looking ahead 180

    6.6 Policy autonomy 182

    6.7 Conclusions 188

  • ix Contents

    7 Gains from capital market integration 190

    7.1 Introduction 190

    7.2 International allocation of savings and investments 191

    7.3 The degree of international capital market integration and a puzzle 196

    7.4 Does capital flow in the wrong direction? 198

    7.5 Capital flows and risk diversification 205

    7.6 Firm investment and asymmetric information 210

    8 Investors, exchange rates and currency crises 217

    8.1 Introduction 217

    8.2 What is a currency crisis? 218

    8.3 Characteristics of currency crises 222

    8.4 First generation models 226

    8.5 Second generation models 229

    8.6 Coordination 233

    8.7 Efficiency 235

    8.8 Frequency and measurement 237

    8.9 Looking ahead 240

    9 Financial crises, firms and the open economy 241

    9.1 Introduction and terminology 241

    9.2 An asymmetric information view of financial crises 242

    9.3 Disruptions and asymmetric information 243

    9.4 A financial crisis framework 245

    9.5 Financial crises in an open economy 247

    9.6 Wake-up call and perverse savings 252

    9.7 Evidence about twin crises 256

    9.8 Bad fundamentals or malicious investors? 259

    9.9 Synthesis and conclusions: the vicious circle 261

    Part IV Policy, dynamics and organization

    10 Trade and capital restrictions 267

    10.1 Introduction 267

    10.2 Welfare effects of trade restrictions: a tariff on imports 268

    10.3 World welfare effects of trade restrictions 272

    10.4 More on protectionism 273

    10.5 Trade agreements 277

    10.6 Evaluation of the demand for and supply of trade protection 283

    10.7 Capital restrictions: the trade-off between efficiency and stability 285

  • x Contents

    10.8 The welfare effects of a tax on capital inflows 287

    10.9 The pricing of risk and the role of policy 289

    10.10 Two examples of capital restrictions: preventing crises 293

    10.11 Capital restrictions as a cure for crises 296

    10.12 Changing the international financial system? 298

    10.13 Rounding up the restrictions 300

    11 Globalization and economic growth 304

    11.1 Introduction 304

    11.2 Catching-up 305

    11.3 Production, capital and investment 307

    11.4 Empirical implications 312

    11.5 Technology, knowledge, innovation and TFP growth 318

    11.6 Open economies, TFP and economic growth 320

    11.7 An historic example: Japan 325

    11.8 A recent example: China 332

    11.9 Conclusions 335

    12 Nations and organizations 339

    12.1 Convergence or divergence? 339

    12.2 Game theory: basics and terminology 347

    12.3 An experiment 350

    12.4 HRM and cultural diversity 352

    12.5 Corporate governance and institutional diversity 359

    12.6 Recent Americanization? 365

    12.7 Conclusions 369

    Appendix: the Bertrand duopoly experiment 370

    Part V Conclusions

    13 Globalization: is it really happening? 375

    13.1 Introduction 375

    13.2 Income inequality over time 377

    13.3 Does globalization make the rich richer and the poor poorer? 378

    13.4 Low-skilled labour, trade and within-country income inequality 381

    13.5 Low-skilled labour and the irrelevance of trade 383

    13.6 Outsourcing and income inequality 388

    13.7 Developing countries and the globalization bonus 390

    13.8 Conclusions 395

  • xi Contents

    14 Towards an international economics and business? 397

    14.1 Glocalization 397

    14.2 More than macro or micro alone: multi-level interaction 402

    Bibliography 406

    Author index 426

    Subject index 430

  • Figures

    1.1 Big Bang and beyond page 5

    1.2 Development of world population over the last 2,500 years 6

    1.3 Developments in world population, 20002050 7

    1.4 Gross domestic product (GDP) and gross national product (GNP) 12

    1.5 Correction of GDP per capita for purchasing power, 2000 16

    1.6 Development of world per capita income over the last 2,000 years 22

    1.7 Advantages and disadvantages of logarithmic graphs 23

    1.8 Leaders and laggards in GDP per capita: a widening perspective 25

    1.9 Carrying capacity of European merchant fleets, 14701780 27

    1.10 Two waves of globalization 29

    1.11 Trade and market integration 31

    1.12 London external bond spread, 18701940 35

    1.13 Foreign capital stocks, assets/world GDP, 18602000 35

    1.14 Relative migration flows, Western Europe and Western Offshoots,

    18701998 37

    1.15 Traditional and globalized fragmented production processes 38

    2.1 A countrys balance of payments 42

    2.2 Current account balance, selected countries, 19702000 46

    3.1 Wages per hour and GDP per hour, 19972001, selected countries 68

    3.2 An isoquant 75

    3.3 Cost minimization 76

    3.4 Lerner diagram, goods prices and factor prices 77

    3.5 The impact of international trade 79

    3.6 Fragmentation possibility 86

    3.7 Fragmentation profitability 87

    3.8 Labour re-allocation between Home and Foreign 90

    4.1 Manufacturing intra-industry trade: high and increasing intra-industry

    trade countries 99

    4.2 Increasing returns to scale and perfect and imperfect competition 102

    4.3 A trading equilibrium: monopoly versus duopoly 103

    4.4 Intra-industry trade as a result of transportation costs 106

  • xiii List of figures

    4.5 The varieties approach of monopolistic competition 110

    4.6 Monopolistic competition, demand and costs 112

    4.7 Monopolistic competition and foreign trade pressure 115

    4A.1 Derivation of firm As reaction curve 122

    4A.2 Cournot duopoly equilibrium 123

    5.1 Monopolistic competition and the re-location of a firm 137

    5.2 Development of world GDP, foreign direct investment (FDI) and trade,

    19702000 140

    5.3 Profits in the Home and Foreign market: national exporting firm 142

    5.4 Going multinational: the horizontal case 143

    5.5 Going multinational: the vertical case 144

    5.6 Summary of the firms main decisions 145

    5.7 The effects of outsourcing on production and income distribution 150

    5A.1 Decision process and firm types 154

    5A.2 Endowment distributions in the Edgeworth Box 155

    5A.3 Characterization of market structure 156

    5A.4 Stylized impact of parameter changes for market structure 157

    6.1 Global net capital flows, average for fifteen countries 163

    6.2 Capital outflows 18601910, selected countries 164

    6.3 Net private capital flows to emerging markets, 19922000 166

    6.4 Evolution of net financing through international financial markets,

    19831998 168

    6.5 Evolution of British and American share in foreign assets, 18252000 171

    6.6 Interest rate differential, 18801994 175

    6.7 Spider web spiral: world imports, JanuaryDecember 19291933 178

    6.8 The policy trilemma 183

    7.1 Capital mobility is welfare-enhancing 192

    7.2 Capital re-allocation between Home and Foreign 199

    7.3 Firm investment, supply of funds and asymmetric information 211

    8.1 The Asian crisis: rapid drop in the value of some currencies, 19852002 218

    8.2 The Asian crisis: current account balance, 19802000 223

    8.3 The Asian crisis: developments of GDP per capita, 19902002 225

    8.4 Interest rates in Germany and Italy, 19922004 230

    8.5 Crises frequency, percentage probability per year 238

    9.1 Stylized balance sheets of firms and banks 244

    9.2 Financial crisis in an asymmetric information framework 246

    9.3 Share of $US-denominated debt, 19961998, selected countries 249

  • xiv List of figures

    9.4 Profitability of non-financial firms, emerging markets, 19922004 251

    9.5 Perverse savings and the backward-bending savings curve 255

    9.6 The unfolding of a financial crisis 257

    9.7 The vicious circle of financial crises 262

    10.1 Domestic welfare effects of imposing a tariff 269

    10.2 The world welfare effects of a tariff 273

    10.3 Predicted duration of the Doha round 278

    10.4 Customs union: trade creation 281

    10.5 Customs union: trade creation and diversion 282

    10.6 The net supply of and demand for funds 287

    11.1 France, share of income invested, 1950-2000 310

    11.2 Income levels and capital accumulation (Solow) 311

    11.3 Education and total factor productivity (TFP) in developing countries 313

    11.4 USA: GDP per capita 314

    11.5 Japan and Indonesia: GDP per capita 315

    11.6 Machinery imports and TFP in developing countries 318

    11.7 Intertemporal adjustments in Singapore, 19722001 322

    11.8 Foreign research and development (R&D) capital stock and TFP in

    developing countries 324

    11.9 A Dutch ship in Nagasaki, 1859 327

