31
INTERNATIONAL FOOD POLICY RESEARCH INSTITUTE Public grain reserves: International experience and lessons for Malawi Nicholas Minot International Food Policy Research Institute IFPRI-Malawi, Lilongwe, 27 January 2017

Public grain reserves: International experience and lessons for Malawi

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • INTERNATIONAL FOOD POLICY RESEARCH INSTITUTE

    Public grain reserves: International experience and lessons for Malawi

    Nicholas Minot

    International Food Policy Research Institute

    IFPRI-Malawi, Lilongwe,

    27 January 2017

  • 2

    Outline Objectives of public grain reserves Current issues

    Public food distribution Emergency relief Price stabilization

    International experience Future directions Conclusions & lessons for Malawi

  • Food and nutrition security: ensuring that all people at all times have access to sufficient nutritious food for a healthy, active life

    Public reserves can promote FNS in three ways Reserves can supply food distribution network

    assistance to chronically poor households Reserves facilitate emergency relief

    assistance to temporarily poor household due to flooding, drought, or other natural disaster

    Reserves can be used for food price stabilization reduce risk to households and farmers

    Objectives of public grain reserves

  • Capacity and stocks needed for public food distribution depend on: Monthly quantity distributed (Q) Average time (months) in storage (T) Capacity requirement = 2QT (under certain conditions)

    Current issues:Public food distribution

    Chart1

    50

    0

    50

    0

    50

    0

    50

    0

    50

    0

    50

    0

    50

    0

    Y-Values

    Months

    Quantity in stock over time

    Sheet1

    X-ValuesY-Values

    050

    10

    1.0150

    20

    2.0150

    30

    3.0150

    40

    4.0150

    50

    5.0150

    60

    6.0150

    70

  • Traditional approach: procurement in surplus areas or from imports, sell to consumers in urban areas and sometimes rural areas at subsidized prices

    Cost-effectiveness as poverty reduction strategy depends on targeting

    Studies show leakage to non-poor households is common

    Shift from universal distribution to geographic targeting to social safety net programs

    Current issues:Public food distribution

  • Capacity and stocks needed for emergency relief depend on: Time needed to obtain supplies from imports or other

    sources Distribution of emergency need within that time Percentage of emergencies to be fully covered

    Current issuesEmergency relief

    Chart1

    0.5

    0.25

    0.125

    0.0625

    0.03125

    0.015625

    0.0078125

    0.00390625

    0.001953125

    0.0009765625

    0.0004882813

    1 in 30 year emergencyrequirements

    Y-Values

    Emergency requirements

    Probability of different emergency requirements

    Sheet1

    X-ValuesY-Values

    00.5

    250.25

    500.125

    750.0625

    1000.03125

    1250.015625

    1500.0078125

    1750.00390625

    2000.001953125

    2250.0009765625

    2500.0004882813

    Chart1

    110

    110

    110

    110

    40

    110

    110

    110

    110

    70

    110

    110

    110

    110

    110

    110

    110

    110

    10

    110

    110

    110

    110

    110

    110

    110

    110

    110

    110

    20

    110

    Y-Values

    Years

    Stock over time

    Sheet1

    X-ValuesY-Values

    0110

    1110

    2110

    3110

    440

    5110

    6110

    7110

    8110

    970

    10110

    11110

    12110

    13110

    14110

    15110

    16110

    17110

    1810

    19110

    20110

    21110

    22110

    23110

    24110

    25110

    26110

    27110

    28110

    2920

    30110

  • Fuzzy boundary between emergency relief and price stabilization, particularly if emergency defined broadly

    Traditionally emergency relief in form of food (cereals, vegetable oil, etc)

    Increasing use of cash assistance Cash assistance is cheaper for government & more

    flexible for beneficiary Works well if shortages are local and market work well Food aid still needed if emergency is national or markets

    dont work

    Current issuesEmergency relief

  • Motivation for price stabilization

    Current issuesPrice stabilization

    By comparison, for six Asian countries, the CV for rice prices ranged from 12% in Bangladesh to 25% in the Philippines

    Chart1

    0.26TanzaniaTanzania

    0.27ZambiaZambia

    0.29KenyaKenya

    0.31MozambiqueMozambique

    0.36Avg for s & e AfricaAvg for s & e Africa

    0.37Avg of 7 countriesAvg of 7 countries

    0.43UgandaUganda

    0.49MalawiMalawi

    0.51EthiopiaEthiopia

    Series 1

    Column1

    Column2

    Sheet1

    Series 1Column1Column2

    Tanzania26%

    Zambia27%

    Kenya29%

    Mozambique31%

    Avg for s & e Africa36%

    Avg of 7 countries37%

    Uganda43%

    Malawi49%

    Ethiopia51%

    To resize chart data range, drag lower right corner of range.

