46
Year-Round School Incentive Progratns An Evaluation Legislative Analyst's Office April 1990

Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Year-Round SchoolIncentive Progratns

An Evaluation

Legislative Analyst's OfficeApril 1990

Page 2: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Table of Contents

Introduction 1

Executive Summary 3

Chapter IDescription of State Year-Round Incentive Programs 7

Chapter IICriteria for Evaluating Year-Round Incentive Programs 11

Chapter IIIEvaluation of Existing Year-Round Incentive Programs 13

Chapter IVAn Alternative Method of Providing Incentive Payments 19

Chapter VSummary of Findings and Recommendations .. 23

Appendix AGlossary of Terms Used in Report ~ 25

Appendix BMembers: Year-Round Incentive Payments Advisory Committee 27

Appendix C"Year-Round Schools"Reprinted from The 1989-90 BUdget: Perspectives and Issues 29

Appendix DCosts of Building a New School Compared to Costs of ProvidingYear-Round Incentive Payments Under the SB 327 Program 37

Appendix EEconomic Analysis: Practical Method for Determining theOptimal Level of Incentive Payment 41

Page 3: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Introduction

This report is submitted pursuant to Chapter886, Statutes of 1986 (SB 327, Leroy Greene).

Chapter 886, the Greene-Hughes School Fa­cilities Act of 1986, made numerous changesand additions to the state's school facilities aidprogram. One such provision established afinancial incentive payment programfor quali­fied school districts operating year-roundschools because of overcrowding. This pro­gram was in addition to a separate year-roundincentive program established in 1984-85 byChapter 498, Statutes of 1983 (SB 813, Hart).Chapter 886 also requires the Legislative Ana­lyst to report to the Legislature regarding thevalue of year-round education incentive fund­ing pursuant to this act in reducing the need forschool facility construction.

Because of significant similarities betweenthe incentive programs provided for in Chap­ters 498 and 886, we treat both programs to­gether in this review. In particular, both pro­grams (1) require, as a condition of eligibility,that a school district be sufficiently overcrowdedto otherwise qualify for state school construc­tion aid and (2) provide general-purpose aid(in the form of incentive payments) in returnfor accommodating additional pupils throughthe use ofmultitrack year-round schedules. Asa result, both programs provide incentive pay­ments to virtually the same group of schooldistricts.

The first chapter of this report contains a briefdescription of year-round education and de­scribes the state's current involvement in pro­viding financial incentives to school districts tooperate year-round education programs. Chap­ter II presents our criteria for evaluating suchincentive payment programs, and Chapter III

Introduction

evaluates the existing programs based on thesecriteria. Based on this evaluation, we concludethat the existing year-round incentive programsare of little or no value in serving the state'sinterest in promoting year-round schools as analternative to constructing new facilities. Con­sequently, we recommend that the Legislaturerepeal the existing programs.

Recognizing that the Legislature may, never­theless, wish to continue to provide some formof year-round incentives, Chapter IV describesthe major features that an alternative incentivepayment program should include, in order tobetter meet the criteria identified in Chapter II.Chapter V summarizes our findings and rec­ommendations.

In addition to Chapter 886, The SupplementalReport of the 1989 Budget Act directed theLegislative Analyst to convene an advisory groupto provide advice and assistance in determin­ing the effectiveness of the current year-roundincentiv~paymentprograms. This supplemen­tal language provided for the membership ofthe advisory committee to include, at a mini­mum, representatives from: (1) the State De­partment of Education, (2) the Office of LocalAssistance in the Department of General Serv­ices, (3) the Department of Finance, and (4) theNational Association for Year-Round Educa­tion, including a public school governing boardmember, a public school administrator, and apublic school teacher.

This advisory committee met five times be­tween July 1989 and October 1989. Individualmembers are identified in Appendix B.

We would like to acknowledge and thank themembers of the advisory committee for thevaluable assistance they provided us. The

Pagel

Page 4: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Introduction

conclusions and recommendations containedin this report, however, are solely those of theLegislative Analyst, and are not necessarilyendorsed by the advisory committee or theagencies whose cooperation facilitated the re­port's completion.

Page 2

This report was prepared by Nancy RoseAnton under the supervision of Ray Reinhard.Jon DavidVascheprovidedvaluable commentsregarding the economics of incentive payments.Secretarial services were provided by MariaPonce, and the report was formatted for publi­cation by Kathy Van Dort.

Page 5: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Executive Summary

Program Description• California provides year-round school

incentive funds through two separateprograms-"SB 813" and "SB 327"-toencourage school districts to operateyear-round educationprograms as an al­ternative to constructing new school fa­cilities. To qualify for these incentivefunds, school districts must (1) be eli­gible to participate in the State SchoolBuilding Lease-Purchase program and(2) accommodate overcrowding throughthe use of year-round schools.

• The SB 813 and SB 327 programs shareseveral features in common, including(1) providing funding only for year­round schools that are operated on a"multitrack" basis; (2) designating theincentive funding as general-purpose aid,which may be spent for any purpose thedistrict chooses; and (3) allowing schooldistricts to remain "in line" for state­financed new schools, while receivingthe incentive funds.

• The SB 813 program, which began in1984-85, provides a flat rate payment of$25 per pupil, for every pupil attendingan eligible year-round school. In addi­tion to this $25 payment, the SB 327 pro­gram, which began in 1987-88, providesa variable rate payment of up to $125 (asadjusted annually for inflation), for ev­ery such pupil. The SB 327 payments areintended to share with the affected schooldistrict the state's "savings" resultingfrom avoiding the costs of constructing anew school.

• In 1988-89, the state provided a total of$34.8 million ($30 million from the State

Executive Summary

School Building Lease-Purchase Fund and$4.8 million from the General Fund) tofund both the SB 327 and SB 813 pro­grams. These funds were provided to 31school districts for an estimated 272,000students that were attending eligible year­round schools. In the current year (1989­90), $43 million has been made availableto fund these two programs ($35.7 mil­lion from the General Fund and $7.3 mil­lion from the Lease-Purchase Fund).

The State's Interest inYear-Round Schools

• We find that the state's primary interest inyear-round education is its potential forreducing school districts' demands forlimited state resources to construct newschool facilities.

• Other reasons why the state might beinterested in promoting year-roundeducation, besides its potential to reducethe need for new funds for school facilityconstruction, either have not been con­clusively established or are not stronglyenough in the state's interest to merit theprovision of financial incentives.

.Criteria for Evaluating Year-RoundSchool Incentive Programs

• Primary Criterion: Maximizing TheState's Net CostAvoidance. Our reviewindicates that, given the potential for year­round school programs to reduce thedemand for school facilities aid funds,the state's primary goal in providing in­centive payments should be to maximize

Page 3

Page 6: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Executive Summary

the net amount of the state's cost avoid­ance from not having to construct newfacilities. Net cost avoidance or "net sav­ings" means the amountofcosts avoidedby not constructing a new school facility(the "gross" cost avoidance or "savings"),less the costs of providing year-roundschool incentive payments.

• Secondary Criterion: Simplicity. Ourreview indicates that a secondary, thoughalso desirable, feature in a year-roundschool incentive program is simplicity­from the perspectives of both the stateand the participating districts. The goalof simplicity, however, may sometimesconflict with the primary criterion ofmaximizing the net amount of the state'scost avoidance. For this reason, we be­lieve that simplicity alone should notcompensate for a formula's failure tomaximize the state's "net savings."

Evaluation of Existing Year-RoundIncentive Programs

• Primary Criterion. Ourreviewindicatesthat the SB 327 and SB 813 programs failto maximize the amount of the net statecost avoidance, for three reasons:- First, for most school districts, the

combined level of incentives providesmore than 100 percent of the state's costavoidance, thereby resulting in no netsavings that the state could use to meetother districts' pressing school construc­tion needs. The only possible excep­tion to this general conclusion may occurfor school districts that have extraordi­narily high land costs (such as LosAngeles Unified). .In such cases, the$125 "cap" in the SB 327 program mayserve to limit the amount of the incen­tive payment.

- Second, even in school districts withhigh land costs and/or high percent­ages of excess pupils accommodated,the state still may realize no net savings.This is because:

Page4

*The SB 327 incentive payment for­mula overpays school districts for landcosts relative to the actual costs whichwould have been incurred under thestate building program.

*As currently designed, the programsmayfunction as asubsidyfor a districtwhile waiting in line for new con­struction funds, rather than as an al­ternative to new construction. To theextent that a district receives both the in­centive payments and a new facility, thestate clearly realizes no savings at all.

- Third, there is little evidence that theexisting incentive programs have hadany discernible impact in increasingthe total number of pupils on multi­track year-round schedules statewidebeyond levels that would have occurredin the programs' absence. Instead, whatappears to motivate school districts toimplement year-round programs is theirrecognition that funding provided throughthe State School Building Lease-Purchaseprogram will not become available quicklyenough to meet pressing needs for addi­tional capacity.

• Judging by the criteria identified above,we conclude that the existing incentiveprograms have little or no effect in pro­moting the state's primary interest inyear-round education, which is to maxi­mize the amount of the state's net costsavoided by reducing demand for state­financed school construction.

Recommendations• We recommend that the Legislature re­

peal the existing year-round school in­centive programs. Our review indicatesthat the SB 327 and the SB 813 programscould be eliminated, with very littleimpact on the total number of pupilsattending year-round schools. The Leg­islature could then use the associatedfunding for other, higher priority pur­poses within K-14 education.

Page 7: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

• We recognize, however, thatthe Legisla­ture may wish to continue to providesome form of year-round school incen­tives to the extent that some school dis­tricts may respond by increasing thenumbers ofpupils attending year-roundschools. If the Legislature wishes tocontinue to provide incentive paymentsusing a uniform percentage of savingsmethod, we recommend that the Legisla­ture enact an alternative program of in­centives which includes all of the follow­ing features:- Provide school districts with no more

than SO percent of the state's "savings."- Reflect district-specific land and con­

struction costs, as provided for in theState School Building Lease-Purchaseprogram.

Executive Summary

- Include safeguards to ensure that in­centives are an alternative to new schoolconstruction, rather than a subsidywhile waiting in line for a state-financedschool. These features assume the con­tinuation of existing practices for fi­nancing new construction through theLease-Purchaseprogram. Totheextentthat the Lease-Purchase programchanges, these features would proba­bly also change.

PageS

Page 8: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Executive Summary

Page 6

Page 9: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter 1: State Year-Round Incentive Programs

Chapter I

Description of State Year-Round Incentive Programs

. Year-Round SchoolsYear-roundeducationis an alternative sched­

ule for learning that reor·ganizes the academiccalendar so that instructional blocks and vaca­tion periods are evenly distributed across a 12­month calendar. Year- round education is notan alternative curriculum for learning. Stu­dents attending a year-round school attend thesame types of classes and receive the sameamount of instruction-generally 180 days peracademic year-as students attending tradi­tional nine-month calendar schools.

In general, there are three reasons why schooldistricts may choose to adopt year-round cal­endars. These are:

• To increase school facilities capacity;• To attempt to improve academic achieve­

ment; and/or• To accommodate parental and teacher

preferences for an alternative calendaroffering shorter, but more frequent, va­cations.

Year-round schools canbe operated on eithera "single-track" or "multitrack" basis; however,it is onlywhen the multitrackformat is implementedthat the enrollment capacity of a school can beincreased and corresponding facility-related costsreduced. A single-track system provides for theentire school population (that is, all studentsand teachers) to follow the same calendar withthe same vacation periods. This means that allstudents and teachers are either in school or onvacation at the same time. Ona multitracksystem, however, students and their teachersare grouped into different tracks, with stag­gered instructional blocks and vacation peri­ods. While one track is on vacation, anothertrack is using its space, thereby allowing for an

increase in the enrollment capacity of the school.Because the existing state incentive programs

provide payment only for schools that haveincreased their enrollment capacity (that is, thosethatoperate on a multitrack basis), for purposesof this report, the term "year-round"-unlessotherwise indicated-will refer exclusively tomultitrack programs. (For further informationregarding the mechanics of year-round schooloperations, as well as the advantages and dis­advantages ofyear-round education, please seeAppendix C of this report, which is reprintedfrom our publication The 1989-90 Budget: Per­spectives and Issues.)

Current Year-Round IncentivePrograms

Through the State School Building Lease­Purchase program, the state provides funds toschool districts for the construction of new, orthe modernization of existing, school build­ings. In order to receive these funds, an eligibleschool district is required to:

• Contribute a Specified Local Match. Thismatch is based on the amount that theschool district could raise if it imposedthe maximum level of developer fees,authorized by current law, for a speci­fied time period. (Statewide, the amountof the local match constitutes about 5percent of total costs to acquire a newfacility.) The state funds the balance ofthecosts ofacquiring land and construct­ing the facility, and rents it to the districtfor a minimal fee (usually $1 per year)under a long-term, lease-purchase agree­ment.

