Whether Free or Fair Trade, Corporate Mercantlism Rules the Day - Peter W .B . Phillips

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/13/2019 Whether Free or Fair Trade, Corporate Mercantlism Rules the Day - Peter W .B . Phillips

    1/4

    ANALYSIS

    Whether Free or Fair Trade, 

    Corporate Mercantilism Rules the Day

    The world has gone “ free trade”

    mad. There appears to be almost

    universal public agreement these

    days that the world must reduce the barriers to trade in order to return to

    economic growth and prosperity. It is

    hard to pick up the business section

    of a newspaper or to scan the covers

    of news magazines without seeing

    mention of ongoing or proposed inter-national trade negotiations, either

    among Canada, Mexico and the

    United States, in the European Com-

    munity or at the General Agreement

    on Tariffs and Trade (GATT).

    Despite apparent unanimity about

    the goal o f free trade, managed trade

    is the rule. Indeed, mercantilism

    thrives and has adapted to the eco-

    nomic world of the 1990s. Corpora-

    tions have replaced nations as the

    driving force behind efforts to manage

    the international trade system.

    Corporate mercantilism propelled by

    the multinational enterprise is the

     prevailing model.

    ‘‘Slaves o f defun ct ec onom ists’ ’

    Mercantilism is a term that historically

    was applied to the trading practices

    of European countries during the

    sixteenth, seventeenth, and eigh-

    teenth centuries. Trade surpluseswere sought through the use of

    tariffs and nontariff barriers (NTBs)

    to discourage imports, and by

    subsidies to encourage exports.

    The popularity of mercantilism has

    ebbed and flowed over the centuries

    and appeared to be in total retreat

    with the multilateral negotiation of

    the GATT following the Second

    World War. Although mercantilist

     practices multiplied in the 1980s ascountries used NTBs and state

    subsidies, the start of the GATT

    round in 1986 appeared to signal that

    the days of these practices were

    numbered.But neither the logic nor evidence

    conclusively supports this view.

    Free trade negotiations are always

     based on the assertion tha t “ we arenot rich enough to ignore free

    trade.” Economic theory suggests

    that the free flow of goods across

    international boundaries leads to the

    maximum wellbeing of all nations.

    This, however, is only true in a perfect

    world. In reality, the organization

    and operation of a world economy

    leads to perverse results. The theory

    assumes that trade is between

    countries and companies; in practice,

    international trade is increasingly between subsidiaries and affiliates

    of multinational corporations. Further-

    more, history does not support the

    hypothesis that tradeopening efforts

    will be conducted for the public

    good. In fact, trade negotiations are

     based on national interests of countries,

    which are the private interests thatare made effective by domestic

     bargains between the government

    and industry. “ Free trade” is there-

    fore a poor basis for negotiatinginternational trade rules.

    John Maynard Keynes, the British

    economist who pioneered a new

    approach to manage the macroeco-

    nomy, wrote in 1936 that “ practical

    men, who believe themselves to be

    quite exempt from any intellectual

    influences, are usually the slaves of

    some defunct economist.” In this

    case, the ‘ ‘free trad ers’ ’ (academics,

    and business and government leaders)

    are the slaves of eighteenth century

    classical economists and their ‘ ‘aca-demic scribblings” on the theory of

    gains from trade.

    Convent iona l t h ink ing andstrategizing around international

    trade negotiations flows directly from

    the seminal work prepared in the

    eighteenth century by David Ricardo,one of England’s first economic theo-rists. His theory of the gains from

    trade, elaborated in chapter seven of

    The Principles ofPolitical Economy 

    and Taxation  published in 1817,

    hypothesizes that each country

    could ben efit if it specializes in the

     production of those produc ts for

    which it has comparative advantage.

    He argued that national comparative

    advantage depends on the endow-

    ments of the factors of production—land, labour, and c apital. In short,

    countries endowed relatively highly

    with fertile land could better their

    standard of living by producing

    fieldbased crops and trading those

    crops for manufactures, while those

    endowed with ample labour should

    concentrate in the production of

    laborintensive goods (such as tex-

    tiles). Countries could then better

    their standard of living by trading.

    Ricardo went on to show in hisnowfamous example of Portugal

    and England that in that period

    Portugal should concentrate on

     producing wine and England cloth,

    even though Portugal had a clear

    absolute advantage in both products.

    By specializing and trading for the

     products they did not produce , both

    Portugal and England could increase

    their wellbeing.

     January-February 1992/Challenge

  • 8/13/2019 Whether Free or Fair Trade, Corporate Mercantlism Rules the Day - Peter W .B . Phillips

    2/4

    Classical paradigm now invalid 

    This classical paradigm assumes

     perfect competition. Perfect competi-

    tion assumes a homogeneous product,

    free entry to and exit from the sector,

    constant (or at least largely equal)

    returns to scale, full information,

    rational actors, and a large number

    of firms. Furthermore, the theory

    assumes trade is largely between

    different firms in different countries.

    Provided these conditions hold, it

    would be irrational for countries to

    erect trade barriers in the form of

    tariffs or nontariff measures.

    The logical consequence of the

    theory is that states should unilater-

    ally remove their trade barriers

     because they would be unquestion-

    ably better off than otherwise. In

    reality, governments are extremely

    slow to negotiate changes to their

    trade and tariff rules. And it is

    companies which now lead the

    charge to reduce barriers to trade in

    services and flows of intellectual and

    financial capital.

    Concerns with free trade are valid;

    the problem with the theory of gains

    from trade lies in its assumptions. In

    short, the classical economic paradigm

    is no longer valid, if it ever was.