  • Benefits of price stabilization Importance to consumers depends on share of budget spent

    on grains Importance to farmers depends on share of income from

    grain sales Studies find benefits of price stabilization to be relatively

    small (0-2% of income) but political pressure for stabilization remains strong

    Costs of price stabilization to government Amortized cost of storage facilities Transport and handling Spoilage in storage Financial costs (buy now, sell later)

    Current issuesPrice stabilization

  • If band is too high: Buying more than selling Accumulation of stocks Eventually exhaust

    funding or storage capacity

    If band is too low: Selling more than buying Depletion of stocks Eventually exhaust stocks

    One option: adjust mid-point using rolling average (e.g. past 3 years)

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    120

    140

    160

    180

    200

    1 11 21 31 41 51 61 71 81 91

    With buffer stock

    Without buffer stock

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    120

    140

    160

    180

    200

    1 11 21 31 41 51 61 71 81 91

    With buffer stock

    Without buffer stock

    Level of price band

  • Wide band implies: Less price stabilization Less frequent

    intervention Lower cost

    Narrow band implies: More price

    stabilization More frequent

    intervention Higher cost

    Width of price band

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    120

    140

    160

    180

    200

    1 11 21 31 41 51 61 71 81 91

    With buffer stock

    Without buffer stock

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100

    120

    140

    160

    180

    200

    1 11 21 31 41 51 61 71 81 91

    With buffer stock

    Without buffer stock

  • 12

    Benefits of price stabilization

  • Costs of price stabilization depend on details

    0

    200

    400

    600

    800

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21

    Pric

    e (U

    S$/to

    nne)

    0

    200

    400

    600

    800

    1000

    1200

    1400

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21

    Cos

    t (U

    S$ m

    illio

    n/ye

    ar)

    CV

    of p

    rice

    (%) Price

    volatility (CV)

    Annual cost of stabilization

    Price ceiling

    Price floor

    For hypothetical country producing 2 m tonnes/year with high volatility, relationship between width of band

    and cost of price stabilization for a country producing 2 million tonnes per year with high price volatility

  • Public food reserves in practice Typically managed by state-owned enterprise Reserves in main staple cereal and 1-2 others

    Root crops and cooking bananas too perishable Food reserves in developing countries have multiple objectives

    Price stabilization, preparation for emergencies, support farm price, keep down consumer prices, etc.

    Food reserves use different types of interventions Not just buying & selling, but import & export policy,

    government imports and exports, regulations of grain marketing

    Food reserves do not use consistent buy/sell rules Intervention depends on budget resources, politics, etc.

  • Discretionary Rule-based

    Definition Decisions about buying and selling are made based on judgement based on a wide range of factors

    Decisions about buying and selling are based on explicit criteria using a small number of quantifiable factors such as price

    Factors influencing decision

    Weather, harvest size, world prices, stocks, availability of funding, political pressure, political debate, leadership decisions

    Usually just buying price and selling price, though may be adjusted occasionally

    Predictability Less predictable Predictable based prices

    Effect on private sector

    Lower investment in storage and transport capacity because of uncertainty

    Greater investment due to predictability

    Potential for rent-seeking

    Higher Lower

    Buying and selling policies

    Public food reserves in practice

  • International experience: Eastern and Southern AfricaPublic food reserves in practice

  • Public food reserves in practiceExamples of minimal intervention

    Uganda Plan for Modernization of Agriculture says:

    The Government recognises that publicly held food reserves are very expensive under the best of conditions and require careful management to minimise losses due to spoilage. Such schemes have had limited success in other countries, but have certainly exerted substantial demands upon public funds. Therefore, government will not adopt any policy to accumulate such stocks unless and until careful studies in Uganda have determined their efficacy.

