COPING WITH THE COLLAPSE A Stock-Flow Consistent, Monetary Macro-dynamics of … · 2016-12-22 ·...

Preview:

Citation preview

0/69

AIEE Energy SymposiumCurrent and Future Challenges to Energy Security

COPING WITH THE COLLAPSE

A Stock-Flow Consistent, Monetary Macro-dynamics of Global Warming

December 1, 2016

Gaël Giraud Florent Mc Isaac Emmanuel Bovari Ekaterina Zatsepina

University of Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne

Chair Energy and Prosperity

Centre d’Économie de la Sorbonne

Agence Française de Développement

1/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

2/69

� IntroductionClimate change as a milestone for the XXIst century

3/69

� IntroductionThe 2008 crisis: a revival of Minsky’s theory of financial instability

myf.red/g/7Dv0

-4

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

4.0

4.8

5.6

6.4

7.2

8.0

8.8

9.6

10.4

11.2

1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

fred.stlouisfed.org

NonfinancialBusiness;CreditMarketInstruments;Liability,Level/GrossDomesticProduct(left)CivilianUnemploymentRate(right)

%C

hg.o

f(B

il.o

f$/B

il.o

f$)

Percent

Figure: Time series of the private debt ratio and employment rate in the United States over the period 1990-2010.

4/69

� IntroductionKey research highlights

1. Combine two sources of global instabilities (climate and finance) in a min-imal and rational framework to provide prospective analysis insight on theclimate-economy interactions

2. Identify the instability factors and their transmission channels (in particularthe pivotal role of private debt)

3. Provide public policy guidance for the implementation of the emblematicobjective of the Paris Agreement to contain global warming below 1.5◦C

5/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 ContextThe Keen model (1995)[9]

The DICE model (2013)[11]

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

6/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 ContextThe Keen model (1995)[9]

The DICE model (2013)[11]

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

7/69

� Context – The Keen model (1995)[9]

Theoretical elements

� Minimum (bounded) rationality

� Endogenous business cycles as in the Goodwin model (1967)[6]

� Mathematical formalization of Minsky’s moment� Lotka-Volterra relationship linking the employment rate to the wage share� Dynamics of the private debt of firms

� Phenomenological empirical approach to ground aggregated behavior:� Short-term Phillips curve (Mankiw (2010)[10], Krugman (2014))� Investment function

� Dualism of long-term equilibria:� A desirable steady-state equilibrium� A bad attractor leading to a breakdown

8/69

� Context – The Keen model (1995)[9]

Convergence to the locally asymptotically stable steady-state equilibrium

Figure: Phase diagram in the Keen model (1995)[9].

9/69

� Context – The Keen model (1995)[9]

Viability analysis through the basin of attraction

Figure: Basin of attraction of the desirable steady-state in the Keen model. Source: Grasselli et al. (2012)[7]

10/69

� Context – The Keen model (1995)[9]

Stock-Flow consistency “à la” Godley-Lavoie (2012)[5]

Households Firms Banks Sum

Balance SheetDeposits M -MCapital K KDebt −D D

Net Wealth Xh Xf Xb X

Transactions current capitalConsumption −C CInvestment I −IAccounting Memo [PIB] [Y ]Wages W −WInterests on Debt −rD rDNet Profits −Π Π

Financial Balance −D Πb

Flow of FundsGross Fixed Capital Formation I IChange in Loans −D DColumn Sum Π D I

Change in Net Wealth X f = Π − δK ˙Xb = Πb X

Table: Balance sheet, transactions, and flow of funds in the world economy.

11/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 ContextThe Keen model (1995)[9]

The DICE model (2013)[11]

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

12/69

� Context – The DICE model (2013)[11]

A seminal model of IAMs

Figure: Trajectories from the model Dynamic Integrated Climate Economy (DICE). Source: Nordhaus (2013)[11].