    11.10 The Japanese economy, 15001998 328

    11.11 Rapid growth in EuropeAsia trade, 15001800 329

    11.12 Multinational trade composition, Portugal, the Netherlands and England 331

    11.13 Developments in Chinese income and trade flows, 19602001 333

    11.14 China: geographic export market composition, 1997 334

    12.1 Results from three experiments: A, B and C 351

    12.2 Correlation in cultural characteristics 356

    12.3 Correlation between corruption and social economic conditions 364

    13.1 Inequality among world citizens, 18201992 378

    13.2 Growth rates in open and closed economies, 197089 379

    13.3 Income levels, growth rates and population, 19802002 380

    14.1 Chinas FDI and trade connections 404

  • Tables

    1.1 The twenty countries with the highest population and population density,

    2000 page 8

    1.2 Population projections, 20002050, the world and continents 8

    1.3 The twenty most powerful economies, 2000 13

    1.4 Assumed labour productivity, Australia and Botswana 14

    1.5 Price convergence and declining transport cost, 18701913 33

    1.6 Tariffs on manufactures for selected countries, 18201950 34

    2.1 Analytic presentation: balance of payments, 2002 43

    2.2 A firms statement of income 49

    2.3 A firms balance sheet 50

    2.4 Abstracts from the annual report of DaimlerChrysler, 2003 51

    2.5 Abstracts from the annual report of Royal Dutch Shell, 2002 and 2003 52

    2.6 Top 100 based on a salesGDP ranking, 2002 57

    2.7 Top 100 based on a value addedGDP ranking, 2000 58

    2.8 The size ranking of firms in terms of sales vis-a`-vis value added, 2000 59

    3.1 Hypothetical labour productivity: production per hour 65

    3.2 Production of cloth and wine in the EU and the USA 66

    3.3 Sign tests of factor abundance 82

    3.4 Multinationals, investment, trade and income 85

    4.1 Manufacturing intra-industry trade, 19882000 98

    4.2 AirbusBoeing strategic interaction pay-off matrix 109

    4.3 Strategic interaction pay-off matrix after Airbus subsidy 109

    4.4 Country similarity and intra-industry trade 118

    5.1 CIF/FOB ratios, 19651990 127

    5.2 Regional trade pattern of Europe, 18601996 128

    5.3 Geography of sales 134

    5.4 Transport costs 135

    5.5 FDI inflows and outflows, share in total flows 141

    6.1 Size of net capital flows since 1870, selected countries 163

    6.2 Net capital flows to emerging market economies, 19922000 166

  • xvi List of tables

    6.3 Net financing at international financial markets, 19831999, seventeen

    countries 169

    6.4 Gross financial stocks, 18251938 171

    6.5 Looking for the trilemma: estimates of 185

    6.6 Effective corporate income tax rates across the EU, 19901999 188

    7.1 Correlation between national savings and investment, 19601999 197

    7.2 The FeldsteinHorioka test 198

    7.3 Institutions and financial development 201

    8.1 Real income growth and capital account crises 225

    8.2 Median changes in private capital flows and current account 226

    8.3 Coordination of a speculative attack 234

    8.4 The incidence of global contagion, 19701998 239

    9.1 Cost of crises in lost output (relative to trend output) 242

    9.2 Developing countries: external debt and equity financing, 19972003 248

    9.3 Profitability of non-financial firms in emerging markets, 19922001 250

    9.4 Possible relationships between signals and crises 258

    9.5 Percentage of crises accurately called 258

    9.6 Ratio of short-term debt to total debt and to reserves, June 1997 260

    10.1 GATT and WTO rounds, 1947 278

    10.2 Gross capital inflow to Chile, 19881997 295

    10.3 Annual growth rate, 19701989 302

    11.1 GDP per capita, 19902000 growth projections 305

    11.2 GDP per capita growth rates per decade, 19602000 306

    11.3 GDP per capita 19602000 growth projections 307

    11.4 European output and TFP growth, 18702001 316

    12.1 Overview of multinational organizations typologies 344

    12.2 Top ten non-financial multinationals, 2003, ranked according to TNI 346

    12.3 Firm IFirm II interaction pay-off matrix 347

    12.4 Reciprocal dumping game 349

    12.5 Information, culture and trustworthiness 352

    12.6 International cultural diversity in four dimensions, index scores, 1994 355

    12.7 Corporate governance around the world 362

    12.8 Political risk diversity, 2003 365

    12.9 Effectiveness of downsizing 368

    12.10 Stock exchange reactions to downsizing announcements 368

    12A.1 Firm IFirm II interaction pay-off matrix 371

  • xvii List of tables

    13.1 Price changes, manufacturing industries 384

    13.2 Wage differentials, by education 385

    13.3 Unemployment and labour skills 386

    13.4 Changes in labour productivity, Europe and USA, 19792001 388

    13.5 Imported intermediate deliveries, industry, 19741993 389

    13.6 Institutions and economic performance 393

  • Boxes

    1.1 Purchasing power parity (PPP) corrections page 14

    1.2 Logarithmic graphs 22

    2.1 The balance of payments for Germany and the USA 42

    2.2 Annual reports for DaimlerChrysler and Royal Dutch Shell 50

    2.3 Why accounting is useful and why accounting is not explaining 59

    3.1 Wages and productivity 68

    3.2 Isoquants 75

    3.3 Empirical tests of factor abundance: Ricardo revisited? 81

    3.4 Multinationals, fragmentation and investment 85

    3.5 The economic effects of international migration 89

    3.6 The extent of the firm 92

    4.1 Intra-industry trade 97

    4.2 Alternative explanations for intra-industry trade 106

    4.3 Imperfect competition in international business: Fuji versus Kodak 108

    4.4 Models compared 114

    4.5 Competitive advantage and MNEs 120

    5.1 The relevance of transportation costs 126

    5.2 The location decision of MNEs in international business 139

    5.3 Another look at multinationals 140

    5.4 The regional bias of FDI 147

    5.5 Maquiladoras 149

    5.6 Competitive advantage and the location decision 151

    6.1 The spider web spiral 177

    6.2 EU countries and the effective income tax rate 187

    7.1 How to test for UIP 194

    7.2 The importance of institutions for financial development and growth 203

    7.3 Insurance against shocks through portfolio diversification 207

    7.4 Ethnic bias in FDI 209

    7.5 The financing of firm investment and the external finance premium 214

  • xix List of boxes

    8.1 Foreign exchange risk, hedging and multinational firms 220

    8.2 The second-generation model of currency crises 231

    9.1 Moral hazard and over-investment: an example 253

    10.1 The costs of protection 270

    10.2 The EUUSA steel conflict 275

    10.3 World Trade Organization (WTO) and General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade

    (GATT) trade rounds 277

    10.4 The politics of free trade zones: how many trade blocs? 283

    10.5 Asset/price inflation 290

    10.6 Policy options and moral hazard behaviour 291

    10.7 Political risk and the multinational firms investment strategy 296

    10.8 Trade, financial liberalization and economic growth 302

    11.1 Growth accounting and growth modelling 308

    11.2 TFP and school enrolment in developing countries 312

    11.3 TFP and imports of machinery and equipment in developing countries 317

    11.4 Foreign R&D and TFP in developing countries 324

    11.5 VOC: the worlds first multinational 329

    11.6 The PrebischSinger hypothesis 336

    11.7 A multinationals experience and performance in transition economies 337

    12.1 Cross-national culture clashes in the business world 341

    12.2 International outsourcing 343

    12.3 The case for dominant transnationality 346

    12.4 Hard institutions and soft cultures: competition or cooperation? 353

    12.5 Culture distance and foreign entry mode 358

    12.6 Delegation games and managerial compensation 360

    12.7 Institutional diversity 364

    12.8 Shareholder value, Americanization and downsizing 367

    13.1 Globalization and international labour migration 375

    13.2 A closer look at wage differentials and labour market differences 385

    13.3 Philips Electronics 387

    13.4 Lets dance to the New (International) Order (NIO) 392

    14.1 Glocalization 400

    14.2 Ceremonial adoption 401

    14.3 FDI and trade in China 404

  • Preface

    The title Nations and Firms in the Global Economy: An Introduction to International

    Economics and Business reflects our main motivations for writing this book. It con-

    tains the six core elements we address (i) introduction, (ii) the global economy,

    (iii) nations, (iv) firms, (v) international economics and (vi) international business.