    Mozambique No strategic grain reserve or price stabilization efforts

    Tanzania Has Strategic Grain Reserve but has been too small to affect prices

    (purchases are about 1% of production)

  • Public food reserves in practiceExamples of more interventionist policies

    Ethiopia Ethiopia Grain Trading Enterprise (EGTE) Ad hoc intervention in maize & wheat markets In 2006-8, rising grain prices, surpassed import parity

    Inflation Harvest smaller than estimated No private imports because announced government imports and foreign exchange shortage

    Kenya National Cereals & Produce Board (NCPB) Successful in partial stabilization and raising maize prices Major price spike in 2009 caused by

    High import tariff (50%) No private imports because announced government imports When tariff lowered, congestion in transport routes

    Major corruption scandal Allocation of valuable import licenses Allocation of subsidized maize from NCPB

  • 1980s: maize marketing controlled by National Ag Marketing Board (NAMBOARD), which set pan-territorial and pan-seasonal prices and handled maize imports and distribution

    1989: NAMBOARD abolished and private trade legalized 1996: Food Reserve Agency (FRA) formed to administer grain

    reserve as buffer stock, private trade remains legal FRA procurement was small or zero over 1996 2001,

    expanded since 2002, dominant buyer since 2005 Other intervention: export bans, tariff rates, govt maize

    imports

    Public food reserves in practiceZambia

  • Study by Mason and Myers (2013) Method: VAR time-series analysis of effect of FRA purchase

    and sales on maize prices in Zambia over 1996-2008 Results: FRA reduced CV of maize price by 17% FRA raised average price of maize by 10% Welfare effect of price increases much larger than welfare

    impact of stabilization Benefits to large surplus farmers, losses to urban consumers

    and small net-maize buyers in rural areas

    Public food reserves in practiceZambia

  • Public food reserves in practiceMalawi

    Agricultural Development & Marketing Corporation (ADMARC) and Food Reserve Agency (FRA)

    Three price spikes since 2000 Poor rainfall played a role but price spike exacerbated by: Lack of transparency about grain stock size Government announcements of imports, then delays Procurement for government export

    In spite of efforts to stabilize maize price, volatility among the highest in sub-Saharan Africa Question is whether volatility is high in spite of stabilization

    efforts or whether intervention may contribute to spikes

  • Maize prices in MalawiSeasonal price index (1.0=average)

    0.8

    0.9

    1.0

    1.1

    1.2

    1.3

    1.4

    M4 M5 M6 M7 M8 M9 M10 M11 M12 M1 M2 M3

    2015 2016

    SI_NOMINAL SI_REAL

  • Maize prices in MalawiAdmarc sales, retail maize and MFG prices, 2005-2016

    102030405060708090

    100110120130140150160170180190200210220230240250260270280290300

    Jan-

    05

    Apr

    -05

    Jul-0

    5O

    ct-0

    5Ja

    n-06

    A

    pr-0

    6Ju

    l-06

    Oct

    -06

    Jan-

    07

    Apr

    -07

    Jul-0

    7O

    ct-0

    7Ja

    n-08

    A

    pr-0

    8Ju

    l-08

    Oct

    -08

    Jan-

    09

    Apr

    -09

    Jul-0

    9O

    ct-0

    9Ja

    n-10

    A

    pr-1

    0Ju

    l-10

    Oct

    -10

    Jan-

    11

    Apr

    -11

    Jul-1

    1O

    ct-1

    1Ja

    n-12

    A

    pr-1

    2Ju

    l-12

    Oct

    -12

    Jan-

    13

    Apr

    -13

    Jul-1

    3O

    ct-1

    3Ja

    n-14

    A

    pr-1

    4Ju

    l-14

    Oct

    -14

    Jan-

    15

    Apr

    -15

    Jul-1

    5O

    ct-1

    5Ja

    n-16

    A

    pr-1

    6Ju

    l-16

    Oct

    -16

    nom

    inal

    MK

    /kg

    Average National Retail Price

    ADMARC Sales Price

    MFG maize prices

  • Maize prices in Malawi Domestic price and import & export parity over 2004-2016 in US$