13/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the modelThe macroeconomic frameworkThe climate moduleClimate damages and mitigationWrap-up: stock-flow consistent table

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

14/69

� Structure of the modelKey modeling highlights

Taking advantage of two prominent models:

� The macrodynamic model of Keen (1995)[9] refined with:� Price system under imperfect competition (Grasselli et al. (2014)[8])� Sigmoïd pattern of the global workforce (UN population scenarios (2015)[1])� Dividends payments of firms to households

� The DICE model of Nordhaus (2013)[11] refined with:� More convex damage functions (Weitzman (2011)[13], Dietz et al. (2015)[3])� Allocation of environmental damage between:

1. Output

2. Capital accumulation (Dietz et al. (2015)[3])

3. Labor productivity (Burke et al. (2015)[2])

15/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the modelThe macroeconomic frameworkThe climate moduleClimate damages and mitigationWrap-up: stock-flow consistent table

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

16/69

� Structure of the model – The macroeconomic frameworkFramework

� Closed economy

� Continuous time

� No public sector

� Three agents: households, firms and banks

17/69

� Structure of the model – The macroeconomic frameworkMain variables considered

� Real output: Y

� Global workforce: N

� Employed workforce: L

� Unitary wage: w

� Private debt stock: D

� Short-term interest rate: r

� Price index level: p

� Capital stock: K

� Dividend payment: Di

� The net result of firms: Π = pY − wL − rD

18/69

� Structure of the model – The macroeconomic frameworkThe reduced variables

� The profit share: π :=Π

pY

� The employment rate: λ :=LN

� The private debt ratio: d :=D

pY

� The global workforce: N

19/69

� Structure of the model – The macroeconomic frameworkThe main macroeconomic relations

� The production: Y :=Kν

� The capital accumulation: K := I − δK

� The private debt accumulation: D := pI + ∆(π)pY − Π

� Short-term Phillips curve:ww

:= Φ(λ) + γi

� Price dynamics: i :=pp

:= ηp(mω − 1) + iLT

� The global workforce dynamics:NN

:= q(

1 − NP

)

� The labor productivity: a := (1 − D)YL

20/69

� Structure of the model – The macroeconomic frameworkDifferential system

� A 4-dimensional system of differential equations:

ω = ω[

Φ(λ) − (1 − γ)i(ω) − aa

]λ = λ

[YY − a

a − NN

]d = d

[r −

(YY + i(ω)

)]+ κ(π) + ∆(π) − (1 − ω)

N = qN(

1 − NPN

)� Where intervene the following variables of interest:

π = 1 − ω − rd

YY

=κ(π)

ν− δ

i(ω) = ηp(mω − 1) + c

21/69

� Structure of the model – The macroeconomic frameworkConvergence toward a steady-state without climate change

Figure: Phase diagram in the absence of climate change (calibrated model).

22/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the modelThe macroeconomic frameworkThe climate moduleClimate damages and mitigationWrap-up: stock-flow consistent table

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

23/69

� Structure of the model – The climate modulePhysical process overview

Real Output

CO2 Emissions

CO2 Accumulation

Radiative Forcing

Temperature Change

Figure: Climate-economy interactions diagram.

24/69

� Structure of the model – The climate moduleCO2 emissions

Global CO2 emissions are the sum of two contributions: E := Eind + Eland

� Endogenous industrial emissions:

Eind := Yσ(1 − n)

� Proportional to real output Y

� Emission intensity of the economy: σ

� Emissions reduction rate: n

� Exogenous emissions linked to land-use change Eland

25/69

� Structure of the model – The climate moduleCO2 accumulation (1/2)

Layer AT

Atmosphere

Layer UP

Biosphere Upper part of the oceans

Layer AT

Lower part of the oceans

Three-Layer Model of CO2 Accumulation

CO2 Emissions

Radiative Forcing

Figure: CO2 accumulation in a three-layer model.

