41
© 2013 Pearson Australia

© 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Page 2: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

12 Consumer Choicesand Constraints

Page 3: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

After studying this chapter you will be able to

Describe a household’s budget line and show how it changes when prices or income change

Use indifference curves to map preferences and explain the principle of diminishing marginal rate of substitution

Predict the effects of changes in prices and income on consumption choices

Page 4: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

As the prices of music downloads and e-books have fallen, we’re downloading ever more songs and books.

But e-books have made a smaller inroad into the overall market for books than downloads have in the market for recorded music.

Why?

As the price of a DVD rental has fallen we’re renting ever more of them, but we’re also going to movie theatres in ever-greater numbers.

Why are we going to the movies more when it is so cheap and easy to rent a DVD?

Page 5: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Consumption Possibilities

A household’s consumption choices are constrained by its income and the prices of the goods and services available.

The budget line describes the limits to the household’s consumption choices.

Page 6: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Consumption Possibilities

Lisa has $40 to spend, the price of a movie is $8 and the price of soft drink is $4 a case.

The rows of the table show combinations of soft drink and movies that Lisa can buy with her $40.

The graph plots these six possible combinations.

Page 7: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Consumption Possibilities

Lisa can afford any of the combinations at points A to F.

Some goods are indivisible goods and must be bought in whole units at the points marked (such as movies).

Other goods are divisible goods and can be bought in any quantity (such as petrol).

The line through points A to F is Lisa’s budget line.

Page 8: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Consumption Possibilities

The budget line is a constraint on Lisa’s consumption choices.

Lisa can afford any point on her budget line or inside it.

Lisa cannot afford any point outside her budget line.

Page 9: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

The Budget Equation

We can describe the budget line by using a budget equation.

The budget equation states that

Expenditure = Income

Call the price of soft drink PS, the quantity of soft drink QS, the price of a movie PM, the quantity of movies QM, and income Y.

Lisa’s budget equation is:

PSQS + PMQM = Y.

Consumption Possibilities

Page 10: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

PSQS + PMQM = Y

Divide both sides of this equation by PS, to give:

QS + (PM/PS)QM = Y/PS

Then subtract (PM/PS)QM from both sides of the equation to give:

QS = Y/PS – (PM/PS)QM

Y/PS is Lisa’s real income in terms of soft drink.

PM/PS is the relative price of a movie in terms of soft drink.

Consumption Possibilities

Page 11: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

A household’s real income is the income expressed as a quantity of goods the household can afford to buy.

Lisa’s real income in terms of soft drink is the point on her budget line where it meets the y-axis.

A relative price is the price of one good divided by the price of another good.

Relative price is the magnitude of the slope of the budget line.

The relative price shows how many cases of soft drink must be forgone to see an additional movie.

Consumption Possibilities

Page 12: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

A Change in Prices

A rise in the price of the good on the x-axis decreases the affordable quantity of that good and increases the slope of the budget line.

The budget line has become steeper because the relative price of movies has increased.

Consumption Possibilities

Page 13: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Consumption Possibilities

A fall in the price of the good on the x-axis increases the affordable quantity of that good and decreases the slope of the budget line.

The budget line has become flatter because the relative price of movies has decreased.

Page 14: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

A Change in Income

An change in money income brings a parallel shift of the budget line.

The slope of the budget line doesn’t change because the relative price doesn’t change.

Figure 12.2(b) shows the effect of a fall in income.

Consumption Possibilities

Page 15: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

An indifference curve is a line that shows combinations of goods among which a consumer is indifferent.

Figure 12.3(a) illustrates a consumer’s indifference curve.

At point C, Lisa sees 2 movies and drinks 6 cases of soft drink a month.

Preferences and Indifference Curves

Page 16: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Preferences and Indifference Curves

Lisa can sort all possible combinations of goods into three groups: preferred, not preferred, and just as good as point C.

An indifference curve joins all those points that Lisa says are just as good as C.

G is such a point. Lisa is indifferent between the combination at point C and at point G.

Page 17: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

All the points on the indifference curve are preferred to all the points below the indifference curve.

All the points above the indifference curve are preferred to all the points on the indifference curve.

Preferences and Indifference Curves

Page 18: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

A preference map is a series of indifference curves.

Call the indifference curve that we’ve just seen I1.

I0 is an indifference curve below I1.

Lisa prefers any point on I1 to any point on I0 .

Preferences and Indifference Curves

Page 19: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

I2 is an indifference curve above I1.

Lisa prefers any point on I2 to any point on I1 .

For example, Lisa prefers the combination at point J to the combination at either point C or point G.

Preferences and Indifference Curves

Page 20: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Marginal Rate of Substitution

The marginal rate of substitution, (MRS) measures the rate at which a person is willing to give up good y to get an additional unit of good x while at the same time remaining indifferent (remaining on the same indifference curve).

The magnitude of the slope of the indifference curve measures the marginal rate of substitution.

Preferences and Indifference Curves

Page 21: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

If the indifference curve is relatively steep, the MRS is high.

In this case, the person is willing to give up a large quantity of y to get a bit more x.

