Click here to load reader

Territorial use rights

  • Upload
    suvham

  • View
    48

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

SIF

Citation preview

  • 1. Territorial use RightsBy-Priyanka ChatterjeeSchool of industrial FisheriesRoll number 14, M.sc. 4th semester

2. Use RightsWhere open access is critical problem, thesolution would seem to lie in limiting access.If this is done, only a limited number ofindividuals will have the right to go forfishing, i.e. to access the fishery. Thoseentitled to do so are said to hold use rights. 3. Approaches to Fishery Management involve Customary marine tenure (CMT) and territorial use rights infishing (TURFs) have long been applied by indigenouspeople in determining the usage of local resources. Limited entry, providing a limited number of individuals withthe right to access the fishery, was the initial approach to userights in modern state management in fisheries. Quantitative use rights approaches are increasingly beingadopted, based on allocation of rights either (a) to fish at acertain level of effort, perhaps using specified bundles ofgear for certain time periods, or(b) to catch a specified amount of one or more species offish, with allocation through community institutions or market-basedapproaches.Use Rights 4. Different Forms of Use Rights 5. Access rights, which permit the holder to take part in afishery (limited entry) or to fish in a particular location(territorial use rights or TURFs) Withdrawal Rights, which typically involve quantitative(numerical) limits on resource usage, either through input(effort) rights or output (harvest) rights. 6. Territorial use rights Input(effort) rights including limited entry Output(harvest) rights 7. Territorial Use RightsTURFs may be defined as community held rights of use(or tenure) and exclusion over the fishery resourceswithin a specific area and for a period of time.Accompanying these rights might be certainresponsibilities for maintenance and propermanagement of the resource base, as well asrestrictions on the exercise of the rights of use andexclusion. 8. The territory governed by a TURF can relateto the surface, the bottom, or to the entirewater column within a specific area. The size of the territory will vary with the use,the resources being harvested and thegeographical characteristics. It should be sufficient in size, however, sothat use outside of the territory does notsignificantly diminish the value of use within. 9. A TURF is not so much resource specific as itis site specific. The territory should be readily defensible andprotected by the laws and institutions of thecountry. The boundaries of the territory should,therefore, be clearly demarcated andidentifiable. 10. TURFs as a Means for Increasing Fishery Net BenefitsThe establishment of a TURF may help generate or increasenet benefits from a heretofore open-access fishery in anumber of ways: By excluding outsiders from the territory of the TURF By controlling the use of labour and capital within the territoryof the TURF By dealing with spatial and other externalities partly throughinternationalization and partly through coordination withadjacent TURFs which share the same stocks. By investing to enhance future returns, negatively throughincreased incentives to avoid depletion and positively throughcommunity works such as landing places, artificial reefs,aggregation devices and aquaculture By providing flexibility to adjust to changes in technology,markets, resource characteristics and the socio-economicstructure of the fishing community (flexibility includes thedivisibility of the TURF). 11. TURFS as a means for improving the distribution ofbenefitsTURFs may help improve the distribution of benefitsamong the members of a fishing community in a numberof ways: By improving local employment opportunities By increasing local income, consumption and nutritionand evening out fluctuations in income By making possible the preservation of community socialorganization and reducing intra-and inter-communityconflicts By promoting social mobility and learning by doing 12. The owner of a TURF can be a private individual a private individual enterprise a group of individuals such as a cooperative, anassociation or a community a political subdivision such as a town or a province a national government a multinational agency 13. In addition, owners of individual TURFs can createa form of cooperative ownership in which individualrights are constrained by joint decisions. Generally, the effectiveness of a TURF will begreatest where the specificity of the ownership isthe highest. Individuals can usually make decisions more easilythan group of individuals. However, with regard to the objective of improvingthe welfare of small-scale fishing communities,ownership of use rights by private individuals couldwell be damaging. In these cases, some form ofcommunal ownership of a TURF will be desirable. 14. Advantages of localized TURFs More economically efficient use of the resources Improving welfare of small-scale fishing community The owner of the TURF can limit the input of capitallabour at the point where the greatest net benefits areproduced Opportunity and incentives to manage the resourceswithin the territory 15. Traditional TURFs and Problems of OpenAccess FisheryTerritorial Use Rights in fisheries, in the sense ofcommunity-held rights of use over resources withina territory at the exclusion of others have beenknown to exist for centuries. Examples of traditionalTURFs are still found today, among other places, inBrazil, Sri Lanka, Papua New Guinea, Oceania,Ivory Coast. Many of these customary rights arenow crumbling under the pressures of populationgrowth, technological change andcommercialization of subsistence fisheries. 16. Evaluation of TURFs as potentialmanagement tool can be done in terms of Eficiency EquityA TURF is an efficient management tool if it providesthe means for generating or increasing the net benefitsfrom a given fishery (or part of the fishery). A TURF is"equitable" if it provides the means for improving thedistribution of benefits within the community from theexploitation of the fishery. 17. Finally, TURFs, or at least the most successful ofthem, may produce revenues for the society atlarge: (a) by saving on management andenforcement cost; (b) by reducing the need forcostly welfare/development assistance todepressed fishing communities; and (c) bygenerating substantial resource rents, part of whichmay be creamed off by the government.