0230221696

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    1/43

    Contents

    List of Tables, Figures and Boxes vi

    List of Abbreviations viii

    Acknowledgements x

    Notes on the Contributors xi

    Foreword xiv

    1 Development Aid: Expectations, Effectiveness and Allocation 1

    George Mavrotas and Mark McGillivray

    2 Decentralizing Aid with Interested Parties 15

    Gil S. Epstein and Ira N. Gang

    3 Blind Spots on the Map of Aid Allocations: Concentration

    and Complementarity of International NGO Aid 26

    Dirk-Jan Koch

    4 On the Volatility and Unpredictability of Aid 58

    David Fielding and George Mavrotas

    5 Aid Project Proliferation and Absorptive Capacity 79David Roodman

    6 Aid Allocation and Aid Effectiveness: An Empirical Analysis 114

    Alessia Isopi and George Mavrotas

    7 The Fiscal Effects of Aid in Developing Countries:

    A Comparative Dynamic Analysis 158

    Tim Lloyd, Mark McGillivray, Oliver Morrissey andMaxwell Opoku-Afari

    8 Development Effectiveness: An Evaluation Perspective 180

    Robert Picciotto

    9 Evaluating Aid Impact 211

    Howard White

    Index 233

    v

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    2/43

    1Development Aid: Expectations,Effectiveness and AllocationGeorge Mavrotas and Mark McGillivray

    Introduction

    The international community has come to expect much of foreign

    development aid in recent years, especially since the adoption of the

    Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) at the UN Millennium Summit

    in September 2000. The MDGs aim inter alia by 2015, to halve the 1990figures for numbers of people living in extreme income poverty, achieve

    universal primary schooling, and reduce by two-thirds the 1990 mortal-

    ity rate among children worldwide. A key component of the strategy to

    achieve, or at least work towards, the MDGs is a substantial scaling-up of

    aid flows by OECD donor nations (United Nations Millennium Project,

    2005). This strategy is clearly evident in aid statistics on global Official

    Development Assistance (ODA) from members the Development Assis-tance Committee of the OECD (see Figure 1.1). The level of DAC ODA

    rose from US$69 billion in 2003 to US$107 billion in 2005, the highest

    annual level of ODA on record. While the level of ODA fell slightly to

    US$104 billion in 2006, it is expected to rise to US$130 billion in 2010,

    and to somewhere between US$160 and US$170 billion by 2015 (OECD,

    2007a, 2007b).

    This chapter serves as an introduction to Development Aid: A Fresh

    Look and the chapters that follow. It consists of two further sections.

    The first provides brief surveys of the two kinds of literature to which

    the book principally attempts to contribute: those on aid effectiveness

    at country level; and on those on the inter-country allocation of aid

    by recipient. The second provides details of the remaining chapters in

    this book.

    1

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    3/43

    2 Expectations, Effectiveness and Allocation

    0

    20,000

    40,000

    60,000

    80,000

    100,000

    120,000

    140,000

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    2001

    2002

    2003

    2004

    2005

    2006

    2007

    2008

    2009

    2010

    Netdisbursements

    ($USmillions,

    2005prices)

    Actual Predicted

    Figure 1.1 Total ODA from DAC member countries, 19902010Source: OECD (2007a, 2007b).

    Aid effectiveness and allocation: brief surveys

    Aid effectiveness

    An obvious premise of strategy to accelerate progress towards the MDGs is

    that aid is, or can reasonably be made, effective in promoting outcomes

    such as reduced poverty, increased schooling and improved health. Isthis premise valid? There are a number of ways in which this question

    can be examined. One is to look at the research literature on aid effective-

    ness and allocation. A question that has dominated the aid effectiveness

    literature is the relationship between aid and per capita national income

    growth in recipient countries. The key questions are whether growth

    would be lower in the absence of aid, and if so, by how much? This is

    of clear relevance to the MDGs. While growth alone is clearly not suffi-cient to achieve the MDGs, it is agreed reasonably widely that increased

    growth is necessary for this achievement. Therefore, it is instructive to

    examine initially the aid-growth literature, before turning to other areas

    of aid effectiveness research.

    For many decades, the research literature on the country-level impacts

    of aid sent mixed messages as to whether aid was effective in promoting

    economic growth. Some empirical studies found evidence of a positive

    association between aid and recipient country growth; other empirical

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    4/43

    George Mavrotas and Mark McGillivray 3

    studies either failed to find any association, or if they did, found that

    it was negative. The second group of studies had support from non-

    empirical research, with many influential writers providing damning

    critiques of aid, from both left- and right-wing perspectives. The lack

    of a consensus regarding the country-level impact of aid combined with

    strong evidence that aid projects were in general effective in attaining

    their intended outcomes, was described as the micromacro paradox of

    aid (Mosley, 1986). This paradox was widely accepted in the aid policy

    and research circles.

    The late 1990s saw a fundamental change in the literature on aid and

    growth, however. Beginning with the publication of the seminal andextremely influential study by Burnside and Dollar (1997), a new stream

    of empirical studies emerged. They use better cross-country empirical

    methods (in particular, those that involve pooling of time series and

    cross-section data), are based on more informative theories about the

    determinants of growth, and use better data. These studies provide a rea-

    sonably clear and consistent message that growth would on average be

    lower in the absence of aid. This has proved to be a quite robust research

    finding drawn by the clear majority of an increasingly large number of

    empirical studies of aid and growth conducted since Burnside and Dollar

    (1997). The consistency of this finding across studies is evident from an

    objective reading of a number of aid-growth literature surveys (Hansen

    and Tarp, 2000; Morrissey, 2001; Beynon, 2002; McGillivray, 2003a;

    Clemens et al., 2004, Addison et al., 2005; McGillivray et al., 2006). This

    is not to imply that there are some who still claim that aid does not

    contribute to growth (see, for example, Easterly, 2007; Rajan and Sub-ramanian, 2008); simply that any objective reading of the aid-growth

    literature from the late 1990s onwards tells us that, in the absence of

    aid, growth in recipient countries would have been lower over recent

    decades. The macromicro paradox of aid would therefore appear to be

    dead and buried.

    The next question to ask is: if growth would have been lower in the

    absence of aid, how much lower would it have been? This question, sur-prisingly, has not been addressed explicitly in much of the literature,

    which has confined itself simply to the detection of causal relationships,

    rather then the extent or numerical size of their impact. But it is possible

    to derive this information mathematically; using the results of some of

    the most econometrically and theoretically robust post-late-1990s stud-

    ies (Hansen and Tarp 2000, 2001; Dalgaard and Hansen, 2001; Dalgaard

    et al., 2004; Clemens et al., 2004). This suggests that real per capita

    economic growth would be around 1 per cent lower in the absence of

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    5/43

    4 Expectations, Effectiveness and Allocation

    aid. There are results reported in the literature that suggest growth gains

    that are a little lower than this, and some suggest one or slightly more

    percentage points higher than this, but we consider that one percentage

    point is a reasonable, representative approximation.

    What does an approximately one percentage point contribution of aid

    to growth mean with regard to the role of aid in achieving or promoting

    progress towards the MDGs, in particular the goal of halving by 2015 the

    proportion of the worlds population living in extreme income poverty?

    Achieving the MDG income poverty goal involves reducing the number

    of people living in absolute poverty by a little over 60 billion per year

    between 2004 and 2015 (United Nations, 2007). Given these numbers,the answer to the above question is that, while aid will certainly play a

    role in promoting progress towards the MDGs, it will be only partial if

    assessed solely on the basis of its contribution to growth. Even the most

    favourable estimates of the impact of growth on income poverty will see

    aid having a comparatively small impact on growth-induced progress

    towards the MDGs.1

    Aid can, of course, contribute towards poverty reduction or, more gen-

    erally, wellbeing enhancement more directly, via channels other than

    growth. Gomanee et al. (2005) look at aid and pro-poor expenditure,

    finding that aid is associated with increases in such expenditure, and, in

    turn, improvements in the achievement of overall wellbeing. Kosack

    (2003) found that, contingent on the extent of democracy in recipi-

    ent countries, aid was associated positively with the achievement of a

    level of wellbeing across countries, as measured by the Human Develop-

    ment Index. A related literature, one that has grown rapidly in recentyears, looks at the impact of aid on various categories of public expen-

    diture and revenue. This is an important area of research. Most aid is

    allocated by donors to the public sector of recipient countries. How

    this sector uses aid will almost certainly mediate its broader impacts on

    growth, poverty reduction and other developmental outcomes. More-

    over, included in expenditure categories examined by this research are

    those that support the provision of health and education services impor-tant to MDG achievement. These studies are surveyed in McGillivray and

    Morrissey (2004). More recent studies include Mavrotas (2002, 2005),

    McGillivray and Ouattara (2005) and Mavrotas and Ouattara (2006,

    2007). The evidence emerging from these studies is not as unambigu-

    ous as that emerging from the aid-growth literature, but it is often the

    case that aid results in higher public expenditure than would otherwise

    have prevailed, although it can also result in decreases in tax revenue

    and increases in public sector debt.

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    6/43

    George Mavrotas and Mark McGillivray 5

    The demise of the macromicro paradox and some agreement in

    other areas of aid research does not imply that there are no remaining

    controversies or gaps in knowledge regarding aid effectiveness within

    research circles that aid works in all countries and at all levels. A repeated

    finding of the recent aid-growth literature is that there is an inverted

    U-shaped relationship between aid and growth. It is not beyond the

    bounds of imagination to infer that the levels of inflows to some coun-

    tries are such that aid might have in fact reduced growth within them.

    This is obviously a huge issue in the context of substantially larger

    global aid budgets and progress towards the MDGs. There are also

    widespread concerns about the impact of aid in what the donor com-munity has termed fragile states those judged to have especially bad

    policies and poorly performing institutions (McGillivray, 2005). A dis-

    puted finding in the literature, which to date remains unsettled, is

    that the impact of aid on growth is contingent on the policy regimes

    of recipient countries. Some studies conclude that policies do matter

    for aid effectiveness, including those of Burnside and Dollar (1997,

    2000, 2004), but more conclude otherwise. Some studies point to the

    importance of alternative contingencies (Hansen and Tarp 2000, 2001;

    Dalgaard and Hansen, 2001; Guillaumont and Chauvet, 2001; Chauvet

    and Guillaumont, 2002; Dalgaard et al., 2004). These include political

    stability and structural vulnerability (Guillaumont and Chauvet, 2001;

    Chauvet and Guillaumont, 2002). More generally, a great failing of the

    aid-growth literature, which has relied almost entirely on the estimates

    of cross-country growth modelling, is that it has yet to reach a con-

    sensus on this issue, which is clearly of great relevance to policy. Normight it ever be able to reach this consensus if the Roodman method-

    ological warnings regarding the limits of cross-country econometrics are

    taken into account (Roodman, 2007). If donors are to make aid more

    effective, they need to know what its effectiveness is contingent upon.

