28
WHY DOES MIGRATION DECREASE FERTILITY? EVIDENCE FROM THE PHILIPPINES 1 Eric R. JENSEN 2 and Dennis A. AHLBURG 3 April 14, 2003 Prepared for presentation at the 2003 Population Association of America meetings, Minneapolis. 1 The authors thank Lixia Xu and Hanley Chiang for valuable research assistance and Berhanu Abegaz, Phil Martin, Andy Mason, Karen Mason, Stan Panis, Bob Retherford, Fiona Steele and Peter Xenos for useful comments. 2 Department of Economics, College of William and Mary: [email protected] . 3 Industrial Relations Center and Minnesota Population Center, University of Minnesota and Department of Social Statistics, University of Southampton: [email protected] .

WHY DOES MIGRATION DECREASE FERTILITY? EVIDENCE FROM … · why does migration decrease fertility? evidence from the philippines1 ... phil martin, andy mason, karen ... why does migration

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

WHY DOES MIGRATION DECREASE FERTILITY? EVIDENCE FROM THE PHILIPPINES1

Eric R. JENSEN2 and Dennis A. AHLBURG3

April 14, 2003

Prepared for presentation at the 2003 Population Association of America meetings, Minneapolis.

1 The authors thank Lixia Xu and Hanley Chiang for valuable research assistance and Berhanu Abegaz, Phil Martin,

Andy Mason, Karen Mason, Stan Panis, Bob Retherford, Fiona Steele and Peter Xenos for useful comments. 2 Department of Economics, College of William and Mary: [email protected] . 3 Industrial Relations Center and Minnesota Population Center, University of Minnesota and Department of Social

Statistics, University of Southampton: [email protected] .

WHY DOES MIGRATION DECREASE FERTILITY? EVIDENCE FROM THE PHILIPPINES

Abstract: In this paper we use 1993 Philippines data and model the impact of past migration on fertility. Overall fertility declines of women who move and subsequently work actually are slightly larger for moves between equally urbanized areas than for moves to more urbanized areas. If not followed by work for pay, the fertility impact of any type of migration is much smaller. We assume that fertility norms fall with increasing urbanization, and therefore interpret this as evidence in support of the notion that, while women may adapt to lower fertility norms, the impact of changed opportunity costs is a more important determinant of post-migration declines in fertility. Introduction

In many developing countries urban fertility rates are lower than rural fertility rates, there

is significant rural-urban migration, and national fertility rates are falling. From these

demographic observations, the inference is often drawn that rural-urban migration plays a role in

explaining declining fertility rates. The Philippines would seem to fit the stylized demographic

facts, and it is tempting to infer a causal link between migration and declining fertility. As of

1995, the urban total fertility rate (TFR) was 3.5 and the rural TFR was 4.8. In the last two

censuses about seven percent of persons over the age of five years were not resident in the city or

municipality they resided in five years ago (Flieger 1995). Perhaps more importantly for a study

examining fertility, large numbers of women are migrants. In the 1980s one of every five

women in the metropolitan Manila region and one in ten in all other urban areas of the country

was a migrant (Perez 1995). This was consistent with earlier data on Philippine migration,

which showed 20 percent of women in their twenties migrating from Mindanao in the 1960’s

(Hiday 1978). The percentage of the population classified as urban rose from 36 percent in the

mid-1970s to 52 percent in the early 1990s (Flieger 1995), although Flieger shows that some of

this increase in urbanization was due to reclassification of rural areas to urban. The national TFR

fell from 5.5 in the mid-1970s to its 1995 level of 3.9 (World Bank 1995).

The conclusion that migration causes fertility to decrease as urban fertility norms are

adopted by migrants often rests on these sorts of stylized facts, but this ignores more subtle

behavioral patterns. Most notably, in the nationally representative Philippines data we employ in

this paper, more than four out of five moves are to areas no more urbanized than the migrant’s

area of origin. This alone would seem to limit the potential utility of rural-urban migration, and

by extension, of behavioral models such as normative adaptation that rely on such migration, in

accounting for declining fertility rates. With this in mind, we present and examine a model

based on opportunity cost as an alternative to the normative adaptation model. We use the large

number of moves we find in the data between areas that presumably are normatively similar to

identify the impact of competing motives for fertility reduction.

Section 1: Migration and Fertility

A negative association between fertility and migration may exist because of selectivity,

disruption, or adaptation. Selectivity implies that migrants are different from nonmigrants in a

number of ways, both observable (for example, education and age) and nonobservable (for

example, motivation), that lead migrants to have lower fertility than nonmigrants. Selectivity

alone is generally not a causal explanation of the contribution of migration to declining national

fertility, because the lower fertility attributable to being the sort of individuals who elect to

migrate presumably would be observed even if they were somehow prevented from migrating.

Disruption associated with migration can cause lower fertility through the physical

separation of spouses (Goldstein and Tirasawat 1977, Kiningham et al. 1996, Harrison et al.

1986). Disruption also can increase fertility by causing an interruption in the supply of

contraceptives or by the weakening of controls on sexual behavior (Moreno 1994, Bloom and

Mahal 1995, Lansdale and Havan 1996; Ahlburg and Jensen 1997).