Page 7

Page 10: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter 1: State Year-Round Incentive Programs

• Meet a Minimum Threshold of Over­crowding. A school district generallymust accommodate 10 percent morestudents than it has the capacity to ac­commodate on a traditional nine-monthcalendar-as measured by existing statestandards-in order to be eligible forlease-purchase funds.1

Currently, school districts are eligible to re­ceive year-round incentive funds if they (1) areeligible to participate in the Lease-Purchaseprogram and (2) mitigate overcrowding throughthe use of year-round schools. The purpose ofthe incentive payments is to encourage schooldistricts to operate year-round education pro­grams as an alternative to using state funds toconstruct new school facilities under the StateSchool Building Lease-Purchase program. Theincentive funds are provided through two dif­ferentprograms-"SB 813" and "SB 327"-eachauthorized under a separate statute.

The SB 813 and the SB 327 programs shareseveral features in common. Specifically, theyboth:

• Provide incentive funding only for year­round schools that are operated on amultitrack basis;

• Provide the incentive funding as gen­eral-purpose aid, which maybespentforany purpose the district chooses; and

• Allow school districts to remain "in line"for state aid to construct new facilities toaccommodate these pupils, while theyreceive the incentive funds.

Specific details of each program are as fol­lows:

Senate Bill 813 (Ch 498/83). Among numer­ous other provisions related to education fi­nance and reform, SB 813 (Hart) authorizes aHat rate incentive payment of $25 per pupil, forevery pupil in an eligible school which is oper­ated on a year-round basis because of over­crowding. In 1988-89, the fifth year ofprogram

1 In addition to the Lease-Purchase program, the stateoper­ates a number of other school facilities aid programs,including the State School Deferred Maintenance Program,The School Facilities Asbestos Abatement Program and theEmergency Portable Classroom Program.

Page 8

operations, the, 5B 813 program provided $6.7million in payments to school districts.

Senate Bill 327 (Ch 886/86). The 5B 327(Leroy Greene) program authorizes a slidingscale incentive payment of up to $125 (adjustedannually for inflation), in addition to the $25payment provided by SB 813, for every pupil in aneligible school which is operated on a year­round basis because of overcrowding. Theexact per-pupil amount variel' among districtsand is based on a complicated formula thatgenerally reflects both (1) the amount it wouldhave cost the state to acquirea site and constructa new school of sufficient size to house theexcess students accommodated through year­round operations and (2) theextent to which thedistrict succeeds in increasing its enrollmentcapacity to a target level of 15 percent more stu­dents than its traditional (nine-month calen­dar) capacity. In 1988-89, the second year ofprogram operations, the SB 327 program pro­vided $28.1 million in payments to school dis­tricts.

The additional incentive payments availableunder the SB 327program are intended to sharewith the affected school districtthe state's "sav­ings" resulting from avoiding the costs of con­structing a new schooL Under the terms of thelaw (as amended by the annual Budget Act),districts meeting the 15 percent target may an­nually receive incentive funding equal to 5 per­cent of the amount it would cost the state (intotal, excluding interest costs) to purchase a siteand construct a school of sufficient size to servethe excess students accommodated through year­round education. The incentive payment iscapped at a maximum of $125 per pupil (as an­nually adjusted for inflation). The total amountof funding provided to a district under thisprogram is reducedmore-than-proportionallyif it fails to meet the target level of 15 percentexcess capacity accommodated, and is increasedproportionally (paralleling the state's savings)if it exceeds this leveL

Because the 5B 327 incentive amount is recal­culated annually, based on the prevailing costof construction and land acquisition, the amountof the incentive funds provided keeps pacewith inflationary increases in these costs. As

Page 11: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter 1: State Year-Round Incentive Programs

35%3025

Incentive Payment

201510

may not exceed the overall"cap" of$125 (as ad­justed for inflation).

Thus, the SB 327 program appears to havebeen intended to provide school districts withan incentive to accommodate at least 15 percentexcess capacity through the use of year-roundeducation; more modest incentives beyond the15 percent level are provided in order to con­tinue increasing the percentage of excess pupilsserved. The effect of these incentives, however,may be significantlyweakenedby the impactofthe overall $125 cap. (Though not evident fromChart 1, the percentage at which the cap be­comes operative varies depending on the levelof land costs; the higher the cost of land in adistrict, the lower is the percentage of excesscapacity at which the cap takes effect.)

5

Percent Excess Capacity Accommodated

25

50

100

75

$250..----------------------,

225

200

175

150

125

$ per Pupil

Chart 1

Relationship Between S8 327 Incentive Paymentand Level of Excess Capacity Accommodated

noted, however, the law provides that in nocase shall the total amount of the incentivepayment per pupil attending the eligible year­round schools exceed $125, increased annuallyfor inflation based on a specified cost of con­struction index; in the current year the "cap" is$131.

Chart 1 shows how the amount of per-pupilincentive payment provided under the SB 327program varies, depending on the percentageof pupils accommodated through year-roundoperations, in excess of "traditional" (nine­month) facilities capacity. (The specific ex­ample shown is for a hypothetical school dis­trict, with land costs of $250,000 per acre.)

As the chart shows, if this district uses year­round education to accommodate 5 percent orfewer additional pupils,then the SB 327 programprovides a very low level­about $10 or less-of an­nual incentive payment perpupiL However, as a dis­trict accommodates an in­creasing percentage ofexcess capacity up to 15percent, the level of per­pupil payment increasessignificantly. In this par­ticular case, the incentivepayment reaches a level ofapproximately $90 per pu­pil annually at 15 percentexcess capacity accommo­dated. Although furtherincreases (beyond 15 per­cent) in the percentage ofexcess capacity accommo­dated result in additionalincreases in the incentivepayment, these increasesare not as great as in thezero percent to 15 percentrange. Finally, the chartshows that the level of per­pupil incentive payment

Page 9

Page 12: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter 1: State Year-Round Incentive Programs

Funding HistoryTable 1 displays the participation and fund­

ing history for both the SB 813 and the SB 327programs, since the inception of each.

The table shows that, since the inception ofthe first incentive payment program in 1984,the state has provided a total of approximately$119 million in year-round incentivepayments.Of this amount, $78.1 million was from tide­lands oil revenues within the State School Build­ing Lease-Purchase (SSBLP) Fund; the remain­ing $40.5 million was appropriated from theGeneral Fund.

Table 1

1984-85 through 1989-90(dollars in millions)

tory provision every year since 1986-87, due toshortfalls in the actual level of such revenues.Because past appropriations of tidelands oilrevenues within the SSBLP Fund have beenexhausted and projections indicate that reve­nues will continue to fall short of the levelneeded to result in allocations for school facili­ties, it is likely that any future funding for theincentive program would be provided entirelyfrom the General Fund.

Table 1 also shows that, on an annual basis,the SB 327 program has cost about four times asmuch as the SB 813 program. Finally, the table

1984-85 13 180,972 $4.5 $4.5a

1985-86 11 176,153 4.4 4.4a

1986-87 15 206,036 5.2 5.2a

1987-88 18 220,043 5.5 13 193,862 $21.2 26.7a

1988-89 29 269,964 6.7 27 245,742 28.1 34.8b

1989-90 NN NA NA NA NA NA 43.0d

Total State Cost $118.6

a Funding Source: State School Building Lease-Purchase (SSBLP) Fund (tidelands oil revenues).

b Funding Source: $30 million from the SSBLP Fund and $4.8 million from the General Fund.

c Not available.

d As appropriated in the 1989-90 BUdget Act. Funding Source: $35.7 million from the General Fund and $7.3million from the SSBLP Fund.

Although current law requires that $150 mil- shows that, with the exception of one smalllion in tidelands oil revenues be appropriated decline between 1984-85 and 1985-86, the num­annually through 1990-91 for school facilities ber of districts participating in each of theseprograms, the Legislature has waived this statu- programs has steadily increased.

Page 10

Page 13: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter 1/: Criteria For Evaluating

Chapter /I

Criteria for Evaluating Year-Round Incentive Programs

As noted in the Introduction to this report,Chapter 886 requires the Legislative Analyst toreport on the "value" of year-round educationincentive funding in reducing the need for schoolfacility construction. In order to respond to thisdirective, it is necessary to clarifywhat is meantby the term "value." Our approach to this taskwas first to determine the state's interest in pro­moting year-round education. Having donethis, we identified two key criteria that shouldbe satisfiedby any incentive program that seeksto further the state's interest.

State's Interest in PromotingYear-Round Education

Our review indicates that the state's primaryinterest in year-round education is its potentialfor reducing school districts' demands for lim­ited state resources to construct new schoolfacilities. (This interest is based on the existenceof the current state Lease-Purchase programwhich in recent years has provided substantialfinancial assistance-hundreds of millions ofdollars annually-to school districts to buildnew facilities. To the extent that the Lease­Purchase program is altered, or the state nolonger provides such assistance to school dis­tricts, the nature of the state's interest in year­round education would probably change.)

There are several other reasons why the statemight be interested in promoting year-roundeducation, besides its potential to reduce theneed for new state funds for school facilityconstruction. Our review indicates, however,that such reasons either have not been conclu­sively established or are not strongly enough inthe state's interest to merit the provision offinancial incentives. Two of these reasons arediscussed below.

• Enhancing Educational Quality. It hasbeen suggested by some (includingmembers of the advisory committee tothis study) that, to the extent that year­round education results in improvedacademic performance, the state shouldbe willing to pay some amount (perhapseven an amount in excess of its facilities­related cost avoidance) in order to pro­mote year-round education. Althoughwe concur with the theory behind thisposition, there is a significant practicalproblem in identifying this as a justifica­tion for state interest. Specifically, ourreview of the existing field of literaturesuggests that students in multitrack year­round programs generally do no better orno worse than their counterparts in tradi­tional calendar schools. In the absence ofevidence to indicate that year-round E.'!du­cation results in improved academicper­formance, therefore, we can find noanalytical justification for the state toprovide financial incentives based on im­proving educational quality. (Please seeAppendix C for additional informationregarding academic achievement andyear-round school programs.)

• OffsettingIncreased Operational Costs.It has also been suggested that year­round education results in additionaloperating costs to districts, and that thestate should have an interest in provid­ing some amount of financial assistanceto districts to help defray these costs.Our review of a small field of literature(two studies), however, indicates that al­though there maybeinitialstart-upcosts,the ongoing operational costs of year-

Page 11

Page 14: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter II: Criteria For Evaluating

round schools on a per.c.pupil basis gener­ally are slightly less than those of theirtraditional calendar counterparts. (Thisis because certain fixed costs of opera­tion are "spread out" over a largernumber of pupils.) Given this finding,we can find no analytical justificationforproviding financial assistance based onthis rationale. Moreover, even if it couldbe demonstrated that year-round schoolswere more costly to operate than theirtraditional calendar counterparts, we donot believe that the mere existence ofsuch costs would provide a compellingrationale for providing state aid. Putanother way, we can find no justificationfor the state--in the absence of any otherdemonstrable benefits-to provide fund­ing for an activity simply because it iscostly.

Having identified the state's primary interestin year-round education as promoting a lesscostly alternative to new construction, we nowdiscuss the criteria that an incentive formulashould meet in order to further this interest.

Primary Criterion: MaXimizing NetState Cost Avoidance

Our review indicates that, given the potentialfor year-round school programs to reduce thedemand for school facilities aid funds, the state'sprimary goal of providing year-round schoolincentive payments should be to maximize thestate's "net cost avoidance" or "net s.avings."By "net cost avoidance" or "net savings" wemean the amount of costs avoided by not con­structing a new school facility (the "gross" costavoidance or "savings,") less the costs of pro­viding year-round school incentive payments.In other words, the state should seek to maxi­mize the total amount of resources "freed up"from both the State School Building Lease-Pur­chase program and the General Fund, afteraccounting for the cost of the incentive pay­ments. In this manner, the state will be able toensure that its limited resources are used toaccommodate the maximum number of pupilsneeding school facilities.

Page 12

Secondary Criterion: SimplicityOurreviewindicates thata secondary, though

also desirable,feature in a year-round incentivepayment program is simplicity-from the per­spectives of both the state and participatingdistricts. For the state, simplicity refers to theability of the state to easily identify eligibleparticipants, and also calculate quickly andaccurately an individual district's level of pay­ment.

On the local level, simplicity refers to theability of school districts to understand theprogram so that they can accurately determinewhether (1) they are, in fact, eligible (therebyminimizing the amount of time they and thestate must spend completing and reviewingpotentially unnecessary paperwork) and (2) itis worth participating (that is, that the "incen­tive" outweighs both any monetary costs andpotential community resistance). Simplicityalso refers to a district's ability to determine thelevel of payment it will be eligible for, both as acheck on the state's accuracy in calculating theincentive payment and as a tool for predictingfuture revenues.

The goal of simplicity, however, may some­times conflict with the primary criterion ofmaximizing the net amount of the state's costavoidance. For example, in order to maximizethe total amount of net state "savings," a for­mula might provide a higher level of incentivepayment to school districts with higher landcosts, because in these cases the potential costavoidance to the state is greater. This, in turn,leads to a formula which is more complicatedthan a formula in which the level of incentivepayment is not affected by land costs or otherindividualized district features.