    Indeed, there is a case for turning away from the literature as currently

    defined unless there are signs that this controversy cannot be settled

    reasonably quickly. This involves two acceptances. The first is that aiddoes result in higher per capita national income growth than would oth-

    erwise be the case. As Riddell (2007) argues convincingly, this renders

    further cross-country aid-growth as it is currently conducted unneces-

    sary, as it simply reaffirms what we already know.2 The second is that

    cross-country growth modelling is inappropriate for providing robust

    information on what makes aid effective, be it in terms of growth or other

    growth-driven outcomes against which the effectiveness of aid can be

    judged.

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    7/43

    6 Expectations, Effectiveness and Allocation

    Aid allocation

    An additional premise of the strategy to achieve the MDGs is that donors

    are in fact motived by developmental considerations, such as povertyreduction. Put differently, it is assumed that donors strive consciously to

    achieve development outcomes in their aid programmes. An empirical

    literature that dates back to the 1960s has sought to address this issue by

    seeking to analyse the determinants of allocation of aid among recipient

    countries. Put differently, this literature attempt to explain the observed

    inter-recipient allocation of aid. Most explanatory aid allocation studies

    posit that donors pursue humanitarian, commercial and political objec-

    tives in their aid programmes. The humanitarian or altruistic motiveinvolves the promotion of development and alleviation of need. The

    aid allocation literature hypothesizes that, if donors are genuinely moti-

    vated by humanitarian concerns, they will allocate aid among recipients

    on the basis of relative need, allocating most aid to countries with low

    levels of development, high levels of poverty, and so on. The commercial

    and political motives relate to donor self-interest. Pursing commercial

    motives involves such behaviour as allocating funding in such a waythat it promotes trade and investment opportunities. More aid than

    would otherwise be the case is allocated to countries that buy, or are

    likely to buy, relatively large amounts of exports from the donor in ques-

    tion, should that donor be motivated by commercial interests. The same

    would apply to countries in which the donor has investment interests.

    Allocating aid according to political motives involves such actions as

    giving more aid to countries with which the donor has close political

    ties or interests, be it a result of geographical proximity, historical rela-

    tions or other reasons. It might also involve penalizing a country for a

    particular course of action to which the donor objects, or vice versa.

    Traditional aid allocation research tended to reject humanitarianism as

    a motive for official aid. This was based on the finding, reported by some

    highly influential studies, that the inter-recipient allocation of aid, espe-

    cially that from bilateral agencies, was consistent with relative recipient

    need. McKinley and Little (1979: 243), for example, concluded that thereare no grounds for asserting that humanitarian criteria have any signif-

    icant direct influence on aid allocation. Similarly, Maizels and Nissanke

    (1984: 891) concluded that bilateral aid allocations are made solely

    in support of donors perceived foreign economic, political and security

    interests and not, therefore, on the basis of relative need. While these

    studies have been questioned on methodological grounds (McGillivray,

    2003a, 2003b), simple descriptive statistics bear this out. In 1995, Israels

    income per capita was twenty-seven times that of Sierra Leone, and

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    8/43

    George Mavrotas and Mark McGillivray 7

    the life expectancy of its citizens was forty-three years longer. During

    the period 196995, Sierra Leone received an annual average of US$74

    million in net disbursements of ODA from all sources, while over the

    same period Israel received an annual average of US$937 million

    roughly thirteen times the amount allocated to Sierra Leone, or twelve

    times if these amounts are measured using the respective population sizes

    of each country (UNDP, 1998; OECD, 2002).

    More recent research has generally found that recipient needs do influ-

    ence inter-country aid allocation (Alesina and Dollar, 2000; Alesina and

    Weder, 2002; Berthlemy and Tichit, 2004; Berthlemy, 2006). This is

    potentially good news from an MDG perspective, although these studiesalso find that self-interest remains a significant determinant. A theme of

    recent aid allocation studies has been whether governance is important

    to aid allocation. The question under consideration is whether donors

    reward recipients that have good governance records, and penalize those

    with bad records. Good governance is defined using various criteria, such

    as official respect for political and civil rights, the absence of official cor-

    ruption, the promotion of democratic principles, or the performance of

    public institutions. It can also be defined in terms of the quality of poli-

    cies. This brings us back to the research by Burnside and Dollar, cited

    above. As mentioned earlier, this research finds that the impact of aid on

    growth is contingent on the policy regimes of recipient countries. More

    precisely, the finding is that, the better are these policies, the larger is the

    impact. It follows logically that, if donors want to maximize the global

    effectiveness of aid, in terms not only of its impact on growth but also

    in terms of growth-driven reductions in income poverty, they shouldallocate it among countries on the basis of the quality of policy regimes.

    Collier and Dollar (2001, 2002) originally described such an allocation

    strategy as aid selectivity.

    Aid allocation research has provided mixed results regarding the extent

    to which good governance, variously defined, has been relevant to

    inter-country aid allocation. This generally reflects the large diversity

    among donors. Svensson (2000) found that political and civil rightslead to higher total aid flows from Canada, Denmark, Norway and

    Sweden the so-called like-minded countries that traditionally put

    an emphasis on democracy and human rights in their development

    assistance and the UK. Alesina and Dollar (2000) came to a similar

    conclusion for the amount of aid allocated by Australia, Canada, Ger-

    many, Japan, the Netherlands, the Nordic countries, the UK and the

    US, but not for Austria, Belgium, France and Italy. Burnside and Dollar

    (2000) found that allocation decisions by all bilateral donors were not

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    9/43

    8 Expectations, Effectiveness and Allocation

    consistent with a selectivity strategy, but that multilateral aid allocation

    decisions were.

    Volume contents

    Development Aid: A Fresh Look consists of nine chapters. Chapters 2

    and 3 look at aid allocation issues; Chapters 46 look at the interface

    between aid allocation and aid effectiveness; and Chapters 79 look

    purely at recipient country-level aid effectiveness issues. Details of each

    follow.

    Chapter 2, a theoretical piece by Gil Epstein and Ira Gang, is enti-tled Decentralizing Aid with Interested Parties. The chapter responds to

    the observation that donors have moved towards allocating aid among

    recipient countries on the basis of good governance. This is broadly

    consistent with the donor communitys espousal of the findings of the

    influential work of Burnside and Dollar, discussed above. Epstein and

    Gang define decentralizing aid as allocating these flows only to countries

    with good governance. Chapter 2 analyses the decentralization of aid

    decision-making in a theoretical rent-seeking framework. It models the

    aid allocation decision where the donor government has announced that

    good governance is the criterion for receiving aid. Potential recipients

    must therefore compete for aid funds. The chapter shows that the struc-

    ture of the competition is important to the donor in terms of achieving

    good governance, and to the recipients in terms of what they will receive.

    It also investigates whether, under certain reasonable conditions, aid

    procedures will lead to the development of a poverty trap.The literature on aid effectiveness, in particular that having an empir-

    ical orientation, focuses overwhelmingly on aid from official agencies.

    Aid from non-government organizations (NGOs) is examined relatively

    rarely. Chapter 3, entitled Blind Spots on the Map of Aid Allocations:

    Concentration and Complementarity of International NGO Aid, by

    Dirk-Jan Koch, addresses this imbalance. Using a new dataset and Lorenz

    curves, this chapter shows that NGOs are very active in some countriesbut not in others. Clustering of NGO activity takes place in UN-labelled

    high priority countries, but ample room for improved targeting exists.

    Aid concentration curves provide insights as to whether NGOs tar-

    get the same countries as bilateral donors. The chapter concludes that

    they do, and are thus acting as complements. The drawback of this

    complementary approach is that it reinforces the donor darling/donor

    orphan divide. The chapter ends with some research suggestions and

    preliminary policy implications.

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    10/43

    George Mavrotas and Mark McGillivray 9

    There have in recent years been growing concerns over year-on-year

    volatility in the amount of aid allocated to recipient countries. Such

    volatility makes the management of aid inflows more difficult and can

    offset the potentially positive impact of these inflows, especially if year-

    on-year changes are not anticipated by recipients. Chapter 4, by David

    Fielding and George Mavrotas and entitled On the Volatility and Unpre-

    dictability of Aid, explores this issue. The chapter examines aid volatility,

    using data for sixty-six aid recipients over the period 19732002. It

    improves upon earlier work in this important area by disaggregating

    total aid inflows into sector and programme aid, and in this way it

    avoids focusing on a single aggregate, unlike most previous studies onaid volatility. Chapter 4 finds that recipient country institutional quality

    affects the stability of sector aid but not that of programme assistance.

    Macroeconomic stability affects the stability of both kinds of aid, as does

    the extent to which a country relies on a small number of individual

    donors.

    Much public discussion about foreign aid has focused on whether (and

    how) to increase its quantity. But recently, aid quality the efficiency of

    the aid allocation or delivery process has come to the fore. Chapter 5,

    by David Roodman, entitled Aid Project Proliferation and Absorptive

    Capacity, focuses on one process problem, namely the proliferation of

    aid projects and the associated administrative burden for recipients. It

    models aid delivery as a set of production activities (projects) with two

    inputs the donors aid and a recipient-side resource; and two outputs

    development and throughput, which represents the private benefits

    of implementing projects, from kickbacks to career rewards for disburs-ment. The donors allocation of aid across projects is for the purposes

    of the chapter taken as exogenous, while the recipients allocation of

    its resource is modelled and subject to a budget constraint. Unless the

    recipient cares purely about development, an aid increase can reduce

    development in some circumstances. Sunk costs, representing for the

    recipient the administrative burden of donor meetings and reports, are

    introduced. Using data on the distribution of projects by size and coun-try, Chapter 5 reports results of simulations of aid increases run in

    order to examine how the project distribution evolves, how the recip-

    ients resource allocation responds, and how this affects development

    if the recipient is not a pure development optimizer. A threshold is

    revealed beyond which marginal aid effectiveness drops sharply. It occurs

    when development maximization calls for the recipient to withdraw

    from some donor-backed projects, but the recipient does not, for the

    sake of throughput. Roodman argues that donors can push back this

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    11/43

    10 Expectations, Effectiveness and Allocation

    threshold by moving to larger projects if there are scale economies in aid

    projects.

    Chapter 6, by Alessia Isopi and George Mavrotas and entitled Aid

    Allocation and Aid Effectiveness, looks at the selectivity issue discussed

    above. It does so by augmenting an explanatory model of aid alloca-

    tion with a variable measuring past developmental outcomes from aid.

    Past developmental outcomes, in turn, serve as the measure of how

    effectively the recipient in question has been able to use aid inflows.

    Chapter 6 therefore seeks to establish the extent to which this effective-

    ness determines the allocation of aid among recipients after controlling

    for donor self-interest and other altruistic or developmental concerns.The chapter analyses data covering twenty aid donor countries and 176

    recipients over the period 19802003. It finds that while both altruis-

    tic and selfish donor motives seem to motivate aid allocation for most

    donors over the two periods under examination, a small group of donors

    do seem to have adopted a selectivity approach to aid allocation since

    the late 1990s.