Adaptation generally is taken to imply that since average fertility in the destination is

lower than average fertility in the origin, migration may reduce fertility. Typically, in the

demographic literature, an important mechanism is the adoption of prevailing lower-fertility

norms. From an economic perspective, however, adaptation may come from a change in demand

for children generated by changes in prices (woman’s wage, cost of childcare, costs of fertility

regulation) and changes in income (Easterlin and Crimmins 1985; Rosenzweig and Schultz

1985). If many migrants from rural to urban areas subsequently display lower fertility, this is

consistent with either a norms-based explanation, in which fertility declines because migrants

conform to prevailing behaviors at the destination, or an economic explanation, in which fertility

declines as prices rise. In the absence of specific information on post-migration employment, or

where most moves are to more urbanized areas, it is difficult to distinguish empirically between

these alternative explanations. By examining the fertility impact of moves between areas with

similar fertility (and so presumably similar fertility norms), and by distinguishing employed

7 See Lillard and Panis (2000) for a full description of the technique and its implementation.

migrants from other migrants, we hope to distinguish between the norms and opportunity cost

models of fertility adaptation.

Although a large number of empirical studies of developing nations have found evidence

of a negative association between fertility and migration, this finding has not been universal (see

Lee 1989). Lee (1989: 1599) discusses several reasons that have been put forth to explain

differences in the findings among studies: different study designs, different operationalization of

key concepts, and failure to control for selectivity. Selectivity criticisms of analyses of migration

impacts center on the failure to control for the differences that helped make some individuals

migrants in the first place. We will examine this contention in some detail in the next section.

Some studies, notably Goldstein and Goldstein (1983), and Lee and Pol (1993), attempt

to identify separately each of the three explanations (selectivity, disruption, and adaptation) and

find support for each. In two recent studies, Moreno (1994) attempted to identify each of these

effects of migration on contraceptive use in Brazil, and White, Moreno, and Guo (1995) these

effects on fertility in Peru. Contraceptive use is one of several channels through which migration

could affect fertility. Moreno found some association between migration and contraceptive use,

but the relationship was not strong. White, Moreno, and Guo found a negative effect of

childbearing on migration (ever moved) and migration on fertility. They also found some

evidence for selectivity and modest support for disruption and adaptation. A parallel literature

exists on the effect of migration on fertility for migration to developed countries. Much of this

research focuses on the US and has found evidence of temporary disruption followed by rising

fertility (Jasso and Rosenzweig 1990; Blau 1992).Overall, disruption dominated assimilation. In

contrast, recent studies in Europe on completed fertility favor the assimilation model of fertility

adjustment (Schoorl 1990; Mayer and Riphahn 1999). It is not clear why the US and European

experience differs.

Philippine studies have shown ambiguous results with respect to the relationship between

migration and fertility. Hendershot (1971) found strong support for a model of social mobility in

which migrants are selected by their high mobility aspirations, and subsequently, participate

more in the urban culture. Participation creates pressure for migrants to adapt to local family

size norms. Hiday (1978) found a negative association between fertility and social distance from

the rural home community, age at marriage and education; and a positive association between

age at marriage and education, and social distance. She interprets these correlations as

supportive of the social mobility model. Bacal (1988) models the impact of migration on

fertility. She concludes that migration has little impact on fertility; however, Bacal employs as

an explanatory variable contraceptive usage, which presumably is an important mechanism

through which migration would generate fertility decline.

Using Peruvian DHS data, White, Moreno, and Guo (1995) were able to exploit the

longitudinal nature of the retrospective calendar to study separately the impact of migration on

fertility and of fertility on migration. They estimated a hazard model of birth interval duration,

which employed residence and recent migration as predetermined variables. Recent migration

had a large, negative, but statistically insignificant coefficient. Recent migration was included to

examine the impact of disruption on fertility. It is not clear why only recent migration would

influence fertility through adaptation, and so these findings may not bear directly on the question

of adaptation.

Section 2: Model and Methods

Conditional estimation of the impact of migration on fertility

The literature supports, to some extent, the notion that migration causes fertility to fall

through some form of adaptation. We have found no examination of the importance of

competing models of adaptation, notably the sociological normative adjustment model versus the

new home economic model. To examine the question, we develop a simple model that allows us

to assess the importance of the two frameworks. We will compare instances in which norms

may be reasonably presumed constant to others in which the same can be said about opportunity

costs, and examine the relative importance of the two effects. Before proceeding to the model,

we will discuss the notion that migrant selectivity requires that fertility and migration must be

estimated simultaneously.

The first concern we have with a simultaneous model of migration and fertility is

pragmatic. The empirical difficulties in identifying such a model are formidable, requiring either

exclusionary or distributional assumptions to resolve them. Exclusionary restrictions, familiar in

a simultaneous linear equations context, involve specifying structural equations for fertility and

migration that each exclude a sufficient number of predetermined variables to allow for a unique

solution for the estimators. Among the variables typically affecting migration available in a

Demographic and Health Survey (or similar data set), only moving cost can reasonably be

excluded from a structural equation for fertility. Unfortunately, because it is contingent on

distance from origin to destination, this cost is only available for those who actually migrated.

