Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    1/15

    Ajay Shah's blog

    Wednesday, October 02, 2013

    Who's afraid of a big current account deficit?

    A big CAD is a bad thing -- much like a big fiscal deficit.

    A country is always betteroff with a smallorzero CAD orideally

    a surplus.

    The CAD is a drag on growth.

    The large CAD is a profound drag on India's outlook.

    Ifwe managed to reduce the CAD, things would getbetter.

    Statements like this are rife. They are wrong.

    The CAD is three things, all of which are identical. It is the gap betweenrevenues from selling goods and services versus the payments made for

    buying goods and services. This has to be exactly matched by the capital

    inflow into the country. This is exactly equal to the gap between

    investment and savings. These three relationships are accounting

    identities.

    If there was no capital account, then the proceeds from selling goods andservices would have to exactly match the payments for goods and

    services, in every minute. Every small mismatch between the two would

    generate extreme currency f luctuations (large enough to incite a current

    account response).

    The capital account is what smooths these things out. Let us imagine the

    currency market for one minute in which someone is buying $1 billion in

    order to import something. In that very same minute, it is very unlikely that

    there will be a double coincidence of wants, in the form of an exporter

    who wishes to sell $1 billion. What fills the breach is the capital account.Some speculator comes in and supplies that $1 billion in the hope of

    scoring a short-term speculative prof it. The real economy demands

    liquidity in the currency market and f inance supplies this, through the

    capital account.

    What is the CAD?

    What if there was no capital account?

    Search

    Search This

    Blog

    Myhomepage

    My twitterfeed

    How to usethis blog

    My guestbook

    Links

    Enter your

    email address:

    Subscribe me!

    An email

    subscription

    service:

    An RSS feed:

    Implicationsof thePensions

    Act

    In 1998, theMinistry ofSocialJustice andEmpowerment setup`ProjectOASIS', ledbySurendraDave, toengage indeepthinkingabout p...

    RBIstatement

    Posts of note

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    2/15

    The CAD is exactly equal to the gap between savings and investment. A

    CAD of zero is tantamount to only investing what we have saved. In

    general, this is a bad idea. If the country is all set to invest 35% of GDP,

    and savings are only 30% of GDP, it is a goodthing if capital flows of 5%

    of GDP show up, through which investment exceeds savings.

    Should you be unhappy that investment is bigger than domestic savings

    by 5 per cent of GDP? If we insisted that the CAD should be 0 (i.e. we

    had no capital account) then investment would have to be lowerand

    savings would be higher (which in turn implies reduced consumption).

    This would give reduced GDP growth.

    Financial autarky implies that we live within our means. With savings of

    30% of GDP, investment is forced to 30% of GDP under autarky.

    Opening up to the world makes it possible for a country to import orexport capital.

    If a country has good prospects but low savings, running a CAD is a way

    to f ront-load the investment, and service the foreign capital through a

    stream of dividends, interest payments and debt repayments into the

    future. If a country has poor prospects, it is better off sending capital to

    good uses overseas, instead of investing it domestically. For these

    gains, we have to have an open capital account and run large and

    variable CADs.

    (There are also gains from risk sharing from large gross capital flows,

    even if the CAD is 0, but that's a separate topic of discussion).

    In 1991, FERA (1973) was in force. Capital account transactions by

    private parties had been criminalised. The only mechanism that

    generated flows on the capital account was the government. The entireCAD had to be f inanced by government borrowing. When the government

    lost creditworthiness in the eyes of the world, we had a funding crisis on

    the capital account.

    On a day to day basis, imports required dollars which came from the

    government. The Ministry of Finance monitored daily inflows and

    outflows of dollars, and controlled who could access foreign exchange.

    When GOI lost credit-worthiness in the eyes of overseas lenders, this

    was a collapse in the flow of dollars. If you wanted to import penicillin,

    you needed to get dollars, and RBI had none. That's where it came to

    crunch: when an importer is told that he cannot import as there are no

    dollars.

    Nothing remotely like this can happen in the present environment. With

    Should we bemoan the large Indian CAD?

    A big CAD got us into trouble in 1991. Won't that

    happen again?

    failed toreduceuncertainty

    Today RBIsaid theywill: -reduce themarginalstanding

    facility(MSF) rateby 75 basispoints from10.25 percent to 9.5per centwith ...

    Who'safraid of abig current

    accountdeficit?

    A big CADis a badthing --much like abig fiscaldeficit. Acountry isalwaysbetter offwith a smallor zeroCAD orideally asurpl...