    Chapter 7, entitled The Fiscal Effects of Aid in Developing Countries:

    A Comparative Dynamic Analysis and authored by Tim Lloyd,

    Mark McGillivray, Oliver Morrissey and Maxwell Opoku-Afari, looks

    at the impact of aid on fiscal aggregates in recipient countries, thus

    attempting to contribute to the literature discussed above. The principal

    innovation in this chapter is to conduct a comparative study of twenty-

    one countries, applying the same econometric method to each. Vector

    autoregressive (VAR) methods are used to estimate the effect of aid on

    fiscal aggregates, especially whether aid is endogenous (in the long run)or exogenous (short run only) to the fiscal relationship. Results suggest

    that, for low-income countries, aid is generally significant in the fiscal

    relationship and tends to be associated with lower tax effort. In middle-

    income countries, while aid is part of the long-run fiscal relationship in

    most cases, often it only has a short-run effect and there is no consis-

    tent association with tax effort. In general, the results suggest that aid

    has causal fiscal effects; that is, is part of the long run, although preciseeffects are country-specific.

    Much analysis of aid impact has been at the macro level and has

    relied heavily on cross-country regressions focusing on linkages between

    aid and growth. The principal limitation of these studies, as noted

    above, is that they do not to inform more intricate aspects of aid pol-

    icy and management. What is required to do that is more detailed

    analysis of aids impact on the ground, at the level of individual coun-

    tries. This is the focus of Chapter 8, by Robert Picciotto, and entitled

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    12/43

    George Mavrotas and Mark McGillivray 11

    Development Effectiveness at the Country Level. The chapter argues

    that the mix of qualitative and quantitative methods fashioned by inde-

    pendent evaluators constitutes a serviceable approach to the assessment

    of aid effectiveness, at both project and country level. The chapter sug-

    gests that, despite the risks involved, aid does the most good when it

    privileges the weakest and poorest economies, and those most vulnera-

    ble to shocks. It further argues that development operations should be (i)

    selected to fit within coherent country assistance strategies; (ii) aligned

    with the priorities of the country; and (iii) co-ordinated with other

    policies and the actions of partners. The final proposition offered by

    Chapter 8 is that professionally administered aid works, but that it wouldwork even better in concert with reforms of rich countries policies geared

    to levelling the playing field of the global market and to peace-building

    and human security in the zones of turmoil of the developing world.

    The focus on country-level analyses of aid impact is continued in

    Chapter 9, entitled Evaluating Aid Impact and written by Howard

    White, the chapter outlines developments in field analyses of the

    impact of aid on outcomes such as infant mortality, gender dispar-

    ity in schooling, and income-poverty. It argues that, while technical

    rigour is important, it is at least as important not to lose sight of policy

    relevance, which is achieved by avoiding black box approaches. The

    chapter then discusses basic concepts and principles in impact evalua-

    tion, and approaches to measuring impact. This discussion draws on the

    experiences of a number of official agencies in evaluating the impact of

    aid. It concludes by arguing that, properly done, impact evaluation not

    only provides evidence as to whether aid works, but also how to make itwork better.

    The topics covered in this book address important issues relating to

    development aid research, policy and practice. They are useful in their

    own right, but beyond that it is hoped that they will stimulate further

    discussion aimed at better and more effective aid that contributes more

    substantially to the fight against poverty, and results in a fairer, more

    equitable and more stable world. This is, of course, fully consistent withthe very essence of the MDGs.

    Notes

    1. Collier and Dollar (2001, 2002) look at the inter-country allocation of aidthat maximizes global poverty reduction, using a growthpoverty reduction

    elasticity of minus two.

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    13/43

    12 Expectations, Effectiveness and Allocation

    2. It should, however, be emphasized that Riddells insights apply to research ongrowth and aggregate aid flows as there remain substantial gaps in knowledgeon the impact of different aid modalities. Mavrotas and Nunnenkamp (2007)

    provide a recent review of this issue.

    References

    Addison, T., G. Mavrotas and M. McGillivray (2005) Development Assistanceand Development Finance: Evidence and Global Policy Agendas, Journal of

    International Development, 17: 81936.

    Alesina, A. and D. Dollar (2000) Who Gives Foreign Aid to Whom and Why?,Journal of Economic Growth, 5: 3363.

    Alesina, A. and B. Weder (2002) Do Corrupt Governments Receive Less ForeignAid?, American Economic Review, 92: 112637.

    Beynon, J. (2002) Policy Implications for Aid Allocations on Recent Research onAid Effectiveness and Selectivity, in B. Mak Arvin (ed.), New Perspectives on

    Foreign Aid and Economic Development, Westport, Conn.: Praeger.Berthlemy, J.-C. (2006) Bilateral Donors Interest vs. Recipients Development

    Motives in Aid Allocation: Do All Donors Behave the Same?, Review of

    Development Economics, 10 (2): 17994.Berthlemy, J.-C. and A. Tichit (2004) Bilateral Donors Aid Allocation

    Decisions a Three Dimensional Panel Analysis, International Review of Eco-nomics and Finance, 13: 25374.

    Burnside, C. and D. Dollar (1997) Aid, Policies, and Growth, World Bank PolicyResearch Working Paper 1777, World Bank, Washington, DC.

    Burnside, C. and D. Dollar (2000) Aid, Policies and Growth, American EconomicReview, 90 (4): 84768.

    Burnside, C. and D. Dollar (2004) Aid, Policies, and Growth: Reply, American

    Economic Review, 94 (3): 78184.Chauvet, L. and P. Guillaumont (2002) Aid and Growth Revisited: Policy,

    Economic Vulnerability and Political Instability, Paper presented at the AnnualBank Conference on Development Economics: Towards Pro-poor Policies, June,Oslo.

    Clemens, M., S. Radelet and R. Bhavnani (2004) Counting Chickens When TheyHatch: The Short-term Effect of Aid on Growth, Centre for Global DevelopmentWorking Paper 44, Centre for Global Development, Washington DC.

    Collier, P. and D. Dollar (2001) Can the World Cut Poverty in Half? How Policy

    Reform and Effective Aid Can Meet the International Development Goals,World Development, 29 (11): 1787802.

    Collier, P. and D. Dollar (2002) Aid Allocation and Poverty Reduction, European Economic Review, 26 (8): 1475500.

    Dalgaard, C. and H. Hansen (2001) On Aid, Growth and Good Policies, Journalof Development Studies, 37 (6): 1735.

    Dalgaard C., H. Hansen and F. Tarp (2004) On the Empirics of Foreign Aid andGrowth, Economic Journal, 114 (496): F191F216.

    Easterly, W. (2007) Was Development Assistance a Mistake?, AEA Papers and

    Proceedings, 97 (2): 32832.

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    14/43

    George Mavrotas and Mark McGillivray 13

    Gomanee, K., O. Morrissey, P. Mosley and A. Verschoor (2005) Aid, GovernmentExpenditure, and Aggregate Welfare, World Development, 33: 35570.

    Guillaumont, P. and L. Chauvet (2001) Aid and Performance: A Reassessment,

    Journal of Development Studies, 37 (6): 6687.Hansen, H. and F. Tarp (2000) Aid Effectiveness Disputed, Journal of International

    Development, 12 (3): 37598.Hansen, H. and F. Tarp (2001) Aid and Growth Regressions,Journal of Development

    Economics, 64 (2): 54770.Kosack, S. (2003) Effective Aid: How Democracy Allows Development Aid to

    Improve the Quality of Life, World Development, 31 (1): 122.Maizels, A. and M. Nissanke (1984) Motivations for Aid to Developing Countries,

    World Development, 12 (9): 879900.

    Mavrotas, G. (2002) Foreign Aid and Fiscal Response: Does Aid DisaggregationMatter?, Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 138: 53459.

    Mavrotas, G. (2005) Aid Heterogeneity: Looking at Aid Effectiveness from aDifferent Angle, Journal of International Development, 17 (8): 101936.

    Mavrotas, G. and P. Nunnenkamp (2007) Foreign Aid Heterogeneity: Issues andAgenda, Review of World Economics, 143 (4): 58595.

    Mavrotas, G. and B. Ouattara (2006) Aid Disaggregation and the Public Sectorin Aid-recipient Economies: Some Evidence from Cte dIvoire, Review of

    Development Economics, 10: 43451.

    Mavrotas, G. and B. Ouattara (2007) Aid Modalities and Budgetary Response:Panel Data Evidence, Review of World Economics, 143 (4): 72041.

    McGillivray, M. (2003a) Aid Effectiveness and Selectivity: Integrating MultipleObjectives in Aid Allocations, DAC Journal, 4 (3): 2336.

    McGillivray, M. (2003b) Modelling Foreign Aid Allocation: Issues, Approachesand Results, Journal of Economic Development, 28 (1): 17188.

    McGillivray, M. (2005) Aid Allocation and Fragile States, Background paper pre-pared for the Senior Level Forum on Development Effectiveness in Fragile States,1314 January, Lancaster House, London.

    McGillivray, M. and O. Morrissey, (2004) Fiscal Effects of Aid, in T. Addison andA. Roe (eds), Fiscal Policy for Development: Poverty, Reconstruction and Growth,Basingtoke: Palgrave Macmillan for UNU-WIDER.

    McGillivray, M. and B. Ouattara (2005) Aid, Debt Burden and Government FiscalBehaviour in Cte dIvoire, Journal of African Economies, 14: 24769.

    McGillivray, M., S. Feeny, N. Hermes and R. Lensink (2006) Controversies overthe Impact of Development Aid: It Works, It Doesnt, It Might, but thatDepends , Journal of International Development, 18 (7): 103150.

    McKinley, R. D. and R. Little (1979) The US Aid Relationship: A Test of the

    Recipient Need and Donor Interest Models, Political Studies, 27 (2): 23650.Morrissey, O. (2001) Does Aid Increase Growth?, Progress in Development Studies,

    1 (1): 3750.Mosley, P. (1986) Aid-Effectiveness: The MicroMacro Paradox, IDS Bulletin, 17:

    21425.OECD (2002) International Development Statistics Online, Paris: OECD.OECD (2007a) OECD Journal on Development: OECD DAC Development Co-operation

    Report 2006, Paris: OECD.OECD (2007b) Press Release: Development Aid from OECD Countries Fell 5.1%

    in 2006, Paris: OECD.

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    15/43

    14 Expectations, Effectiveness and Allocation

    Rajan, R. and A. Subramanian (2008) Aid and Growth: What Does the Cross-Country Evidence Really Show?,Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.

    Riddell, R. (2007) Does Foreign Aid Really Work?, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Roodman, D. (2007) Through the Looking-Glass, and What OLS Found There:On Growth, Foreign Aid and Reverse Causality, Centre for Global DevelopmentWorking Paper 137, Centre for Global Development, Washington DC.

