51
Market Failures: Public Goods and Externalities 05 McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

Chap5

  • Upload
    lonewiso

  • View
    2.661

  • Download
    10

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Market Failures: Public Goods and Externalities

05

McGraw-Hill/Irwin Copyright © 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

Market Failures

• Market fails to produce the right

amount of the product

• Resources may be:

•Over-allocated

•Under-allocated

LO1 5-2

Demand-Side Failures

• Impossible to charge consumers

what they are willing to pay for the

product

•Some can enjoy benefits without

paying

LO1 5-3

Supply-Side Failures

•Occurs when a firm does not pay

the full cost of producing its output

•External costs of producing the

good are not reflected in supply

LO1 5-4

Efficiently Functioning Markets

• Demand curve must reflect the

consumers full willingness to pay

• Supply curve must reflect all the costs

of production

LO1 5-5

Consumer Surplus

• Difference between what a consumer

is willing to pay for a good and what

the consumer actually pays

• Extra benefit from paying less than

the maximum price

LO2 5-6

Consumer Surplus

LO2

Consumer Surplus

(1)

Person

(2)

Maximum

Price Willing

to Pay

(3)

Actual Price

(Equilibrium

Price)

(4)

Consumer

Surplus

Bob $13 $8 $5 (=$13-$8)

Barb 12 8 4 (=$12-$8)

Bill 11 8 3 (=$11-$8)

Bart 10 8 2 (=$10-$8)

Brent 9 8 1 (= $9-$8)

Betty 8 8 0 (= $8-$8)

5-7

Consumer Surplus

LO2 LO2

Pri

ce

(p

er

ba

g)

Quantity (bags)

D

Q1

P1

Consumer

Surplus

Equilibrium

Price

5-8

Producer Surplus

• Difference between the actual price a

producer receives and the minimum

price they would accept

• Extra benefit from receiving a higher

price

LO2 5-9

Producer Surplus

LO2

Producer Surplus

(1)

Person

(2)

Minimum

Acceptable

Price

(3)

Actual Price

(Equilibrium

Price)

(4)

Producer

Surplus

Carlos $3 $8 $5 (=$8-$3)

Courtney 4 8 4 (=$8-$4)

Chuck 5 8 3 (=$8-$5)

Cindy 6 8 2 (=$8-$6)

Craig 7 8 1 (=$8-$7)

Chad 8 8 0 (=$8-$8)

5-10

Producer Surplus

LO2 LO2

Pri

ce (

per

bag

)

Quantity (bags)

S

Q1

P1

Equilibrium

price

Producer

surplus

5-11

Efficiency Revisited

LO2

Pri

ce

(p

er

ba

g)

Quantity (bags)

S

Q1

P1

D

Consumer

surplus

Producer

surplus

5-12

Quantity (bags)

Pri

ce (

per

bag

)

Efficiency Losses

LO2

c

S

Q1 Q2

D

b

d

a

e

Efficiency loss

from underproduction

5-13

Efficiency Losses

LO2

c

S

Q1 Q3

D

b

f

a

g

Quantity (bags)

Pri

ce

(p

er

ba

g)

Efficiency loss

from overproduction

5-14

Private Goods

• Produced in the market by firms

• Offered for sale

• Characteristics

•Rivalry

•Excludability

LO3 5-15

Public Goods

• Provided by government

•Offered for free

• Characteristics

•Nonrivalry

•Nonexcludability

• Free-rider problem

LO3 5-16

Summary

LO3 5-17

Excludable Non-excludable

Rivalrous Private Good Food, clothing, cars,

personal electronics

Common Goods Fish stocks, timber, coal

Non-rivalrous Club Good Cinemas, private parks,

satellite television

Public Good Free-to-air television, air,

national defense, city

fireworks shows

Demand for Public Goods

LO3

Demand for a Public Good, Two Individuals

(1)

Quantity

of Public

Good

(2)

Adams’ Willingness

to Pay (Price)

(3)

Benson’s

Willingness to

Pay (Price)

(4)

Collective

Willingness

to Pay (Price)

1 $4 + $5 = $9

2 3 + 4 = 7

3 2 + 3 = 5

4 1 + 2 = 3

5 0 + 1 = 1

5-18

Demand for Public Goods

LO3

$6

5

4

3

2

1

0

P

Q 1 2 3 4 5

$6

5

4

3

2

1 0

P

Q 1 2 3 4 5 Adams

Benson

D1

D2

Adams’ Demand

Benson’s Demand

$3 for 2 Items

$4 for 2 Items

$1 for 4 Items

$2 for 4 Items

$9

7

5

3

1

0

P

Q 1 2 3 4 5 Collective Demand and Supply

DC

S Collective Demand

$7 for 2 Items

$3 for 4 Items

Connect the Dots

Optimal Quantity

Collective Willingness

To Pay

5-19

Cost-Benefit Analysis

• Cost

•Resources diverted from private

good production

•Private goods that will not be

produced

• Benefit

• The extra satisfaction from the

output of more public goods

LO3 5-20

Cost-Benefit Analysis

LO3

Cost-Benefit Analysis for a National Highway Construction Project

(in Billions)