    What valuedoes auniversityadd?

    In judgingwhat a

    universitydoes to astudent, akeyproblemlies indistinguishingdifferencesin rawmaterial vs.differences

    in trainin...

    11thConferenceof theMacro/Fina

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    3/15

    capital account liberalisation, many channels have opened. There is FII

    investment in equity and debt, there is FDI, there is ECB, and so on. The

    money moving in these channels dwarfs the borrowing by the

    government. India is now well connected into financial globalisation. All

    these channels won't choke.

    Suppose there is some big mess abroad and all fixed income funds stop

    buying Indian bonds. Under these circumstances, capital inflow will comethrough the other channels. The more we open up to a diverse array of

    investors into a diverse array of asset classes, the safer the environment

    becomes, the lowerthe exchange rate volatility becomes.

    We require a capital inflow, on average, of Rs.20 billion per day. That's

    the gap, on the currency market, which has to be filled. If foreign capital

    does not come in, there is a supply-demand mismatch on the currencymarket. This gives a currency depreciation.

    Ex-post, supply always equals demand. On the market, this demand will

    be met. Every day, the CAD of the day willequalthe capital inflow of the

    day. The only question is: At what price?

    When bad news comes out in India, foreign capital becomes more

    circumspect. They require a more attractive exchange rate at which to get

    in. Or, to say it differently, suppose INR/USD is at Rs.65 to the dollar.

    Suppose bad news come out. The inflow of Rs.20 billion is not

    forthcoming. The market has a gap. The rupee starts falling. At Rs.70 to

    the dollar, some foreign investors think `Hmm, maybe at this price, it's a

    good deal, and I should get in'.

    How far does the depreciation go? Minute by minute, the rupee moves

    to elicitthe netcapital inflow (oroutflow) required to clearthe currency

    market. In response to bad news, the INR drops till a speculator feels that

    it might be a good idea to come into India, buy a 91 day treasury bill, and

    hope that the rupee will do well in a few minutes or few days. That's how

    the current account deficit always gets financed under a floating exchange

    rate.

    Rupee depreciation makes Indian assets more attractive. It would be

    nice if foreign capital found Indian assets attractive for other reasons. But

    when all else fails, rupee depreciation is what gets the job done.

    Sharp spikes of the rupee are fertile ground for currency speculators. The

    more currency speculators that we have, who are operating on the rupee

    market, the smaller is the INR movement associated with an event.

    Imagine an INR depreciation of 5% in one day. A currency speculator

    Why won't all channels choke all at once?

    What kinds of foreign investors respond the most to

    rupee depreciation?

    nce Group

    All thematerialsare up onthewebsite.

    RaghuramRajan's day

    1 statement

    Everyoneshould readit .

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    4/15

    believes this is over done and wishes to come in. What does he do? He

    sells dollars, buys INR, and invests in short-dated government bonds.

    This would add up to a pure play on INR. Currency speculators are not

    comfortable holding Nifty in India. They want a pure exposure to INR.

    Hence, the best way to obtain a deep and liquid currency market, where

    shocks will lead to small exchange rate fluctuations, is to remove capital

    controls on the rupee denominated debt market.

    Sudden stops are ultimately about asymmetric information in the hands

    of foreign investors. If India has a deep engagement with financial

    globalisation, then the informational asymmetry will be removed.

    Our policy goal should be to have thousands of global financial firms who

    are running business activities connected with India, who have large scale

    organisational and human capital that is devoted to understanding India.

    This deep engagement will deter problems such as home bias, sudden

    stops, etc.

    The Indian capital controls are damaging this deep engagement. As an

    example, repeated stop-go policies f rustrate the development of teams

    inside global financial firms that have deep knowledge about India. When

    these teams know less about India, there is a greaterlikelihood ofencountering the pathologies of international finance.

    When India does silly things like trying to ` crush the speculators' through

    various means fair and foul, this hinders a mature engagement with

    financial globalisation. When global capital feels that India operates on

    stable rules of the game and has mature policy makers, the resources

    committed for building organisational capital connected with India will be

    greater.

    In order to avoid international finance pathologies such as sudden stops,our engagement with financial globalisation should be a deep

    engagement. While this issue becomes particularly salient when the CAD

    is large, but there is no short term solution. Over the years, we have to

    chip away at building a deep engagement with financial globalisation at all

    times, so as to reduce the risk when there is a large CAD.

    This is like a rules versus discretion problem. When discretion is used at

    a time of a large CAD, it contaminates credibility at all times. A mature

    approach to public policy involves establishing capable institutions that

    implement stable rules of the game and not tactical dogfights.