    Svensson, J. (2000) Why Conditional Aid Does Not Work and What Can Be DoneAbout It?, Journal of Development Economics, 70 (2): 381402.

    United Nations (2007) The Millennium Development Goals Report 2007, New York:United Nations.

    United Nations Millennium Project (2005) Investing in Development: A PracticalPlan for Achieving the Millennium Development Goals, New York: United Nations

    Development Programme.UNDP (United Nations Development Programme) (1998) Human Development

    Report 1998, New York: Oxford University Press.White, H. (1992) The Macroeconomic Impact of Development Aid: A Critical

    Survey, Journal of Development Studies, 28 (2): 163240.

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    16/43

    Index

    Key: bold=extended discussion; b=box; f= figure; n=note; t= table.

    absorptive capacity 9, 58, 79113,189

    accountability 40, 53(n11), 106,181, 185, 190b, 193, 208(n30)

    accounting identity 1623,177(n4)

    Acharya, A., et al. (2006) 83, 112

    Lima, A. de 112

    Moore, M. 112

    ActionAid International xi, 190b

    Addison, T. 76n

    Addison, T., et al. (2005) 3, 12

    Mavrotas, G. 12McGillivray, M. 12

    Addison, T., et al. (2005a, 2005b)76(n2), 77

    Mavrotas, G. 77

    McGillivray, M. 77

    administrative burden 9

    administrative capacity 199

    administrative costs 82, 190b

    Africa 356, 37t, 61t, 713, 82, 106,158, 182, 197, 202

    African Development Bank 69t,207(n22)

    African Development Fund 69t

    agency theory 30

    agents: types (Isopi and Mavrotas)116

    agglomeration economies (Bielefeld

    and Murdoch) 29aggregation bias 63

    agriculture 80, 201, 206(n10), 217,224, 225

    Ahmed, A. 160, 179

    aid

    and arms transfers 124t

    benefit derived 116

    bilateral 312, 3840, 42, 43f, 47,

    54(n14), 11416, 186

    bilateral (2004) 4851t

    bilateral (country-wisedisbursement) 44f, 44

    per capita 367, 424, 44f, 115,119, 122, 1267, 1303

    centrality of side effects(Hirschman) 184

    commitments versusdisbursements 83, 112(n2),119, 154(n89), 159

    conditional 119

    cross-country competition 1623

    decentralization 1525different measures 15960

    diminishing returns 58, 189

    doctrinal positions 204

    doctrinal shifts 191

    dual role 164

    endogeneity issue 15960

    expenditure per capita (bilateraldonors versus NGOs) 44

    fiscal effects in developing countries15879

    as fraction of GNI 612t, 62

    government-to-government 27,3841

    humanitarian 53(n3), 114, 132,184, 200

    impact on development 191

    initial 68, 723t

    legitimacy problem 1801long-run-forcing 169

    macroeconomic consequences 188

    macroeconomic effectiveness 158

    making a difference 1825

    marginal effectiveness 105

    marginal productivity 84, 105

    misdirected 190b

    money dimension 202

    multilateral 3940, 116

    233

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    17/43

    234 Index

    aid continued

    versus national income growth percapita in recipient countries 24

    NGO 2657NGO (country-wise disbursement)

    44f, 44

    not spent in recipient country 170

    not spent throughrecipient-country budget 170

    past developmental outcomes 10

    perspectives (left- and right-wing)3

    price 39probability of receiving 17, 115

    professionally administered 11

    proportionate to governancequality 20, 212

    quantity versus quality 79

    recipient performance 117

    results-based, not a panacea 205

    securitization 200single aggregates 59, 76(n5)

    social and economic components135

    targeted 43f

    treated as endogenous/exogenous1778(n6)

    true value 190b

    weak exogeneity 173t, 175

    see also development aidaid: volatility and unpredictability 8,

    9, 5878

    aid shocks (measuring) 647,77(n13)

    assumptions 63

    correlation matrix for governanceindicators 70t

    cross-country correlations 645,

    71, 77(n12)cross-country variation (modelling)

    6774, 77(n1416)

    cross-section regressions forconditional aid volatility 73t

    data deficiencies 60, 70,77(n1516)

    empiricism 58, 59, 6474,77(n1316)

    literature 59, 76(n8)

    methodology and data issues604, 767(n1012)

    policy implications 746, 77(n17)

    aid activities 812, 112(n2)aid administration 181, 191

    economics 105aid agencies 389, 45, 125, 181, 186,

    188, 204, 21719, 229cannot be voted out of power 40evaluation departments 212, 228governmental 31, 39, 58multilateral 203

    official 8, 11regional desks 33universalistic 31

    aid agency performance versusdevelopment outcomes 1989

    aid allocation xiv, 1617, 31, 38,425, 107, 176, 200, 204

    average per capita (2004) 35, 37tfactors 114

    inter-country 11(n1)inter-recipient determinants 68interface with aid effectiveness 8,910

    literature survey 1, 68

    by NGOs (2004) 4851toptimal 116regional 17small-country bias 37

    stylized cases 18aid allocation (research blind spots):

    concentration andcomplementarity of internationalNGO aid 8, 2657

    aid allocations by Germany,Netherlands, Norway, USA (2004)4851t

    assumptions 41, 42, 45, 47

    caveats 456complement view 401concentration 26, 2830, 32, 334,

    468country allocation processes

    (background) 323, 53(n2)data 348, 53(n36)data deficiencies 26, 46, 512,

    53(n11)

    dispersion 302, 48

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    18/43

    Index 235

    empiricism 414, 54(n1014), 57equality of opportunity approach

    31

    further research required 45, 46,47

    literature 27, 289, 31, 32NGO aid (complementarity versus

    substitution) 38NGO-selection criteria 53(n2)non-profit location theory 278,

    53(n1)policy recommendations 47

    priority countries 26, 346, 37t, 47response rate 53(n3)reverse causality 46substitute view 3840, 53(n9)substitutes versus complements

    414, 47theory 42, 48utilitarian approach 31

    aid allocation and aid effectiveness:

    empirical analysis 8, 10, 11457assumptions 122, 126, 128, 131,

    154(n6), 155(n18)bilateral aid and arms transfers 124tbilateral per capita aid and per

    capita income 121tcross-country variations 11415,

    125data deficiencies 127, 154(n14),

    155(n212)definitions of variables and data

    issues 11925, 1545(n815)estimation methodology 1256,

    155(n1618)estimation results 12634, 1407t,

    155(n1921)estimation results for selected

    donors (19902003) 14853t

    estimation results for twenty donorcountries 1407t

    literature 114, 125, 126, 127, 134,136, 139, 1537

    model 11618, 154(n37)sensitivity analysis (testing for

    experience of 19902003)1349, 14853t, 155(n22)

    usual factors 123

    variables 120t, 155(n18)

    aid allocation rules 208(n33)aid budget/s 17, 68, 69, 77(n14)aid in budget

    dynamic considerations 1667,1778(n6)

    aid changemarginal impact 108

    aid commitments (indicator) 120t,123, 125, 155(n17), 177, 177(n3),178(n8), 190b

    per capita 119definition 154(n8)

    aid concentration 8, 26, 2830, 32,334, 42, 468, 54(n13), 68,154(n13)

    aid conditionality 59, 205aid coordination 189, 191aid crises 211aid deflator 68aid delivery 79, 189, 190baid dependency 183, 184, 188, 204,

    208(n31), 209aid disbursements 132, 177,

    177(n3), 178(n8)definition 154(n9)donor measures versus

    recipient-country statistics 170,178(n8)

    aid dispersion 28, 302, 48aid doctrines 193

    aid donors xiv, 5, 9, 1617, 31, 35,39, 43, 48, 6971, 745, 77(n14),7991, 93t, 93, 94, 96, 1057,11619, 1223, 1267, 12930,132, 1347, 154(n15), 159, 1667,169, 171(n3), 1756, 178(n8),181, 1845, 1879, 190b, 1934,199, 2035, 207(n17, n21), 224

    bilateral 78, 15, 27, 32, 412,

    457, 197characteristics 68

    coalitions 204coordination 79, 81foreign policy goals 114missions 81motives 154(n4)multilateral 15, 27, 812, 204multiplicity 207(n19)

    national and multinational 69t

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    19/43

    236 Index

    aid donors continued

    NGOs 46official versus voluntary 201

    official 53(n10)political allies 115preferences 118, 139, 188proliferation 84, 192self-interest 67, 10see also donor countries

    aid effectiveness xiv, 5, 7, 15, 17, 27,80, 1324, 158, 194

    evaluation hierarchy 192

    instrument selectivity critical 186interface with aid allocation 8,910

    literature survey 1, 25,1112(n12)

    obstacles 1889

    qualitative and quantitativemethods 11

    recipient country-level 8, 1011

    unit of account 186, 206(n12)see also development effectiveness

    aid evaluation systems 189aid fatigue 211aid flows 1, 12(n2), 62, 6971, 75,

    12730, 154(n15), 189, 2002,205, 206(n10), 207(n1516)

    disaggregation 60pro-cyclical 59, 76(n4)

    size 68uncertainty 678

    aid fragmentation (number of donors)834, 189, 204, 207(n19)

    aid funds (fungibility) 188aid given to one country only

    1920, 212, 24(n56)aid grants 162, 177(n4)aid heterogeneity 76(n6)

    aid impact: evaluation 8, 11,21131

    approaches 21316, 229(n14)assumptions 2201balance 228baseline (absence) 2246baseline versus endline surveys

    218before versus after 21315,

    229(n14)

    causal chain 225concepts and principles 21218,

    229(n14)

    contamination problem 21718cross-country regressions 211, 228data deficiencies 215, 217, 221,

    222, 230(n6)dummy variables 21516, 223evaluation design: summary

    2268experimental approaches 21820further research required 228

    impact evaluation design 21828,22930(n56)

    literature 211, 229(n2)modelling of determinants

    approach 216modelling the theory 2234natural experiments 220observable versus unobservable

    characteristics 216

    pipeline approach 2201, 226,227f, 22930(n56)

    quasi-experimental approaches2213, 224, 227f

    regressions 211, 223, 226, 228selection bias 21617theory-based approach 218, 223,

    228, 229aid increases

    modelling 8491, 10612aid industry

    direction 199202, 208(n301)doctrinal debates 200fragmented and competitive

    2001new kid on block 180reform 189revised strategy needed 2025,

    208(n326)aid inflows 177(n5)

    disaggregation (sector versusprogramme aid) 9

    aid inputsversus development outcomes 185

    aid levels 115, 11719aid loans 162, 177(n4)aid management 189

    aid markets 84

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    20/43

    Index 237

    aid measures 171(n3), 177aid modalities 59aid obligation 180

    aid officials 80aid optimists 183aid outcomes

    good policy 187aid pessimism 183, 184, 200, 211Aid, Policies, and Growth (Burnside