In evaluating alternative incentive formulas,therefore, we believe that the simplicity crite­rion should generallybe used as a "tiebreaker."Thus, in a comparison of two formulas that areroughly equivalent in terms of maximizing thenet amount of state cost avoidance, the simplerformula would be preferred. Simplicity, how­ever, would not compensate for a formula'sfailure to maximize the amountof the state's netcost avoidance.

Page 15: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

ChapterIll: Evaluation

Chapter III

Evaluation of Existing Year-Round Incentive Programs

In Chapter II of this report, we identified twocriteria~neprimary and one secondary-bywhich to assess the value of year-round schoolincentive payment programs in reducing theneed for new school facilities. In this chapter,we assess the existing system ofproviding stateincentive payments according to these criteria.

Primary Criterion: Maximizing Net StateCost Avoidance

Our review indicates that the SB 327 and SB813 programs fail to maximize the amount ofnet state cost avoidance, for three reasons.

First, for most school districts achieving the"target" level of 15 percent excess capacity ac­commodated, the state provides a combinedlevel of incentive payment that exceeds thestate's "savings" (that is, the programs cost thestate more than it would cost to build newfacilities, resulting in no net savings).

Second, even in school districts where-intheory-the "savings" could potentiallyexceedthe costs of incentive payments, the state maynot realize any net savings in practice.

Third, even at the high levels of incentivepayment noted, there is little evidence that theexisting programs have had any discernibleimpact in increasing the total number of pupilson multitrack year-round schedules statewidebeyond levels that would have occurred in theprograms' absence.

Incentive ,Payment Can ExceedState's Gross Cost Avoidance

As partof this report, we conducted a detailedanalysis of the fiscal effects of the 5B 327 and SB813 programs. Specifically, we compared the

costs to state taxpayers of accommodating stu­dents through the construction of new, state­funded schools (financed over a 20-year pe­riod), to those of providing year-round schoolincentives under the SB 327 and SB 813 pro­grams. (In the Analysisofthe1987-88 Budget Bill,we presented a similar analysis of the fiscaleffects of the SB 327 program alone; that analy­sis has been updated with more recent data andis presented in Appendix D of this report.)

The SB 327 incentive payments are intendedto share with the affected school district thestate's "savings" from avoiding the costs ofconstructing a new school under thestatebuild­ing program. And, although current law issilent as to the purpose of the $25 per-pupilpaymentprovidedby theSB 813 program, thereis little reason in practice to distinguish its effectfrom that of the 5B 327 program.

In particular, both programs (1) require, as acondition of eligibility, that a school district besufficiently overcrowded to otherwise qualifyfor state school construction aid and (2) providegeneral-purpose aid in return for accommodat­ing additional pupils through the use of multi­track year-round schedules. As a result, bothprograms providefunding to virtually the samegroup of school districts. Specifically, in 1988­89, of the 29 districts that received fundingunder the SB 327 program, 25 also receivedfunding under the SB 813 program.

How, then, does the combined level of incen­tive payments provided under both the SB 327and the SB 813 programs compare to the state'sgross cost avoidance from not having to buildschool facilities? As shown in Charts 2 through4, the answer to this question depends primar­ily on the level of land costs in the particularschool district. For most school districts (except

Page 13

Page 16: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter /1/: Evaluation

5 10 15 20 25 30 35%

State "SaVings"

Incentive Payment ~__.,-~

$ per Pupil

$250...------------------.,

225

200

175

150

125

100

75

50

25

Percent Excess Capacity Accommodated

Land Cost of $250,000 per Acre

5 10 15 20 25 30 35%

(such as Escondido, Fresno, and Oakland), apicture similar to that of Chart 2. Specifically,for districts with land costs in this range, thelevel of the incentive payment exceeds theamount of state savings in all cases-unlessmore than 33 percent excess capacity is accom­modated. (We know of only one calendar sched­ule- predominantly used by Los Angeles­which allows a district to achieve a greater than33 percent capacity increase.)

round school-where just one additional pupilis accommodated, and increases at a faster ratethan does the state "savings" up to approxi­mately $93 per pupil at the target level of 15percent excess capacity accommodated. There­after, the per-pupil payment increases at a rateparalleling the state "savings," until the $150payment cap is reached.

Chart 3 (land cost of $250,000 per acre) pro­vides, for locations with moderate land costs

all cases exceeds the amount of state savings atall levels ofexcess capacityaccommodated. Thelevel of incentive payment ranges from a low of$25 per pupil-forall pupils attending the year-

$ per Pupil

$250...------------------,

225

200

175

150

125

100

75

50

25

Chart 2

Percent Excess Capacity Accommodated

Land Cost of $50,000 per Acre

those with extraordinarily high land costs),however, the combined effect of the two pro­grams is generally to provide districts with alevel of annual incentive payment that exceedswhat it would have cost the state to provide apermanent school facility-irrespective of thelevel ofexcess capacityaccommodated throughthe use of year-round operations.

The three charts show the relationship be­tween per-pupil costs and state "savings," asthe amount of excess capacity accommodatedincreases from 0 to 35 percent. The land costsshown in these charts were chosen to representthe range of such costs identified by the 25districts which participated in both programsin 1988-89.

Specifically, Chart 2 (land cost of $50,000 peracre) shows that, for locations with relativelylow land costs (such as Fontana, Madera, or ElkGrove), the level of the incentive payments in

Page 14

Page 17: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Little Discernible Impact on·Numberof Year-Round PupUs

Although itis difficult to estimate precisely theeffect of the existing year-round incentives,available evidence suggests that the number ofpupils attending year-round schools has beenaffected little-if at all-by the existence of suchpayments. Instead, it appears that the majorimpetus for districts to adopt year-round sched-

2JS Page 15

Chapter11/: Evaluation

• The SB 327 incentive payment formulaoverpays school districts for land costsrelative to the actual costs which wouldhavebeen incurred under the state build­ing program.

• As currentlydesigned, theprograms mayfunction as a subsidy for a district while itwaits in line for new construction funds,rather than as an alternative to new con­struction. This is because both programsallow school districts to receive incentivepaYments while they "wait in line" toreceive new school facility fundingthrough the Lease-Purchase program. Tothe extent that a district receives both theincentive payments and a new facility, thestate clearly realizes no savings at all.

In the specific case of Los Angeles UnifiedSchool District, even if one were to correct theproblems just noted, the level ofincentive pay­ment still would be "too high" to maximize theamount of the state's net cost avoidance. This isbecause (as demonstrated in greater detail laterin this report) the only case in which the stateshould pay a district more than 50 percent of the .state's gross cost avoidance is where the districtresponds to a given percentage increase in thelevel of incentive paYment with a more-than­equivalent percentage increase in the number ofstudents attending year-round schools. In thecase ofLos Angeles, however, (l)the majorityofthe district's pupils attending year-round schoolswere doing so prior to the enactment of theincentive programs and (2) a 500 percent in­crease in the level of incentive paYment (imple­mented in 1987-88) has led to only a 0.6percentincrease in the total number of pupils on multi­track year-round schedules.

Incentive Payment

$ per Pupil

$250'-r---------,-------,225200175150125100755025

Percent Excess Capacity Accommodated

5 10 15 20 25 30 35%

State "Savings" versus State Cost ofYear-Round Incentive Payments

Chart 4

Land Cost of $1.5 million per Acre

SaVings In Theo!y May Not EqualSaVings In Practice

Our review indicates that, even in school dis­tricts with high land costs, the state may notealize any net savings in practice. This is be­ause:

In sum, these charts indicate that-for mostcurrently~participating school districts-theexisting year-round school incentive paYmentprograms actually cost the state taxpayers morethan itwould have cost to accommodate these •students by building additional, traditional­calendar school facilities.

Finally, Chart 4 (land cos,t of $1.5 million pere) shows that for districts with extraordi­

arily high land costs (such as Los AngelesUnified) the amount of the state's cost avoid­ance-in theory- consistentlyexceed.s the level,....pincentive paYment. As noted below, how­ever, there are several reasons why-in prac­tice-the state still may realize no net savingseven under these circumstances.

lar,.e.e,sL-

l-

n

L5e­tc50

)ilted-

:J­

ts

Page 18: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter 11/: Evaluation

Chart 5

Number of Pupils in Year-Round SchoolsIncreases As School ConstructionFunding Backlog Grows -

were motivClting school districts to switch toyear-round education programs.;,;Chart 5 presents the second set of data on

numbers of pupils in year-round schools­from 1984-85 through 1988-89. The chart also:R!~esents data on the dollar value of applica­tions for new construction funds under theLease-Purchase program at the beginning ofthe preceding school year. As the chart shows,the numbers of pupils qualifying for year­round school incentive payments has been stead­ily increasing over this entire period. More im-

2.0

1.0

Dollars(billions)

$3.0

100

200

Pupils(thousands)

300

1973-74 through 1983-848,b

Growth of Year-Round EducationPrograms in California

ules is the combined effects of (1) overcrowdedschools and (2) a recognition that state fundingwill not become available quickly enough tomeet pressing needs for additional capacity.

Unfortunately, consistent data on numbers ofdistricts, schools, and pupils under year-roundschedules do not exist for the entire period1973-74 through 1988-89. Instead, we have twosomewhat dissimilar data sets: one from 1973­74 through 1983-84, covering both single-trackand multitrack schools, and another from 1984­85 through 1988-89, covering just those multi­track schools that qualified for either the SB 327or SB 813 incentive payments.

Table 2 presents the first of these two datasets, covering 1973-74 through 1983-84. As thetable shows,both the number ofschools and thenumber of pupils on year-round schedules grewsubstantially over this period-prior to the exis­tence of the state's first year-round incentivepayment program in 1984-85. Specifically, thenumber of schools on year-round schedulesincreased from 100 to 253, while the number ofpupils on such schedules nearly quadrupled­growing from 61,233 to 230,797. Clearly, in theabsence of incentive payments, other factors

illlllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllllillilllillililifllltl~iilililllllllillll::II:illillllli«lli111111111111:1111!(ltlllllllllll1973-74 30 100 61,2331974-75 38 127 79,3051975-76 45 159 102,1841976-77 56 200 116,2421977-78 56 195 106,3221978-79 42 138 76,5311979-80 40 148 86,3821980-81 45 195 154,0001981-82 41 260 219,8751982-83 NAc NA NA1983-84 39d 253 230,797

a Source: California State Pirectory of Year-Round Education, StateDepartment of Education 1984-85.

b Includes districts operating and students attending single-track aswell as multitrack year-round programs.

c Not available.

d Represents a loss of three districts and a gain of one district.

84-85 85-86 86-87 87-88 88-89a Number of pupils qualifying for year-round school incentives.

b Dollar value of applications for school construction aid, as of Julyof prior fiscal year.

portantly, this trend appears to be stronglyrelated to-and explainable by-the extent ofdemand for state school facilities aid.

Specifically, the chartshows that, as the extentof the ''backlog'' in requests for state new con­struction funds grows (that is, the dollar valueof applications on file increases), the number ofpupils in eligible year-round schools increases­with about a one-year lag. In other words, whatappears to be motivating school districts toimplement year-round programs is their recog­nition that funding provided through the Lease-

Page 16

Page 19: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Purchase program will not become availablequickly enough to meet pressing needs foradditional capacity. (Because the Lease-Pur­chase program generallyprovides schoolfacili­ties aid on a "first-come, first-served" basis,increases in the "backlog" of requests translateinto longer waiting periods from the time anapplication is filed to the completion ofconstruction.) In fact, a more detailed statisti­cal analysis indicates that, when the level ofdemand for new construction funds is con­trolled for, the availability of the SB 327 year­round incentive payments has no discernible,statistically significant effect on the totalnumber of pupils in year-round schools.

Neither Table 2 nor Chart 5 contain the datanecessary to identify the impact of the SB 813($25) incentive program, which began in 1984­85. Our review indicates, however, that, of the13 districts that received SB 813 incentive pay­mentsin the program's first year, 11 (85 percentof the total) were operating year-round pro­grams prior to the advent of the incentives.Specifically, five of the 11 had begun their pro­grams by 1974, and three more had begun pro­grams by 1980.

In sum, the available evidence indicates that:• The number of pupils attending year­

round schools was growing significantlyprior to the adventof thefirst year-roundincentive program in 1984-85;

• The SB 813 ($25) program had little impactin its firs t year (1984-85) in increasing thenumber of school districts operating year­round schools; and

• Growth since 1984-85 in the numbers ofpupils attending year-round schools thatare eligible for state incentive paymentsappears to be explainable as a schooldistrict responds to increasing backlogsin the dollar value of applications forschool construction aid.

Based on this evidence, it appears that thenumber of excess pupils accommodated throughyear-round·operations is not responsive to theavailability of incentive payments, within therange ofpayment levels provided by the SB 327and SB 813 programs. To the extent that this is,in fact, the case, then the bulk of the $43 million

ChapterIII: Evaluation

in incentive payments appropriated in 1989-90will not influence school district behavior, butwill merely provide "windfall gains" to thosedistricts that receive such funding.