    A big CAD increases the damage caused by a sudden

    stop in capital inflows. What should the country do to

    forestall this?

    What is the role of MOF or RBI in ensuring adequate

    capital comes into the country to match the CAD?

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    5/15

    On a day to day basis -- nothing. It's a purely market process. The market

    does it. There are no gray men who look at the CAD and figure out how

    to finance it and then undertake actions through which it gets f inanced.

    The financing of the CAD is purely a market process.

    The role for MOF and RBI is to get out of the way by removing capital

    controls, so as to reduce the magnitude of INR depreciation required

    when a certain negative event takes place.

    A large CAD is dangerous when there is a managed exchange rate.

    Under a managed exchange rate, there is a propensity to borrow in

    foreign currency and leave it unhedged. These borrowers (whether

    corporations or governments) get into big trouble when there is a large

    exchange rate depreciation.

    The central bank is much more likely to fail on exchange rate

    management when there is a large CAD.

    The witches' brew that adds up to trouble is a central bank that believes

    there should be exchange rate policy + borrowers who believe the central

    bank will pursue exchange rate policy + a large CAD.

    While India has a de facto floating exchange rate, RBI has not yet

    stopped talking about dreams of exchange rate management. We are

    relatively safe because borrowers don't believe RBI can do much about

    the exchange rate. Hence, there is no moral hazard and a large CADposes no threat.

    With a large CAD, India is beholden to foreign capital inflows. If foreign

    investors are displeased, we get a big rupee depreciation. This generates

    accountability.

    When India enacts capital controls, orthe Food Security Bill, we get arupee depreciation. This irritates policy makers, who feel that mirrors

    should reflect a little before throwing back images.

    Nobody likes accountability. Hence, people in positions of power do not

    like a large CAD.

    In a mature market economy, a key channel of accountability for the

    government is the bond market. When the government does bad things,

    their cost of financing goes up, and this directly hits the ability of

    politicians to spend on their pet projects. In India, the bond market hasbeen muzzled by setting up a system of financial repression. The job of

    intimidating the authorities is then left to Nifty and the rupee. The voice of

    the latter is amplified when there is a large CAD.

    Does this work differently for other countries?

    Why is a large CAD seen as a big problem?

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    6/15

    at 9:22 AM

    Labels: capital controls, currency regime, GDP growth, policy process

    If you look at the world from the viewpoint of the people who run the

    place, there is a desire to muzzle Nifty and the rupee (particularly when

    the latter is speaking loudly thanks to a large CAD). From that viewpoint,

    a large CAD is a bad thing. Because the establishment has a

    disproportionate impact upon the climate of ideas, we have started

    accepting their claim, that a large CAD is a bad thing.

    If you care about India's future, a large CAD is a good thing, as itenhances accountability. By this logic, other things being equal, the Indian

    policy process generates superior outcomes when there is a large CAD.

    If we had a small CAD, Mr. Mukherjee might have been finance minister

    today.

    Financial globalisation is work in progress. Capital controls and source-

    based taxation hinder international capital mobility. Even if there are norestrictions, it is hard for investors in country i to properly utilise the

    investment opportunities in country j, for reasons of ` information

    distance'. All too often, there is home bias (people in a country holding

    vastly greater domestic assets than is optimal from the viewpoint of

    diversification). There are international f inance pathologies such as

    capital surges, sudden stops, investments by foreigners in wrong assets,

    and so on. These are the hurdles along the road.

    In the destination state, there is no good reason why the investment

    opportunities in country i at time t should match the savings of country i attime t. We should judge the success of the project of financial integration

    by the extent to which we are able to achieve large and variable current

    accounts.

    In addition, in a place like India, a big CAD generates greater

    accountability on the part of the government. One would predict better

    economic policy when there is a large CAD.

    The widespread mistrust of a large CAD may reflect two things. Some

    don't see the extent to which we're not in 1991 anymore: there is much

    more of a deep engagement with financial globalisation, and the

    exchange rate floats enough that the borrowers are not unhedged. And,

    establishment figures resent accountability.

    I am grateful to Josh Felman for illuminating discussions on these issues.

    Conclusion

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    7/15

    Replies

    Reply

    15 comments:

    RMB Wednesday, October 2, 2013 at 10:14:00 AM GMT+5:30

    When rupee depreciates, indian assets earning rupees won't change

    profitability.

    If asset price goes down in dollar terms, earnings also go down in dollar

    terms.