    & Dollar, 2000) 135, 155aid policy 117, 189, 191, 193aid portfolios 83, 85

    aid predictability 76(n5)aid programmes

    harmonization and co-ordination185

    implementation 194outcomes 193relevance 194

    aid project outcomes 117, 204, 216ratings 197

    aid project proliferation andabsorptive capacity 8, 910,79113

    assumptions 80, 82, 88, 90, 967,99, 1048, 110

    background and motivation 804,112(n13)

    causality direction 96continuous setting 97104,

    112(n4)data deficiencies 80, 81, 83definitions 813empirical distribution of aid

    projects 916empiricism 84, 99, 102, 104, 105further research required 105key ideas 845literature 834, 11213

    maximum likelihood estimates ofmodel parameters (2003) 93t

    modelling effects of aid increases8491, 10612

    proposition (with proof) 11011sensitivity tests 102, 1034fsimulations with sunk costs

    96104, 112(n4)theory 105

    aid project size 105

    aid projects 11, 87, 90, 99, 116, 125,1545(n15), 1857, 195

    budget constraints 219

    commitments (19952003) 82t, 83coordinated 180costs and benefits 217de-funding 101, 102, 1056design 204distribution 92fdonor-controlled 170duration 112(n3)empirical distribution 916

    inputs 84marginal total productivity 90multiplicity 189, 207(n1920)outputs 85performance 116programmes 15results 1945results-aggregation 192selectivity 1923

    side-benefits 85water 214t

    aid proliferation (dispersion) 83aid quality 9, 189, 2045

    dimensions 1845

    aid quantity 9, 106, 117, 1301, 139optimal 117

    aid selectivity (Collier & Dollar)78, 10

    see also selectivityaid shocks (measuring) 647,

    77(n13)aid target 178(n8)aid targeting 8, 36, 122aid-for-trade schemes 201aid transfers 126

    equilibrium level 117aid tying 85, 189, 190b, 204,

    207(n17)aid untying 79aid volatility

    conditional 667tsee also aid: volatility and

    unpredictabilityaid volume 1834, 1878aid works 187aidgrowth literature 25

    aidgrowth relationship 211

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    21/43

    238 Index

    Akaike information criterion (AIC)71, 723t, 734, 170

    Albania 48t

    Alesina, A. 7, 59, 11415, 155Algeria 48t, 61t, 67t

    all-pay auctions 1920

    altruism 6, 10, 116, 122, 1289,1334, 139

    Andhra Pradesh 229(n5)

    Angola 48t, 183Annual Review of Development

    Effectiveness (World Bank) 120t,

    124Argentina 48t, 61t, 67t, 196b, 220

    Armenia 48t

    arms 203

    arms transfers (indicator) 120t, 123,124t, 12734, 1368, 14053t,155(n212)

    Asia 61t, 201, 202

    Asian Development Bank 69t

    Asian Development Fund 69tAssessing Aid(World Bank) 39

    Augmented DickeyFuller (ADF) test170, 171, 172t, 178(n10, n12)

    DickeyFuller test 63

    Australia 7, 69t, 115, 121t, 140t,142t, 144t, 146t, 207(n22)

    aid allocation process 131

    Australian Agency for InternationalDevelopment (AusAID) xiii,214, 230

    Austria 7, 69t, 115, 121t, 141t, 143t,145t

    aid allocation process 134

    autocorrelation 171, 172n

    automatic stabilizers 76(n7)

    average costs 29

    Azerbaijan 48t, 183

    back donors 27, 33, 37t, 447,53(n1)

    versus NGOs (country-wisedisbursements) 45, 46f, 46

    Bahamas 1723t, 174

    Bangladesh 48t, 61t, 66t, 1723t,1745, 177(n1), 178(n10,

    n1213), 205, 226, 230

    Bangladesh Integration NutritionProject (BINP) 223, 224, 225

    bank deposits

    ratio to GDP 183banking sector 183Baum, J. A. C. 30Baye, M. R., et al. (1993) 19, 24

    Kovenock, D. 24Vries, C. G. de 24

    Belarus 48tBelgium 7, 69t, 115, 121t, 122, 134,

    141t, 143t

    Belize 48t, 62t, 67tbeneficiaries 215, 219beneficiary impact assessment 213Beni Suef (Egypt) 214tBenin 49t, 62t, 66tBerthlemy, J. C. 114, 115, 119, 125,

    155Beynon, J. 3, 153(n2), 155Bhavnani, R. 12, 77, 209

    Bhutan 49tBiekart, K. 39Bielefeld, W. 29, 30Blndal, N. 229nblack box approaches 11, 212, 215,

    2223, 2289Blair, H. 39blame-sharing effects 28t, 28, 30, 31,

    48

    Bolivia 49t, 623t, 66t, 196bcountry assistance strategy 197,

    208(n29)borrowing 162, 177(n4), 198

    domestic 1706, 178(n13)government borrowing 160, 163,

    177(n5)Bosnia-Herzegovina 49tBotswana 49t, 61t, 66t

    bottom-up approach 202, 228boundary conditions 109boundary solution 111Brandt Report (1980) 211, 230Brazil 49t, 61t, 66t, 1823, 195, 196bBrown, G. 79budget constraint/s 89, 109, 15961,

    166, 167, 171, 176, 177(n6), 192see also fiscal effects

    budget discipline 188

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    22/43

    Index 239

    budget planning 166, 167, 170budget support 202, 204, 206(n10)budgetary disequilibrium 175

    budgetary equilibrium 167, 169, 176questions 1634role of aid 1745

    budgetary process 176budgetary targets 160Buenos Aires 220Bulr, A. 59, 63, 76(n3, n5, n89),

    77(n17)Bulgaria 196b, 199

    bureaucracies 30, 54bureaucratic planning 16Burkina Faso 49t, 62t, 66t, 196b, 197Burnside, C. 3, 5, 78, 114, 135, 155Burton, J. 76nBurundi 49t, 623t, 66tbusiness: ease of starting 183business analysis 29business practices 207(n18)

    calculus of variations problem 109Cambodia 49t, 196b, 218Cameroon 45, 49t, 61t, 66t, 196b,

    197Canada 7, 69t, 115, 121t, 122, 124t,

    140t, 142t, 144t, 146t, 148t, 150taid allocation and aid effectiveness

    (19902003): sensitivity analysis

    136aid allocation process 129

    Canavire, G., et al. (2005) 114,11516, 125, 155

    Nunnenkamp, P. 155Thiele, R. 155Triveno, L. 155

    capacity building 1934, 202,207(n18)

    Cape Verde 49tcapital revenue 58CARE 26CARE Norway 52CARE USA 52cash transfers 219Cassen, R. 76(n6), 114, 155censored regression model 1256Central African Republic 26, 34, 45,

    47, 49t, 62t, 66t

    Centre for Global Development:Evaluation Gap Working GroupReport (2006) 212, 230

    centrifugal/centripetal forces 28t,2832, 37, 48

    Chad 49t, 623t, 66tchain rule 86, 107Chauvet, L. 5, 76ncharities

    see non-governmentalorganizations as well asindividual citations

    children 200, 209, 214, 215, 224mortality rate (MDG) xivwelfare indicators 33see also education

    Chile 43, 49t, 61t, 67t, 1723t,1745, 196b, 205, 2223

    China 42, 44, 49t, 83t, 91, 92f, 183,195, 199, 201, 203

    economic growth 1812,

    206(n34)has received little aid 182

    Christian Childrens Fund 52civil liberties 118, 1223, 1279,

    133, 154(n12)civil rights 7, 115civil society 40, 41, 2035, 207(n21)Civil Society Unit 47Clarke, M. xii

    class size 220Clemens, M. 84, 112Clemens, M., et al. (2004) 3, 12,

    76(n6), 77, 184, 206(n10), 209Radelet, S. 12, 77, 209Bhavnani, R. 12, 77, 209

    Clements, B. 78clustering 289, 37, 56co-financing systems 32

    Coady, D. 218, 230CobbDouglas production function

    856, 96, 97, 98, 102Cogneau, D. 31cointegrating relation 165, 166, 168,

    169, 173tcointegrating relationship 1725cointegrating vectors 178(n13)cointegration 161, 164, 1724,

    178(n1112)

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    23/43

    240 Index

    cointegration (long-run)relationships 168

    cointegration relationships 171

    Cold War 135, 202Collier, P. 7, 11(n1), 31, 208(n334),

    209Colombia 49t, 61t, 67t, 1723t, 174colonial ties 45, 115, 118, 130, 139,

    154(n7), 197Commission for Africa 158, 178Commitment to Development Index

    xiii, 122

    common pool good 31communism 208(n32)community-driven projects 21617community-level organizations 204Comoros 49tcomparative dynamic analysis

    fiscal effects of aid 15879comparison groups 21419, 2212,

    224, 229(n23)

    data on interventions 218single and double difference project

    impact estimates 21516,229(n4)

    competition 24(n3), 28aid donors versus recipient

    governments 84between aid donors 834

    competition effects 28t, 30

    competitive bidding 181computable general equilibrium

    (CGE) models 229(n2)conditionality policies 175conflict (violent) 2023conflict analysis 204conflict prevention 204, 208(n33)Congo Democratic Republic

    [Congo-Kinshasa] 49t, 61t, 63t,

    67tCongo Republic [Congo-Brazzaville]

    49t, 61t, 67tconstant-elasticity-of-substitution

    functions 105consultants 29, 201consumer price index (CPI) 723t,

    734consumer price inflation 70, 71

    consumer search costs 29

    consumption 123, 158fluctuations 76(n4)private 118

    contamination/contagion problem21718

    contest success function (CSF) ix,1920

    continuous setting 97104

    control groups 2203, 229(n1),230(n6)

    see also comparison groupsCordaid 51

    Cordella, T. 76(n6)coreperiphery 29corner solution equilibrium 117,

    154(n5)corporatism 32corruption 24(n3), 53(n11), 70, 71,

    72t, 80, 85, 115, 118, 1667, 197,200, 218, 224

    bribery 17

    misappropriation of funds206(n11)

    Costa Rica 49t, 61t, 66t, 1723t, 175,196b

    micromacro disconnect 198Cte dIvoire 49t, 61t, 66t, 179counterfactual analysis 192, 21215,

    21718country allocation system formalized

    33country assistance evaluations (CAEs)

    192, 208(n268)country assistance programmes 204

    evaluation 1945, 208(n26)country assistance strategies (CASs)