Credible exclusions of fertility determinants from structural migration equations are equally

difficult to find. For example, contraceptive costs (in money and time) theoretically affect

fertility, but probably not migration, directly. However, they often are reflective of social

infrastructure (in fact are often the only such indicator in common surveys such as Demographic

and Health Surveys), and so in practice also are likely determinants of migration. Less clearly

theoretically relevant instruments may exist, but the cautionary tone of the literature on weak

instruments (e.g., Bound, Jaeger and Baker 1995) is instructive here.

Lillard (1993), Lillard, Waite and Brien (1995), Upchurch, Lillard and Panis (2002),

Steele and Curtis (2003) and others have pursued an alternative identification path based on

distributional assumptions7. In Steele and Curtis, for example, time to contraceptive

discontinuation is a function of contraceptive method chosen, and method choice is in turn

modeled as a multinomial probit. In the current context, fertility could be modeled as a waiting

time to conception, with a set of discrete past (or possibly concurrent) migration choices made

that influence waiting time. The duration model is very appealing for fertility, contraceptive

usage and other demographic processes, in that women are assumed to make a choice, and then,

as time passes, to incur the consequences of that choice. The residuals of the various (hazard and

probit) regressions represent unmeasured individual heterogeneity. They are assumed to be

draws from a multivariate normal distribution, and allowed to be correlated. In this way

simultaneity of the underlying processes is captured, without the need for exclusionary

restrictions.

For the problems to which this method has been applied, the payoff is the ability to make

unconditional statements about randomly chosen members of the population. Steele and Curtis

examine the probability that a woman will choose and then use a contraceptive, and Lillard and

coauthors examine the interrelationship of marriage, cohabitation and fertility. This strategy

certainly would be applicable to the migration-fertility nexus, with fertility hazards dependent

upon past, potentially endogenous migration choices. However, the Lillard approach assumes

that unmeasured heterogeneity in hazards is normally distributed. A well known cost of

employing such a parametric strategy is the strong dependence of results on the specific

parameterization of frailty (Heckman and Singer 1984).8 An alternative is to employ

nonparametric frailty specifications. Unfortunately, such methods are extremely computationally

intensive, even for a univariate frailty (Heckman and Singer, 1984; Ahlburg, McCall and Na,

2002).

The issue that either simultaneous equation method is designed to address is the

estimation of structural parameters that allow for the joint impact of multiple processes on

outcomes. This is as familiar problem in many contexts. Consider, for example, the basic

Heckman (1979) model of wages and labor force participation. An exogenous increase in the

demand for labor causes wages of current workers to increase, and also causes wages of new

entrants to increase from zero. An unconditional estimate of the impact on labor supply of the

demand-for-labor shift must consider both of these effects, a fact that forms the basis of the

selectivity bias literature. Estimation of the impact on wages of an increase in demand,

conditional on continuous participation in the labor market, would simply be the regression of

wages on the relevant covariates, and is straightforward to obtain. However, this conditional

estimate often is not of central interest in the labor market example.

8 Heckman and Singer (1984) have a striking example for unemployment duration in which they compare Weibull

models with differing heterogeneity assumptions. For their first model, they assumed normally distributed heterogeneity, and estimated a positive impact of local labor market conditions on unemployment duration. A second was based on log-normal frailty, and predicted a negative estimate of the impact of local conditions on duration. A third model, in which they assumed heterogeneity was gamma distributed, yielded a positive but insignificant effect of labor market conditions on duration. Thus, any empirical conclusion on the effect of local

In contrast, the case for the usefulness of conditional estimators in the present context is

strong. Most discussions of the impact of migration on fertility, whether new home economic

adjustment to wages or normative adaptation, contain an implicit timing element. Migration

occurs, and then fertility outcomes obtain. Moreover, as we have alluded to already, much of the

migration decision is masked for nonmigrants. These individuals made the same sort of

calculations that migrants did, but, because they chose not to migrate, we do not observe much

about them. Therefore, an unconditional estimate of the joint effects of migration and fertility is

empirically difficult to obtain (at best).

A key insight was made on this point by Sjaastad (1962). Sjaastad realized that psychic

costs were a major component of migration, and that psychic costs were by their nature

unobservable. However, all migrants have proved themselves willing to bear this cost, and so

confining his attention to migrants allowed Sjaastad to focus on other, more measurable costs. In

so doing, he showed that key variables of interest could be studied from a comparison of migrant

origins and destinations, conditional on observed migration. We follow this general framework

in obtaining conditional estimates of the impact of various types of migration on the fertility of

migrants. It is important to note that, as a result, we are not able to make statements about joint

fertility-migration choices. We are able to make conditional statements about the impact of past

migration choices on fertility. The models of fertility adaptation with which we are concerned

are explicitly conditioned on past migration, so this is not a significant limitation of our

approach. We cannot test directly for the importance of migrant selectivity in a conditional

framework; however, we control for its potential impact by including only migrants (presumably

labor market conditions on unemployment durations is supportable with the proper choice of heterogeneity.

self-selected) into our analysis. Moreover, a simple Hausman test for the importance of

selectivity can be constructed by comparing the results from the conditional model with an

identical model estimated on the full sample of migrants and nonmigrants; differences in

coefficients between samples is evidence of inconsistency in parameter estimates, and would be

interpreted as evidence of the importance of selectivity in accounting for lower migrant fertility.