    We briefly review these components and their interaction in this preface.

    Introduction Our book is an introduction to the subject, indicating that our

    target audience consists of students interested in (international) economics and

    (international) business for whom this is the first structured encounter with the issues

    discussed, who wish to get acquainted with the facts and forces of the hotly debated

    globalization process. Depending on the background of the student and the type of

    programme (s)he is enrolled in, this first encounter could be in different parts of the

    curriculum, although it will usually be in the first or second year of an undergraduate

    programme. For other interested readers, this book offers an up-to-date introduction

    to what we know about globalization, its drivers and its consequences, particularly

    from an economics and business perspective. The preliminary requirements for a

    proper understanding of our book are limited. We assume that the reader has taken

    an introductory (micro and macro) economics course, and that (s)he has some grasp

    of elementary mathematics allowing him or her to understand simple graphs and

    equations. We also provide some technical material in boxes, as quick reminders of

    essential concepts.

    The global economy We analyse the global economyor, as it is more popularly

    known: the globalization process. As this is an introduction to the global econ-

    omy, we define in chapter 1 what we mean by globalization and what we will and

    will not analyze in the sequel. Throughout the book, we provide ample empirical

    information on the globalization process so that we may distinguish between fact

    and myth. In presenting the facts, we show longer time series than most textbooks

    or popular introductions. This enables readers to place current developments into

    their proper perspective, providing a better understanding of the developments giv-

    ing rise to todays complex structure of the international economy. We address all

    the major economic components of the globalization process, both real and mon-

    etary. We discuss international trade and capital flows, foreign direct investments

    (FDI), multinational firms, exchange rates, financial crises, outsourcing, economic

    development, location and much more. In doing so, the emphasis will be more on

  • xxii Preface

    international trade and capital mobility, and less on international labour mobility,

    which reflects the fact that in economic terms international trade and capital flows

    are much more important than international labour migration, as we shall show.

    Nations A proper understanding of the globalization process necessarily looks

    at the role of nations, governments and international organizations.

    Why do nations specialize in the export of certain types of goods and services, andimport others?

    Is specialization always beneficial, or are there winners and losers from the globaliz-ation process?

    If so, who are these winners and losers? Why do governments adhere to particular policies regarding exchange rates, trade

    flows and capital mobility?

    And so on and so forth. We address these and other issues from both a theoretical

    and a practical point of view by giving many empirical examples and discussing

    numerous case studies.

    Firms In many respects, the decisions by individual (multinational) firms pro-

    duce the most important driving forces behind the globalization process, ultimately

    determining international trade, capital flows and FDI. Naturally, these firms react to

    the conditions of the economic environment in which they operate, which is deter-

    mined to a considerable extent by governments and international organizations.

    Firms therefore both shape the global environment and are shaped by it. Through-

    out the book, we discuss the forces with which firms are confronted, the competitive

    forces they unleash and how the interaction of these powers influences the firms

    organizational structure, human resource management (HRM), corporate gover-

    nance and other issues internal to the firm. Here, our focus is on the multinational

    enterprise (MNE).

    International economics To some extent, it could be argued that the international

    economics literature tends to emphasize the role of nations (and comparative advan-

    tage) rather than the role of firms in the globalization process. This is, of course, not

    entirely accurate as the role of the industrial organization and international business

    literatures, and thus the factors influencing the organizational structure of indi-

    vidual firms, is becoming increasingly important in the international economics

    curriculum. We argue, therefore, that it is becoming increasingly clear that the latter

    type of analysis complements the former. Compared to other introductory text-

    books on international economics, the primary goal of our book is not to cover the

    whole field, but to focus on those theories and insights that help us to understand

    the economic causes and consequences of globalization, as well as the role played

    by both nations and (multinational) firms. To give just one example, monetary

    policy is discussed in our analysis of international capital mobility, but we do not

    dwell on issues such as the conduct of monetary policy or the theory of monetary

  • xxiii Preface

    integration as such. We discuss such issues only if they are relevant within the con-

    text of the main theme of our book. This also means that when it comes to under-

    standing the global economy, we cover a lot more ground than other introductory

    textbooks.

    International business It could be argued that the international business literature

    tends to emphasize the role of firms (and competitive advantage) rather than the

    role of nations in the globalization process. This, too, is not entirely accurate as the

    international economic environment in which the (multinational) firm operates is

    an increasingly important part of the international business curriculum. Once again,

    the latter type of analysis complements the former, which is the reason we combine

    these perspectives throughout the book. After all, MNEs do not operate in a vacuum

    on the contrary, they must take account of all kinds of issues related to international

    economics, from exchange rate fluctuations and capital market restrictions to fiscal

    policies and labour market conditions.

    To complement the material presented in this textbook, there is a website avail-

    able providing additional information and supporting material. Its location is:

    www.charlesvanmarrewijk.nl.

    The website provides: (i) background information on the structure of the book;

    (ii) background information on the authors; (iii) additional illustrations and data

    material, such as all the figures and tables used in the book; (iv) different types of

    exercises for self-study, as well as answers to (a subset of) these exercises; (v) other

    self-study material; and (vi) updates, and links to useful other sources of information.

    The choice of posting questions on a website rather than including them in the book

    itself is motivated by the important advantage that it allows us to integrate and

    respond to recent developments in the global economics and business environment

    in the questions posed.

    Parts of this book were written during a visit by Brakman, Garretsen and van

    Marrewijk to the Department of Economics at Princeton University in JuneJuly

    2003, and during a visit by van Marrewijk to the School of Economics at the University

    of Adelaide in 2004. We are grateful to Princeton University and the University of

    Adelaide for their hospitality. In particular, we would like to thank Avinash Dixit,

    Gene Grossman and Ian McLean for making these visits possible. Moreover, we are

    grateful for financial support from the University of Groningen (Brakman and van

    Witteloostuijn), Utrecht School of Economics (Garretsen), the Erasmus University

    Trust Fund (van Marrewijk), the University of Adelaide (van Marrewijk) and the

    University of Durham (van Witteloostuijn).

    We would also like to thank Bart van Ark, Gerrit Faber Karl Farmer, Peter Kenen,

    Henryk Kierzkowski and Chris Harrison for help in finding relevant data, and for

    providing useful comments and suggestions. Steven Poelhekke provided able research

    assistance for parts of this book. Harry Garretsen would also like to thank Hans van

  • xxiv Preface

    Ees, Hans Groeneveld and Ralph de Haas for the opportunity to make use of previous

    mutual work.