This evidence also suggests that, if the Legis­lature is interested in encouraging school dis­tricts to use existingschool facilities more inten­sively through year-round operations, the mostcost-effective way of doing so would be tochange the existing school building aid pro­gram. Specifically, the Legislature may wish toconsider (as we recommended in our publication,The 1989-90 Budget: Perspectives and Issues) pro­viding school facilities aid only in amounts suf­ficient to support the construction of new schoolsthat would be operated on a year-round basis,accommodating additional capacity beyond thatof a traditional, nine-month calendar school. Astronger incentive for year-round operationswould be to calculate a school district's overalleligibility for state building aid under the as­sumption that it had already taken full advan­tage of districtwide year-round operations as ameans of accommodating overcrowding. Underthis approach, a district might not qualify forstate aid until it was at least 10 percent over­crowded using a year-round calendar standard ofoperations (which would be equivalent to, say,30 percent overcrowded using a traditional,nine-month standard)-rather than the 10 per­cent (traditional calendar) threshold currentlyused to determine eligibility.

Secondary Criterion: Simplicity

Our review indicates that by having two dif­ferent incentive payment programs to promoteyear-round education, the existing system ismore complicated than is necessary. Moreover,one of these two programs-the SB 327 variablerate incentive-is a complex and difficult pro­gram both to understand and to administer.

Because the SB 327 program is so compli­cated, most school districts are unable to calcu­late their own funding entitlement. In the cur­rent year, the formula is statutorily composedof 15 steps that must be executed for each year-·round school within an applicant district. Inaddition, because of the complexity, differentinterpretations have been assigned to the dif-

Page 17

Page 20: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter /II: Evaluation

ferent steps, resulting in significant statutorychanges to the formula in every year of theprogram's three-year existence.

ConclusionJudging by the criteria identified above, we

conclude that the existing year-round schoolincentive payment programs are of little or novalue in promoting the state's primary interestin year-round education-which is to maxi­mize the amount of net costs avoided by reduc­ing demands for state-financed new schoolconstruction.

Put another way, the available evidence sug­gests that the SB 327and SB 813 programs couldbe eliminated, with little impact on the totalnumber of pupils attending year-round schools.The Legislature could then use the associatedfunding for other, higher priority purposeswithinK-14 education. (Proposition 98require-

Page 18

ments preclude these funds from being used fornonK-14 purposes.)

For this reason, we recommend that the Legis­lature repeal the existing year-round schooIincentive programs.

We recognize, however, that the Legislaturemay wish to continue to provide some form ofyear-round school incentives, to the extent thatsome school districts may respondby increasingthe numbers of pupils attending year-roundschools. In Chapter IV of this report, we iden­tify those features that our analysis indicatesshould be included in a revised incentive pro­gram, in order to better achieve the primarygoal of maximizing the state's net cost avoid­ance and the secondary goal of simplicity.

Page 21: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter IV: An Alternative Method

Chapter IV

An Alternative Method of Providing Incentive Payments

In this chapter, we describe the primary fea­tures of an alternative year-round incentiveformula-should the Legislature choose tocontinue to pay incentives based on sharingstate UsavingsU-that would better meet thetwo criteria presented earlier. Again, the fea­tures of such a formula are based on existingpractices for financing new construction throughthe Lease-Purchase program. To the extent thatthe Lease-Purchaseprogram changes, thesefea­tures would probably also change. Specifically,these features are:

• Provide school districts with the optimallevel of shared Usavings," in order tomaximize the state's net cost avoidance;

• Reflect district-specific land and con­struction costs, as provided for in theState School Building Lease-Purchaseprogram; and

• Create an alternative to new school con­struction, rather than a subsidy whilewaiting in line for a state-financed school.

Provide Optimal Level of Shared"Savings"

As outlined in Chapter II, the optimal level ofincentive payment is that which maximizes thetotal amount of the state's net cost avoidance.How, in practice, does one determine what thispayment should be? The answer to this ques­tion consists of two parts: (1) a procedure fordetermining the theoretically optimal paymentlevel and (2) a practical procedure for deter­mining the optimal payment level, if the condi­tions necessary for determining the theoreti­cally optimal level cannot be met.

Theoretical Optimum: Vary Payment by Dis­trict Responsiveness. In theory, the ideal wayof maximizing the state's net cost avoidance isto vary the level of incentive payment depend­ing upon how responsive districts are in plac­ing pupils on multitrack year-round schedules.(A district would be "responsive," if the per­centage increase in the number of pupils onyear-round schedules in the district is greaterthan the given percentage increase in the levelof per-pupil incentive payment.) Under suchan approach, the state would not pay any year­round incentives for students who would havebeen on year-round schedules in the absence ofthe incentives. In addition, the state wouldoffer relatively lowincentive payments to thosedistricts in which the number ofpupils on year­round schedules were less responsive to suchincentives, and relatively higher payments todistricts in which the number of pupils weremore responsive. In no case, however, would thestate offer a level of incentive payment that exceeded100 percent of its gross cost avoidance.

In order to implement this type of incentivepayment system, however, one must be able toestimate the extentto which individual districtswould respond to the offering of year-roundschool incentives. This,in turn, requires a fairlysophisticated analysis of data from individualschool districts, which controls for all signifi­cant factors other than the level of incentivepayment (for example, the degree of districtwideovercrowding using a traditional, nine-monthschedule) that might affect the usupply" ofpupils attending year-round schools in eachdistrict.

Page 19

Page 22: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter IV: An Alternative Method

This is not to say that a practical system ofproviding differential levels of incentive pay­ments, based on degree of school district re­sponsiveness, cannot be developed. Unfortu­nately, however, within the constraints of time,data, and resources available to prepare thisreport, we were unable to conduct the type ofanalysis necessary to do so. Moreover, we arenot aware of any research supporting the no­tion that the extent to which a district accommo­dates pupils in excess of its traditional calendarcapacity-one of the factors affecting the levelof SB 327 incentive payments-is related to itsresponsiveness to incentives. As a result, ourresearch suggests that if the Legislature wishesto optimize incentive payments, a new pay­ment system must be put in place. We can findno evidence that a modified version of the SB327 program's variable payment approach wouldserve to maximize the amount of the state's netcost avoidance.

Practical Solution: Uniform Percentage of1/Savings" for All Districts. Hit is not possibleto distinguish among individual districts' re­sponsiveness to the offering of year-round in­centives, then a reasonable alternative wouldbe to pay all districts the same percentage of thestate's gross cost avoidance. (Individual dis­tricts' per-pupil payments would still vary, toreflect differences in gross cost avoidance re­lated to costs of land and construction.) Asdemonstrated in greater detail in Appendix E,the optimal level of incentive payment whichshould be provided to school districts underthese conditions (that is, paying all districts thesame percentage of the state's "savings") de­pends upon the overall, statewide level of schooldistricts' responsiveness to changes in the levelof such payments.

Based on the evidence presented in ChapterIII, it appears that the total number of pupilsattending year-round schools statewideis quiteunresponsive to the level of incentive paymentoffered. This, in turn, implies that if the Legis­lature wishes to pursue the alternative of pro­viding all school districts with the same per­centage of the state's gross cost avoidance, thissharing ratio should probably also be quitelow-and in no case should itexceed50percent.

Page 20

We note that, even if the sharing ratio were setat no more than 50 percent, this would noteliminate the possibility of "windfall gains" tocertain school districts. To the extent that aschool district was alreadyoperating its schoolsyear-round prior to the offering of incentivepayments-or had no practical alternative butto move to a year-round calendar in order toaccommodate overcrowding-the provision ofincentive payments would not result in anyadditional pupils on year-round schedules, butwould merely reward the district for actions itwould have taken anyway in the program'sabsence. Such windfall gains will always occurin any practical funding mechanism that isunable to distinguish each district's uniqueresponsiveness to the offering of incentives.(Please see Appendix E for a mathematicalproof of the maximum sharing ratio.)

Reflect Individual Land andConstruction Costs

Because the amount of the per-pupil grosscost avoidance varies significantly dependingupon a district's land costs (and, to a lesserextent, its construction costs), any formula thatseeks to maximize the amount of the state's netcost avoidance should take these factors intoaccount.

In order to reflect accurately the state's costavoidance, the computation of land and con­struction costs must parallel the actual practicesof the Lease-Purchase new construction pro­gram. This is because the primary interest ofthe state in the incentive program is to avoid thecost of building schools. Because the Lease­Purchase program does not pay districts forsites that the district has already acquired, nei­ther should the incentive formula. Specifically,this means that the cost of land should be fac­tored into an incentive formula only where adistrict does not already have a site-irrespec­tive of who actually paid for the site. Bysimilarlogic, the estimated amount of land and con­struction costs avoided through using year­round operations should be based on actualpractices of the Lease-Purchase program, inwhich the total number of excess pupils accom-

Page 23: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter IV: An Alternative Method

5 10 15 20 25 30 35%

Percent Excess Capacity Accommodated

Alternative Fonnulaa

Current LawState "SaVings"

-------

$ per Pupil$250,------------~

225

200

175

150

125

100

75

50

25

Land Cost of $50,000 per Acre

• Maximum level of Incentive payment, assuming adoption of all otherchanges (see text).

ConclusionCharts 6 through 8 show the maximum level of

year-round school incentive payment that shouldbe provided to school districts, if the Legislaturedecides to continue to provide incentive paymentsusingauniform percentage ofsavings method. (Thecharts illustrate the maximumlevel ofincentivepayment for school districts with the levels ofland costs previously illustrated in Charts 2through 4.) These charts assume that the re­vised year-round school incentive programwould also (1) reflect district-specific land andconstruction costs, as provided for in the StateSchool Building Lease-Purchase program and(2) create an alternative to new school construc­tion, rather than a subsidy while waiting in linefor a state-financed school.

Specifically, Chart 6 (land cost of $50,000 peracre) shows that, for locations with relativelylowland costs, the maximum level ofstate incen­tive payment should range from zero (wherenoadditional pupils are accommodated) to ap­proximately $69 per pupil (at 35 percent excesscapacity accommodated). (For levels of excesscapacity accommodated in excess 6f35 percent,the maximum incentive payment that should

modated would have been aggregated into~roupsof sufficient size to justify the construc­tion of a new school (or schools). (Under theexisting incentive programs, the land and con­s~ructioncosts are estimated under the assump­tionthat the state would have built numerousunrealistically small schools, each accommo­~ating a small number of pupils. This assump­tion can overstate-by over 100 percent-theamount of land and construction costs actuallyavoided by the state.)

Create an Alternative, Not a SubsidyIn order to maximize thestate's netcostavoid­

ance, the purpose of any incentive paymentprogram must be to encourage year-roundprograms as an alternative to new construction,rather than as a subsidy while waiting for newconstruction funding. Our review indicates!hat th.ere are at least two methods by which anIncentIve program can ensure that this is ac­complished:

• HGetting Out of Line." Under this ap­~roach,a school district receiving incen­tIve payments would be required toreduce its applications for new schoolfacilities funding by the amount of ex­cess pupils accommodated (and receiv­~ng p~yment) through the year-roundIncentIve program.

• Financial Penalties. Under this approach,a district would be assessed penalties ifit used state funds to build new schoolsto accommodate students for which the~tate J?reviously provided year-roundIncentive payments. Such penalties"could include (1) a requirement to payback incentive payments previouslyreceived, or (2) a reduction from anyfuture state construction funding alloca­tion in an amount equal to the incentivesthat previously had been paid to thedistrict.

O~r re",:iew indicates that th: particular typeof fInanCIal safeguard chosen IS not as impor­!ant as.a safeguard being part of any alternativeIncentIve program enacted by the Legislature.

Page 21

Page 24: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter IV: An Alternative Method

State "Savings"

5 10 15 20 25 30 35%

Percent Excess Capacity Accommodated

/ Alternative Formula",...,.'-----~........-+ Current Law

$ per Pupil

$250,--------r--,----.....,225

200

175

150

125

100

75

50

25

Chart 8- - - -

State Cost versus State "Savings":Current Law and Alternative Formula

Land Cost of $1.5 million per Acre

Chart 7

State Cost versus State "SaVings":Current Law and Alternative Formula

be provided would increase proportionally.)The chart also shows that in no case would suchpayments exceed 50 percent of the state's "sav­ings" at any given level of excess capacity ac­commodated.

Chart 7 (land cost of $250,000 per acre) showsthat, for locations with moderate land costs, themaximum level of state incentive payment shouldrange from zero (where no additional pupilsare accommodated) to approximately $84 perpupil (at 35 percent excess capacity accommo­dated).

Land Cost of $250,000 per Acre" Maximum level of Incentive payment, assuming adoption of all other

changes (see text).

In sum, adoption of this alternative wouldensure that-to the extent practicallyfeasible­the incentive payment program maximizes theamount of the state's net cost avoidance (that is,the avoided costs from not having to buildschool facilities, minus the costs of the incentivepayments). Adoption of this alternative wouldalso ensure that school districts receive year­round school incentives as an alternative tonew construction, rather than as a subsidy whilewaiting for such funding. The "savings" sogenerated could be used to address the press­ing statewide demand for school facilities aid,odorother high-priorityK-12 education needs.

Akernatlve Formula"----

State "Savings".---"""':'"-=-tCurrent Law

--

$per Pupil

$250,----~------.