26/69

� Structure of the model – The climate moduleCO2 accumulation (2/2)

Modeling through the following system:

˙CO2AT

˙CO2UP

˙CO2LO

:=

E00

+

−φ12 φ12

COATinit2

COUPinit2

0

φ12 −φ12CO

ATinit2

COUPinit2

− φ23 φ23CO

UPinit2

COLOinit2

0 φ23 −φ23CO

UPinit2

COLOinit2

COAT

2

COUP2

COLO2

27/69

� Structure of the model – The climate moduleRadiative forcing

Radiative forcing is the sum of two contributions: F := Find + Fexo

� CO2 accumulation in the atmospheric layer:

Find :=F2×CO2

log(2)log

(COAT

2

COATinit2

)

� Exogenous radiative forcing Fexo to model residual factors (dynamics cal-ibrated on the IPCCs’ RCPs (2013)[12])

28/69

� Structure of the model – The climate moduleTemperature change (1/2)

Upper Layer

AtmosphereBiosphere

Upper part of the oceans

Lower Layer

Lower part of the oceans

Two-Layer Model of Mean Temperature

Radiative Forcing

Real Output Damage

Figure: Dynamics of temperature.

29/69

� Structure of the model – The climate moduleTemperature change (2/2)

Temperature’s evolution is inspired by Geoffroy et al. (2013)[4]:

� Energy Balanced

� A two-layer model:

� Atmosphere, biosphere, ocean upper level (temperature anomaly):

CT = F − ρT − γ∗(T − T0)

� Deep ocean (temperature anomaly T0):

C0T0 = γ∗(T − T0)

30/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the modelThe macroeconomic frameworkThe climate moduleClimate damages and mitigationWrap-up: stock-flow consistent table

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

31/69

� Structure of the model – Climate damages and mitigationEnvironmental damages due to global warming

0,0

0,1

0,2

0,3

0,4

0,5

0,6

0,7

0,8

0,9

1,0

0 1 2 3 4 5 6

Da

ma

ge

s (

fra

ctio

n o

f o

utp

ut)

Temperature increase (°C)

Nordhaus Weitzman Dietz and Stern

Figure: Comparison of the shape of covered damage functions.

32/69

� Structure of the model – Climate damages and mitigationAllocation of environmental damages between output flows and capital stock

� Allocation of damages according to:

� Damages on capital stock:DK := fK D

� Damages on output flows:

DY := 1 −1 − D

1 − DK

� Introduction of damages in the macroeconomic model:

� Capital accumulation:K := I − (δ + DK)K

� Production function:Y := (1 − DY)

33/69

� Structure of the model – Climate damages and mitigationEnvironmental damages on labor productivity

� Alternate definition of the damage function introduced by Burke et al.(2015)[2] as a quadratic alteration of the labor productivity.

� Endogenous labor productivity growth:

aa

:= α1Ta + α2T 2a

34/69

� Structure of the model – Climate damages and mitigationMitigation effort

� Impulsed by the emission reduction rate n sets by public authorities, in-spired by Nordhaus (2013)[11] :

� Exogenous trajectories of the carbon price pC

� Exogenous de-growth trajectories of the backstop technology pNC

� Arbitrage relationship:

n := min

{(pc

pNC

) 1θ2−1

; 1

}

35/69

� Structure of the model – Climate damages and mitigationAbatement cost of carbon

� The implementation of mitigation effort impose a burden on the economymodeled through the abatement cost of carbon: G := θ1σpBSnθ2

� This cost is partly born by firms:

� The effective Gross Capital Fixed Formation: Ief := (κ(π) − µG)Y

� The accumulation of capital:

K := Ief − δK

= κ(π)Y −(δ + DK +

µ

νG)

K

� The dynamics of private debt:

D := pI + ∆(π)pY − Π

36/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the modelThe macroeconomic frameworkThe climate moduleClimate damages and mitigationWrap-up: stock-flow consistent table

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

37/69

� Structure of the model – Wrap-up: stock-flow consistent tableStock-flow consistency à la(Godley et Lavoie (2012)[5]

Households Firms Banks Sum

Balance SheetDeposits + M - MCapital stock pK pKLoan −D D

Sum (net worth) Xh Xf Xb X

Transactions current capitalConsumption −pC pCInvestment pI −pIAccounting memo [GDP] [pY (1 − DY )]Wages W −WInterests on debt −rD rDFirms’ net profit −Π ΠDividends Di −DiFinancial Balances Sh −D Πb

Flow of fundsDeposits +M -MGross Fixed Capital Formation pI pIChange in loans −D D

Column sum Sh Π − Di D pI

Change in net worth Sh X f = Π − Di + (p − (δ + DK +µν

G)pK ˙Xb = Πb X

Table: Balance sheet, transactions, and flow of funds in the world economy.