(1)

Plan

(2)

Total Cost

of Project

(3)

Marginal

Cost

(4)

Total

Benefit

(5)

Marginal

Benefit

(6)

Net Benefit

(4) – (2)

No new construction $0 $0 $0

A: Widen existing highways 4 $4 5 $5 1

B: New 2-lane highways 10 6 13 8 3

C: New 4-lane highways 18 8 22 10 5

D: New 6-lane highways 28 10 26 3 -2

5-21

Quasi-Public Goods

• Could be provided through the market

system

• Because of positive externalities the

government provides them

• Examples: education, streets,

libraries

LO3 5-22

The Reallocation Process

• Government

• Taxes individuals and businesses

• Takes the money and spends on

production of public goods

LO3 5-23

Externalities

• A cost or benefit accruing to a third

party external to the transaction

• Positive externalities

• Too little is produced

•Demand-side market failures

• Negative externalities

• Too much is produced

•Supply side market failures

LO4 5-24

Externalities

LO4

(a)

Negative externalities (b)

Positive externalities

0

D

S

St

Overallocation

Negative

Externalities St

Underallocation

Positive

Externalities

Qo Qo Qe Qe

P P

0 Q Q

D

Dt

a

c

z

x

b y

5-25

Government Intervention

• Correct negative externalities

•Direct controls

•Specific taxes

• Correct positive externalities

•Subsidies and government

provision

LO4 5-26

Government Intervention

LO4

(a)

Negative Externalities

D

S

St

Overallocation

Negative

Externalities

Qo Qe

P

0 Q

a

c

b

(b)

Correct externality with

tax

D

S

St

Qo Qe

P

0 Q

a

T

5-27

Government Intervention

LO4

(a)

Positive Externalities

0

St

Underallocation

Positive

Externalities

Qo Qe

D

Dt

z

x

y

(b)

Correcting via a subsidy

to consumers

0

St

Qo Qe

D

Dt

(c)

Correcting via a subsidy

to producers

0

S't

Qo Qe

D

Subsidy

St

Subsidy

U

5-28

Government Intervention

LO4

Methods for Dealing with Externalities

Problem

Resource Allocation

Outcome Ways to Correct

Negative externalities

(spillover costs)

Overproduction of output

and therefore

overallocation of

resources

1. Private bargaining

2. Liability rules and lawsuits

3. Tax on producers

4. Direct controls

5. Market for externality rights

Positive externalities

(spillover benefits)

Underproduction of output

and therefore

underallocation of

resources

1. Private bargaining

2. Subsidy to consumers

3. Subsidy to producers

4. Government provision

5-29

Society’s Optimal Amounts

LO5

0

So

cie

ty’s

Marg

inal

Be

nefi

t an

d M

arg

inal

Co

st

of

Po

llu

tio

n A

bate

men

t (D

ollars

)

Q1

MB

MC

Socially

Optimal Amount

Of Pollution

Abatement

5-30

Government’s Role in the Economy

• Government can have a role in

correcting externalities

• Officials must correctly identify the

existence and cause

• Has to be done in the context of

politics

LO5 5-31

Controlling Carbon Dioxide Emissions

• Cap and trade

•Sets a cap for the total amount of

emissions

•Assigns property rights to pollute

•Rights can then be bought and sold

• Carbon tax

•Raises cost of polluting

• Easier to enforce

5-32

Problem #1

Market failure is said to occur whenever:

A. private markets do not allocate resources

in the most economically desirable way.

B. prices rise.

C. some consumers who want a good do not

obtain it because the price is higher than

they are willing to pay.

D. government intervenes in the functioning

of private markets.

5-33

A

Problem #2

Refer to the diagrams for two separate product markets. Assume that

society's optimal level of output in each market is Q0 and that

government purposely shifts the market supply curve from S to S1 in

diagram (a) and from S to S2 in diagram (b). We can conclude that the

government is correcting for:

A. negative externalities in diagram (a) and positive externalities in

diagram (b).

B. positive externalities in diagram (a) and negative externalities in

diagram (b).

C. negative externalities in both diagrams.

D. positive externalities in both diagrams.

5-34

A

Problem #3

Refer to the diagrams for two separate product markets.

Assume that society's optimal level of output in each

market is Q0 and that government purposely shifts the

market supply curve from S to S1 in diagram (a) and from S

to S2 in diagram (b). The shift of the supply curve from S to

S1 in diagram (a) might be caused by a per unit:

A. subsidy paid to the producers of this product.

B. tax on the producers of this product.

C. subsidy paid to the buyers of this product.

D. tax on the buyers of this product.

5-35

B

Problem #4

Producer surplus:

A. is the difference between the maximum prices

consumers are willing to pay for a product and the

lower equilibrium price.