    1867, 203evaluation 1914, 2078(n225)joint evaluation 192

    outcome ratings 196bratings 1945, 196b

    country policy and institutionalassessment (CPIA) index 191, 205

    country programmes 1857country size 47, 83, 119, 1314, 139,

    154(n10)country studies 162covariance matrix

    non-diagonal 168

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    24/43

    Index 241

    credit access 220

    critical values 171, 172n

    Croatia 49t

    Cuba 49tculture 200

    cumulative causation processes 29

    Dalgaard, C. 3, 5

    Dalgaard, C., et al. (2004) 3, 12

    Hansen, H. 12

    Tarp, F. 12

    Danida (Danish InternationalDevelopment Agency) 225, 226,230

    data

    censored 125

    cross-section 3

    ex post 217

    stationary versus non-stationary

    168see also time-series econometrics

    data pooling 3

    databases 59, 60, 81, 112(n3), 126

    datasets 8, 267, 60, 64, 101, 2256,228

    dbrent routine 100

    de Renzio, P. 76(n2)

    debt crisis (1980s) 187

    debt relief 82, 190bdebt sustainability 163

    decentralizing aid with interestedparties 8, 1525

    aid given to one country only1920, 24(n56)

    aid proportionate to governancequality of each country 20

    appropriate channelling of

    resources 21assumptions 1620, 23, 24(n4)

    comparing aid to one country andproportional aid 212

    empiricism 24(n2)

    endogenous poverty 223

    incentives often work innon-obvious ways 16, 23

    literature 17, 19, 24(n2)

    model 1622, 24(n46)

    theoretical rent-seeking framework16

    decision-makers 48, 161, 185

    decision-making 33, 161budgetary process 159decentralization 8

    default 208(n34)DellAriccia, G. 76(n6)demand 28, 29, 38demand dispersion 28t, 30, 48democracy 4, 115, 12733, 1356,

    138, 184, 197, 200, 202, 207(n16)

    demonstration effects 195Denmark 7, 69t, 115, 121t, 122,

    124t, 139, 141t, 143t, 145t, 147t,149t, 1512t

    aid allocation and aid effectiveness(19902003): sensitivity analysis136

    aid allocation and aid effectiveness(19992003): sensitivity analysis

    138aid allocation process 132

    Denmark: Royal Ministry of ForeignAffairs xi

    design 207(n18)deterministic behaviour 171developed countries 202

    aid target (0.7 per cent of GDP) 79economic growth 181

    income per capita (PPP) 206(n4)industrial countries 211industrial democracies 205industrialized countries 192northsouth (global divide) 200rich countries 11, 79, 1801, 185,

    201, 203, 206(n4)see also OECD

    developing countries 10, 11, 42,

    58, 128, 1801, 189, 2002,206(n6)

    economic growth 1812fiscal effects of aid 15879

    higher-income 171income per capita (PPP) 206(n4)least-developed countries 47low-income countries 10, 158,

    164, 170, 172t, 1756, 183, 203,

    209

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    25/43

    242 Index

    developing countries continued

    low-income countries: definition177(n1)

    lower-income countries 130middle-income countries 10,

    1301, 158, 170, 172t, 1756,183, 203

    poor countries 24(n3), 175,1845, 2013, 206(n13),208(n30), 209

    poorer countries 53(n12), 177poorest countries 122, 171, 189,

    191, 201, 2034, 207(n17),208(n31)

    very poor countries 136weakest and poorest economies

    11development 6, 9, 10, 53(n2), 7980,

    82, 8690, 96105, 1078, 112,114, 116, 1334, 164

    aid project output 85

    conceptions 186diseconomies of scale 102f, 102,

    1034f, 104economic 15, 42optimization 101f, 101potential versus actual 101sound policy framework 1867

    development agencies 15, 207(n25)development aid 24(n3)

    see also ODAdevelopment aid: expectations,

    effectiveness, allocation 114,211

    assumptions 6cross-country modelling 5, 10empiricism 23, 6key questions 2knowledge gaps 5, 12(n2)

    literature 10literature survey: aid allocation 1,

    68literature survey: aid effectiveness

    1, 25, 1112(n12)methodology 6theory 3, 8

    development challenge 199development cooperation 192, 203

    changing nature 201

    development economics 187development education

    high priority 205

    development effectiveness: evaluationperspective 8, 1011, 180210

    agency performance versusdevelopment outcomes 1989

    aid: making a difference (or not)1825, 206(n710)

    aid: true value 190baid industry: direction 199202,

    208(n301)

    assumptions 185, 190bcountry assistance strategies:

    evaluation 1914, 2078(n225)country assistance strategy 196bcountry-level evaluation 1945,

    207(n26)cross-country

    differences/correlations 180,183, 186, 187, 199200

    development: achievement 1812from projects to country

    programmes 1857,206(n1112)

    literature 183, 187, 20810micromacro disconnect 198micromacro paradox 18791,

    2067(n1321)misconceptions 2045

    project portfolio outcome ratings196b

    project-level and country levelresults: congruence 1958,208(n279)

    questions 180, 181regional [continental] differences

    182what is to be done? 2025,

    208(n326)Development Gateway 207(n20)

    Accessible Information onDevelopment Activities (AiDA)databases 112(n3)

    development impact assessment1934

    development indicators 15development ministries 201

    development NGOs 53(n3)

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    26/43

    Index 243

    development optimization 108

    development outcomes 4

    versus aid agency performance

    1989development path (optimal) 102

    development planning 59

    development policy 16, 206(n8)

    development profession 185

    development projects 130

    development technologies 106

    dictatorship 39

    Dietz, T. 37

    difficult partnership countries (DPCs)58

    digital divide 201

    diplomatic leverage 186

    diplomatic representation 45

    distance 217

    district primary education programme(DPEP) 222

    division of labour

    country-wise 44geographical (absent) 45

    Djibouti 49t

    Doha Round 201

    Dollar, D. 3, 5, 78, 11(n1), 12, 31,39, 589, 11415, 134, 135, 155

    Dollar and Kraay openness index(2003) 70, 77

    Dominican Republic 49t, 61t, 66t,1723t, 196b, 218, 2301

    donor countries 1, 16, 18, 203, 36,88, 1845

    priorities 44

    see also aid donors

    donor darlings 47, 105

    donor governments 8, 15

    donor orphans 47

    double counting 53(n10)double difference 21516, 221, 225

    Doucouliagos, H. 187, 206(n13), 209

    drugs [medicines] 201

    drugs [narcotics] 203

    Dutch disease 84, 2067(n14)

    dynamic structural models 168

    East Asia 182

    East Asia and Pacific 36, 37t

    East Asian financial crisis (1997) 197Easterly, W. 3, 30, 54Eastern Europe and Central Asia 202

    econometric analysis 1701econometrics 3, 10, 1256, 15961,

    169, 179, 183, 205fiscal effects of aid 1645

    large-scale models 207(n23)notions of long- and short-run

    1647see also time-series econometrics

    economic crises 59

    economic diversification 195economic equity 203economic factors 137, 138, 139economic growth 15, 24(n2), 58, 75,

    85, 126, 158, 1834, 187, 197,202, 206(n8), 211

    aid impact 10per capita 1812long-term models 207(n23)

    real per capita 34economic growth theory 206(n12)economic liberalization 24(n2)Economic and Sector Work 207(n18)economic stabilization 197economic theory 169

    static 165economics 164

    classical 180

    neo-classical 187, 202economies of scale 10, 869, 100f,

    101, 1034f, 1046diseconomies of scale 868, 91,

    102f, 102external 29, 38internal 289

    economists 289, 180Ecuador 49t, 196b

    education 24(n3), 40, 154(n11), 158gender disparity 11, 212primary 1, 219, 222, 231universal (MDG) xv, 1, 4, 219see also schools

    educational delivery projects 218,219

    educational institutions 222Edwards, M. 39

    Eeckhout, M. 76n

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    27/43

    244 Index

    efficiency 31, 118, 1934Egypt 49t, 61t, 66t, 196b, 214tEl Nio 199

    El Salvador 34, 49t, 61t, 63t, 66t,196b

    eligibility stage (Neumayer) 33elites 206(n11)

    private benefit 118type I agents 11618, 154(n3)

    emergency aid 59, 60, 63, 82, 202as fraction of GNI 63tunconditional volatility 63t

    see also humanitarianismenergy sector reform 195Envelope Theorem 87, 108environment 201, 202, 203

    social and institutional 183environmental impact analysis 212environmental protection 195environmental sustainability 203Epstein, G. S. xi, 8, 20, 24(n1), 245

    Epstein, H. 207(n18), 209equality of opportunity 31equilibrium/disequilibrium 164equilibrium fiscal relation 174equity [fairness] 31equity flows 201equity investment 82Eritrea 49t, 183, 196b, 200error correction coefficient 166, 168

    error correction mechanism 166Ethiopia 49t, 183, 196b, 198,

    206(n7)Euler equation 109Europe and Central Asia 36, 37tEuropean Bank for Reconstruction

    and Development 207(n22)European Commission 69t, 69,

    723t

    European Union 205, 2078(n25)evaluation design 2268

    Evangelischer Entwicklungsdienst 52exchange rate

    real 188, 206(n14)exchange-rate dollars 99100exogeneity test (Johansen) 169export competitiveness 188,

    2067(n14)

    exports 119, 120t

    F-statistic 64Faaland, J. 76nfactor endowments 207(n23)

    Fagerman, B. xfamily planning 31, 224farmers 215, 229(n5)Feeny, S. 13, 25fiduciary assurance gaps 197fiduciary controls 181fiduciary rules 204field surveying 225Fielding, D. xi, 9, 76n

    Fiji 49t, 61t, 66tfinance 80financial flows, geographical

    distribution 120tfinancial sector 197financing from abroad 170, 1723t,

    175, 178(n13)Finland 69t, 121t, 122, 141t, 143t,

    145t, 147t, 149t, 151t, 152t

    aid allocation and aid effectiveness(19902003): sensitivity analysis136

    aid allocation and aid effectiveness(19992003): sensitivity analysis138

    aid allocation process 1334

    Finland: Ministry for ForeignAffairs x

    FINNIDA 214n, 229(n2), 230firms 28, 220first-order conditions 86, 88, 107first-order serial correlation 178(n11)fiscal aggregates 10fiscal balance (long-run) 171fiscal effects of aid in developing

    countries: comparative dynamicanalysis 8, 10, 15879

    assumptions/presumptions 1603,165, 168, 16970, 177(n3)

    causality 174, 175, 176caveats 162, 178(n12)conceptualizing aid in the budget:

    dynamic considerations 1667,1778(n6)

    data and model specification16970, 178(n89)

    econometric method 1645

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    28/43

    Index 245

    impact of aid: representation andhypotheses 1604, 177(n25)

    fundamental issue 158

    further research required 162,1767

    key concepts 165literature 15860, 163, 174,

    177(n6), 178(n8), 1789policy implications 176questions 1634results and discussion 1715,

    178(n1013)

    statistical preliminaries 1656theory 159, 1601, 1645unit root tests 1723tVAR approach 1689, 1701,

    178(n7)see also government budgets

    fiscal imbalance 169fiscal reform 195fiscal response models (FRMs) 159,

    1602, 167, 16970, 1746,177(n2), 1778(n6), 178(n8)

    questions 1634Flanagan, A. 229nFlannery, B. P. 113focus groups 226food aid 76(n7)foreign direct investment (FDI) 201,