38/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate changeMathematical analysisNumerical analysis

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

39/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate changeMathematical analysisNumerical analysis

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

40/69

� Impact of climate change – Mathematical analysisProperties of the global long-term equilibria

1. The energy shift is performed (no more emissions or abatement cost)

2. The climate and economic modules are decoupled and can be studiedseparately

3. The climate module admits a unique equilibrium characterized by:

(i) The quantity of CO2 is the sum of the predindustrial one plus total emissions(ii) The relative preindustrial quantities of CO2 in each layer are respected

(iii) The mean atmospheric deviation is constant and strictly positive(iv) The radiative forcing is constant and strictly positive

4. The macroeconomic module admits at least 2 equilibria

41/69

� Impact of climate change – Mathematical analysisShape of the steady-state macroeconomic equilibrium

� Assuming constant prices, the steady-state equilibrium is defined by:

π1 = κ−1

(ν(

gaeq +δ+DKeq)

1−DYeq

)ω1 = 1 − π1 − rd1

= 1 −(

1 − rgaeq

)π1 − r κ(π1)+∆(π1)

gaeq

λ1 = Φ−1(gaeq )

d1 =κ(π1)+∆(π1)−π1

gaeq

N1 = P

gaeq =aa

(T = T eq)

� At the desirable steady-state, the income distribution is shifted at the ex-pense of households:

� Converse forces on the profit share reasonably pushed forward� Increased debt ratio by cutting wages in case of “over-optimism”� Unfavorable for wage share

42/69

� Impact of climate change – Mathematical analysisStability of the macroeconomic equilibria

� Assuming a constant dividend and considering damages on output:

� A necessary condition for the stability of the steady state equilibrium is:

π1 >ν(δ + DK

eq)

1 − DYeq

� A necessary condition for the stability of the breakdown attractor is:

r >κ0

ν(1 − DY

eq) − (δ + DKeq)

� The local stability conditions are twisted by climate in favor of the break-down attractor

� Global warming tends to drive the economy out of the desirable steady-state basin of attraction

43/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate changeMathematical analysisNumerical analysis

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

44/69

� Impact of climate change – Numerical analysisTemperature paths of the steady-state (1/3)

Figure: Bifurcation graph of the steady-state – Damage on output.

45/69

� Impact of climate change – Numerical analysisTemperature paths of the steady-state (2/3)

Figure: Bifurcation graph of the steady-state – Damage on output and capital.

46/69

� Impact of climate change – Numerical analysisTemperature paths of the steady-state (2/3)

Figure: Bifurcation graph of the steady-state – Damage on capital and labor productivity.

47/69

� Impact of climate change – Numerical analysisBasin of attraction of the steady-state (1/3)

Figure: Basin of attraction without climate change.

48/69

� Impact of climate change – Numerical analysisBasin of attraction of the steady-state (2/3)

Figure: Basin of attraction with damages on output and capital.

49/69

� Impact of climate change – Numerical analysisBasin of attraction of the steady-state (3/3)

Figure: Basin of attraction with damages on capital and labor productivity.

50/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospectiveScope of analysisLow mitigation constraintDeployment of carbon-price instrumentMinimal prospective paths

6 Conclusions

51/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospectiveScope of analysisLow mitigation constraintDeployment of carbon-price instrumentMinimal prospective paths

6 Conclusions

52/69

� Climate prospective – Scope of analysisSimulations calibration

� Identification thanks to the stock-flow consistency property

� Macroeconomic module:� Build a database at World level

World Bank, Penn, Bureau of Economic Analysis, United Nations� Estimation and calibration of the phenomenological functions� Main economic variables:

Parameters Y2010 N2010 ω2010 λ2010 d2010 p2010value 64.4565 4.5510 0.5849 0.6910 1.4393 1

� Climate module: calibrated on DICE (2013)[11]