If the indifference curve is relatively flat, the MRS is low.

In this case, the person is willing to give up a small quantity of y to get more x.

Preferences and Indifference Curves

Page 22: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

A diminishing marginal rate of substitution is the key assumption of consumer theory.

A diminishing marginal rate of substitution is a general tendency for a person to be willing to give up less of good y to get one more unit of good x, while at the same time remain indifferent as the quantity of good x increases.

Preferences and Indifference Curves

Page 23: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Figure 12.4 shows the diminishing MRS of movies for soft drink.

At point C, Lisa is willing to give up 2 cases of soft drink to see one more movie—her MRS is 2.

At point G, Lisa is willing to give up 1/2 case of soft drink to see one more movie—her MRS is 1/2.

Preferences and Indifference Curves

Page 24: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Degree of Substitutability

The shape of the indifference curves reveals the degree of substitutability between two goods. Figure 12.5 shows the indifference curves for ordinary goods, perfect substitutes, and perfect complements.

Preferences and Indifference Curves

Page 25: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Predicting Consumer Choices

Best Affordable Choice

The consumer’s best affordable choice is

On the budget line

On the highest attainable indifference curve

Has a marginal rate of substitution between the two goods equal to the relative price of the two goods

Page 26: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Here, the best affordable point is C.

Lisa can afford to consume more soft drink and see fewer movies at point F.

And she can afford to see more movies and consume less soft drink at point H.

But she is indifferent between F, I, and H and she prefers C to I.

Predicting Consumer Choices

Page 27: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

At point F, Lisa’s MRS is greater than the relative price.

At point H, Lisa’s MRS is less than the relative price.

At point C, Lisa’s MRS is equal to the relative price.

Predicting Consumer Choices

Page 28: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Predicting …A Change in Price

The effect of a change in the price of a good on the quantity of the good consumed is called the price effect.

Figure 12.7 illustrates the price effect and shows how the consumer’s demand curve is generated.

Initially, the price of a movie is $8 and Lisa consumes at point C in part (a) and at point A in part (b).

Page 29: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

The price of a movie then falls to $4.

The budget line rotates outward.

Lisa’s best affordable point is now J in part (a).

In part (b), Lisa moves to point B, which is a movement along her demand curve for movies.

Predicting …

Page 30: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

A Change in Income

The effect of a change in income on the quantity of a good consumed is called the income effect.

Figure 12.8 illustrates the effect of a decrease in Lisa’s income.

Initially, Lisa consumes at point J in part (a) and at point B on demand curve D0 in part (b).

Predicting …

Page 31: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Lisa’s income decreases and her budget line shifts leftward in part (a).

Her new best affordable point is K in part (a).

Her demand for movies decreases, shown by a leftward shift of her demand curve for movies in part (b).

Predicting …

Page 32: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Predicting Consumer Choices

Substitution Effect and Income Effect

For a normal good, a fall in price always increases the quantity consumed.

We can prove this assertion by dividing the price effect in two parts:

Substitution effect

Income effect

Page 33: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Initially, Lisa has an income of $40, the price of a movie is $8, and she consumes at point C.

Lisa’s best affordable point is now J.

The move from point C to point J is the price effect.

The price of a movie falls from $8 to $4 and her budget line rotates outward.

Predicting Consumer Choices

Page 34: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

We’re going to break the move from point C to point J into two parts.

The first part is the substitution effect and the second is the income effect.

Predicting Consumer Choices

Page 35: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Substitution Effect

The substitution effect is the effect of a change in price on the quantity bought when the consumer remains on the same indifference curve.

Predicting Consumer Choices

Page 36: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

To isolate the substitution effect, we give Lisa a hypothetical pay cut.

Lisa is now back on her original indifference curve but with a lower price of movies and her best affordable point is K.

The move from C to K is the substitution effect.

Predicting Consumer Choices

Page 37: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

The direction of the substitution effect never varies:

When the relative price falls, the consumer always substitutes more of that good for other goods.

The substitution effect is the first reason why the demand curve slopes downward.

Predicting Consumer Choices

Page 38: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Predicting Consumer Choices

Income Effect

To isolate the income effect, we reverse the hypothetical pay cut and restore Lisa’s income to its original level (its actual level).

Lisa is now back on indifference curve I2 and her best affordable point is J.

The move from K to J is the income effect.

Page 39: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

For Lisa, movies are a normal good.

With more income to spend, she sees more movies—the income effect is positive.

For a normal good, the income effect reinforces the substitution effect and is the second reason why the demand curve slopes downward.

Predicting Consumer Choices

Page 40: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

Inferior Goods

For an inferior good, when income increases, the quantity bought decreases.

The income effect is negative and works against the substitution effect.

So long as the substitution effect dominates, the demand curve still slopes downward.

Predicting Consumer Choices

Page 41: © 2013 Pearson Australia. 12 Consumer Choices and Constraints

© 2013 Pearson Australia

If the negative income effect is stronger than the substitution effect, a lower price for inferior goods brings a decrease in the quantity demanded—the demand curve slopes upward!

This case does not appear to occur in the real world.

Predicting Consumer Choices