    203

    foreign exchange reserves 75foreign policy 119Foster, M. 76(n2), 77(n17)Fowler, A. 39France 7, 45, 69t, 69, 715, 115,

    121t, 124t, 125, 139, 140t, 142t,144t, 146t, 148t, 150t, 152t

    aid allocation and aid effectiveness(19902003): sensitivity analysis

    135aid allocation and aid effectiveness

    (19992003): sensitivity analysis137

    aid allocation processes 128Franco-Rodriguez, S., et al. (1998)

    159, 160, 178(n6), 178McGillivray, M., 178Morrissey, O. 178

    freedom from fear/want 200

    Freedom House democracy index120t

    Freedom House Evaluation website

    120tFreedom House index of civil liberty

    122Friedrich Ebert Stiftung 52fruit of disappointment 206(n11)Fruttero, A. 301funding 28, 30, 53(n2), 154(n8)

    competitive pressure 47private and public 34

    fungibility 1589, 2045

    G7 aid money 207(n17)Gabon 49t, 61t, 67tGambia 49t, 63t, 66t, 76(n10)Gang, I. N. 8, 24(n1), 24Gates, S. 11415, 135, 155Gauri, V. 301Gemmell, N. 58, 78

    gender 11, 212geo-economics 191

    geographical economics 28, 38, 55geography 6, 30, 32, 185, 193, 217

    geo-politics 71, 189, 191, 200,208(n32)

    Georgia 49t, 182Germany 7, 69t, 69, 72t, 745, 115,

    121t, 122, 124t, 140t, 142t, 144t,

    146t, 148t, 150t, 152taid allocation and aid effectiveness

    (19902003): sensitivity analysis135

    aid allocation and aid effectiveness(19992003): sensitivity analysis137

    aid allocation processes 1289

    aid allocations 4851t

    NGOs 32, 34, 36f, 36, 37t, 46f, 47,4851t, 52

    Germany: Ministry of EconomicCooperation and Development(NGO Division) 52

    Ghana 49t, 62t, 66t, 177(n5), 179,183, 196b, 198, 205, 2245

    Gini coefficient 334, 54(n13)Gini index 118, 120t, 123, 1269,

    1313, 1368, 14053t

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    29/43

    246 Index

    girls 215, 222Girma, S. 78Glinskaya, E. 222, 231

    global market 11, 200global warming 201globalization 202, 203Gomanee, K., et al. (2003) 76(n2), 78

    Girma, S. 78Morrissey, O. 78

    Gomanee, K., et al. (2005) 4, 13Morrissey, O. 13Mosley, P. 13

    Verschoor, A. 13goods and services 79, 154(n9), 189Gounder, R. 114, 155governance

    democratic 3940, 42rules-based 183

    governance indicators 70tgovernance quality 78, 1516, 27,

    3944, 53(n11), 54(n14), 56, 75,

    84, 115, 131, 186, 1978, 202,2045, 209

    aid proportionate to 20, 212investment in 1722, 24(n46)

    governance targeting 423government (indicator) 120t,

    1223, 127, 1328, 14053t,154(n12)

    government budgets 40, 81, 97, 101,

    1067, 108accounting framework 162aid component (dynamic

    considerations) 1667,1778(n6)

    deficits 162, 169, 177, 177(n4)primary surplus 162, 163share allocated to aid 205,

    208(n35)

    surplus 169see also budget constraint/s

    government effectiveness 70t, 70,72t

    governments 16, 28, 40, 45, 47, 84,104, 11617, 154(n3, n8), 1979,2034, 229n

    core functions 189donor versus recipients 53(n9)

    targeting criteria 31

    Grangers Representation Theorem1656

    grants 24(n3), 32, 33, 82, 177, 201,

    206(n8), 222Greece 69t

    Groot, D. de 52n

    gross domestic product (GDP) 60,84, 100, 119, 183

    GDP per capita 202

    GDP per capita (real) 119, 120t,122, 12734, 136, 138, 14053t

    GDP deflator 170

    GDP growth (indicator) 119, 120t,122, 126, 1278, 1302, 14053t

    GDP growth rate 118

    gross national income (GNI) 60,645, 68, 76(n10), 172t, 177(n1),183

    aid as fraction of 612t, 62

    national income 201

    national income growth 23, 5,

    12(n2)gross national product (GNP) 183,

    186

    growth/poverty-reduction elasticity11(n1)

    Guatemala 49t, 61t, 67t, 196b, 197

    Guillaumont, P. 5, 12

    Guinea 49t

    Guinea-Bissau 47, 49t

    Gupta, S. 76(n2)

    Gupta, S., et al. (2004) 76(n7), 78

    Clements, B. 78

    Tiongson, E. 78

    Guyana 49t, 623t, 67t

    Haiti 49t, 62t, 66t, 196b, 199, 221

    Hamann, J. 59, 63, 76(n3, n5, n89)

    Hamilton, J. D. 168, 178(n7), 178Hansen, H. 3, 5, 12

    harmonization 79, 207(n21)

    health 2, 4, 154(n11), 158, 215, 224

    health care 24(n3), 214

    contracting out 218

    health clinics 217

    Heckelman, J. 24(n2)

    Heckman sample selection model

    125

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    30/43

    Index 247

    Heller, P. 76(n2)

    Herfindahl index 723t, 74

    Hermes, N. 13, 25

    heteroscedasticity 171, 172nLagrange multiplier (LM) test

    723t

    Hirschman, A. O. 184, 185, 209

    HIV/AIDS 182, 197, 201, 203, 209,214, 230

    Hivos 51

    Hodrick, R. 59, 67

    Hoeffler, A. 11415, 135, 155

    Honduras 49t, 623t, 66t, 183Hook, S. 156

    horizontal inequalities 204

    households 120t, 123, 220

    housing quality 222

    Hulme, D. 39

    human capital 38, 59

    human development 133

    Human Development Index 4, 33

    Human Development Report(UNDP)34, 120t

    human fertility 224

    human resources 122, 1278, 195

    personnel quality 38

    human rights 115

    human security 11, 204

    human trafficking 203

    human welfare 182

    humanitarianism 6, 34, 53(n3), 114,132, 184, 200

    Hungary 205

    Hunt, J. xii

    ICCO 51

    ideas 191, 203

    Im, K., et al. (2003) 63, 78

    Pesaran, H. 78Shin, Y. 78

    immobility of inputs (Krugman) 30

    immunization 199200, 224, 226

    impact evaluation

    definitions 21213

    import tariffs 201

    imports 119

    income per capita 130, 183,

    206(n7)

    income distribution 120t,123, 1278, 1301, 134,1368

    income inequality 34income poverty 11, 212

    MDG 1, 4, 7independent and identically

    distributed (i.i.d.)random variables 126residuals 64

    India 34, 42, 44, 47, 49t, 61t, 66t,83t, 1723t, 177(n1), 183, 196b,

    199, 201, 203, 206(n7), 218, 222,229(n5)

    aid received 206(n5)economic growth 181, 206(n34)reforms (1991) 206(n5)

    indirect demand function 107indirect supply functions 107indirect utility function 107individuals 27, 120t

    Indonesia 49t, 61t, 66t, 83t, 196b,197

    inequality, international andsub-national 199200

    infant mortality 11, 120t, 123,12633, 135, 1378, 14053t,182, 199, 21213

    inflation 75, 188, 197information 29, 60, 207(n20)

    information asymmetry 206(n2,n11)

    see also knowledgeinfrastructure 29, 80, 158, 202, 204,

    206(n10), 219inputs 29, 85, 105, 223

    cheaper 29price 48

    Institute of Social Studies, the Hague

    52ninstitutional development 194institutional frameworks 207(n23)institutional mapping 226institutional quality 9, 68, 701, 72t,

    745institutions 15, 52, 84, 135, 166,

    186, 191, 197, 200, 202democratic 138

    economic 188, 207(n15)

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    31/43

    248 Index

    institutions continued

    political 75, 135, 188, 207(n16)

    public 7

    quality 183sound 135, 1867

    intellectual property 201, 203

    Inter-American Development Bank(IDB) 69t, 207(n22), 2213, 230

    IDB Special Fund 69t

    International Cooperation Academyon Civil Society 52n

    International Development

    Association (IDA) 69t, 69, 723tInternational Finance Corporation

    204, 208(n34)

    International Finance Facility (IFF)58, 76(n1), 78, 79

    international financial institutions191, 207(n25)

    International Fund for AgriculturalDevelopment (IFAD) 69t, 225,231

    International Monetary Fund (IMF)120t, 188

    international relations 180,208(n32)

    internet 81, 112(n1), 207(n20)

    interviews 267, 323, 38, 41, 45,512, 53(n2)

    qualitative 226 Investing in Development(UNDP, 2005)79, 113

    investment 6, 1589, 183, 187, 195,207(n15), 208(n34), 224

    private 202

    public 185, 186

    public (big push) 206(n12)

    investment guarantee institutions

    201Iran 50t

    Iraq 54(n14), 200

    Ireland (ROI) 69t, 121t, 122, 141t,143t, 145t, 147t

    aid allocation process 1312

    irrigation 224, 229(n5)

    Islamic Development Bank 207(n22)

    Islei, O. 179

    isomorphic transformation 45

    Isopi, A. xi, 10, 116, 139, 154(n5,n14), 156

    Israel 67, 220

    Italy 7, 69t, 115, 121t, 131, 139,141t, 143t, 145t, 147t, 152t,207(n17)

    Jalan, J. 222, 231

    Jamaica 50t, 66t, 196b

    Japan 7, 69t, 69, 723t, 745, 80,115, 121t, 122, 124t, 125, 139,140t, 142t, 144t, 146t, 148t, 150t,152t, 180

    aid allocation and aid effectiveness(19902003): sensitivity analysis135, 155(n22)

    aid allocation and aid effectiveness(19992003): sensitivity analysis1378

    aid allocation process 129,155(n19)

    JarqueBera tests 723t

    Joassart-Marcelli, P. 32

    Johansen, S. 164, 168, 169, 179

    Johansen trace statistic 172, 173t

    Johnston, T. A. 81, 113

    Jordan 50t, 61t, 66t, 196b, 207(n22)

    Juselius, K. 168, 179

    Kandy (Sri Lanka) 214tKaufmann, D., et al. (2003) 70,

    77(n15), 78

    Kraay, A. 78

    Mastruzzi, M. 78

    Kaufmann indicators 53(n11)

    Kazakhstan 50t, 196b, 207(n22)

    Keeble, D., et al. (1999) 29, 55

    Lawson, C. 55

    Moore, B. 55Wilkinson, F. 55

    Keen, M. 175, 179

    Kenya 50t, 62t, 66t, 81, 170, 1723t,177, 177(n1), 178(n12), 179, 215,218, 221, 225, 230

    Keynes, J. M. 206(n1)