225

200

175

150

125

100

75

50

25

Finally, Chart 8 (land cost of $1.5 million peracre) shows that, for locations with extraordi­narily high land costs, the maximum level ofstate incentivepaymentshould rangefrom zeroto $175 per pupil (at 35 percent excess capacityaccommodated). The chart also shows that, incases where such school districts accommo­dated additional pupils in excess of 30 percentof capacity, the maximum level of incentivepayment could exceed the amount providedunder the existing SB 327 and SB 813 programs.

Percent Excess Capacity Accommodated

" Maximum level of Incentive payment, assuming adoption of all otherchanges (see text).

5 10 15 20 25 30 35%

Page 22

Page 25: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Summary

Chapter V

Summary of Findings and Recommendations

In this chapter, we summarize the findingsand recommendations that result from theanalysis presented in the previous chapters.

Our review of the SB 327 and the SB 813 year­round school incentive payment programsindicates that they are of little or no value inpromoting the state's primary interest in year­round education-which is to maximize theamount of net costs avoided by reducing de­mands for state-financed new school construc­tion. This is because:

• For the vast majority of school districtsachieving the "target" level of 15 percentexcess capacity accommodated, the ex­isting programs provide a combined levelof incentive payment that exceeds 100percent of the state's gross cost avoid­ance (that is, the programs result in in­centive-payment costs which exceed thecosts the state would have incurred hadit built new schools.)

• Even in school districts with high landcosts, the state still may realize no netsavings because (1) the incentive pay­ment formula overpays districts for landcosts, relative to the actual costs whichwould have been incurred under thestate building program and (2) the in­centive programs may function as asubsidy for districts while they wait inline for new construction funds, ratherthan as an alternative to new construc­tion.

• Even with this generous level of incen­tive payment, there is little evidence thatthe existing programs have had any dis-

cernible impact in increasing the num­ber of pupils on multitrack year-roundschedules beyond levels that would haveoccurred in the programs' absence.

For these reasons, we recommend that theLegislature repeal the existing year-round schoolincentive programs.

We recognize, however, that the Legislaturemay wish to continue to provide some form ofyear-round school incentives, to the extent thatsome school districts may respond byincreasingthe numbers of pupils attending year-roundschools. If the Legislature wishes to continue toprovide incentive payments based on sharing auniform percentage of the state's "savings," werecommend an alternative program that wouldinclude all of the following features:

• Provide school districts with no morethan 50 percent of the state's "savings";

• Reflect district-specific land and con­struction costs, as provided for in theState School Building Lease-Purchaseprogram; and

• Create an alternative to new school con­struction, rather than a subsidy whilewaiting in line for a state-financed school.

These features assume the continuation ofexisting practices for financing new construc­tion through the Lease-Purchase program. Tothe extent that the Lease-Purchase programchanges, these features would probably alsochange.

Page 23

Page 26: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Chapter V: Summary

Page 24

Page 27: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Appendix A

Glossary of Terms Used in Report

Excess capacity accommodated: The numberof additional pupils accommodated in a schoolin excess of its traditional (nine-month calen­dar) capacity, expressed as a percentage of thistraditional capacity.

Gross cost avoidance: The costs avoided bythe state by not building new school facilitiesunder the StateSchool BuildingLease-Purchaseprogram, as a result of school districts accom­modating excess capacity through year-roundeducation. (In this report, the term "savings" issometimes used as a briefer-though less pre­cise-alternative to "gross cost avoidance.")

Net cost avoidance: Gross cost avoidance,minus the cost to the state of paying year-roundschool incentives. (The term "net savings" issometimes used as an equivalent term.)

Appendices

Present discounted value: A mathematicaltechnique used to calculate the value at thepresent time of a stream of payments (or asingle payment) to be received in the future,based on a specific discount rate. It is based onthe simple notion that a dollar's worth of goodsor services received one year from today isworth less than the same goods or servicesreceived today. The discount rate reflects thefact that money can be invested to earn interestor, alternatively, that borrowing money costsinterest.

Year-round education: An alternative sched­ule for learning that reorganizes the academiccalendar so that instructional time blocks andvacation periods are evenly distributed through­out the year.

Page 25

Page 28: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Appendices

Page 26

Page 29: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Appendices

Appendix B

Members: Year-Round Incentive Payments Advisory Committee

Warren BakerBoard MemberHesperia Unified School District

Charles BallingerExecutive DirectorNational Association for Year-Round Edu­cation (NAYRE)

Tom BancroftLegislative Advocate NAYRE

Larry BranmanResource SpecialistMontebello Unified School District

Kathy GaitherRick VargasDepartment of Finance

DuWayne BrooksHenry HeydtState Department of Education

Eddie HernandezJohn JenkinLori MorganOffice of Local Assistance, Department ofGeneral Services

Bernie KorensteinAssistant Superintendent, EducationalServicesOxnard School District

Page 27

Page 30: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Appendices

Page 28

Page 31: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

AppendixC

"Year-Round Schools"(Reprinted from The 1989-90 BUdget: Perspectives andIssues, pp. 170-183)

Appendices

Page 29

Page 32: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

"tJ

t8(J)

~170

Year-Round Schools

What Are Year-Round Schools and How Can Their Use Reduce theDemand for Limited School Facilities Aid FundsP

Summary

• Currently, school district requests for state aid to accommodateunhoused students through the State School Building Lease­Purchase program far exceeds-by several billion dollars-the amountoffunds currently availablefrom the state. In addition, the demandfor these limited state resources will mount in the coming years asthe K-12 school-age population continues to grow.

e Through the use of year-round education, school districts can makemore intensive use of existing facilities, thereby expanding thecapacity of a school site by up to one-third (or more, in certaincases).

• As a result, year-round school programs can reduce the demand forschool construction funds by hundreds of millions of dollars. Inaddition, these programs can reduce school district per-pupil oper-ating casts. '

• .The academic achievement ofstudents attending year-round schoolprograms is generally comparable to that of their counterparts intraditional calendar schools.

• In order to maximize the number of pupils that can be housed withlimited state financial resources for school construction, we recom­mend that the Legislature enact legislation requiring Lease-Purchaseprogramfunds for new construction to be allocated to school districtsas if the facility would operate on a year-round basis.

Introcludlon

The Deparhnent of Finance (DOF) estimates that, on a statewidebasis, the California K-12 school-age population will grow by approxi­mately 140,000 students per year between now and 1997, resulting in aneed for an additional 2,100 new schools. The State Dep~rtment ofEducation (SDE) estimates that the cost associated with providing theseadditional facilities could be as high as $11 billion. There are severalmethods available to school districts to finance their school facilities needsusing either state resources, local resources, or a combination of the two.First, the State School Building Lease-Purchase program provides most ofthe money used by local public school districts to construct and/ormodernize school facilities. Currently, school district requests for state aid

171

through the Lease-Purchase program far exceed the funding available forthis purpose. Specifically, as of November 1988, applications from schooldistricts for state aid ($4.3 billion) exceeded existing available funding($800 million) by approximately $3.5 billion.

In addition to the state progrp, school districts may raise funds locallyfor school facilities through three primary methods:

• The Mello -Roos Community Facility Act of1982. Pursuant to thisact, school districts are authorized to form "community facilities"districts, subject to the approval of two-thirds of the voters, to sellbonds to raise revenue for building new, or modernizing existingschool facilities.

• Local General Obligation Bonds. School districts are generallyauthorized to incur bonded indebtedness for school facilities con­struction purposes, subject to a two-thirds voter approval.

• Developer Fees. Since January 1, 1987, school districts have beenauthorized to impose developer fees, as specified, on a per-square­foot basis upon new residential and commercial/industrial construc­tion. These fee revenues can be used only for the construction ormodernization of school facilities. .

One important way to reduce the cost of providing school facilities isthrough the use of year-round schools. Year-round school provides a moreintensive use of existing facilities, thereby expanding the capacity of aschool site, and commensurately reducing the need for new facilities. Inthe discussion that follows, we describe what year-round education is,how its use can accommodate more students at an existing site, why it iseducationally sound, and why we believe it should be an essentialcomponent of any state program to assist school districts in meeting theirschool facility needs.

What II Year-Round Education?

Year-round education is an alternative schedule for learning; it is not analternative curriculum for learning. Students attending a year-roundschool go to the same types of classes and receive the same amount ofinstruction-generally 180 days per academic year-as stUdents attendingtraditional nine-month calendar schools. The.year-round school calendaris organized into instructional blocks and vacation periods that l!re evenlydistributed across a 12-month calendar year.

Specifically, on a traditional calendar, students generally attend schoolfor nine months followed by a three-month sUmmer vacation. On ayear-round calendar, the three-month summer vacation is divided intoseveral shorter vacation periods which are then spread throughout theschool year. As a result, year-round students receive several shortervacations; however, the total amount of vacation afforded to each pupil is

).

~(J)::J.

~~

Page 33: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

172173

•~r~~o~:d~~~:t~n1te!:;i:(3)s~h':':~2,r;::~8= \~~=~~BJ:e-1~(~g~In':~~~~.a:n~(4) that lUll capac"y Incre... can be Obtained.

Chart 1

Attendance PatternsTraditional, Single-Track and Multitrack Calendar ProgramsaFor A School WhIch Can Accommodate 600 Students At Any TIme

).

~~

~m

o School

• Vacation

TrackD200 Students

TrackC200 Students

Track a200 Students

':rrI'l4Q!JIPN41ff'j

All 600 Students

,;$If,l~lml*'iI

All 600 Students

still the same as that of students attending a traditional-calendar school.Typically, a year-round student receives three one-month vacations orfour three-week vacations during one academic year.

Single-Track Versus Multitrack. Year-round schools can be operatedon either a "single-track" or "multitrack" basis; however, it is.only whenthe multitrack format is implemented that the capacity ofthe school canbe increased. A single-track system provides for the entire schoolpopulation (that is, all students and teachers) to follow the same calendarwith the same vacation periods. This means that, at any given time, all ofthe students and teachers are in school, or they are all on vacation. Theschool is typically closed during the vacation periods when neither thestudents nor teachers are present.

On a "multitrack" system, students and their teachers are grouped intodifferent tracks, with staggered instructional blocks and vacation periods.While one track is on vacation, another track can use its space; therebyallowing for an increase in the capacity of the school. For example,depending on the actual calendar used, students and their teachers maybe divided into four tracks. At anyone time, three of these tracks, orthree-quarters of the school's students/teachers, will be in school, and theremaining track, representing one quarter of the school's students/teach­ers, will be on vacation. (The remainder of this. discussion will focus onthe characteristics of multitrack programs because it is only on amultitrack system that the capacity of a school site can be increased lindcorresponding facility-related costs reduced.)

Chart 1 compares the different attendance patterns for a traditional,single-track and multitrack calendar program. It shows that both the·traditional calendar and single-track calendar can accommodate only 600students lind that all students are either in school or on vacation at thesame time. Chart 1 also shows that, by dividing students into four tracksand staggering instruction and vacation periods, the multitrack calendarcan accommodate 800 students, a 33 percent increase in capacity.

Track Assignments. On a multitrack system, students and teacherstypically are assigned to one of either three or four "tracks." There are avariety of methods for assigning students to tracks including: (a)geographically (that is, by address), with entire blocks, sides of streets, orapartment buildings assigned to the same track; (b) randomly (forexample, alphabetically); (c) by ability grouping (for example, by astudent's proficiency with English); (d) self-selection; and (e) individu­ally (that is, a one-by-one placement to customize the characteristics ofeach track).

Most districts offer parents the opportunity to indicate a preferredchoice of tracks, and also provide for students from the same family to be"8

~(.)-

Page 34: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

a'cg~

174

assigned to the same track. Similar variations occur regarding theassignment of teachers to tracks, although generally a much larger degreeof self-selection is available (providing that each track yields the neces­sary number of teachers for each grade level).

Shared Classrooms. Because a classroom remains in use when onetrack goes on vacation, teachers are generally grouped so that fourteachers share three classrooms. Teacher grouping is generally made onthe basis of grade level, so that similar supplies and equipment can beshared.

By necessity, the sharing of rooms requires a revised system for thestorage of teacher and classroom materials during the "off-track" period.Most multitrack programs have developed some type of modular orportable storage system that can be moved between classrooms andstorage areas. Innovative designs in schools specifically designed and builtto accommodate year-round programs provide a central teacher storage/workspace area linked to several classrooms.

Year-Round EducatIon In CalifornIa

According to the SDE, there are currently an estimated 69 Californiaschool districts operating year-round school programs, with about 360,000stUdents (about 8 percent of pupils statewide) attending such programs.Thirty-five of these districts operate multitr~ck programs, with anestimated 300,000 students enrolled in such programs. A review ofdistricts operating multitrack year-round programs indicates that themajority of these programs-approximately 90 percent-are operated atthe elementary school level, with the remainder operated at the juniorhigh or senior high school level. For the most part, multitrack programshave been implemented for the sole purpose of relieving either site­sp~cific or districtwide overcrowding.