    So how does rupee depreciation make assets cheaper for outsiders?

    Are we confusing currency calls with asset valuations?

    Or I have a vacuum somewhere in the way I have understood it?

    Reply

    Ajay Shah Wednesday, October 2, 2013 at 4:19:00 PM

    GMT+5:30

    A sharp rupee depreciation offers a possibility that INR has

    overshot. If so, a speculator who comes in to buy INR will get agood return in a short time when the rupee comes back closer to

    fair value.

    Walking is controlled falling.

    Anonymous Wednesday, October 2, 2013 at 1:01:00 PM GMT+5:30

    Quite remarkable. Please try and get this published somewhere, such as

    American Economic Review. This is the stuff that makes our academics in

    our great public institutions such great economists, universally lauded for

    their insights worldwide. I enjoyed it immensely. Such wisdom is rare.

    Thanks.

    Reply

    Anonymous Thursday, October 3, 2013 at 10:40:00 AM GMT+5:30

    You are distorting one of the basic economic identities to suit your

    arguments. I challenge if this can go beyond mere a "blog" entry and stand

    up to scrutiny of any decent journal. But then the purpose here is to

    influence/fool the general public.

    If a country is running current account deficit then that's needs to financed

    by capital account surplus which is nothing but "selling" of domestic assets

    either held abroad or inside the country's boarders.

    If the capital was freely flowing, as you make it to be, without any

    "ownership" or any "nationality" attached to it then we would not be

    discussing any current and capital account in the first place.

    The trick employed by apologists of foreign ownership of domestic assets

    like you (in the form of "CAD is such a good thing") is you completelycamouflage the ownership angle as if whether the Indian assets are

    owned by Indians or foreigners doesn't matter at all.

    But the cake will take the "accountability" argument. It's like arguing that if

    I own a house I will not be accountable for it's maintenance but if I take a

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    8/15

    Replies

    Reply

    house on rent I will always be accountable to the owner of the house and

    that's such a good thing!!

    Reply

    Anonymous Thursday, October 3, 2013 at 1:59:00 PM

    GMT+5:30

    FDI isn't just about 'owning' domestic assets, but investment into

    creating new domestic assets (which might not even be physical

    assets, but IP, etc) which make a return for the foreign owner

    and the local economy. So, it depends on other rules and policies

    to do with FDI. That being said, I would prioritize domestic

    investment over FDI. Today, domestic investors are also not

    investing due to various problems and are going abroad, so those

    problems should be prioritized.

    We often tend towards xenophobia because of our colonial past.

    But, if one looks at many MNCs, they tend to have better

    governance and technology and quality standards than local

    business and we get to import technology and know-how which is

    pretty standard in the rest of the world. So, FDI has a lot of

    benefits as long as your concerns are reflected by adequate

    protections on the investment made into domestic assets.

    Furthermore, foreign capital can demand greater accountability

    from the government as opposed to domestic capital (which is

    boxed in and has no choice). When the government is the

    bottleneck as it is today, that is a good thing.

    Anonymous Thursday, October 3, 2013 at 1:11:00 PM GMT+5:30

    Economic well being is not equal to overall economic growth. There is the

    question of inflation and how individuals are impacted by a set of policy

    options. Depreciation of Ruppee (with fall in capital flows) increases

    inflation and disadvantages certain people e.g., who consume a lot of

    petroleum products, kids wanting to go overseas for education, people

    whose incomes are fixed, etc.

    Q for the author -- 5 people are earning Rs 20 each (Rs 100). As a result

    of a policy, 4 people start earning Rs 15 each and one starts earning 50

    (total of 110). Overall impact is an increase in income of 110. However, 4

    are negatively impacted and 1 benefits. Should the policy be implemented

    or not ?

    Another question for the author -- if CAD was to increase to say 100% of

    the economy, no capital would flow. Question for you what is a

    comfortable level of CAD ?

    Actually the reverse happens in Petro states -- Countries export oil and

    use the earnings to fund expenditure. When prices for oil fall -- people's

    income come and down and puts a huge pressure on the economy. This

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    9/15

    Replies

    happenned to esrtwhile Soviet Union. We are opposite, relying on capital

    flows -- whenever it falls (we are squeezed).

    Reply

    Anonymous Thursday, October 3, 2013 at 2:08:00 PM

    GMT+5:30

    Two things:

    The rupee depreciation is not a root cause as you make it out to

    be. For rupee to appreciate we need to fix the root causes of low

    productivity and low competitiveness. It makes no sense to ask

    for a stronger rupee without asking to fix the root causes which

    need long term commitment and a major change in the way we

    function.