Theoretical model

Let ‘child services’, that is, the product of the quantity n and quality q of children, be

represented by C, and all other utility be provided by a composite good Z. The underlying

theoretical model is as follows:

),(),()1( ZnqUZCUU ==

),()3(

),()3(

),()2(

),()2(

,

,

,

,

KKKq

KKKn

qKq

nKn

Ywstb

Ywrta

Xtqqb

Xtnna

=

=

=

=

We assume that number and quality of children in a family are increasing functions of time t and

other commodities X devoted to their production. Furthermore, we assume that times spent on

producing n and q decrease as wages in location K increase. Therefore, migration from K to

some other location L will have a fertility effect contingent upon the wage differential. For wL >

wK, migration will cause time contributions to the production of both number and quality of

children to decrease, all else constant. Purchased inputs are likely to increase as a result of

higher incomes, especially quality-enhancing inputs, potentially concentrating the effect of

increasing wages in decreasing numbers of children. We will interpret results showing post-

migration fertility responsiveness to wages as supportive of a new home economic framework.

If post-migration fertility is lower than pre-migration fertility without evidence of wage change,

we will interpret this finding as supportive of the less specific sociological model of normative

adaptation.

The empirical model of conception hazard, conditional on migration, is as follows:

tMtTttTtPMth k

tij δδ

δ

),|(lim)|()4(0

≥+≤≤=

→.

Adding covariates yields

),,,(),,|()5( πγβ ijkijiij MwxtgMwxth = .

where hij represents the hazard of conception to woman i in interval j, conditional on having

made migration M of type k. The function g(.) represents a generic hazard function, which we

will assume is Weibull13 in our empirical work. Some variables (x) are fixed for women over

multiple conceptions, and others (w) vary between conceptions. Migration also may vary from

conception to conception, and Mijk denotes that migration of type k was the last migration

13 The key results are largely robust to a range of typical parameterizations and most reassuringly, to a

semiparametric Cox specification.

occurring prior to observing woman i in conception interval j. Migration types may include the

direction of migration (to a more, less or equally urbanized destination) as well as the purpose of

migration (migration that is followed by employment in the month of, or month after, arrival).

Coefficient vectors β, γ, π and the Weibull shape parameter are to be estimated. Note that while

we have argued that we do not require the specification of frailty to estimate a simultaneous

model, the likely presence of unobserved heterogeneity in durations implies that our omission of

it will bias our results toward negative duration dependence (Heckman and Singer 1984).

Intuitively, this is because those most ‘frail’ (in our case those most prone to conceive for

unobserved biological, behavioral or other reasons) contribute short intervals, on average, to the

analysis.

Section 3: Data

We use data from the 1993 National Demographic Survey of the Philippines (Philippines

National Statistics Office and Macro International 1994) to examine the relationship between

fertility and female migration. This is a nationally representative survey in the Demographic and

Health Surveys series, in which 15,029 women were interviewed. Ever-married women

completed a monthly retrospective calendar of roughly five and one-half years duration on

several events, including migration and conception, pregnancy and childbirth. Out-of-wedlock

birth carries a stigma in the Philippines, a predominantly Catholic country. We therefore

excluded unmarried women from our analysis. We also excluded sterilized and nulliparous

women. Migrations were recorded over the duration of the calendar, as well as the date and type

of last pre-calendar migration (or date of birth, for never-migrants). Migration origins and

destinations were broadly categorized during coding as urban, ‘town’, or rural. We classified

moves as being to a more urbanized area, a less urbanized area, or an equally urbanized area in

comparison to the origin. While very crude, this gives us some indication of the character of the

move. We also identified work status in the month of, or month after, migration, and flagged

women who were working after migrating. Pregnancy histories allowed us to retrieve the

starting date of intervals that were in progress at the start of the calendar. We used all birth

intervals after the first birth for which the subsequent interval extended into the calendar period,

beginning them at the month of previous birth and extending them until the next calculated

conception date, or until censored by the survey.

Our final sample consisted of 7,123 birth intervals, contributed by 6,605 women. Of

these, 2,156 ended during the interval, and the rest were censored. Only 44% of these birth

intervals were contributed by women who had migrated at some time in their lives, so we

constructed a subsample of conception intervals of ever-migrants. This consisted of 3,381 birth

intervals contributed by 3,149 women, with 858 observed births and 2,523 open intervals. In

either sample, we were able to capture the hierarchical nature of the data, and estimate models

that controlled for clustering at the level of the mother. Table 1 presents brief variable

summaries and descriptive statistics for both samples, including the distribution of origin and

destination states. The wealth variable is a factor score based on ownership of the durable goods

stove, refrigerator, television, bicycle, motorcycle, and automobile. Migration dummies were

constructed by examining reported moves within the calendar, together with responses on

precalendar migrations, and reflect the last migration (if any) prior to the end of the conception

interval. 52.5% of women reported no migration. Most of the remaining women reported one

migrating once, though 86 conception intervals ended following a second migration, and 23

intervals ended after a third, fourth, or fifth migration. The ‘work’ migration variables equal one

if the woman moved and reported working the month of the move or the month after. The first

column reports means and standard deviations for all women in the sample, and the second

column reports only on those women who reported some sort of migration.