Table 1 identifies the 10 districts which have the greatest number ofstudents attending multitrack year-round programs. It shows that duringthe current year, the 10 largest multitrack year-round programs includeapproximately 234,000 students, or about 25 percent of the districts'overall enrollment. Of these programs, the Los Angeles Unified SchoolDistrict (LAUSD) operates the largest program, with an estimated135,000 students participating, and the Oxnard Elementary School Dis­trict operates the most extensive program, with all of its studentsattending year-round programs.

175

Table'Ten Lergest Multitrack Yaar·Round Programs

(by district)1988-89

EnrollmentYear-ROiiiiil

PercelltofDistrict Districtwide Number Total1. Los Angeles Unified. 594,000 135,000 22.7%2. San Diego City Unified........................... 117,000 17,700 15.13. Fresno Unified....... 65,500 17,900 27.34. Santa Ana Unified.......................... 40,000 12,000 30.05. Montebello Unified............................... 31,600 8,200 25.96. Lodi Unified....................................... ·22,500 9,900 44.07. Fontana Unified............. 22,300 7,600 34.18. Rialto Unified......... 17,300 7,700 44.59. Oxnard Elementary............................... 11,600 11,600 100.0

10. Hesperia Unified........................ 10,900 6,200 56.9Totals........................................... 932,900 234,000 25.1%

Of the 10 largest school districts in California, six currently operatemultitrack year-round school programs, with a range from between 5percent to 35 percent of students attending a year-round program.

Variation ofCalendars. Our review indicates that there are four basiccalendars used by the districts in the state which operate year-roundprograms. The calendar adopted by a school district for its year-roundeducation program determines the frequency and length of the instruc­tional blocks and vacation periods that students and teachers will receive.Generally, the type of calendar selected does not affect the. extent towhich a facility will be able to accommodate additional pupils; rather, itonly affects the number of transitions students and teachers have to makebetween periods of instruction and vacation.

The majority ofstudents attending multitrack year-round programs areaccommodated by some variation of the following four basic calendars:

• "90/30." On the "90/30" calendar, each track of students and theirteachers are present in school for 90 days (18 weeks) , and then recessfor 30 days (6 weeks). This calendar is similar to a "two semester"school schedule in that instruction occurs during two 18 week blocks,each separated by a six-week break.

• "60/20." On the "60/20" calendar, each track attends school for 60days (12 weeks), and then recesses for 20 days (4 weeks). On thistype of calendar, students/teachers. are present in school duringthree three-month blocks, each separated by a one-month break.

• ''45/15.'' On the "45/15" calendar, students/teachers are present inschool for 45 days (9 weeks), and then recess for 15 days (3 weeks).This calendar involves four transitions-the most of any of thesecalendars-between instruction and vacation during an academicyear.

»~~

~CDC/)

Page 35: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

L Not appUcable.

As mentioned above, districts often modify a particular basic calendarformat in order to meet their individual needs. For example, one schoolwith a typically low enrollment during January arranged its calendar sothat the school was closed that month. Other districts that wanted toprovide a slightly longer vacation period during the summer months

176

• "Concept 6." This calendar provides for only 163, rather than ISOdays ofinstruction; however, the school day is lengthened by 25 to 38minutes, depending on the grade level. Consequently, over anacademic year students still receive the same amount of instructionaltime as their counterparts in a traditional-calendar school.

The "Concept 6" calendar divides the year into six instructional terms(each about two months long), with students required to attend four ofthe six terms (for an eight-month school year). This calendar allows adistrict to accommodate the greatest percentage increase in additionalstudents (up to 50 percent). Despite this, Concept 6 has not been used bymany districts. This is because, prior to July 1, 1988, school districts (withthe exception of the LAUSD) were prohibited from offering studentsfewer than 175 days of instruction per academic year. This made theConcept 6 calendar difficult to implement. FromJuly 1,1988 through JulyI, 1995, however, current law authorizes all school districts to offer aConcept 6-type calendar, provided that the total amount of instructionaltime. provided to students meets existing statutory requirements.

Table 2 provides a comparative summary of these four basic year­round calendars with that of the traditional-calendar school. It shows that,although the length and number of instructional terms vary among thedifferent calendars, all but the Concept 6 calendar provide students withthe same number of instructional days-generally lBO-per academic year.Table 2 also shows that, although the length and number of vacations varybetween the different calendars, all students receive approximately 12weeks of vacation, except for Concept 6 students, who receive approxi­mately 16 weeks of vacation.

Tabla 2Comparativa Summary

Traditional and Year-Round School CalendarsCalendor

"'tJ

c8(J)

t:

FeaturesNumber of instructional days .Number of instructional tenus .Length of teon....................•...

Number of Vacations ..Length of Vacation .Maximum percent capacity galn .Number of Tracks .

TtiiiJ,HOtiiil180

1180 days

(36 weeks)1

12 weeksa

90/30180

290 days

(18 weeks)2

6 weeks33%4

"60/20180

360 days

(12 weeks)3

4 weeks33%4

45715180

445 days

(9 weeks)4

3 weeks33%4

Cancept6163

441 days

(8.2 weeks)2

8.1 weeks50%3

.. '

177

lengthened the vacations falling during this period and commensuratelyshortened other breaks. Our review of California school districts which

. operate a year-round program indicates that no two districts haveidentical calendars; in fact, it is not uncommon for a single district tooperate several different calendars.

No "Best" Calendar. Our review indicates that, although there arevirtually an unlimited variety of calendars that can be implemented foryear-round education, there is no single "best" calendar. For example, aschool needing to accommodate only 20 percent more students may notwant to implement the Concept 6 calendar, which provides for increasingstudent capacity by up to 50 percent. Similarly, a district with a largerdegree of overcrowding might determine that it makes more sense tooperate one or several Concept 6 calendar schools, rather than anincreased number of "45/15" or "60/20" schools, each of which individ­ually affords a smaller capacity increase. A district with overcrowdingonly at the high school level might elect to implement the Concept 6model, as it provides the greatest flexibility for scheduling classes wherestudents rotate among teachers because it has fewer but larger tracks. Onthe other hand, a district with overcrowding only at the elementary levelmight opt for a calendar which allows for the easiest transition forstudents from a year-round calendar elementary school to a traditional­calendar secondary school. In sum, our review indicates that the "best"calendar is the one that fits a particular district's (and its community's)needs.

Capacity. As illustrated above, most multitrack calendars allow for a 33percent increase in capacity. Most schools, however, achieve a lowercapacity increase for several reasons.

First, not all classrooms that are available on a traditional calendar canbe maintained as classroom space in a year-round calendar program. Forexample, because generally one quarter of the teachers are not present at .anyone time, space needs to be allocated for the storage of theseteachers' materials and as a workroom in which they can prepareupcoming materials during their "off-track" time. Second, because theschool site is in continual use, such necessary maintenance and upkeepactivities as cleaning and painting are difficult to perform unless someclassrooms are periodically "cycled out" and kept empty and available forsuch services. Finally, in order to operate "intersession" programs-theyear-round school equivalent of summer school-additional classroomspace must also remain unoccupied. .

Uses ofIncreased Capacity. The increased capacity that results from amultitrack system may be desirable for reasons other than providingspace for unhoused students. For example, where overcrowding hasalready been accommodated through other means-such as using libraries,

»~~

~m

Page 36: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

"tJ

~CD

~178

computer labs, special education or multipurpose rooms as classroomspace-the conversion to multitrack may simply allow a school site to again"free up" these areas for their originally designated educational purposes.

Where overcrowding is unique to a particular site or sites, rather thandistrictwide, the increased capacity can be used to reduce or eliminatethe need for busing students from a crowded site to one that has availablespace or for altering individual school site attendance areas.

The increased capacity also can be used to integrate selectively a schoolthat is segregated racially, socially, or by ability. For example, theincreased capacity generated at a racially segregated school can be ruledwith students of underrepresented races.

Finally, a change to a year-round calendar could be made to reduceclass sizes without having to expand the facility. For example, a schoolwith an enrollment of 480 stUdents and an average class size of30 studentsrequires 16 classrooms. To reduce the class size by 20 percent (to 24students per class), four additional classrooms (a total of 20 classrooms)would normally be required. By converting to a multitrack schedule,however, the school could make five additional classrooms available,thereby avoiding the costs of constructing any additional classroom

spaces.

Adva"tages and DisadvantagesThere are both benefits and costs-monetary and otherwise-associated

with operating multitrack year-round educational programs. Below, wefocus on two of the more significant areas of state concern-the costs andsavings associated with year-round schools and its impact on students'academic achievement. In addition, we summarize other advantages and

. disadvantages of a multitrack calendar.Costs and Savings. In the area of capital outlay, the use of multitrack

year-round programs could result in major state and local savings inschool construction and rehabilitation costs. For example, our analysisindicates that, on average, it costs almost $5 million to purchase acreageand build a new elementary school to house 500 California students, fora per-student cost of about $10,000. Thus, each unhoused student who isaccommodated through the use of a year-round schedule saves the localdistrict a significant amount of capital outlay funds. For the state, theimplementation of year-round programs in lieu of constructing newfacilities would reduce the demand for state school facilities aid funds bypotentially hundreds of millions. of dollars.

These savings would be offset by certain capital and one-time costs tooperate year-round schools. For example, many schools would require airconditioning and added insulation to operate during summer months,and almost all schools would have additional storage needs. Our review

!71)

indicates, however, that these one-time costs are fairly small in compar-ison to the capital savings. .

In the area of operating expenditures, we are aware of only two in­depth financial analyses which compare the costs of year-round andtraditional schools: one by the Oxnard Elementary School District andthe other by the San Diego City Unified School District.

The Oxnard district is an entirely year-round district serving approxi­mately 11,800 K-8 students. In a study conducted in 1986-87, the districtcompared actual per-pupil costs over a fout-year period (1981-82 through1985-86) of operating its year-round schools to its costs of operatingtraditional-calendar schools. The study found that the annual per-pupilcost of maintaining year-round schools averaged about 5.5 percent (or$123) less than what the district paid for traditional schools. The districtattributes the overall savings primarily to economies of scale-that is, theadditional enrollment permitted by a year-round program did not

. require a proportionate increase in expenses. In addition, the studyidentified four specific factors which contributed to these operationalsavings:

• Sharing of classroom and reference materials since four classes ofstudents share three sets of materials.

• Avoiding the cost of additional benefit packages, as staff extendedfrom 10-month to 11- or 12-month contracts did not require addi­tional benefits.

• Reduced student and teacher absenteeism.• Reduced school site burglary and vandalism.

The San Diego Unified School District is a K-12 district servingapproximately 117,000 pupils. Of these, almost 18,000, or 15 percent,attend year-round schools. In a study focusing on the 1987-88 school year,the district compared the ongoing operational costs of accommodatingexcess enrollments through year-round schools to those of traditionalschools. The district determined that, on an ongoing, per-pupil basis,there were no increased costs when capacity was increased by 20 percentand there were savings of $8.92 per pupil per year when capacity wasincreased by 25 percent. (The district's analysis also identified $400,000 inone-time costs associated with the conversion to year-round operations.)

Thus, while there currently is limited information on this issue, theevidence from these two studies indicates that, on a per-pupil basis, theoperational costs of year-round schools are slightly less than those of theirtraditional calendar counterparts.

Academic Achievement. In evaluating year-round education, a criticalconcern is its impact on academic performance. The field of literature

~:g~

~

Page 37: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

180181

Chart 2

Multitrack Year-Round SchoolsAdvantages and Disadvantages

."

c8CD

~

addressing this issue is quite limited. Following are the conclusions ofseveral of the studies that have been conducted:

• A 1979 study of thePajaro Valley Unified School District conducted.by the Stanford Research Institute indicated that its year-roundschool program had little impact on a student's achievement testscores.

• A 1984 study conducted by the Los Angeles Unified School Districtconcluded that its year-round programs relieved overcrowdingwithout reducing educational quality or negatively affecting stu­dent's academic performance.

• The authors of a 1986 study of proficiency scores in the OxnardElementary School District found that year-round students outper­formed traditional students in math, but the reverse was true inreading-although the differences in performance in both cases weresmall.

• The SDE, in a 1987 report on year-round education, analyzed testscores of students attending traditional, single-track, and multitrackcalendar schools. Allowing for the special needs and demographics ofthe communities in which multitrack year-round schools have beenplaced, SDE concluded that the year-round calendar is a viableeducational option "that can be associated with achievement at orabove predicted levels."

.Thus, a review of these studies suggests that students in year-roundprograms generally do no better or no worse than their counterparts intraditional calendar schools. We also discussed the issue of academicachievement with various practitioners during the course of our review.There appears to be a general consensus among principals and teachersin year-round schools that students' retention of subject matter is greater,thereby leading to a reduction in the amount of time that must bedevoted to reviewing old material and enabling more new material to becovered.

Other Considerations. Chart 2 highlights many of the advantages anddisadvantages associated with multitrack year-round education programs.Specifically, the chart indicates that year-round education can increaseboth the supply of substitute teachers and teachers' overall earnings tothe extent that "off-track" teachers make themselves available as substi­tute teachers during some or all of their vacation time. Our visits todistricts operating year-round programs indicate that almost all offeroff-track teachers first priority for substituting at their home schoolduring their vacation periods. Multitrack programs generally also offerthe opportunity for classified personnel (for example, maintenance andcafeteria workers) to increase their overall earnings by converting from10- or U-month contracts to full-year contracts.