    Steven Brakman

    Harry Garretsen

    Charles van Marrewijk and

    Arjen van WitteloostuijnGroningen, Utrecht, Rotterdam and

    GroningenDurham

    February 2005

  • Glossary

    ASEAN Association of Southeast Asian Nations

    BCG Boston Consulting Group

    BIS Bank of International Settlements

    boe barrels of oil equivalent

    BPR business process re-engineering

    CEE Central and Eastern European

    CEO chief executive officer

    CFO chief financial officer

    CIF cost, insurance, freight

    CIS Confederation of Independent States

    COMESA Common Market of Eastern and Southern Africa

    CPE centrally planned economy

    FDI foreign direct investment

    EADS European Aeronautic Defence and Space Company

    EFTA European Free Trade Association

    EIC East India Company

    EITF Emerging Issues Task Force

    EMS European Monetary System

    EMU European Monetary Union

    EMBI Emerging Market Bond Index

    ERM Exchange Rate Mechanism (EU)

    EU European Union

    EVA economic value added

    FOB free on board

    FSU former Soviet Union

    FTA free trade area

    GAAP Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (US)

    GATT General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade

    GCI gross capital income

    GDP gross domestic product

    GGDP Groningen Growth and Development Centre

    GNP gross national product

    HGB German Commercial Code

  • xxvi Glossary

    HRM human resource management

    IB international business

    ICP International Comparison Project (UN)

    ICRG International Country Risk Guide

    ICT information and communication technology

    IE International economics

    IFI international financial institution

    IFS International Financial Statistics (IMF)

    IMF International Monetary Fund

    IO industrial organization

    IPO initial public offering

    IT information technology

    ITC International Trade Commission (US)

    JIT just-in-time

    JV joint venture

    M&As mergers and acquisitions

    MC marginal costs

    MERCOSUR Southern Common Market

    MFN most-favoured-nation

    MITI Ministry of International Trade and Industry (Japan)

    MNC multinational corporation

    MNE multinational enterprise

    MPC marginal productivity of capital

    MR marginal revenue

    NAFTA North American Free Trade Agreement

    NIC newly industrializing country

    NIO New International Order

    NTB non-tariff barrier

    NW Net worth

    NYSE New York Stock Exchange

    OECD Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development

    OLI Ownership, Location and Internalization (Dunning)

    PPC production possibility curve

    PPP purchasing power parity

    PTA preferential trade agreement

    PWT Penn World Tables

    R&D Research and Development

    SAR special administrative region (Hong Kong)

    SDR Special Drawing Rights (IMF)

    SDRM sovereign debt restructuring mechanism

  • xxvii Glossary

    SEC Securities and Exchange Commission (US)

    SI savingsinvestment (model)

    SITC Standard International Trade Classification

    SOE state-owned enterprise

    SSA Sub-Saharan Africa

    TFP total factor productivity

    TNE transnational enterprise

    TNI TransNationality Index

    UDROP universal debt rollover option with a penalty

    UIP uncovered interest parity

    UN United Nations

    UNHCR United Nations High Commissioner for Refugees

    USTR United States Trade Representative

    VMPL value marginal product of labour

    VOC Verenigde Oostindische Compagnie

    WB World Bank

    WTO World Trade Organization

  • Suggested course structure

    Our book consists of five parts Introduction (part I), Firms, trade and location

    (part II), Capital, currency and crises (part III), Policy, dynamics and organization

    (part IV) and Conclusion (part V). As the name suggests, part I provides an intro-

    duction into the world economy. We recommend that any course based on this

    book should always start with studying chapters 1 and 2. Part II concentrates on

    the real aspects of the global economy and analyzes, for example, production struc-

    ture, trade flows, multinational firms and migration. Part III concentrates on the

    monetary aspects of the global economy and analyzes, for example, exchange rates,

    capital flows, investments, risk and uncertainty and financial crises. Depending on

    the focus of the course and the available time, either part II or part III can be skipped.

    We recommend that any course focusing on the real aspects of the global economy

    should study chapters 35 in sequence. Similarly, we recommend that any course

    focusing on the monetary aspects of the global economy should study chapters 69

    in sequence. The first two chapters of part IV present important topics with a real

    monetary combination. Both could be dealt with in a course skipping either part II

    or part III of the book, although a more complete comprehension is obtained when

    both parts are studied before turning to these chapters. Independently of the details

    of the course structure, we always recommend that any course should conclude by

    studying chapter 12 (on the organizational implications for the firm of operating in

    a global environment) and the two chapters of the concluding part V (an evaluation

    of globalization, from both a macro and micro perspective).

  • Part I

    Introduction

  • 1The global economy

    KEYWORDS

    population GDP in history barriers to trade

    distribution of population GDP and GNP GDP per capita

    globalization global market integration capital flows

    history of globalization migration

    1.1 Introduction

    Numerous factors active in the global economic environment affect the decisions that

    managers of firms have to make regarding the price to charge for their products, how

    much to produce, how much to invest in R&D, how much to spend on advertising

    and so on. Some of these factors are the number of firms competing in a market,

    the relative size of firms, technological and cost considerations, demand conditions

    and the ease with which competing foreign firms can enter or exit the market. The

    economic globalization process that is, the increased interdependence of national

    economies, and the trend towards greater integration of goods, labour and capital

    markets (see section 1.4) influences all these factors, and thus indirectly affects

    managerial decisions and market organization.

    International economics analyses the interactions in the global economic environ-

    ment. International business analyses the managerial decisions taken on the basis of

    a costbenefit analysis in this global economic environment. In view of the above, we

    argue that central topics in international finance, business and public policy cannot

    be understood without a knowledge of international economics. Similarly, we con-

    clude that the central topics in international economics cannot be fully understood

    without insights from international business.

    This book provides an introduction to the global economy: what it is, how big

    it is, how it functions and how participants interact. Throughout the book, we

    analyse how international businesses are affected by the global economic environ-

    ment and discuss the role played by firms in this process, thus allowing businesses

    to make better decisions. This is our primary perspective. In addition, we discuss

  • 4 Introduction

    examples of the other causality: from international businesses to (inter)national

    economies.

    Before we can begin to analyse the global economy in chapter 2 and beyond,

    however, this chapter provides and evaluates some basic theoretical and empirical

    background information about the global economy concerning population, income,

    international trade, capital flows and the phenomenon of globalization. According to

    OECD Secretary-General Donald Johnston (see Maddison, 2001, p. 3), John Maynard

    Keynes argued that the master economist should examine the present in light of

    the past, for the purposes of the future. We concur with this view, and shall not

    only pay attention to the current structure of the global economy, but also discuss

    how the economy has evolved over time in particular, how globalization in its

    two basic manifestations (international trade and factor mobility) has progressed

    and culminated in the two waves of globalization of the nineteenth and twentieth

    centuries.

    1.2 A sense of time: the universe and population

    Some knowledge of the roles of time and history is helpful if we are to appreciate

    the modest position of the human species on a cosmic scale, relative to its current

    dominant position on our planet, to which we have become so accustomed. It all

    started with a Big Bang which created the ever-expanding universe about 13.7 billion

    years ago: at least, that is the most recent and accurate estimate of NASAs cosmic

    background explorer (COBE) programme, based on measurements of minuscule

    differences in temperature. The first stars were formed some 200 million years later

    (earlier than initially anticipated). Our galaxy was formed some 10 billion years ago

    and our solar system some 5 billion years later. As further summarized in figure 1.1,

    the formation of planet earth took some 1.5 billion years, so the geologic eras started

    3.5 billion years ago. The atoms gave way to molecules, the molecules to cells and the

    cells to life the oldest known fossils (worms and algae) date back 3 billion years.

    The process of photosynthesis by plants began some 2 billion years ago. Mankind

    appeared on the scene only 1.8 million years ago, taking homo erectus who invented

    tools as the starting point. In short, on a cosmic time scale mankind barely exists and

    our formidable achievements have not made a lasting impression.

    Population size

    Estimates of the size of the global population prior to 200 BC are based on archaeolog-

    ical and anthropological evidence, see Deevey (1960). In the nomadic period (before

  • 5 The global economy

    Big Bang

    First stars

    Beginning of our galaxy Beginning of our solar system

    Beginning of the geologic erasOldest known fossil

    Beginning of photosynthesisEnd of precambrian era

    End of primary era

    present time13.7 billion years

    10 billion years

    200 million years

    200 million years

    800 million years

    5 billion years3.5 billion years

    3 billion years

    2 billion years

    Figure 1.1 Big Bang and beyond

    Data sources: Louis Henri Fournet (1998) and the website http://www.nasa.gov, A baby picture of the

    universe tells its age, 11 February 2003.

    8000 bc), Fournet (1998, p. 5) notes that: the population subsisted primarily on

    gathering berries . . . and . . . it takes about five square kilometres to feed a human

    being. Population growth rates were very low for a very long time period. According

    to the data sources in Kremer (1993), there were about 125,000 people 1 million years

    ago. Their number quadrupled to 1 million in the next 700,000 years and reached

    about 170 million when Christ was born. The estimates become more reliable after

    this, as they are based on Roman and Chinese censuses.