(Table 1 here)

Section 4: Empirical Results

In Tables 2 and 3, we present the results of survival regressions of durations of intervals

following a birth and either censored or ending in conception. Table 2 shows conditional results

for ever-migrants. The results are reported in the form of time ratios, with probability values for

testing the hypothesis that the time ratio equals 1 against a two-tailed alternative in parentheses.

So for example, from the first column of results in Table 2, an increase of one year in wife’s age

at marriage is associated with a conception interval 93% as long as a woman married at the mean

age at marriage would be predicted to experience. Education of the woman and her spouse are

important lengtheners of conception intervals. A representative woman who entered or

completed secondary school has a conception interval 129% as long as one who did not enter

secondary school. Having entered or completed tertiary schooling, having a husband who has

entered or completed either level of school all have a comparable lengthening impact. Because

the secondary variable is zero when tertiary equals one, and vice-versa, this implies that any

level of education beyond primary carries roughly the same impact. However, the separate

effects for wife and husband are multiplicative. A couple consisting of a woman with post-

primary education married to a man with post-primary education would be predicted to have

conception intervals 1.57 (1.29 times 1.22) times longer than a couple with primary or lower

education. Wealth, a rough proxy for permanent income, shows shorter conception intervals

with increasing wealth, but the standard deviation of the wealth variable is small enough that this

accounts for relatively little variation in fertility. Controlling for the cost of children or taste

concerns, to the extent they are embodied in the education variables, this may reflect a relatively

pure income effect.

Migration to less urbanized areas is the excluded category in Table 2. Neither of the

migration coefficients in the ‘migration only’ column is significant. However, when

employment at the destination is added in (the ‘migration and work column’), we find a much

longer birth interval for women who moved between comparably urbanized places and went to

work for pay when they arrived. The net impact of migration between similarly urbanized areas

followed by employment, calculated as the product of the ‘same move’ and ‘same work’ time

ratios, is to increase birth intervals to 233% of durations experienced by those who moved to less

urbanized places. The Weibull shape parameter is positive, implying positive duration

dependence. This may be an artifact of very low hazards early in the conception interval, since

all intervals start the month after a preceding birth. Alternatively, this may reflect conscious

spacing of fertility, with low conception hazards early in intervals, but increasing hazards as

intervals lengthen. It probably is not due to age-related changes in fecundity, because age enters

as a polynomial elsewhere.

Table 3 shows results for a sample that includes nonmigrants. Based on a sample more

than twice as large as the migrant sample, standard errors are generally smaller than those

underlying the results of Table 2, yielding minor differences in the level of significance of some

control variables. The migration results are qualitatively similar to those in the previous table,

but there are some differences between samples in the size and statistical significance of the

migration variables’ time ratios. In the full sample, merely moving to an urban area increases

conception intervals by a statistically significant 24%, without accounting for subsequent

employment. The ‘migration and employment: less-urban moves excluded’ column shows the

impact of post-migration employment. The combined impact of migration followed by

employment to an urban area is to double conception intervals, although the point estimate of the

impact of employment is statistically insignificant. Women who work following moves between

similarly urbanized areas experience birth intervals that are slightly more that two and one half

times as long as the comparison group, though in this case the impact of moving alone is not

statistically different from zero. Because the comparison group in the full sample includes not

just those who migrated to less urbanized places (as was the case in the migrant sample), but also

nonmigrants, these two groups have been separated in the final column, with no real impact on

the results.

We note that part of the issue here is the relative rarity of the events that we are

examining. Of all migrants, only 9% were employed in the month of, or month after, arrival

from a similarly urbanized area, and less than 2% were employed immediately after moving

from a less to a more urbanized area. That so few women reported being employed soon after

moving to a more urbanized area is of course partly due to the surprising rarity of moves to more

urban areas, as only 17% of migrants and 8% of the full sample made such moves. It is also due

to our strict definition of employment. Our goal is to tie migration tightly to employment, but to

the extent that job searches take longer than the period we have allowed, a clear cost of our

strategy is to understate the true number of women who migrated and were subsequently

employed. Because those migrants who begin work in the second or later post-arrival month are

classified as non working, our results are conservative estimates of the true impact of post-

migration employment on fertility.

Finally, we test for the importance of migrant selectivity in accounting for the lower

fertility of migrants. The estimators in the migrant-only sample are consistent, but possibly

inefficient, while the estimators based on the full sample, because they ignore migrant

selectivity, potentially are inconsistent. Our Hausman test statistic shows no significant

difference in estimates between the two samples in either comparable specification, although we

note that the impact of migrant selectivity appears more important where information about

employment is ignored. We therefore have no evidence that migrant selectivity is an important

determinant of fertility.

Discussion

Migration can affect fertility through selectivity, adaptation (either by adopting

destination fertility norms or by responding to destination opportunity costs), or disruption. By

far the most important in our data is adaptation to post-migration employment, which can result

in birth intervals more than twice as long as those of nonmigrants. We estimate that the adoption

of lower fertility destination norms and migrant selectivity are somewhat less important, together

accounting for a potential post-migration lengthening of birth intervals of up to 24%. We find

little evidence for the importance of migrant selectivity, implying that much of this 24% may be

due to adoption of low-fertility norms. We estimate that disruption may increase birth intervals

by as much as 15%, but our estimates are too noisy on this front to support anything but

speculation.