F1_I: I• Is a cost-effective alternative to construcllng

or modernizIng a new facility.• een reduce per-pupil operating costa.• Reduces student and teacher absenteeism.• Reduces school site burglllty and

vandalism.Facility Utilization: I

• Generally Increases school site capeclty upID 33 pereant dapendlng on lIIe calendarselected, number of !racks. end oilier faclDtyneeds. Alternatively, allows for a reductionIn dass size. wllhout eddlng additionalclassroom specas.

• Acts as an elternative 10 busing, doublesessions, or extended day schildu/es whenovercrowding Is present.

• Increases bolll school and communitylaellity use.

• Allows more slUden1810 attend neighbor­hood schools.

• Increases nexlblllty for meeting dlsb1ctdesegregation needs.

Academlc:JIn81ructlonal: I• Reduces lIIe amount 01 remedial review

done'each September alter lIIe lradltionalvacation period leamlng regression.

• EncourageS/requires teaching staff ID bebeller organiZed.

• Enables Intersesslons to be offered forenrichmenllremedlation programs at morefrequent Intervals lIIen summer school.

Employment: I• Increases availability of sUbstilUte teachers

to the eXlent lIIat year-round teachers electto substilUle during some or all of lIIelr "011­!rack' periods. end also Increases salaryopporlUnlties for lIIose teachers electing IDsubstilUle.

• Provides lIIe opporlUnlty for year-roundemploymenllor bolll support servicepersonnel end educators.

• May provide secondllty slUdenta withgreater opporlUnlUes for vacationemployment.

Other: I• Allows Slall end lamilles lIIe opPorlUnlty ID

take vacations during "nonpeak' times.

FIscal:' I• May present large initial Implementation

costS lor bUilding renovation (for example.Ihe addition ofair conditioning or slDragefacilities).

AdmInIstrative: I• Increases difficulty In scheduling schoolwlde

educational end eXlracuITlcular activltias be­cause one group ofStafflslUdenta Is alwaysabsent.

• Makes II dlfllcullto communlcate willi "off­!rack' students and slafl.

• Increases scheduling problems willi lrans­portatlon, cenlral supply. end maintenance.

• Presents storage dlfficultias for "011- lrack'teache~s and classroom materials.

• Generally requires an Increased I~vel of c0­ordination willi enclllllty community serviceorgenlzadons lhet provide recreadonal andchild care servIces 10 vacationing students.

• May be dlfllcullto schedule children fromIhe same family lIIat ere In different grades.

• Becomes more difficult to regroup studentaoncellley ere assigned ID a track.

Employment: I• May reduce slafl professIonal development

oPPorlUnlties, to lIIe extentlhat courses areoffered only In lIIe summer. .

Other: --- _

• Parenta have difficultyadjusting to a chengeIn lIIe lradltional school calendar.

• Periodic vacations may create baby- silling!child care problems.

• May be difficult for families 10 coordinate va­cations where children alland differentschools lIIat do nol use lIIe same calendar.

).

~~

~m

Page 38: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

~<g(.0)0.

182

Chart 2 also indicates that there are many administrative difficultiesassociated with operating a multitrack year-round program, such ascommunicating with off-track students and staff, and scheduling suchactivities as maintenance, transportation, staff development and school­wide events. In addition, discussions with school district personnelindicate that parents frequently resist attempts to convert to a year­round education program until many of the advantages and disadvan­tages can be identified and thoroughly discussed.

Legislature's Interest In Year-Round Education

State School Building Lease-Purchase Program. As noted earlier, thestate currently has an estimated $800 million in bond funds available tofinance $4.3 billion in requests from school districts under the StateSchool Building Lease-Purchase program. This aid is provided primarilyin the form of grants. To the extent that school districts file additionalrequests for aid between now and the next time additional funds could bemade available to the program-either July 1989 (an appropriation in theBudget Act) or June 1990 (bond funds provided at the next statewideelection)-the disparity between requests and availability of funds willcontinUe to grow.

In addition to aid provided through the Lease-Purchase program, theLegislatrti:e also has enacted two year-round school "incentive" paymentprograms-SB 813 (Ch 498/83) and SB 327 (Ch 886/86)-which provideapproximately $30 million annually to eligible school districts operatingyear-round programs. [A detailed discussion of these programs appears inour 1987-88 Analysis (please see page 1008) and 1988-89 Analysis (pleasesee page 889).]

. There is one low- or no-cost method through which the Lease-Purchaseprogram could promote the use of year-round schools, thereby increasingthe number of pupils that can be housed with available state revenues.Specifically, the Legislature could revise the funding allocation formulasto reflect year-round school operations.

Revise Funding Formula. Under current law, school districts qualify­ing for the new construction program are awarded a total amount offunds based on a complex funding formula. This formula assumes that thenew school to be constructed will operate on a traditional nine-monthcalendar, rather than on a multitrack year-round calendar. However, ifthe facility to be built were to operate on a year-round basis, the samenumber of students could be accommodated in a smaller facility at asignificantly lower cost. To the extent that the state were to allocate fundson this multitrack basis (assuming a minimum 20 percent capacityincrease), the $800 million currently available for expenditure couldfinance the equivalent of $935 million (an additional $135 million) in new

183facilities construction. (The savings is less than 20 percent because thereare certain fixed costs-such as basic acreage allotments and administra­tive facilities-that do not vary with the incremental addition of students.)To the extent that the state were to allocate funds on the assumption thatnewly constructed schools could accommodate greater than a 20 percentcapacity increase (such as the Concept 6 calendar, which yields up to a 50percent capacity increase), state savings would be even greater.

Summary and Recommendation

We recommend that the Legislature enact legislation requiringLease-Purchase program funds for new construction to be allocated toschool districts as if the facility would operate on a year-round basis.

Our review indicates that multitrack year-round programs greatlyreduce the demand for school facilities,are educationally sound andprovide a viable alternative to the traditional nine-month calendareducational program. In light of this, and given the state's limitedfinancial resources for constructing new school facilities, our analysisindicates that it is appropriate for the state to promote the use ofyear-round educational programs in lieu of the traditional nine-monthcalendar schools. Further, we can find very little analytical justificationfor the state to continue to provide funds under the Lease-Purchaseprogram for the construction of traditional, rather than year-roundschools.

Accordingly, to maximize the number ofpupils that can be housed withavailable state revenues, we recommend that the Legislature enactlegislation requiring Lease-Purchase program funds for new constructionto be allocated to school districts as if the facility would operate on ayear-round basis. In implementing this recommendation, the Legislaturewould not have to require districts participating in the Lease-Purchaseprogram to operate year-round schools. Rather, the funds would beallocated as if the school were to be operated on a year-round basis, andthe district could retain the option to operate the school on a nine-monthcalendar basis if locally raised funds were used to construct the larger(and more costly) facility needed to house the same number of students.

»:g~

~

Page 39: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Costs of Building Schools VersusYear-Round Incentives

Table 3 presents the detailed analysis of thecosts to state taxpayers of accommodating stu­dents through the construction of new¥ state­funded schools (financed over a 20-year pe­riod), versus providing year-round school in­centivesundertheSB327programalone(thatis,not including the additional $25 per pupil in­centives provided through the SB 813 program).The table presents this analysis for three hypo­thetical school districts, with widely varyingland costs: (1) $50,000 per acre, (2) $250,000 per

Appendices

APPENDIX D

Costs of Building a New School Compared to Costs of ProvidingYear-Round Incentive Payments Under the S8 327 Program

ill our publication¥ Analysis ofthe 1987-88 Budget acre¥ and (3) $1.5 million per acre.Bill¥ we presented a detailed analysis of the This analysis reflects (l)prindpal and interestfiscal effects of 5B 327. In that analysis¥ we costs of school facilities aid bonds¥ (2) localcompared the costs to state taxpayers of accom- property tax revenue losses associated withmodating students through the construction of removing the site of the new school from thenew¥ state-funded schools (financed over a 20- property tax rolt and (3) the value of the facilityyear period)¥ to those of providing year-round at the end of the 20-year period. In order toschool incentives under the SB 327 program allow for appropriate comparisons of the valuealone (thatis¥providingonly the $125 per-pupil of money over the 20-year time span¥ both theincentive). Using this same methodology¥ we school facility costs and the costs of incentivehave updated the earlier analysis for this re- payments were expressed in present discountedport. value terms. (A upresent discounted valueu

Our analysis indicates that¥ for the majority of expresses future costs in terms of their equiva­school districts participating in the SB 327 pro- lent value at the present¥ by taking into accountgram¥ the level of incentive payment provided the interest rate at which funds may be bor­in the annual Budget Act gives roughly 100 rowed.)percent of the state's gross cost avoidance to any In constructing this table, we have made theschool district attaining at least the 15 percent following, additional assumptions:target" level of excess capacity accommodated • 23,000 pupils attend year-round schoolsthrough year-round operations. The only pos- in the hypothetical districts, and thesesible exception to this general conclusion may schools are accommodating the targetoccur for school districts that have extraordi-narily high land costs (such as Los Angeles level of 15 percent excess capacity.Unified). In such cases, the $125 ucapu may • Constructing a new school to accommo-serve to limit the amount of incentive payment¥ date the 3,000 uexcessu pupils costs $25.5such that the state shares less than 100percentof million ($8,500 per pupil).its gross cost avoidance. • The value of the facility depreciates 2

percent annually over a 20-year period,and the value of the land appreciates 5percent annually over this same period.

• Construction costs increase by 5 percentannually.

• State school construction bonds are soldat a 7 percent interest rate.

Table 3 shows that-for districts not affectedby the $125 (inflation-adjusted) "capu in per­pupil funding-the SB 327 year-round incen­tive program provides school districts withroughly 100 percent of the state's "savingsU

from not acquiring a site and building a school.

Page 37

Page 40: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Appendices

Costs of Building a New School Compared to Costs ofProviding SB 327 Year-Round Incentive PaymentsFor Hypothetical School Districts

(dollars in thousands)

Land Cost of $50,000/Acre

Taxpayer Cost of Taxpayer Cost ofSchool Facility" Year·Round Incentives

1 $161.09 $3,705 $3,4912 157.00 3,611 3,1763 152.91 3,517 2,8874 148.83 3,423 2,6225 144.76 3,329 2,3806 140.69 3,236 2,1597 136.63 3,142 1,9568 132.57 3,049 1,7729 128.52 2,956 1,603

10 124.47 2,863 1,44811 120.43 2.770 1,30812 116.40 2,677 1,17913 112.37 2,584 1,06214 108.34 2,492 95615 104.33 2,400 85916 100.32 2,307 77017 96.31 2,215 69018 92.32 2,123 61719 88.33 2,032 55120 84.35 1,940 490---

$56,372 $31,976LESS Value of:

Facility $17,024 $4,300Land 7,960 2,010

NET TOTAL COST $31,388 $25,665

Cost of Incentives as a Percentage of Facility Cost

Land Cost of $250,000/Acre

$48,283

$1.,4111,3831,3551,3291,3021,2761,2511,2261,2021,1781,1551,1321,1101,0881.0661,0451,0241.004

984965

$23,487

$23,487

91.5%

Taxpayer Cost of Taxpayer Cost ofSchool Facility" Year·Round Incenllves

1 $228.91 $5,265 $4,9612 223.10 5,131 4,5133 217.30 4,998 4,1024 211.50 4,865 3,7265 205.71 4,731 3,3826 199.93 4,598 3,0687 194.16 4,466 2,7808 188.39 4,333 2,5179 182.63 4,201 2,277

10 176.88 4,068 2,05811 171.14 3,936 1,85812 165.41 3,804 1,67613 159.68 3,673 1,51014 153.96 3,541 1,35815 148.26 3,410 1,22016 142.56 3,279 1,09517 136.87 3,148 98018 131.19 3,017 87719 125.52 2,887 78220 119.86 2,757 697---

$80,108 $45,439LESS Value of:

Facility $17,024 $4,300Land 39.799 10,052

NET TOTAL COST $23,284 $31,087

Cost of Incentives as a Percentage of Facility Cost

Page 38

$2,0752,1792.2882.4022,5222,6482,7812,9203,0663,2193,3803,5493,7263,9134,1084,3144,5294,7564,9945.243

$68,612

$68.612

$2.0051,9651,9261,8881,8511,8141,7781,7431,7081.6741,6411,6091.5771,5461,5151,4851.4561,4271.3981,371

$33,376

$33,376

107.4%

Page 41: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Appendices

Table 3 Continued

Land Cost of $1.5 MiJllon/Acre

Taxpayer Cost of Taxpayer Cost ofSchool FacilitY" Year·Round Incentives

1 $652.83 $15,015 $14,1492 636.25 14,634 12,8703 619.70 14,253 11,6994 603.17 13,873 10,6275 586.66 13,493 9,6466 570.17 13,114 8,7497 553.71 12,735 7,9298 537.26 12,357 7,1799 520.84 11,979 6,495

10 504.44 11,602 5,87011 488.06 11,225 5,30012 471.71 10,849 4,77913 455.38 10,474 4,30514 439.08 10,099 3,87315 422.80 9,724 3,48016 406.55 9,351 3,12217 390.33 8,978 2,79618 374.13 8,605 2,50019 357.96 8,233 2,23120 341.82 7,862 1,987

$228,456 $129,585

LESS Value of:Facility $17,024 $4,300

Land 238,797 60,313

NET TOTAL COST ($27,365) $64,972

Cost of Incentives as a Percentage of Facility Cost

$128.09134.49141.22148.28155.69163.47171.65180.23189.24198.70208.64219.07230.03241.53253.60266.28279.60293.58308.26323.67

$2,9463,0933,2483,4103,5813,7603,9484,1454,3534,5704,7995,0395,2915,5555,8336,1256,4316,7527,0907,444

$97,412

$97,412

$2,8462,7902,7352,6812,6272,5752,5242,4742,4252,3772,3302,2842,2392,1942,1512,1082,0662,0261,9851,946

$47,385

$47,385

72.9%

a Assumes: (1) a per-pupil construction cost of $8,500; (2) a facility depreciation rate of 2 percent, and a land appreciation rate of 5 percent;(3) a 7 percent interest rate; (4) 23,000 pupils attending eligible year-round schools where 15 percent excess capacity is accommodated;and (5) a 5 percent annual increase In construction costs.

b Present discounted value at 7 percent.

tive program provides school districts withroughly 100 percent of the state's "savings"from not acquiring a site and building a school.