    The developments in world population over the last 2,500 years are illustrated

    in figure 1.2. Despite the general upward trend there are periods of stagnation or

    decline in world population, for example as a result of the Mongol invasions in the

    thirteenth century, the bubonic plague (or Black Death, which wiped out a third

    of the European population in the sixth century and again in the fourteenth), the

    Thirty Years War (which raged throughout central Europe from 1618 to 1648) and

    the collapse of the Ming dynasty in China. A significant increase in the population

    growth rate began in the seventeenth century and reached a peak in the 1960s,

    leading to dramatic increases in population. There were 1 billion people in 1830,

    2 billion in 1930 and more than 6 billion in 2000. The growth in world population is

    projected to fall significantly in the twenty-first century, partly as a result of a more

    rapid demographic transition process in many developing nations than originally

    anticipated and partly as a result of the raging AIDS epidemic, specifically in Africa.

  • 6 Introduction

    425265170

    6057

    0

    1000

    2000

    3000

    4000

    5000

    6000

    500 0 500 1000 1500 2000Year

    Popu

    latio

    n (m

    illio

    n)

    Mongol invasions

    Black death

    30 years war, Ming collapse

    Figure 1.2 Development of world population over the last 2,500 years

    Data sources: Kremer (1993, table 1) and UN Population Division (2001) (for the estimate of 2000), see

    http://www.un.org/popin.data.html.

    Nonetheless, since demographic transition processes move as slowly as an oil tanker

    in the Thames, the world population is expected by the United Nations (UN) to

    increase to about 8.9 billion in 2050 (see figure 1.3).

    According to the 2002 revision of the UN population division there were 6 billion

    70 million 581 thousand people alive on our planet on 1 July 2000. Of course, given

    the inaccuracy of the data, the UN could have been off by a couple of million. Out

    of every 100 people alive more than twenty live in China and almost seventeen live

    in India. As the only two countries with more than 1 billion inhabitants, China and

    India are by far the most populous nations (see table 1.1). The world population is

    very unevenly divided, as indicated by the second part of table 1.1. The city-state

    of Singapore has the highest population density (6,587 people per km2), followed

    by two other small countries (Bermuda and Malta). Only three of the twenty most

    populous nations, all located in Asia (Bangladesh, India, and Japan), are also among

    the twenty most densely populated nations.

  • 7 The global economy

    8,919

    0

    2,000

    4,000

    6,000

    8,000

    10,000

    1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 2050year

    Popu

    latio

    n (m

    illio

    n)High

    estimate

    Lowestimate

    Realization Projection

    Figure 1.3 Developments in world population, 20002050, UN projection

    Data sources: Kremer (1993, table 1) and UN Population Division (2001), see http://www.un.org/

    popin.data.html.

    Population projections

    In 2000, eleven of the twenty most populous nations were located in Asia, which is

    home to almost 3.7 billion people, or about 60 per cent of the world total (table 1.2).

    Although the Asian population is expected to increase to 5.4 billion by 2050, its share

    is slightly falling to 58 per cent. The population of Africa is expected to increase most

    dramatically, from 796 million to 2 billion (from 13 to 22 per cent), while the only

    decline is expected in Europe, from 727 to 603 million (or from 12 to 7 per cent).

    This can be explained by the much higher total fertility rate the average number

    of children per woman in Africa (5.27) than in Europe (1.41). Total fertility is

    generally higher in the developing countries than in the developed countries. It is,

    for example, below the replacement level of 2.1 children per woman in Europe and

    Northern America. Total fertility will decline for all continents except for Europe,

    where it will rebound slightly from its current low level.

    As a result of better health care systems, sufficient availability of food, and access to

    safe water supplies, life expectancy at birth is higher in the developed countries than

    in the developing countries (75 years versus 63 years in 2000). This gap will remain

    high, although it is expected to narrow over the next fifty years (82 years versus

    75 years). Life expectancy is particularly low in Africa (51.4 years), which has been

  • 8 Introduction

    Table 1.1 The twenty countries with highest population and population density, 2000

    Rank Country Population Country Population density

    1 China 1,262 Singapore 6,587

    2 India 1,016 Bermuda 1,260

    3 USA 282 Malta 1,219

    4 Indonesia 210 Bangladesh 1,007

    5 Brazil 170 Bahrain 1,001

    6 Russian Federation (CIS) 146 Maldives 920

    7 Pakistan 138 Barbados 621

    8 Bangladesh 131 Mauritius 584

    9 Nigeria 127 Aruba 532

    10 Japan 127 Korea, Rep. 479

    11 Mexico 98 Netherlands 470

    12 Germany 82 San Marino 450

    13 Vietnam 79 Puerto Rico 442

    14 Philippines 76 Lebanon 423

    15 Turkey 65 Virgin Islands (US) 356

    16 Ethiopia 64 Japan 348

    17 Egypt, Arab Rep. 64 Rwanda 345

    18 Iran, Islamic Rep. 64 India 342

    19 Thailand 61 American Samoa 327

    20 UK 60 Belgium 312

    Data source: World Bank (2002).

    Notes: Population in millions, population density in people per km2.

    Table 1.2 Population projections, 20002050, the world and continents

    Population Total fertility Life expectancy Median age

    2000 2050 2000 2050 2000 2050 2000 2050

    World 6,057 9,322 2.82 2.15 65.0 76.0 26.5 36.2

    Africa 794 2,000 5.27 2.39 51.4 69.5 18.4 27.4

    Asia 3,672 5,428 2.70 2.08 65.8 77.1 26.2 38.3

    Latin Americaa 519 806 2.69 2.10 69.3 77.8 24.4 37.8

    Europe 727 603 1.41 1.81 73.2 80.8 37.7 49.5

    Northern America 314 438 2.00 2.08 76.7 82.7 35.6 41.0

    Oceania 31 47 2.41 2.06 73.5 80.6 30.9 38.1

    a Unless otherwise specified, the term Latin America includes the Caribbean throughout this

    book.

    Data source: UN Population Division (2001).

    Notes: Population in millions, total fertility in average number of children per woman. Data for

    total fertility and life expectancy at birth are five-year estimates (for 19952000 and 204550). The

    projections for 2050 are based on the UNs medium variant.

  • 9 The global economy

    struck hard by the HIV/AIDS epidemic.1 The most affected countries Botswana,

    South Africa, Swaziland and Zimbabwe are all in Africa. The toll of AIDS in terms

    of increased mortality and population loss can be devastating. In the thirty-five most

    highly affected countries of Africa, for example, life expectancy at birth is estimated

    to be 6.5 years less than it would have been in the absence of AIDS, and the population

    is projected to be 10 per cent less in 2015 than it would have been without AIDS.

    Life expectancy at birth at the world level is estimated to increase from 65 years in

    2000 to 76 years in 2050. Although it will probably remain the worlds laggard, the

    UN expects a huge increase in African life expectancy (from 51 years in 2000 to

    70 years in 2050).

    Population ageing will be the major demographic trend for the next fifty years.

    The rise in life expectancy at birth combined with the decline in fertility rates

    around the world will lead to rapid increases in the share of older people. The median

    age the age that divides the population into two equal halves is used as an indicator

    of the shift of the population age distribution towards older ages. In 2000 the median

    age was 26.5 years, indicating that half of the world population was younger, and

    half the world population was older, than 26.5 years. By 2050 the median age will

    have increased to 36.2 years. Currently, Africa has the youngest and Europe has the

    oldest population (a median age of 18.4 years versus 37.7 years). The most rapid

    increases in the median age will occur in Latin America and Europe (the 505050

    rule: by 2050 roughly 50 per cent of the European population will be above 50 years

    old).

    Population and business

    Do managers of international firms care about the population distribution, the age

    profile, demographic trends and projected developments? Yes, they do. In fact, firms

    study such trends closely (and many more trends not discussed above) and try to

    predict the implications that these trends are likely to have for their core activities

    and strategies. A few examples may illustrate this: First, many automobile firms have started production and assembly plants in China

    since 2000, all with the intention of benefiting from the potentially large and rapidly

    growing Chinese market: almost 1.3 billion customers! In case you are wondering

    why they have not done the same in India, the answer is that automobile firms

    have invested only modest amounts there because the Indian income levels (see

    p. 13) are too low to generate a substantial demand for cars despite having more

    than 1 billion customers.