B. rises as equilibrium price falls.

C. is the difference between the minimum prices

producers are willing to accept for a product and

the higher equilibrium price.

D. is the difference between the maximum prices

consumers are willing to pay for a product and the

minimum prices producers are willing to accept.

5-36

C

Problem #5

The two main characteristics of a public

good are:

A. production at constant marginal cost

and rising demand.

B. nonexcludability and production at

rising marginal cost.

C. nonrivalry and nonexcludability.

D. nonrivalry and large negative

externalities.

5-37

C

Problem #6

Demand-side market failures occur when:

A. the demand and supply curves don't reflect

consumers' full willingness to pay for a good or

service.

B. the demand and supply curves don't reflect the

full cost of producing a good or service.

C. government imposes a tax on a good or

service.

D. a good or service is not produced because no

one demands it.

5-38

A

Problem #7

Amanda buys a ruby for $330 for which she was

willing to pay $340. The minimum acceptable price

to the seller, Tony, was $140. Amanda

experiences:

A. a consumer surplus of $10 and Tony

experiences a producer surplus of $190.

B. a producer surplus of $200 and Tony

experiences a consumer surplus of $10.

C. a consumer surplus of $670 and Tony

experiences a producer surplus of $200.

D. a producer surplus of $10 and Tony

experiences a consumer surplus of $190.

5-39

A

Problem #8

Unlike a private good, a public good:

A. has no opportunity costs.

B. has benefits available to all,

including nonpayers.

C. produces no positive or negative

externalities.

D. is characterized by rivalry and

excludability.

5-40

B

Problem #9

Refer to the above

diagram. Assuming

equilibrium price P1,

consumer surplus is

represented by

areas:

A. a + b.

B. a + b + c + d.

C. c + d.

D. a + c.

5-41

A

Problem #10

From society's perspective, in the presence of a

supply-side market failure, the last unit of a good

produced typically:

A. generates more of a benefit than it costs to

produce.

B. produces a benefit exactly equal to the cost of

producing the last unit.

C. maximizes the net benefit to society.

D. costs more to produce than it provides in

benefits.

5-42

D

Problem #11

Public goods are those for which there:

A. is no free-rider problem.

B. are no externalities.

C. is nonrivalry and nonexcludability.

D. is rivalry and excludability.

5-43

C

Problem #12

Refer to the

diagram. With MB1

and MC1, society's

optimal amount of

pollution abatement

is:

A. Q1.

B. Q2.

C. Q3.

D. Q4.

5-44

A

Problem #13

Which of the following statements is not

true?

A. Some public goods are paid for by

private philanthropy.

B. Private provision of public goods is

usually unprofitable.

C. The free-rider problem results from the

characteristics of nonrivalry and

nonexcludability.

D. Public goods are only provided by

government. 5-45

D

Problem #14

If the demand curve reflects consumers' full

willingness to pay, and the supply curve reflects all

costs of production, then which of the following is

true?

A. The benefit surpluses shared between

consumers and producers will be maximized.

B. The benefit surpluses received by consumers

and producers will be equal.

C. There will be no consumer or producer surplus.

D. Consumer surplus will be maximized, and

producer surplus will be minimized.

5-46

A

Problem #15

Which of the following statements is not

true?

A. Some public goods are paid for by private

philanthropy.

B. Private provision of public goods is

usually unprofitable.

C. The free-rider problem results from the

characteristics of nonrivalry and

nonexcludability.

D. Public goods are only provided by

government. 5-47

D

Problem #16

Refer to the diagram. If actual

production and consumption

occur at Q1:

A. efficiency is achieved.

B. consumer surplus is

maximized.

C. an efficiency loss (or

deadweight loss) of b + d

occurs.

D. an efficiency loss (or

deadweight loss) of e + d

occurs. 5-48

C

Problem #17

Allocative efficiency occurs only at that output

where:

A. marginal benefit exceeds marginal cost by the

greatest amount.

B. consumer surplus exceeds producer surplus by

the greatest amount.

C. the combined amounts of consumer surplus

and producer surplus are maximized.

D. the areas of consumer and producer surplus

are equal.

5-49

C

Problem #18

An efficiency loss (or deadweight loss):

A. is measured as the combined loss of consumer

surplus and producer surplus.

B. results from producing a unit of output for which

the maximum willingness to pay exceeds the

minimum acceptable price.

C. can result from underproduction, but not from

overproduction.

D. can result from overproduction, but not from

underproduction.

5-50

A

Problem #19

The MC curves in the above diagram slope

upward because of the law of:

A. demand.

B. conservation of matter and energy.

C. diminishing marginal utility.

D. diminishing returns.

5-51

D