Specifically, the table shows that, for a schooldistrict with land costs of $50,000 per acre, thestate's taxpayers would pay a total of $48.3million in SB 327 incentive payments, over the20-year period that a facility is typically fi­nanced, for a facility that would have cost ap­proximately $56.4 million (in principal andinterest payments on bonds) to acquire a siteand construct. The table further shows that, if

.we subtract out the value of the site and facilityat the end of this period and express costs interms of their present discounted value, thestate would pay $23.5 million in incentive pay­ments to avoid $25.7 million in costs to providea new facility. Thus, the incentive payments (inpresent discounted value terms) would totalabout 92 percent of the state's net cost of acquir-

ing a site and building a school (again in pres­ent discounted value terms).

The table also shows that, for a school districtwith land costs of $250,000 per acre, the presentdiscounted value of incentive payments overthe 20-year period would equal about 107 per­cent of what it would have cost the state toacquire a site and build a school-after allow­ing for the value of these assets at the end of theperiod.

Finally, the table shows that, for a schooldistrict with extraordinarily high land costs of$1.5 million per acre (such as Los Angeles Uni­fied School District), the present discountedvalue of incentive payments over the 20-yearperiod would equal only 73 percent of the state'scost avoidance. This is because the $125 "cap"acts to limit the amount to which the·districtwould otherwise be entitled under the SB 327program. (Although not shown in the table,

Page 39

Page 42: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Appendices

inclusion of the additional $25 per pupil incen­tive payment provided under the SB 813 pro­gram would raise the present discounted valueover the 20-year period of the combined level ofincentive payments to 83 percent of the state'scost avoidance.)

Even in school districts with high land costs(such as Los Angeles Unified), however, thestate still may realize no net savings. This isbecause:.

• The SB 327 incentive payment formulaoverpays school districts for land costsrelative to the actual costs which wouldhave been incurred under the state build­ing program. Specifically, the formulapays districts for land costs in cases wherethe State School Building Lease-Purchaseprogram would not have bought thedistrict a school site (for example, wherea district already owns a site that it ac-

Page 40

quired with its own funds) and (2) basedon the assumption that the state wouldhave built several unrealistically smallschools, rather than on the state's actualpractice of aggregating the total numberof excess pupils into groups of sufficientsize to justify the construction of a largerschool (or schools).

• As currently designed, both the SB 327and the SB 813 programs may functionas a subsidy for a district while waitinginline for new construction funds, ratherthan as an alternative to new construction.To the extent that a district receives boththe incentive payments and a new facil­ity, the state clear!y realizes no savings atall.

Page 43: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Appendices

Appendix E

Economic Analysis: Practical Method for Determining the OptimalLevel of Incentive Payment

Chart 9

Relationship Between Supply ofExcess Pupils and Optimal Level ofIncentive Payment

1 In economic terms, "elasticity" refers to the responsive­ness of "quantity" (number of pupils attending year-roundschools) to a change in "price" (the level of incentive

. payment). Specifically, elasticity is defined as (1) thepercentage change in the number of pupils on year­round schedules, divided by (2) the percentage changein the level of per-pupil incentive payment. The closerthis quotient is to zero, the more "inelastic" is the supplycurve.

p

Number of ExcessPupils Accommodatedin Year-Round Schools

Supply of Excess Pupils,Accommodated inYear-Round Schools

J.

Incentive Payment perExcess Pupil ($)

J

In Chart 9, the supply curve slopes upward tothe right, reflecting a basic assumption under­lying the offering of incentive payments: thatschool districts will respond to such paymentsby increasing the numbers of pupils on year­round schedules, and that (other things beingequal), a higher level of incentive payment willlead to greater increases. In this particularexample, the curve also crosses the horizontal

This appendix presents a more detailed eco­nomic analysis to support the conclusions that,if the state pays all districts the same percentageof gross cost avoidance:

• The more inelastic! the supply curve ofpupils in year-round schools, the loweris the optimal level of incentive pay­ment, and

• In the case of relatively inelastic supply(elasticity < 1), the optimal level of in­centive payment is no greater than one­half the per-pupil cost of acquiring landand building a new facility.Chart 9 illustrates a hypothetical "sup­

ply curve" relating the number of pupils inexcess of nine-month capacity that are accom­modated through year-round operations (hori­zontal axis) to the level of annual per-pupilincentive payment offered by the state (verticalaxis). Itis important to note that the vertical axisshows the amount of incentive payment ex­pressed as an amount per excess pupil accom­modated through year-round operations (incontrast to the SB 327 program, which providessuch payments based on the total number ofpupils accommodated in year-round schools).

The reasonfor displaying incentivepaymentsin this manner is to make the analysis consistentwith that used in describing the state's costavoidance. Specifically, because only thosepupils in excess of existing schools' capacitieswould otherwise need to be accommodatedthrough acquiring land and building newschools, the per-pupil cost avoidance from nothaving to do so also reflects Olily excess pupils.In order to be consistent, therefore, it is neces­sary to describe the costs of incentive paymentsalso in terms of costs per excess pupil accommo­dated through year- round operations.

Page 41

Page 44: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Appendices

axis at a point to the right of the origin, reflect­ing the reasonable assumption that school dis­tricts would continue to maintain some numberof schools on year-round schedules, even if noincentive payment were offered.2

In the chart, the horizontal line labeled Coindicates the annual amount it would cost thestate per pupil to accommodate excess enroll­ments in newfacilities.3 For any particular levelof incentive payment, I, therefore, the net amountof annual costs avoided per pupil equals Cminus I. Multiplying this amount by the tota~number of pupils in year-round operation, P,gives the total, net amountofannual costavoid­ance associated with any particular level ofincentive payment:

Annual net cost avoidance = (Co-I) * P

In terms of the graph, this amount is given bythe area within the rectangle.

The optimal level ofincentive payment, there­fore, is the one which maximizes the size of therectangle shown in the chart. Put another way,the goal is to increase the level of incentivepayment to the point where any further in­crease in the payment level would result inadditional state costs (in terms of incentivepayments) that exceeded the additional state"savings" (in terms of avoided costs of schoolfacilities). In other words, the optimal level ofincentive payment is the point at which themarginal state "savings" just equal the mar­ginal state costs. In the chart, the optimal level

2 The lack of availability of state school facilities aid funds,forexample, coupled with overcrowding in existing facili­ties, would undoubtedly lead some school districts toimplement year-round operatons, whether or not thestate offered incentive funding. Changes in these, or anyimportant factors other than the level of incentive pay­meny offered by the state, cause the supply curve tochange shape-orto shift position. Thus, Increases inthe level of overcrowding statewide would tend to shiftthe supply curve outward. This, in turn, would lead to anincrease in the numberof excess pupils accommodatedthrough year-round schedules, even with no change inthe level of incentive payment offered.

3 As shown elsewhere in this report, the actual amount ofthis per-pupil cost avoidance can vary greatly, depend­ing primarily on local land costs. For the purpose of theexample, the supply curve assumes an aggregation ofschool districts with roughly similar land costs.

Page 42

of incentive payment is 10, and it is at this pointthat the area within the rectangle is greatest.

Chart 10 shows how the optimal level of in­centive payment is affected by variations in theshape of the supply curve. In this chart, theslope of the curve is much steeper, indicatingthat-in this example-changing the level ofincentive payment would have very little effecton the number of excess pupils accommodatedthrough year-round oper~tions. As the chartshows, in this instance the optimal level ofincentive payment is quite low. Intuitively, thisresult makes sense as well: if school districtbehavior is influenced very little by the level ofincentive payment offered, then a very highlevel of incentive payment will primarily resultin windfall gains to districts that would havebeen using year-round operations in any event.

A supply curve such as the one shown inChart la-in which the percentage change in"quantity" for a given percentage change in"price" is quite small-is said to be "inelastic."Generally speaking, the more inelastic the sup­ply curve, the lower is the level of incentivepayment which maximizes the total amount of

Chart 10

Relationship Between Supply of ExcessPupils and Optimal Level of IncentivePayment-Inelastic Supply

Incentive Payment per Supply of Excess PUpilsExcess Pupil ($) Accommodated In

I -,-- ----'-y,CiCear::.:::oR"-'ou=nd=Sch::.:::o=oIS_--,

p

Number of ExcessPupils AccommodatedIn Year-Round Schools

Page 45: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

net costs avoided by the state. Further, for anysupply curve with an elasticity of less than one(that is, a supply curve in which a given per­centage change in the level of incentive pay­ment results in a lesser percentage change in thenumber of pupils on year-round schedules),the optimal level of per-pupil incentive pay­ment cannot exceed one-half the amount of thestate's gross cost avoidance per pupil.

Mathematical Proof ofOptimization Condition

Assume that the state wishes to maximize thetotal amount of net costs avoided through nothaving to construct new facilities:

(Co-I) *P

where P is the number of pupils in excess offacility capacity who are accommodated onyear-round schedules, Co is the per-pupil cost

. of acquiring land and building new facilities toaccommodate such pupils, and I is the level ofyear-round school incentive payment (per pupilin excess capacity) offered by the state.

Assume further that the number of pupils, P, .on year-round schedules is a function of thelevel of incentive payment, I, offered by thestate:

P = f (I)

Using a standard method of mathematicaleconomics} the optimal level of incentive pay­ment, I, may be found through maximizing thefollowing Lagrangean function, Z:

Z= (P)*(Co-I) - L (P - f(l))

This function, in turn, is maximized by solv­ing the following system of simultaneous equa­tions:

dZ/dI = -P - L(df/dl) = adZ/dP = Co - I +L = adZ/dL = f(I) - P = a

4 See, for example, Alpha C. Chiang, Fundamental Meth­ods of Mathematical Economics (2d ed.), (New York:McGraw-Hili), 1974, pp. 376-9.

Appendices

These equations lead to the optimizationcondition:

dP/dI = P/(Co-I)

Or, multiplying both sides by (I!P):

Ep,I = I/(Co-I)

where Ep,I is the elasticity of P with respect to 1.Rearranging terms and solving this equation

for I yields:

I =Co * (Epi (1+Ep,I))

This equation states that the optimal level ofincentive payment, I, is found by multiplyingthe per-pupil cost of a new facility by the ratioof the elasticity of supply to one plus this elas­ticity.

Thus, for a completely inelastic supply curve(E = 0), the optimal level of incentive paymentis:

I =Co * (0/(1 + 0)) =aAnd, for a relatively inelastic supply curve (E

< 1):

I < Co * (1/2)

Finally, as the elasticity of supply approachesinfinity, the optimal level of incentive paymentapproaches Co' In no case, however, does theoptimal level of incentive payment exceed Co'

Thus, if the overall number of pupils on year­round schedules is:

• Completely unresponsive (that is, a givenpercentage increase in the level of pay­ment results in no increase in the numberof pupils in year-round schools), thenthe optimal level of incentive payment iszero.

• Relatively unresponsive (that is, a givenpercentage increase in the level of pay­ment results in a less-than-equivalentincrease in the number of pupils in year­round schools), then the optimal level ofincentive payment is between apercentand 50 percent of the state's gross costavoidance.

Page 43

Page 46: Year-RoundSchool Incentive Progratns...incentiv~paymentprograms. Thissupplemen tal language provided for the membership of the advisory committee to include, at a mini mum, representatives

Appendices

• Relatively responsive (that is, a givenpercentage increase in the level of pay­ment results in a more-than-equivalentincrease in the number of pupils in year­round schools), then the optimal level ofincentive payment is between50 percentand 100 percent of the state's gross costavoidance.

Page 44

• Infinitely responsive (that is, a givenpercentage increase in the level of pay­ment results in an infinite increase in thenumber of pupils in year-round schools),then the optimal level of incentive pay­ment is 100 percent of the state's grosscost avoidance.