    1 AIDS = acquired immunodeficiency syndrome; HIV = human immunodeficiency virus.

  • 10 Introduction

    Second, all major investment firms are increasing the share of their investments in

    firms and activities that will benefit from the population ageing process, such as

    health care, travel and entertainment and retirement projects. Third, inspired by their marketing departments, firm R&D centres are being given

    instructions to find user-friendly solutions for an ageing population, such as milk

    cartons that do not spill, bottles and jars that can be opened without using pneu-

    matic equipment and digital versatile disc (DVD) players that can be operated

    without reading the 150-page instruction book.

    Business and population

    Businesses are also important drivers of much that happens at the population level,

    both nationally and internationally. Clearly, policy-makers are keen to take account of

    business developments and try to influence them so that the advantages for society at

    large are maximized (or, for that matter, any disadvantages are kept within workable

    bounds). Again, a few examples may illustrate this: According to standard economics logic, businesses are the key drivers of macro-

    economic performance, such as employment and growth, particularly in capitalist

    societies. Within the business world, the production of goods and services is

    extensive; many innovations are developed and commercialized. Macroeconomic

    developments are thus heavily influenced by microeconomic businesses. The allocation of jobs across the globe, for example, cannot be understood without

    insights into the location decision of multinationals. In the late twentieth and early

    twenty-first century, much industrial employment moved out of the Western high-

    wage region into low-wage developing countries. Many other examples are industry-specific. The pharmaceutical industry, for

    instance, is the key producer of new medicines. Because most money is to be

    earned in the rich West, the multi-billion R&D efforts of the multinational phar-

    maceutical companies are heavily biased toward the invention, development and

    commercialization of drugs that can help to prevent or cure Western welfare dis-

    eases (e.g. cancer), rather than the much more common Third World plagues (e.g.

    malaria).

    1.3 Income levels: GNP and GDP

    The best indicator of the economic power of a nation is, of course, obtained by

    estimating the total value of the goods and services produced in a certain time period.

    Actually doing this and comparing the results across nations is a formidable task,

    which conceptually requires taking three steps:

  • 11 The global economy

    First, a well-functioning statistics office in each nation must gather accurate infor-

    mation on the value of millions of goods and services produced and provided

    by the firms in the economy. This will be done, of course, in the countrys local

    currency that is, dollars in the USA, pounds in the UK, yen in Japan, etc. Second, we have to decide what to compare between nations: gross domestic product

    or gross national product. Third, we have to decide how to compare the outcome for the different nations.

    Domestic or national product?

    As mentioned above, we can either compare GDP or GNP between nations. GDP

    is defined as the market value of the goods and services produced by labour and

    property located in a country. GNP is defined as the market value of the goods and

    services produced by labour and property of residents of a country. If, for example,

    a Mexican worker is providing labour services in the USA, these services are part

    of American GDP and Mexican GNP. The term located in sometimes needs to be

    interpreted broadly for example, if a Filipino sailor is providing labour services for

    a Norwegian shipping company, this is part of Norwegian GDP despite the fact that

    the ship is not actually located in Norway most of the time. The difference between

    GNP and GDP does not hold only for labour services, but also for other factors of

    production, such as capital

    GDP + Net receipts of factor income = GNP (1.1)

    So does it really matter whether we compare countries on the basis of GDP or

    GNP? No, for most countries it does not. This is illustrated for 2000 in figure 1.4,

    where the GDP and GNP values are measured in current US dollars. Since almost all

    observations are very close to a straight 45 line through the origin, the values of GDPand GNP are usually very close to one another. For example, British GDP was $1,415

    billion, only 0.2 per cent below its GNP of $1,417 billion. Only two of the thirty-six

    countries with an income level above $100 billion have a deviation between GDP and

    GNP exceeding 5 per cent, namely Switzerland (where GNP is 5.8 per cent higher

    than GDP) and Indonesia (where GNP is 6.9 per cent lower than GDP). For some

    of the smaller countries the difference between GDP and GNP can be substantial in

    relative terms. For example, capital income from abroad ensures that Kuwaits GNP

    is 18.3 per cent higher than its GDP, while payments to capital reduce Irelands

    GNP by 14.5 per cent compared to GDP. Unless indicated otherwise, we will use

    GDP throughout this book.

  • 12 Introduction

    0

    500

    1000

    1500

    2000

    0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000

    GDP

    GN

    P

    Germany

    UK

    France

    Italy

    Canada

    South Korea

    Australia

    Figure 1.4 GDP and GNP, current $, 2000

    Data source: World Bank (2002).

    Note: Data are for 177 countries; observations for Japan and the USA are outside the shown range; the

    thin line is a 45 line.

    Comparison

    When the GDP level for each nation in local currency is simply converted to the

    same international standard currency (usually the US dollar, US $) on the basis of

    the average exchange rate in the period of observation (the current period), it comes

    as no surprise that the USA has the worlds largest economy, with a total production

    value of $9.8 trillion (i.e. $9,800 billion) in 2000.2 Since the total value of all goods

    and services produced in the world was estimated to be $30.8 trillion, measured this

    way the US economy would account for 31.9 per cent of world production, about

    double the share of Japan, and five times the share of Germany (see table 1.3). How-

    ever, a ranking of the worlds most powerful economies based on production values

    measured in current US $ would be deceptive because it would tend to over-estimate

    production in the high-income countries relative to the low-income countries. To

    understand this, we have to distinguish between tradable and non-tradable goods and

    services:

    2 Henceforth the $ sign always refers to the US $, unless stated otherwise.

  • 13 The global economy

    Table 1.3 The twenty most powerful economies, 2000

    GDP ppp GDP GDP per capita

    Curr. int. $, billion Current US $ PPP, curr. int. $

    Country GDP % of total GDP % of total GDP per capita Rank

    1 USA 9,613 21.9 9,837 31.9 34,142 2

    2 China 5,019 11.4 1,080 3.5 3,976 90

    3 Japan 3,394 7.7 4,842 15.7 26,755 11

    4 India 2,395 5.5 457 1.5 2,358 116

    5 Germany 2,062 4.7 1,873 6.1 25,103 15

    6 France 1,427 3.2 1,294 4.2 24,223 18

    7 UK 1,404 3.2 1,415 4.6 23,509 20

    8 Italy 1,363 3.1 1,074 3.5 23,626 19

    9 Brazil 1,299 3.0 595 1.9 7,625 57

    10 Russian Federation (CIS) 1,219 2.8 251 0.8 8,377 55

    11 Mexico 884 2.0 575 1.9 9,023 52

    12 Canada 856 1.9 688 2.2 27,840 7

    13 South Korea 822 1.9 457 1.5 17,380 29

    14 Spain 768 1.7 559 1.8 19,472 27

    15 Indonesia 640 1.5 153 0.5 3,043 105

    16 Australia 493 1.1 390 1.3 25,693 12

    17 Argentina 458 1.0 285 0.9 12,377 41

    18 Turkey 455 1.0 200 0.6 6,974 63

    19 Netherlands 408 0.9 365 1.2 25,657 13

    20 South Africa 402 0.9 126 0.4 9,401 48

    As the name suggests, tradable goods and services can be transported or provided

    in another country, perhaps with some difficulty and at some cost. In principle,

    therefore, the providers of tradable goods in different countries compete with one

    another fairly directly, implying that the prices of such goods are related and can

    be compared effectively on the basis of observed (average) exchange rates. In contrast, non-tradable goods and services have to be provided locally and do

    not compete with international providers. Think, for example, of housing services,

    getting a haircut, or going to the cinema.