� Damage function and endogenous labor productivity growth: literature

53/69

� Climate prospective – Scope of analysisDesign of the prospective scenarios

� Prospective analysis through 5 classes of scenarios:� Baseline: absent climate change� Nordhaus: Nordhaus-type damage on output� Stern: allocation of Weitzman-type damage between output and capital� Burke: Weitzman-type damage on capital and Burke-type damage on labor

productivity� Burke Extreme: Dietz-type damage on capital and Burke-type damage on

labor productivity

� Public policy insight to cope with potential collapse through the appropri-ate carbon-price instrument:

1. Run of the scenarios with a low-constraining carbon-price path2. Analysis of carbon-price instrument deployment trade-offs compatible with

the realization of the +1.5◦C limitation of global warming in 2100 of the ParisAgreement

3. Proposal of minimal carbon-price path for public policy implementation

54/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospectiveScope of analysisLow mitigation constraintDeployment of carbon-price instrumentMinimal prospective paths

6 Conclusions

55/69

� Climate prospective – Low mitigation constraintAn imperious need for public involvement (1/3)

-0.06

-0.04

-0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosBaselineNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Real growth rate (yearly computation)

-0.04

-0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosBaselineNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Inflation rate (yearly computation)

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosBaselineNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Employment rate

1

2

3

4

5

6

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosBaselineNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Private debt ratio

Figure: Trajectories of the main macroeconomic and climate variables absent strong mitigation constraints.

56/69

� Climate prospective – Low mitigation constraintAn imperious need for public involvement (2/3)

0

5

10

15

20

25

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosBaselineNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Global emissions per capita

0

2

4

6

8

10

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosBaselineNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Mean atmospheric temperature deviation

Figure: Trajectories of the main macroeconomic and climate variables absent strong mitigation constraints.

57/69

� Climate prospective – Low mitigation constraintAn imperious need for public involvement (3/3)

0.50 0.52 0.54 0.56 0.58 0.60 0.62

0.69

0.70

0.71

0.72

0.73

0.74

Phase diagram - Nordhaus Scenario - Horizon 2010 to 2500

Wage share

Empl

oym

ent r

ate

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

Phase diagram - Stern Scenario - Horizon 2010 to 2500

Wage share

Empl

oym

ent r

ate

Figure: Phase diagrams in a long term horizon.

58/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospectiveScope of analysisLow mitigation constraintDeployment of carbon-price instrumentMinimal prospective paths

6 Conclusions

59/69

� Climate prospective – Deployment of carbon-price instrumentStability vs Indebtedness trade-offs

0

100

200

300

400

2010 2015 2020 2025 2030

Initial Price102030405060708090

Carbon price

60

85

110

135

2010 2015 2020 2025 2030

Initial Price102030405060708090

Real output

0

1

2

3

4

2010 2015 2020 2025 2030

Initial Price102030405060708090

Private debt ratio

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

2010 2015 2020 2025 2030

Initial Price102030405060708090

Real output growth

Figure: Minimal carbon-price path implementation.

60/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospectiveScope of analysisLow mitigation constraintDeployment of carbon-price instrumentMinimal prospective paths

6 Conclusions

61/69

� Climate prospective – Minimal prospective pathsRealizing the Paris Agreement objective – Initial carbon-price of 10 (1/2)

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Real growth rate (yearly computation)

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Inflation rate (yearly computation)

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Employment rate

1

2

3

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Private debt ratio

Figure: Trajectories of the main macroeconomic and climate variables with minimal mitigation constraint.

62/69

� Climate prospective – Minimal prospective pathsRealizing the Paris Agreement objective – Initial carbon-price of 10 (2/2)

0

1

2

3

4

5

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Global emissions per capita

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Mean atmospheric temperature deviation

Figure: Trajectories of the main macroeconomic and climate variables with minimal mitigation constraint.

63/69

� Climate prospective – Minimal prospective pathsRealizing the +2◦C-global warming limitation objective – Initial carbon-price of 10 (1/2)

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Real growth rate (yearly computation)

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Inflation rate (yearly computation)

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Employment rate

1

2

3

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Private debt ratio

Figure: Trajectories of the main macroeconomic and climate variables with minimal mitigation constraint.