    Killick, T. 52n, 59Kinder Nothilfe Deutschland 52

    Kingsbury, D. xii

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    32/43

    Index 249

    Knack, S. 24(n2), 834, 113

    knowledge 29, 202

    local 31

    see also spillover effectsKoch, D.-J. xi, 8, 27, 32, 39, 47,

    523n, 55, D-J., 37n, 53(n3)

    Kohama, H. 210

    Koizumi, J. 180

    Kono, H. 210Konrad Adenauer Stiftung 52

    Korea: North 39

    Korea: South 50t, 183

    Kosack, S. 4Kosovo 30

    Kovenock, D. 24

    Kraay, A. 70, 78

    Krugman, P. 28, 30, 55

    Kyrgyz Republic 50t, 183, 196b

    labour 29, 30, 217

    labour market thickness 38, 48labour mobility 28t, 28, 2930

    labour productivity 183

    Lagrange multiplier (LM) test 723t

    Lagrangian 86, 106

    land 197, 220

    Landes, D. S. 206(n1), 210

    landlocked countries 26

    Lane, T. 77(n17), 77

    Laos 50tLatin America 347, 62t, 715, 202

    Latin America and Caribbean 35, 37t

    Latvia 183

    Lawson, C. 55

    leaders 16, 24(n5)

    pay-offs 1822

    utility 1718

    leadership 204

    Lebanon 50tlegal framework 15

    legislation 208(n30)

    legislatures 80

    lending agencies (multilateral)154(n15)

    Lennon, J. O. 182

    Lensink, R. 13, 25, 58, 76(n3)

    Lesotho 50t, 196b, 207(n22)

    level playing field 11

    level stage 33

    Levin, V. 39, 58, 11415, 134,155

    liberalism 32Liberia 42, 50t

    Libya 50t

    life expectancy 7, 182

    Lima, A. de 112

    Lin, T. 76(n1)

    Lindi (Tanzania) 214t

    linkages (forward and backward) 29

    literacy 182, 222

    Lithuania 196bLittle, R. 6, 114, 156

    living standards 182, 206(n13)

    Llavador, H. G. 31

    Lloyd, T. xixii, 10, 178(n9), 179

    loans 82, 201, 206(n8)

    concessional 177

    infrastructure 206(n10)

    policy-based, speedy disbursement

    202

    local government 204

    Lockard, A. A. 20

    log frame analysis 30

    Loman, B. 53(n3)

    long run forcing 169

    Lorenz curve 8, 34, 356f

    Lundborg, P. 114, 156

    Luxembourg 69t

    MAmanja, D. 179

    Macedonia 50t

    macro level 229(n2)

    macroeconomic conditions 161

    macroeconomic policy 68, 701,1834, 202

    conditionality 206(n12)

    macroeconomic stability 9, 75macroeconomic stabilization: halo

    effect 197

    macroeconomic variables 60, 75

    macroeconomics 58, 76(n7), 164,188

    empirical 168

    macroeconomists 185

    Madagascar 50t, 62t, 66t

    Maizels, A. 6, 114, 156

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    33/43

    250 Index

    make poverty history 200Malawi 26, 34, 50t, 623t, 66t, 183,

    207(n22), 221

    Malaysia 50t, 61t, 67tMaldives 50t, 196bMali 50t, 623t, 66t, 199malnutrition 130, 182, 199Malthus, T. R. 180marginal productivity 90marginal utility 107market access 216market size 48

    Marshall Plan 208(n36)Martens, B., et al. (2002) 206(n2),

    210Mummert, U. 210Murrell, P. 210Ostrom, E. 210Seabright, P. 210

    Mastruzzi, M. 78mathematics 90, 100, 105, 108

    Mattesini, F. 116, 139, 154(n5), 156Mauritania 50t, 623t, 66tMauritius 50t, 1723tMavrotas, G. x, xii, 4, 9, 10, 12(n2),

    12, 13, 24(n3), 76n, 76(n1, n6),77, 78, 153(n1), 154(n14), 156,160

    maximum likelihood 93t, 93, 94f,125, 168

    McGillivray, M. x, xii, 3, 4, 6, 10, 12,13, 52n, 58, 76n, 77, 78, 114,119, 153n, 153(n2), 156, 158,160, 178(n9), 178, 179

    McGillivray, M., et al. (2005) 24(n2),25

    Feeny, S. 25Hermes, N. 25Lensink, R. 25

    McGillivray, M., et al. (2006) 3, 13Feeny, S. 13Hermes, N. 13Lensink, R. 13

    McKay, J. xiiiMcKinley, R. D. 6, 13, 114, 156Mdecins Sans Frontires 34Mercy Corps 52Mexico 34, 50t, 61t, 67t, 171,

    1723t, 196b, 205, 218, 230

    micro-credit 216micro-economics 185, 197micro-finance 221

    micromacro disconnect 198micromacro gap 41, 42micromacro paradox (Mosley) 3, 5,

    18791, 192, 199, 202,2067(n1321), 228

    project results versus country results187

    micro-states 60Middle East 202

    Middle East and North Africa 358,47, 182

    migrants/migration 60, 201, 203Millennium Challenge Account 16Millennium Challenge Corporation

    16, 24(n3)Millennium Development Goals

    (MDGs) 1, 2, 47, 11, 356,589, 75, 1945, 200, 212

    minority groups 222MISEREOR 52model selection criteria 172nmodelling of determinants approach

    216Moldova 34, 47, 50t, 183Molenaar, H. 52nmonetary policy 188Mongolia 50t, 196b

    monitoring 40, 81, 106, 131,206(n2), 207(n18), 223

    monitoring and evaluation (M&E)systems 222

    monopolies 53(n9)Moore, B. 55Moore, M. 112moral hazard 116, 117Morocco 50t, 61t, 66t, 196b, 198

    Morosino, P. 29Morrissey, O. xii, 3, 4, 10, 13, 58,

    76(n3), 78, 158, 178(n9), 178, 179

    Morrissey, O., et al. (2006) 163, 175, 179Islei, O. 179MAmanja, D. 179

    Morrissey, O., et al. (2007) 170, 177,179

    Lloyd, T. 179

    MAmanja, D. 179

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    34/43

    Index 251

    Morss, E. R. 801, 113

    programme aid 82

    Mosley, P. 3, 13, 76(n1), 114, 156,

    212, 228Mozambique 47, 50t, 83t, 183, 226,

    230

    Mtwara (Tanzania) 214t

    Mummert, U. 210

    Munro, L. 153(n2), 156

    Murdoch, J. C. 29, 30

    Murrell, P. 210

    Myanmar 39, 50t

    NAFTA (North American Free TradeAgreement) 205

    Namibia 50t

    naming-and-shaming 81

    Nash equilibria 1920

    nation-building 186

    national security 186

    natural experiments 220natural resources 185, 197, 200, 202,

    206(n14)

    Naudet, J. D. 31

    neo-institutionalists 45

    Nepal 50t, 62t, 66t, 196b

    Netherlands 7, 69t, 69, 121t, 122,139, 140t, 142t, 144t, 146t, 152t,2067(n14)

    aid allocation processes 1301aid allocations 4851t

    NGOs 32, 36f, 36, 37t, 46f,4751

    Netherlands: Ministry of ForeignAffairs 40, 523n

    Netherlands: Ministry of ForeignAffairs (Division of Effectivenessand Quality) 52

    Neumayer, E. 33, 56, 11415, 156New Zealand 69t, 121t, 139, 141t,

    143t, 145t, 147t, 152t,207(n22)

    aid allocation process 132

    Nicaragua 34, 47, 50t

    Niger 50t, 623t, 66t, 183

    Nigeria 34, 42, 47, 50t, 221

    Nijmegen: Radboud University

    523n

    Nissanke, M. 6, 114, 156Nitzan, S. 20, 245Noakhali Rural Development Project

    (Bangladesh) 225, 230non-governmental organizations

    (NGOs) 8, 15, 24(n1), 37,54(n14), 82, 188, 1912, 200

    choice of location 278

    clustering 8comparative advantage 26concentration and

    complementarity of aid 2657

    country allocation processes(background) 323, 53(n2)

    country-wise disbursement pattern45

    financial dependence on backdonors 45, 46f

    German, Norwegian, American,Dutch 32, 346, 37t, 46f, 4752

    humanitarian 34

    international 52interviews 512local 40versus back donors (country-wise

    disbursements) 45, 46f, 46non-governmental organizations: aid

    41, 53(n10)complement view versus substitute

    view 3841, 53(n69)

    per donor country 36fsub-national level 27

    non-profit location theory 278, 29,53(n1), 54

    non-profit organizations 45ignore equity, particularistic

    312Nordic countries/Scandinavia 7,

    115, 136, 155(n16)

    normality (vector tests) 171Norway 7, 69t, 121t, 122, 141t, 143t,

    145t, 147t, 149t, 151t, 152t,207(n22)

    aid allocation and aid effectiveness(19902003): sensitivity analysis136

    aid allocation and aid effectiveness(19992003): sensitivity analysis

    138

  • 8/2/2019 0230221696

    35/43

    252 Index

    Norway continued

    aid allocation process 133

    aid allocations 4851t

    NGOs 32, 34, 36f, 36, 37t, 46f,4752

    Norway: Ministry of Developmentcooperation (NORAD) 47, 52

    Norway: Royal Ministry of ForeignAffairs x

    Norwegian Church Aid 52

    Norwegian Peoples Aid 52

    Novib (now OxfamNovib) 51

    Nunnenkamp, P. 12(n2), 13, 155

    nutrition 213, 215, 223, 224

    observables/unobservables 227f

    official aid (OA) 42, 120t

    official development assistance (ODA)xiv, 1, 24(n1)

    see also aid

    Ohlin, G. 211, 231

    Okonjo-Iweala, N. 208(n334), 209

    Oliver, C. 30

    Oman 50t, 171, 1723t, 175

    open economies 24(n3)

    Opoku-Afari, M. v, xii, 10, 158,178(n9)

    opportunity cost 117

    ordinary least squares (OLS) 64,155(n18)

    two-stage/three-stage 160

    Organisation for EconomicCo-operation and Development

    aid budget (public perception)205, 208(n36)

    data source 60

    OECD countries 1, 38, 185, 205,

    208(n36)Organisation for Economic

    Co-operation and Development:Development AssistanceCommittee 115, 119, 190b,20810

    aid statistics (major problem) 170

    member countries 2f

    conference (March 2005) 190b

    countries aided by 34, 53(n11)

    data source/statistics 42, 51n,53(n10), 64, 68, 823n, 92n, 113,116, 120t, 125, 139, 170

    donors 133IEGDAC initiative 229n

    ODA 2f, 24(n1)

    OECD DAC: Creditor ReportingSystem (CRS) database 60, 813,91, 112(n23)

    OECD DAC: DevelopmentCooperation Report (2003) 192

    OECD DAC: Network on

    Development Evaluation 192organizational design 27

    organizational growth 30

    Osei, R., et al. (2003) 161, 179

    Lloyd, T. 179

    Morrissey, O. 179

    Osei