    Since (i) different sectors in the same country compete for the same labourers, so

    that (ii) the wage rate in an economy reflects the average productivity of a nation

    and (iii) productivity differences between nations in the non-tradable sectors tend

    to be smaller than in the tradable sectors, converting the value of output in the non-

    tradable sectors on the basis of observed exchange rates tends to under-estimate the

    value of production in these sectors for the low-income countries, as explained in

    box 1.1. For example, on the basis of observed exchange rates, getting a haircut in the

  • Box 1.1 Purchasing power parity (PPP) corrections

    Suppose there are two countries (Australia and Botswana), each producing two

    types of goods (traded goods and non-traded goods) using only labour as an input

    in the production process. All labourers are equally productive within a country

    (homogeneous labour and constant returns to scale), but there are differences

    in productivity between countries. As illustrated in table 1.4, we assume Australian

    Table 1.4 Assumed labour productivity, Australia and Botswana

    Number of products produced per working day

    Traded goods Non-traded goods

    Australia 20 20

    Botswana 4 10

    workers to be five times more productive in the traded goods sector and only twice

    as productive in the non-traded goods sector: Between-country arbitrage Assuming that there are no transport costs or other

    trade restrictions, arbitrage in the traded goods sector will ensure that the wage

    rate in Australia will be five times as high as the wage rate in Botswana, because

    Australian workers are five times more productive. Taking this as the basis for

    international income comparisons leads us to think that per capita income is

    400 per cent higher in Australia than it is in Botswana. Within-country arbitrage Assuming labour mobility between sectors within a

    country, arbitrage for labour between the traded and non-traded goods sector

    will ensure that the price of traded goods in local currency is the same as the

    price of non-traded goods in Australia (because labour is equally productive

    in the two sectors), whereas the price of traded goods in local currency is 2.5

    times as high as the price of non-traded goods in Botswana (because labour

    is 2.5 times less productive in the traded goods sector than in the non-traded

    goods sector). In local currency, therefore, non-traded goods are much cheaper

    compared to traded goods in Botswana than in Australia. Real income comparison Suppose that 40 per cent of income is spent on non-

    traded goods in both countries. Some calculations (based on a CobbDouglas

    welfare function) then show that the real per capita income is 247 per cent higher

    in Australia than in Botswana. Although substantial, this is significantly lower

    than our earlier estimate of 400 per cent because non-traded goods are relatively

    much cheaper in Botswana than in Australia. The 153 per cent (= 400 247per cent) over-estimated difference between income in current dollars and real

    income is larger, (i) the larger the share of income spent on non-traded goods

    and (ii) the larger the international deviation between productivity in traded

    compared to non-traded goods.

  • 15 The global economy

    USA may cost you $10 rather than the $1 you pay in Tanzania, while going to the

    cinema in Sweden may cost you $8 rather than the $2 you pay in Jakarta, Indonesia.

    In these examples, the value of production in the high-income countries relative to

    the low-income countries is over-estimated by a factor of 10 and 4, respectively.

    To correct for these differences, the UN International Comparison Project (ICP)

    collects data on the prices of goods and services for virtually all countries in the

    world and calculates purchasing power parity (PPP) exchange rates, which better

    reflect the value of goods and services that can be purchased in a country for a

    given amount of dollars (box 1.1). Reporting PPP GDP levels therefore gives a better

    estimate of the actual value of production in a country, which is the basis for the

    ranking of the most powerful economies in table 1.3. The USA is still the worlds

    dominant economy, even though its estimated share of the world total has dropped

    from 31.9 per cent to 21.9 per cent. After correcting for purchasing power, China is

    the worlds second largest economy (11.4 per cent of the world total), followed by

    Japan (7.7 per cent) and India (5.5 per cent). The relative production of China is

    more than three times as high after the PPP correction. Similarly for India, Russia

    and Indonesia. The reduction in the estimated value of output is particularly large for

    Japan (falling from 15.7 per cent to 7.7 per cent), reflecting the high costs of living in

    Japan.

    Income per capita

    For an individual inhabitant of a country, the countrys total production value is

    hardly relevant. More important is the production value per person (= per capita). Itshould be noted that income per capita gives an idea of the well-being for the average

    person in the country, but gives no information on the distribution of the income

    level within the country. If Jack and Jill together earn $100 the average income level

    is $50, which holds if they both earn $50 and if Jack earns $1 while Jill earns $99. The

    average income level is therefore a poor indicator of the representative situation in

    a country if the distribution of income is more skewed. In general, the income level

    is more evenly distributed in Europe and Japan than in the USA, where it is in turn

    more evenly distributed than in many low-income countries.

    Table 1.3 also lists the per capita income levels (corrected for purchasing power)

    in 2000 for the most powerful economies. The average income level in the world

    was 7,415 current international dollars (CID) per person. The highest income level,

    almost seven times the world average, was generated in the tiny country of Luxem-

    bourg. The lowest income level ($480 per capita) was measured in Sierra Leone, a

    small African nation. High income levels per capita are generated in North America

    (the USA and Canada), Australia, Japan, Western Europe, and in some oil producing

    nations in the Middle East (e.g. Bahrain, Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emirates). As

  • 16 Introduction

    0

    10,000

    20,000

    30,000

    40,000

    0 10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000

    GDP per capita PPP

    GD

    P pe

    r ca

    pita

    cur

    rent

    $

    USA

    Japan

    Russia

    Figure 1.5 Correction of GDP per capita for purchasing power, 2000

    argued above and illustrated in figure 1.5, the correction generally leads to a down-

    ward revision of per capita income for high-income countries such as Japan and to

    an upward revision for low-income countries such as Russia. Note, in particular, that

    close to the origin in figure 1.5 all observations are clustered significantly below the

    45 line.

    Income and business

    Analogous to the question posed on p. 9 for population distributions and trends,

    we may ask: do managers of international firms care about the (dynamic trends

    of the) income levels generated in countries, corrections for purchasing power, the

    distinction between aggregate and per capita income levels and the distribution of

    income? Again, the answer is clear: yes, they do. One of the most crucial questions a

    firm asks is: how large will the demand be for this product in a particular region or

    country? To answer this question, the total size of the population and the population

    density is important, but the total income level and the per capita income level

    generated by this population and its distribution across the population is even more

    important. Some examples may illustrate this.

    In section 1.2 we noted that many automobile firms are investing in China but not

    in India, despite the fact that both countries have more than 1 billion inhabitants.

    This can be explained by the higher income levels generated in China, where per capita

  • 17 The global economy

    income is double that in India measured in current dollars and 70 per cent higher

    after correcting for purchasing power, leading to a total income level in China which

    is at least double the total income level in India. Together with the more dynamic

    developments in China (to be discussed on p. 332) this double income level makes

    the Chinese car market much more interesting for automobile companies than the

    Indian car market.

    To illustrate the importance of per capita income levels for some goods and services

    we continue with our ChinaIndia example. Since all human beings require the

    consumption of food and drink to survive, everyone spends money on those items,

    no matter how low their income level is. Obviously, the higher the income level, the

    more you can afford to spend on food and drink and the more luxurious the items

    you will buy. Total spending on food and drink will therefore rise quite gradually as

    total income level increases. This is not the case, however, for many other goods and

    services which people will start to purchase only once their individual income level

    has passed a certain threshold level. In the extreme, this holds for the conspicuous

    consumption items such as luxury yachts and private jets which only the happy few

    can afford.3 A less extreme example is provided by mobile telephones, which people

    will buy once their personal income passes a certain level. We noted above that, after

    correcting for purchasing power, Chinese per capita income was 70 per cent higher

    than Indian per capita income ($3,976 versus $2,358). Apparently, people start to

    buy mobile telephones somewhere in between those levels: in 2000 there were 65.8

    mobile telephones per 1,000 inhabitants in China, compared to 3.5 in India. The

    market for mobile telephones in China is therefore not twice as large as in India

    (the total income comparison), but more than 23 times as large (83 million mobile

    phones compared to 3.5 million mobile phones).

    Business and income

    Again, causalities also run the other way around: from business to income. For one

    thing, business developments are a key determinant of any countrys GDP per capita.

    If a nations businesses prosper, so does GDP per capita. Profitable businesses create

    jobs, and profitable businesses can pay well. Loss-making businesses cut jobs, and

    additional unemployed put a downward pressure on wages. Without a large and

    well-performing business sector, a country will face great difficulty in producing

    and sustaining employment and income, as is clear from the economic history of

    developing, socialist and former socialist countries that are in the middle of the tran-

    sition towards market economies. In an international context, the location decisions

    3 The income distribution is important here. Very poor countries may still purchase luxury items if the

    income distribution is so skewed that a few very rich people can afford to buy yachts and jets.