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    500

    600M

    ay-0

    4Ju

    l-04

    Sep-

    04N

    ov-0

    4Ja

    n-05

    Mar

    -05

    May

    -05

    Jul-0

    5Se

    p-05

    Nov

    -05

    Jan-

    06M

    ar-0

    6M

    ay-0

    6Ju

    l-06

    Sep-

    06N

    ov-0

    6Ja

    n-07

    Mar

    -07

    May

    -07

    Jul-0

    7Se

    p-07

    Nov

    -07

    Jan-

    08M

    ar-0

    8M

    ay-0

    8Ju

    l-08

    Sep-

    08N

    ov-0

    8Ja

    n-09

    Mar

    -09

    May

    -09

    Jul-0

    9Se

    p-09

    Nov

    -09

    Jan-

    10M

    ar-1

    0M

    ay-1

    0Ju

    l-10

    Sep-

    10N

    ov-1

    0Ja

    n-11

    Mar

    -11

    May

    -11

    Jul-1

    1Se

    p-11

    Nov

    -11

    Jan-

    12M

    ar-1

    2M

    ay-1

    2Ju

    l-12

    Sep-

    12N

    ov-1

    2Ja

    n-13

    Mar

    -13

    May

    -13

    Jul-1

    3Se

    p-13

    Nov

    -13

    Jan-

    14M

    ar-1

    4M

    ay-1

    4Ju

    l-14

    Sep-

    14N

    ov-1

    4Ja

    n-15

    Mar

    -15

    May

    -15

    Jul-1

    5Se

    p-15

    Nov

    -15

    Jan-

    16

    nom

    inal

    US$

    per

    met

    ric to

    n

    Export parity (USD/mt) Import parity (USD/mt) Malawi domestic price (USD/mt)

  • 25

    Buffer stocks are notorious for being politicised, and making variable pricing decisions depending on political pressures. For this reason, it is argued that they need to be recast as independent agencies or trusts, with a legal status that enables them to operate free of political interference

    maize policy in Malawi is understandably highly political, and many decisions can only be understood in terms of electoral cycles, promises made by political parties and their leaders prior to gaining power, and the goal of securing political support from important sectors of the populace in the future. (Manda, 2010)

    Public food reserves in practiceMalawi

    Role of political factors in public reserves

  • With income growth: share of household expenditure allocated to food declines

    (Engels Law) Share of food spending allocated to staples declines

    (Bennetts Law) Diet shifts away from staple grains and toward meat, fish,

    dairy products, fruits & vegetables, and processed foods Implications for reserves: as importance of staples in diet

    declines, need for grain price stabilization declines

    Future directions

  • With structural transformation of the economy Diversification in farm production into high-value commodities,

    so that income from staple grains becomes less important. Reduction in incidence of poverty due to income growth Gradual long-term shift of poverty from rural to urban Growth in export value & foreign reserves relative to cost of

    imported food, making food imports less of an economic burden and macro-economic risk

    Implications for public grain reserves: Declining importance

    Future directions

  • With development of infrastructure and markets Need to deliver food in kind declines Cash assistance is less expensive to deliver and provides

    more flexibility for beneficiary Cash creates demand, which will draw food supplies to

    region if roads are passable and markets functioning WFP and several countries switching from in-kind assistance

    to cash assistance

    Implications for public grain reserves: Declining need to store grain for distribution

    Future directions

  • Lessons for Malawi Consider shifting from direct in-kind food assistance to

    cash-based assistance Could be provided on pilot basis to test effects Studies in other countries show cost savings and

    satisfaction among beneficiaries with similar benefits for food security

    Open borders provide no-cost price band Impeding imports has exacerbated price spike in

    several cases

  • Lessons for Malawi Price stabilization is expensive

    Large procurement costs (US$ 20-100 m per year) Storage, handling, and overhead State enterprises cannot cover costs with stabilization efforts

    Aggregate benefits are small Most estimates 0 to 4% of farm income

    Benefits of price stabilization not pro-poor Most of benefits to larger commercial farmers, also urban poor

    Food price stabilization prone to rent-seeking Improve consistency and predictability in govt actions

  • Lessons for Malawi Promote private grain storage & imports

    Credit, non-intervention, & storage rental

    Promote consumption of secondary staple crops Cassava can act as shock absorber for grain markets

    Rationale for 3 months grain reserve To cover period until commercial imports can be arranged

    If price stabilization politically necessary Adopt rule-based price band Adopt wide & market based price band Adjust center of band periodically Provide transparency on stock levels and predictability

    in procurement/sales activities

    Slide Number 1Slide Number 2Objectives of public grain reservesCurrent issues:Public food distributionCurrent issues:Public food distributionCurrent issuesEmergency reliefCurrent issuesEmergency reliefCurrent issuesPrice stabilizationCurrent issuesPrice stabilizationSlide Number 10Width of price bandSlide Number 12Costs of price stabilization depend on detailsPublic food reserves in practiceBuying and selling policiesSlide Number 16Public food reserves in practiceExamples of minimal interventionPublic food reserves in practiceExamples of more interventionist policiesPublic food reserves in practiceZambiaSlide Number 20Public food reserves in practiceMalawiMaize prices in MalawiSeasonal price index (1.0=average)Maize prices in MalawiAdmarc sales, retail maize and MFG prices, 2005-2016 Maize prices in Malawi Domestic price and import & export parity over 2004-2016 in US$Slide Number 25Future directionsFuture directionsFuture directionsLessons for MalawiLessons for MalawiLessons for Malawi