64/69

� Climate prospective – Minimal prospective pathsRealizing the +2◦C-global warming limitation objective – Initial carbon-price of 10 (2/2)

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Global emissions per capita

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

2000 2050 2100 2150 2200 2250 2300

ScenariosNordhausSternBurkeBurke Extreme

Mean atmospheric temperature deviation

Figure: Trajectories of the main macroeconomic and climate variables with minimal mitigation constraint.

65/69

� Summary

1 Introduction

2 Context

3 Structure of the model

4 Impact of climate change

5 Climate prospective

6 Conclusions

66/69

� ConclusionsMain results

� Development of a climate feedback framework in a stock-flow consistentmacroeconomic monetary model producing a wide range of outcomes

� Identification of the influence of climate change as a channel of financialinstability

� Key role of the temperature anomaly in the stability of the economy

� Inaction will most likely lead to a global collapse of the financial/socio-economic system

� Trade-off between climate and financial instability in the rhythm of imple-mentation of a carbon price path

� Involvement of firms more than ever necessary to perform this energyshit, as about 70% of the required investment to perform the energy shiftshall come from the private sector

67/69

� ConclusionsLimitations and further research

� Refine economic modeling:

� Substitution between capital and labor� Clarify public policy intervention (including tax incidence)� Clarify the energy shift process through investment and technology� Make explicit the demand side (consumption, public authorities)

� Add limitations on non-renewable energy and materials

� Build the spacial dimension of the energy shit

67/69

Thank you for your attention.

68/69

� Summary

7 Bibliography

69/69

� Bibliography[1] Population division. world population prospects 2015. Data booklet, United Nations, Department of Economic

and Social Affairs, Population Division, 2015.

[2] M. Burke, S. Hsiang, and E. Miguel. Global non-linear effect of temperature on economic production. Nature,527:235–39, November 2015.

[3] S. Dietz and N. Stern. Endogenous growth, convexity of damage and climate risk: How nordhaus’ frameworksupports deep cuts in carbon emissions. The Economic Journal, 125(583):574–620, 2015.

[4] O. Geoffroy, D. Saint-Martin, D. J. L. Olivié, A. Voldoire, G. Bellon, and S. Tytéca. Transient climate response ina two-layer energy-balance model. Part I: Analytical solution and parameter calibration using CMIP5 AOGCMexperiments. Journal of Climate, 26(6):1841–57, 2013.

[5] W. Godley and M. Lavoie. Monetary Economics: An Integrated Approach to Credit, Money, Income, Productionand Wealth. Palgrave Macmillan UK, 2012.

[6] R. M. Goodwin. A growth cycle. In Socialism, Capitalism and Economic Growth, pages 54–8. CambridgeUniversity Press, Cambridge, 1967.

[7] M. R. Grasselli and B. Costa Lima. An analysis of the Keen model for credit expansion, asset price bubbles andfinancial fragility. Mathematics and Financial Economics, 6(3):191–210, 2012.

[8] M. R. Grasselli and A. Nguyen-Huu. A two time scales model of monetary dynamics with variable utilization andcredit investment. Structural Changes and Economic Dynamics, december 2015.

[9] S. Keen. Finance and economic breakdown: modeling Minsky’s "financial instability hypothesis". Journal ofPost Keynesian Economics, pages 607–35, 1995.

[10] N.G. Mankiw. Macroeconomics. Worth Publishers, 2010.

[11] W. D. Nordhaus and P. Sztorc. DICE 2013R: Introduction and User’s Manual, October 2013.

[12] T. F. Stocker, D. Qin, G. Plattner, M. Tignor, S. K. Allen, J. Boschung, A. Nauels, Y. Xia, V. Bex, and P. M.Midgley. Climate change 2013: The physical science basis. Technical report, Intergovernmental Panel onClimate Change, 2013. 1535 pp.

[13] M. L. Weitzman. Fat-tailed uncertainty in the economics of catastrophic climate change. Review of Environ-mental Economics and Policy, 5(2):275–292, 2011.

Recommended