  • 18 Introduction

    of multinationals influence the cross-country distribution of income, and hence of

    GDP per capita. For example, by investing abroad, multinationals stimulate macro-

    economic developments in the host countries by creating jobs and paying wages.

    Such FDI have a direct impact on the host countries GDP per capita, as well as on

    within-country income distribution.

    A nice example is the highly publicized development of top salaries in large (multi-

    national) enterprises in the late twentieth and the early twenty-first century. Under

    the influence of economic and political developments, particularly US large enter-

    prises started to pay their top managers extremely well. Economically, the prosperous

    1990s produced a tail wind: profit levels skyrocketed, as did share prices. Politically,

    the Reaganesque and Thatcherite wave of neo-liberalism, stimulated further by the

    collapse of the Soviet communist empire, set the tone for a new Zeitgeist. In many

    multinationals across the globe, following the US lead, this was translated into a

    shareholders value philosophy. To align the shareholders interests with those of the

    managers, managerial remuneration packages became more and more performance-

    related by including shares and share options. As a result, with escalating share prices,

    the income of many top managers went through the roof. Clearly, this had impli-

    cations for the distribution of income, which became more unequal, particularly

    because the rise in the employees wages lagged far behind the increase in the top

    managers incomes.

    1.4 What is the global economy?

    The short and uninformative but correct answer to the question what is

    globalization? is: everything you want it to be. Many of the heated disputes on

    the streets and in the media about the advantages and disadvantages of the global-

    ization process arise from the fact that this phrase means different things to different

    people. At the 1999 meeting of the WTO in Seattle, the environmentalists dressed in

    sea-turtle outfits cared about different issues than the French farm leaders protesting

    against the McDonaldization driving out the consumption of Roquefort cheese.

    Similarly for the trade unionists and the human right activists. We can consider five

    key issues here:4

    Cultural globalization This pertains to the debate whether there is a global culture

    or a set of universal cultural variables, and the extent to which these displace

    embedded national cultures and traditions. The first version of this section was

    written in the week in which the fifth Harry Potter book (entitled Harry Potter and

    the Order of the Phoenix) went on sale and set new selling records around the globe.

    4 See also McDonald and Burton (2002).

  • 19 The global economy

    To an unprecedented extent we can have similar cultural experiences in virtually

    all countries of the world: we see similar (American) movies, listen to similar

    (American and British) music, eat at McDonalds, drink Coca Cola, drive Toyotas,

    etc. Often, the carriers of culture globalization are argued to be large multinationals,

    which triggered the saying that the world is facing McDonaldization. Some people

    are afraid that this will lead to a boring, homogeneous global culture at the expense

    of local cultures and traditions. Others are not so gloomy, and see enough room

    for local traditions and new developments against a globally oriented background.

    After all, there is great regional cultural variety in China even after thousands of

    years of common experiences, and similarly for Europe. Be that as it may, cultural

    globalization is not the focus of this book. To avoid confusion in this respect from

    the start, the title of the book and the title of this section does not use the term

    globalization, but global economy. Economic globalization This centres on the decline of national markets and the

    rise of global markets as the firms focal point, be it for the production and sale

    of final and intermediate goods and services or for the procurement of inputs

    (labour and capital). Driven by fundamental changes in technology which permit

    new, complicated and more efficient ways of internationally organizing production

    processes, the rules of competition are being redefined along the way and firms

    and governments will have to learn how to adapt. As suggested by the title of

    this book, we focus on the consequences of economic globalization, as defined by

    Neary (2003): the increased interdependence of national economies, and the trend

    towards greater integration of goods, labour and capital markets. Here, businesses

    play a key role, by engaging in FDI and cross-border acquisitions, for example. Geographical globalization This refers to the sensation of compressed time and

    space as a result of reduced travel times between locations and the rapid (elec-

    tronic) exchange of information. Knowledge and production previously confined

    to certain geographical areas may now cross borders and be made available because

    of the rapid transfer of information and transport innovations. Some neo-liberals

    claim this has led to the end of geography in which location no longer matters

    and footloose global capital can quickly cross borders. In a similar vein, global

    business players are said to emerge, without any national roots. This develop-

    ment is reflected in important cross-border acquisitions and mergers, such as

    that of Daimler Benz and Chrysler. Others, notably Porter (1990) and Krugman

    (1991), argue that local production processes and their intricate interconnections

    are required to gain a competitive advantage. Since the advances in information

    technology (IT) and transportation possibilities enable interconnections hitherto

    impossible, geography is becoming more, not less, important. Think, for example,

    of the clustering of international finance, with three global centres (London, New

    York and Tokyo). As this is at the core of many of the economic consequences of

  • 20 Introduction

    globalization, it will be discussed and evaluated throughout the remainder of the

    book. Institutional globalization This relates to the spread of universal institutional

    arrangements across the globe. In the aftermath of US President Reagan and

    UK Prime Minister Thatchers influential programme or revolution of

    neo-liberalism, in combination with the collapse of communist Soviet-type eco-

    nomic systems, more and more countries adopted similar reforms (Albert, 1993).

    These reforms share an emphasis on making markets more flexible, privatiz-

    ing many former state-owned organizations (SOEs), reducing the size of welfare

    arrangements, etc. In an international context, these neo-liberal policies were and

    are promoted by such institutions as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and

    the World Bank, which are often said to have forced the Washington Consensus

    upon the developing world (Stiglitz, 2002). Another example is the WTO, which

    seeks to demolish international barriers to trade, and to the free movement of

    factors of production. In a similar vein, micro-level business institutions are influ-

    enced by global trends. Multinationals adopt similar policies under the pressure of

    competition and regulation. For instance, benchmarking practices are promoted

    by global consultancy businesses such as the Boston Consulting Group (BCG)

    and McKinsey, and the regulations of the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) are

    imposed upon many non-American enterprises (Sorge and van Witteloostuijn,

    2004). As institutions, both at the macro level of countries and at the micro level

    of firms, are key determinants of economic processes, we will deal with issues of

    institutional globalization throughout the book. Political globalization This refers to the relationship between the power of markets

    and (multinational) firms versus the nation-state, which is undergoing continuous

    change and updating in reaction to economic and political forces from counter-

    cyclical national demand policies and international cooperation after the Second

    World War to the renaissance of the belief in the power of the price mechanism

    and market forces for efficient allocation of resources in the 1970s. The global-

    ization process is conditioned by the (financial) institutions and the dominant

    market players, such as multinational corporations (MNCs) and large investment

    firms. Some argue that the competitive pressure of international markets will

    hollow out the functions of the nation-state and lead to an erosion of sovereignty

    and a race-to-the-bottom (be it in corporate tax rates or environmental policies).

    Popular anti-globalist rhetoric argues that large multinationals become more and

    more powerful, out-powering the majority of nation-states. Others point out that

    empirical evidence for these fears is lacking because of the undiminished impor-

    tance of the nation-state for providing security, a legal system, education and

    infrastructure, all of which are vitally important for attracting the economic activ-

    ity required for national prosperity. These issues are also at the core of many of

  • 21 The global economy

    the economic consequences of globalization and will therefore be discussed and

    evaluated throughout the remainder of this book.

    Recall Keynes quote from section 1.1 that the master economist should examine

    the present in light of the past, for the purposes of the future. In this respect, it

    was argued for quite some time that economic globalization was a totally new phe-

    nomenon, so overwhelming in its power that traditional production and organization

    patterns would have to succumb to the new realities (Drucker, 1990) and multina-

    tional firms would create tight-knit international economic relationships (Ohmae,

    1995). Extensive research in the 1990s, however, has shown that economic glob-

    alization meaning increased interdependence of national economies and greater

    integration of goods, labour and capital markets, is not a new phenomenon in his-

    tory at all (see ORourke and Williamson, 1999; Maddison, 2001; Bordo, Taylor and

    Williamson, 2003). Before analysing the global economy in section 1.7 and beyond,

    we shall therefore first give a brief historical overview of some aspects of the global-

    ization process.

    1.5 Globalization and income

    In his impressive work full of historical detail entitled The World Economy: A Millen-

    nial Perspective (2001), Angus Maddison collects detailed statist