Regarding the impact of post-migration employment, we find that women who move

between similarly urbanized places and take paying jobs have birth intervals more than twice as

long as women in the reference category. Employment is important, as the effect of moving to a

similarly urbanized area without working seems if anything to slightly increase fertility. A

typical pattern in the Philippines is for newly married women to leave their village or town and

begin childbearing, so the lack of effect for moves between similarly urbanized places may

reflect this sort of behavior. If so, moves followed by employment are differently motivated than

moves that are not employment related. The former may be moves that are directly tied to

planned employment, and perhaps occur because the migrant has information about jobs at the

destination.

Notably, post-migration employment is not a statistically significant determinant of the

fertility of migrants to more urbanized areas, although our point estimate of the effect is large in

either sample. We estimate that on net, women who migrate between similar areas and then

work for pay have conception intervals 2.3 to 2.5 times longer than the comparison group for the

migrant and full samples. This is slightly larger than the net result of employment following

moves to more urban areas, which is to lengthen birth intervals by 1.8 to 2.0 times. Regarding

these results, with the exception of the point estimate of the impact of more-urban migration in

the full sample, the underlying time ratios are statistically insignificant. The noisy estimation is

due in part to the relatively small number of women who migrate to more urban areas and take

jobs. While slightly under 10% of migrants, either to more urbanized areas or between equally

urbanized areas, subsequently are employed under our restrictive definition of employment,

moves to more urbanized areas were uncommon enough that few women both migrated and took

a job. Besides small-sample imprecision, it also may be the case that there is more uncertainty,

in employment and otherwise, attached to moves to more urbanized places, and this generates a

smaller fertility response.

If fertility norms are comparable in comparably urbanized places, the impact of norms

should be seen in the effect of migration to more urbanized areas, absent employment. We see a

statistically insignificant lengthening, with a point estimate for the time ratio of 1.10, in the

migrant sample. The comparison group is migrants to less urbanized places, which, if norms

operate symmetrically, should highlight the impact of normative change on fertility. The effect

is somewhat larger (1.21 to 1.24) in the full sample, whether the comparison group includes both

migrants to less urbanized places and nonmigrants, or just nonmigrants. In either case, the data

include nonmigrants, and so these estimates also include whatever contribution migrant

selectivity may make to fertility reduction18. While a possible upper bound of the impact of

normative change is a 24% lengthening of birth intervals, some of the observed impact may be

18 Although we find no evidence that migrant selectivity matters, we hestitate to eliminate the possibility based on a

negative result.

due to selectivity, and so the true fertility-depressing effect of adopting urban norms may be

smaller than this upper bound.

Regarding disruption, we note that the estimated time ratio of moves to less urbanized

places is followed by a 15% lengthening of birth intervals, noisily estimated.25 It seems unlikely

that normative pressures to reduce fertility accompany this sort of migration26, and so we offer as

a conjecture the claim that this is an upper bound on disruption effects. Of course, if disruption

is operating to this extent, and moves to equally-urbanized and more-urbanized areas are

otherwise comparable in disruptiveness to moves to less-urbanized areas (in terms of spousal

separation, in particular), this means that, net of disruption, moves between equally urbanized

places would slightly increase fertility in the absence of disruption and employment effects, and

moves to more urbanized areas would have no fertility impact; that is, they have no normative

fertility-decreasing component. The estimates are sufficiently imprecise that we remain agnostic

on the matter of disruption effects.

25 Because we use this group as a control group, and so want a reasonably large number of women in it, we do not

examine the separate impacts of employment for these migrants. 26 If normative effects operate symmetrically, one would predict the normative impact to be fertility increasing for

these moves.

References

Ahlburg, Dennis A., and Eric R. Jensen 1997. Determinants of extramarital sex in the Philippines. Health Transition Review 7 (supplement): 467-480.

Ahlburg, Dennis A, Brian P. McCall and In-gang Na. 2002. “Time to dropout from college: A hazard model with endogenous waiting.” Processed: Industrial Relations Center, University of Minnesota.

Axelson, Roger and Olle Westerlund. 1998. A panel study of migration, self selection and household real income. Journal of Population Economics 11: 113-126.

Bacal, Ro-Ann A. 1988. Immigration and fertility in the Philippines: Hendershot’s selectivity model

revisted. Philippine Population Journal 4: 53-67. Blau, F. D., 1992. “The fertility of immigrant women: Evidence from high-fertility source countries.” In

J. B. George and R. B. Freeman (eds.) Immigration and the Work Force: Economic Consequences for the United States and Source Areas. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, pp. 93-133.

Bloom, David, and Ajay Mahal 1995. The AIDS epidemic and economic policy analysis. Department of

Economics working paper No. 728, Columbia University, New York. Boulier, Brian L. 1984. "Family planning programs and contraceptive availability: Their effect on

contraceptive use and fertility." In Nancy Birdsall (ed) The effects of family planning programs on fertility in the developing world. World Bank Staff working paper No. 677. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Bound, John, David A. Jaeger, and Regina M. Baker. 1995. “Problems with Instrumental Variables

Estimation when the Correlation between the Instrument and the Endogenous Explanatory Variable Is Weak.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 90: 443-450.