    Secondly, its not clear how many people benefit and how many

    don't. Rupee depreciation helps exporters and pretty much every

    company benefits by being more competitive in comparison to

    other countries. IT industry benefits a great deal. All of that leads

    to more jobs in the export services and manufacturing sector.

    Although, its not as much as one would hope for because of other

    hurdles put up by poor government policies. But, because of the

    examples I gave, I am not sure whether we have a net benefit or

    loss.

    Furthermore, it is a self-corrective system. A lower currencywould promote more investment into exports which eventually

    would increase productivity and lead to currency appreciation.

    That is, if we implement the right policies to increase productivity

    which is the only way to have a strong economy and currency, at

    the end of the day.

    Anonymous Thursday, October 3, 2013 at 5:20:00 PM

    GMT+5:30

    Agree that the economy needs to be more efficient and

    competitive and that the value of Ruppee is an outcome of the

    relative strenth of the Indian economy and not a cause.

    There are arguments for both a higher and lower Ruppee. As you

    point out lower Ruppee makes products and services competitive

    but reduces the buying power of the citizens. There are tradeoffs

    involved. Point is not high or low Ruppee but stability in the value

    and not the high level of volatility as has been witnessed. Volatility

    makes planning very difficult.

    Capital flows can slow down for a number of reasons --both

    internal and external. High level of CAD makes the Ruppee

    vulernable to high level of volatility. What happens if the capital

    flows remain low for an extended period of time, Ruppee goes to

    100 and petrol sells for 115 Ruppees ?

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    10/15

    Self correcting mechanism is good in theory, but can be a

    challenge in situations of high volatility e.g., during the GFC,

    should the banks have been allowed to fail and go out of business

    ?

    Point being made was that the article argues the issue from one

    point of view and overlooks the trade offs involved in having a high

    CAD.

    Anonymous Friday, October 4, 2013 at 12:39:00 AM GMT+5:30

    Well, much of the problem accumulates over times of low

    volatility, when the problems are ignored for long periods. The

    actual periods of volatility are actually simply resolution of long-

    standing issues. The period of volatility was great from the point

    of view of long term fundamentals as billion of dollars worth of

    projects got cleared, many measures were taken which were

    long pending - like clearance for foreign universities and FDI forother sectors. If we get the kind of urgency we saw from the govt

    in pushing through policies during this volatility, I'm prepared to

    have rupee go to a 100 and petrol at 115. No problem,

    whatsoever. :) Just imagine how much will get done by the govt if

    that happens!!

    Anonymous Friday, October 4, 2013 at 2:40:00 PM GMT+5:30

    Proof of the pudding lies in eating it. So a suggestion -- you could

    argue to the Government to have policies that will lead to a higerlevel of CAD, as this will drive down Ruppee, spur growth and

    make Indian goods and services more competitive. Make the

    suggestion and find out whether you premise is implementable or

    academic ?

    Anonymous Friday, October 4, 2013 at 2:49:00 PM GMT+5:30

    One more comment -- policy announcements and project

    clearances are not equal to inflows and investment in projects

    e.g., no FDI in retailing till date.

    Anonymous Friday, October 4, 2013 at 10:23:00 PM GMT+5:30

    Why would I argue THAT to the government? And, why put the

    cart before the horse? Even if I had to argue anything to the

    government I would argue in favor of long term policies. The CAD

    is irrelevant, its a secondary measure.

    Yep, very little FDI in retail. Which means that the policies need

    further work. Precisely why one gets the sense that more

    pressure is needed from the market. By the way, I have no desirefor FDI. It would be nicer if it were domestic investment but it

    seems domestic business is not willing to play ball with the govt

    given its arbitrariness. And, similarly for FDI. No wonder there is

    no FDI in retail. That's exactly the point! Another example is the

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    11/15

    Reply

    Replies

    Reply

    policy for foreign universities - in 2008 the goal was a grand

    opening up, and it has been opened up in small steps, liberalizing

    marginally every time because whatever has been done hasn't

    been enough. 5 years and counting... eventually, we will get to

    the right policy for investment into higher education and similarly

    for retail - domestic or FDI or whatever....

    Anonymous Thursday, October 3, 2013 at 6:50:00 PM GMT+5:30

    The statement " CAD is exactly equal to investments minus savings" is

    quite misleading and partially incorrect. I believe budget deficit is the

    primary mechanism to support the gap between investment and savings.