Easterlin, Richard A. and Eileen M. Crimmins. 1985. The Fertility Revolution: A Supply-Demand Analysis. Chicago: university of Chicago Press. Flieger, Wilhelm. 1995. The Philippine Population: 1980-1990. Paper prepared for Conference on

Population, Development and Environment, Program on Population, East-West Center, Honolulu, Hawaii.

Goldscheider, Calvin. 1984. "Migration and rural fertility in less developed countries." In W.A. Schutjer

and C. Shannon Stokes (eds), Rural Development and Human Fertility, pp. 34-48. New York: Macmillan.

Goldstein, Alice, Michael White, and Sidney Goldstein. 1997. “Migration, fertility and state policy in

Hubei Province, China,” Demography 34: 481-491. Goldstein, Sidney, and Alice Goldstein. 1983. Migration and fertility in Peninsular Malaysia: An analysis

using life history data. RAND Note N-1860-AID. Santa Monica, CA: RAND Corporation.

Goldstein, Sidney, and P. Tirasawat. 1977. The fertility of migrants to urban places in Thailand. Honolulu: East-West Population Institute.

Harrison, R. F., R. R. O'Moore, and A. M. O'Moore. 1986. Stress and fertility: some modalities of

investigation and treatment in couples with unexplained infertility in Dublin. International Journal of Fertility 31: 153-159.

Heckman, James J. 1979. “Sample selection bias as a specification error.” Econometrica 47: 153-161. Heckman, James J. and Singer, Burton. 1984. Econometric duration analysis. Journal of Econometrics

24:63-132. Hendershot, G. E. 1971. Cityward migration and urban fertility in the Philippines. Philippine

Sociological Review 19: 183-91. Hiday, Virginia A. 1978. “Migration, urbanization, and fertility in the Philippines”. International

Migration Review 12: 370-385. Jasso, G. and M. R. Rosenzweig. 1990. “The immigrant’s legacy: Investing in the next generation.” In G.

Jasso and M. R. Rosenzweig (eds.) The New Chosen People: Immigrants in the United States. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 382-410.

Kiningham, R. B., B. S. Apgar, and T. L Schwenk. Evaluation of amenorrhea. American Family

Physician 53: 1185-1194. Lansdale, Nancy and Susan M. Havan. 1996. “Migration and premarital childbearing among Puerto Rican women,”Demography 33: 429-442. Lee, Bun Song, and Louis G. Pol. 1993. "The influence of rural-urban migration on migrants' fertility in

Korea, Mexico and Cameroon," Population Research and Policy Review 12: 3-26. Lee, Kye Sik. 1989. "Migration, income and fertility in Malaysia: A simultaneous equations model with

limited dependent variables," Applied Economics 21: 1589-1610. Lillard, Lee A. 1993. “Simultaneous equations for hazards”. Journal of Econometrics 56: 189-217. Lillard, Lee A., Michael J. Brien and Linda Waite. 1995. Premarital cohabitation and subsequent marital

dissolution: A matter of self-selection?” Demography 32: 437-57. Lillard, Lee A. and Constantijn W. A. Panis. 2000. aML User’s Guide and Reference Manual,

release 1.0. Los Angeles: EconWare. Mayer, Jochen and Regina T. Riphahn. 1999. “Fertility assimilation of immigrants: Evidence from count data models.” Discussion paper No. 52. IZA, Bonn., Germany. Moreno, Lorenzo. 1994. "Residential mobility and contraceptive use in northeastern Brazil." DHS

working papers No. 9. Calverton, Maryland: Macro International.

Perez, Aurora E. 1995. "Women, migration and development in the Philippines," paper commissioned by the National Committee on the Role of Filipino Women. Manila, The Philippines.

Philippines National Statistics Office and Macro International. 1994. National Demographic Survey

1993. Manila and Calverton, MD: National Statistical Office and Macro International. Ribe, Helena, and T. Paul Schultz. 1980. Migrant and native fertility in Columbia in 1973: Are migrants

selected according to their reproductive preferences?. Center Discussion paper No. 355. New Haven, CT: Economic Growth Center, Yale University.

Rosenzweig, Mark and T. Paul Schultz. 1985. “The demand for and supply of births: Fertility and its life

cycle consequences,” American Economic Review. 75: 992-1015. Schoorl, J.J. 1990. “Fertility adaptation of Turkish and Moroccan women,” International Migration

Review 28: 477-495. Sjaastad, Larry A. 1962. “The costs and returns of human migration.” Journal of Political Economy

70: Supplement, 80-93. Steele, Fiona and Siận Curtis. 2003. “Appropriate methods for analyzing the effect of method choice on

contraceptive discontinuation.” Demography 40: 1-22. Todaro, Michael P. 1969. A model of labor migration and urban unemployment in less developed

countries. American Economic Review 59(1):138-48. Upchurch, Dawn M., Lee A. Lillard and Constantijn W. A. Panis. 2002. “Nonmarital childbearing:

Influences of education, marriage, and fertility”. Demography 39: 311-330. White, Michael, Lorenzo Moreno, and Shenyang Guo. 1995. "The interrelationship of fertility and

geographic mobility in Peru: A hazard model analysis", International Migration Review 19:492-515.

World Bank. 1995. World Tables 1995. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

Table 1 Descriptive Statistics

Variable

Full Sample Migrants Only

Wife’s age at conception 34.01 (8.04)

35.02 (7.67)

Wife’s age at marriage 20.31 (4.36)

20.36 (4.31)

Wife secondary (=1 if entered secondary level of school)

0.32 (0.46)

0.32 (0.47)

Wife tertiary (=1 if entered tertiary level of school)

0.19 (0.40)

0.22 (0.41)

Husband secondary (=1 if entered secondary level of school)

0.31 (0.46)

0.33 (0.47)

Husband tertiary (=1 if entered tertiary level of school)

0.19 (0.39)

0.21 (0.41)

Wealth (factor score for a set of durable goods; mean value of 0)

0.09 (0.79)

-0.01 (0.83)

More urban move (=1 if last move was from less to more urbanized area)

0.08 (0.27)

0.17 (0.38)

Same move (=1 if last move was between comparably urbanized places)

0.31 (0.46)

0.65 (0.47)

Less urban move (=1 if last move was from more to less urbanized area)

0.08 (0.28)

0.18 (0.38)

More urban work (=1 if last move was from less to more urbanized area, work followed)

0.01 (0.08)

0.01 (0.11)

Same work (=1 if last move was between comparably urbanized places, work followed)

0.02 (0.14)

0.04 (0.20)

Sample size 7123 3381

Table 2 Survival Regression Results, Migrants

Variable

Migration Only Migration and Work

Wife’s age at conception 1.02 (0.57)

1.01 (0.33)

Wife’s age at conception squared 1.00 (0.00)

1.00 (0.00)

Wife’s age at marriage 0.93 (0.00)

0.92 (0.00)

Wife secondary 1.29 (0.00)

1.28 (0.00)

Wife tertiary 1.26 (0.04)

1.22 (0.07)

Husband secondary 1.22 (0.02)

1.23 (0.01)

Husband tertiary 1.40 (0.01)

0.41 (0.01)

Wealth 0.80 (0.00)

0.80 (0.00)

More urban move 1.10 (0.41)

1.07 (0.57)

Same move 0.89 (0.20)

0.85 (0.07)

More urban work 1.68 (0.19)

Same work 2.74 (0.00)

Weibull shape parameter 1.12

(0.02) 1.12

(0.03)

Notes to Table: Table entries represent time ratios associated with unit changes in the associated variables. Values in parentheses under time ratios are p values for a test of no effect (time ratio equals one) versus a two-tailed alternatives. Underlying hazards are Weibull, estimated using Stata in a model accounting for clustering at the level of the mother. The value in parentheses under the shape parameter is its estimated standard error.

Table 3

Survival Regression Results, Full Sample

Migration and Employment Variable

Migration

Only Less urban

moves excluded

Less urban moves

included Wife’s age at conception 1.01

(0.57) 1.01

(0.44) 1.01

(0.35) Wife’s age at conception squared 1.00

(0.00) 1.00

(0.00) 1.00

(0.00) Wife’s age at marriage 0.93

(0.00) 0.92

(0.00) 0.92

(0.00) Wife secondary (=1 if entered secondary level of school)

1.25 (0.00)

1.25 (0.00)

1.24 (0.00)

Wife tertiary (=1 if entered tertiary level of school)

1.21 (0.01)

1.20 (0.01)

1.20 (0.01)

Husband secondary (=1 if entered secondary level of school)

1.21 (0.00)

1.21 (0.00)

1.21 (0.00)

Husband tertiary (=1 if entered tertiary level of school)

1.37 (0.00)

1.38 (0.00)

1.38 (0.00)

Wealth (factor score for a set of durable goods; mean value of 0)

0.81 (0.00)

0.81 (0.00)

0.81 (0.00)

More urban move (=1 if last move was from less to more urbanized area)

1.24 (0.02)

1.21 (0.03)

1.23 (0.02)

Same move (=1 if last move was between comparably urbanized places)

1.00 (0.09)

0.96 (0.41)

0.98 (0.64)

Less urban move (=1 if last move was from more to less urbanized area)

1.15 (0.08)

More urban work (=1 if last move was from less to more urbanized area, work followed)

1.66 (0.18)

1.67 (0.18)

Same work (=1 if last move was between comparably urbanized places, work followed)

2.68 (0.00)

2.69 (0.00)

Weibull shape parameter 1.18

(0.02) 1.18

(0.02) 1.18

(0.02) Hausman test for consistency of estimators vs. migrant sample (p-value)

17.55 (0.07)

16.66 (0.16)

Notes to Table: Table entries represent time ratios associated with unit changes in the associated variables. Values in parentheses under time ratios are p values for a test of no effect (time ratio equals one) versus a two-tailed alternatives. Underlying hazards are Weibull, estimated using Stata in a model accounting for clustering at the level of the mother. The value in parentheses under the shape parameter is its estimated standard error.