    CAD is only a secondary source of support , only to the extent of the need

    for importing capital assets (machineries, intellectual properties etc).

    I think you should have a follow up blog to clarify your thought process.

    Reply

    Ajay Shah Thursday, October 3, 2013 at 7:13:00 PM

    GMT+5:30

    No.

    RG Thursday, October 3, 2013 at 8:03:00 PM GMT+5:30

    Ajay, you crack me up.

    Anyway, I think the comment above it on internal vs external

    drivers of capital flows is the more interesting one.

    In general your piece does a good service, and I'll likely give it to

    students to read. But it appears premised on the standard idea

    that capital responds mostly to domestic conditions. There's a lot

    more room for legitimate argument when K flows are externally

    driven (e.g. Helene Rey's recent piece

    http://www.voxeu.org/article/dilemma-not-trilemma-global-

    financial-cycle-and-monetary-policy-independence).

    In India's case, this isn't to say the rupee didn't deserve to get

    hammered. Rather, the external forces of the QE-driven K inflows

    probably prevented it from getting a much-deserved hammering

    earlier. So India suffered because of not getting the accountability

    signal earlier and having to tolerate Mr. Mukherjee longer than it

    should have.

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    12/15

    Older PostHome

    Subscribe to: Post Comments (Atom)

    Enter your comment...

    Comment a s: Google Accou

    Publish Preview

    Please note: Comments are moderated; I will delete comments that misbehave.

    The rules are as follows. Only civilised conversation is permitted on this blog.

    Criticising me is perfectly okay; uncivilised language is not. I delete any

    comment which is spam, has personal attacks against anyone, or uses foul

    language.

    Create a Link

    Links to this post

    announcements (61)author: Harsh Vardhan (5)

    author: Jeetendra (5)

    author: Percy Mistry (3)

    author: Pratik Datta (6)

    author: Shubho Roy (12)

    author: Suyash Rai (6)

    author: Viral Shah (9)

    banking (63)

    Bombay (25)

    bond market (48)

    business cycle (69)

    capital controls (141)

    China (59)

    clearing corporation (11)

    commodity futures (24)

    competition (45)

    consumer protection (3)credit market (36)

    currency regime (138)

    democracy (72)

    Labels

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    13/15

    derivatives (100)

    diamonds (4)

    education (20)

    education (elementary) (19)

    education (higher) (36)

    empirical finance (13)

    energy (20)entrepreneurship (16)

    environment (8)

    equity (51)

    ethics (36)

    farmer suicide (6)

    finance (innovation) (31)

    financial firms (59)

    financial market liquidity (53)

    financial sector policy (225)

    GDP growth (79)

    geography (12)

    global macro (46)

    global warming (4)

    health policy (6)

    hedge funds (7)

    history (26)

    IMF (9)incentives (17)

    inflation (79)

    informal sector (22)

    information technology (79)

    infrastructure (36)

    international financial centre (63)

    international relations (27)

    labour market (26)

    legal system (100)

    market failure (1)

    media (14)

    migration (9)

    monetary policy (198)

    mores (5)

    national security (1)

    offtopic (6)

    outbound FDI (9)payments (12)

    pension reforms (48)

    police (3)

    policy process (82)

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    14/15

    politics (34)

    privatisation (14)

    prudential regulation (1)

    PSU banks (20)

    public administration (7)

    public goods (34)

    publicfinance (expenditure) (51)publicfinance (tax (GST)) (16)

    publicfinance (tax) (33)

    publicfinance.deficit (45)

    publicfinance.expenditure.transfers (23)

    real estate (17)

    redistribution (22)

    regulatory governance (2)

    reserves (17)

    resolution (2)

    risk management (20)

    securities regulation (77)

    socialism (61)

    statistical system (50)

    success (6)

    systemic risk (3)

    telecom (24)

    the firm (49)trade (39)

    urban reforms (17)

    volatility (12)

    World Bank (7)

    world of ideas (51)

    2013 (85)

    October (1)

    Who's afraid of a big current account deficit?

    September (9)

    August (12)

    July (10)

    June (18)

    May (7)

    April (13)

    March (6)

    February (3)

    January (6)

    Blog Archive

  • 7/27/2019 Who's Afraid of a Big Current Account Deficit

    15/15

    2012 (102)

    2011 (112)

    2010 (131)

    2009 (204)

    2008 (302)

    2007 (247)

    2006 (159)

    2005 (8)

    12,633

    Views this week

    Simple template. Powered by Blogger.