    During the 1970s and 1980s, the

    world economy was transformed by the

    expansion of trade and the operation

    of large transnational corporations.

    The traded share of national GDP

    continued to rise in almost all

    national economies while many

    transnational corporations now

    often produce components o f single

     products in different countries and

    only assemble them in the destina-

    tion market— in socalled “ screw

    driver’ ’ plants. This production system

    depends critically on the continua-

    tion of trade and financial flows.

    By 1972, much intraindustry trade

    was within single firms—automo-

    tive f irms, commodity trading

    houses (see  International Regimes, 

    S. Krasner, editor, Cornell Univer-

    sity Press, 1983, p. 261). Since that

    time, corporate concentration has

    increased, particularly vertical

    integra tion in production of specific

     p roducts su ch as au to m obil es,

    electronics equipment, and food

    from the extraction of the primary

     products up through the processing

    and marketing of the final product.DeAnne Julius, Chief Economist at

    Shell International Petroleum in

    London, England, recalculating trade

     balances for the United States and

    Japan for 1986 on an ownership basis

    and comparing them with conven-

    tional estimates, shows how mislead-

    ing conventional measures can be

    (The Economist,  December 22, 1990,

     p. 45). Whereas national accounts

    show that the United States appears

    to have gross trade of only about $600

     billion, in reality the global trade by

    U.S.owned companies totaled $2.7

    trillion. In contrast, Japanese owned

    companies accounted for $450 billion

    international trade, rather than the

    $260 billion indicated by the national

    accounts. Companies are more

    dependen t on international trade than

    countries and, as such, now are the

    driving force for “ freer” trade.

    The assumption o f perfect compe-

    tition that underlies the theory of

    gains from trade is no longer valid.

    As such, the search for “ free” trade

     between states is not a sound basis

    for international trade negotiations.

    Most trade is not between unrelated

    firms but now is more the result of

    an administrative decision by a

    corporate manager based on the

    maximization of aftertax profits in

    its subsidiaries (regardless of the costs

    or benefits to any single subsidiary

    in one country). Therefore, there is

    no reason to suspect that trade liber-

    alization will yield greater gains

    from trade. The more likely outcom e

    of reduced tariffs and elimination of

    trade barriers will be further expan-

    sion of multinational corporations

    (MNCs) and greater concentration

    of economic wealth and power.

    Because trade now is within

    companies rather than between

    countries, comparative advantage

    no longer based on the initial fact

    endowment of land, labor an

    capital. Instead, William Clin

    economist at the Institute of Intern

    tional Economics in Washingto

    argues that for many industrial secto

    “ comparative advantage is madnot given.” (See  Managing Tra

     R e lati ons in th e 1980s: Issu

     In vo lv ed in the GATT Ministeri

     Meeting o f 1982,  S. Rubin and

    Graham, editors, Rowman & Alle

    1984, p. 26.) As production an

    trade become further captive of t

    multinational companies, the oper

    tion of the financial m arkets and th

    underlying economic climate

    separate countries will determin

    the balance sheet of those countrieIftheclimate becomes less welcomin

    MNCs simply shift their productio

    and profits to more accommodatin

    regions and countries, leaving th

    former host countries in a financi

    and economic bind.

     N ew , m uta te d m ercanti li sm

    Business and government unite

    efforts under the free trade bann

    during the 1980s. Now in the 199there is a surfeit of exercises designe

    to lower trade barriers and increas

    the flow of goods and service

     between countries. If one looks car

    fully at the past and current rounds

    the GATT, it is apparent that me

    cantilism has mutated: nation

    mercantilism has been replaced b

    corporate  mercantilism. As the

    expanded operations globally, MNC

    have sought to strengthen the

    co rpo ra te supp ly connec t ion

    abroad—bankers, insurers, tran

     porters and input suppliers.

    For evidence, one need look n

    further than the United States neg

    tiating stance at the current round

    the GATT. The United States ha

    announced that, in addition to low

    tariffs and NTBs and a better disput

    settlement system, it also seeks fr

    trade in services, rigorous rules o

    Challenge!'January-February 1992

  • 8/13/2019 Whether Free or Fair Trade, Corporate Mercantlism Rules the Day - Peter W .B . Phillips

    3/4

    intellectual property rights, and re-

    duction in barriers to capital flows.

    The theory of the gains from trade

    is based on the production and trade of

    goods, with trade flows determined

     by factor endowments. If the United

    States were able to secure liberalized

    trade in services, intellectual property,and capital, it would materially

    undercut the economic basis for

    international trade. The theory of

    gains holds that as the endowment of

    factors of production is equalized

    across all countries, the com parative

    advantages would diminish. Theo-

    retically, then, as this process contin-ued, there would be progressively

    less to gain from international trade.

    But in practice, an examination of

    U.S. objectives from the corporate perspective demonstrates these make

     perfect sense in the context of the

    emerging corporate mercantilism.

    Corporations worldwide have been

    cooperating to develop vertically

    integrated enterprises, where one

    family of related or friendly companies

    controls the entire production, distri-

     bution, marketing and financing system

    for products. In other words, these

    enterp r i ses— whether Japanese

    keiretsu,  the now legally tolerated

    “ corporate alliances” in the UnitedStates, or consortia of European busi-

    nesses supported by the European

    Community—seek to control products

    from the ground to the consumer, and

     beyond to financing and servicing.

    Some Canadian commentators estimate

    that foreignowned companies oper-

    ating in Canada already purchase

    about 80 percent of their business

    services from their parent companies

    or affiliates.

    These corporate enterprises havetaken strategic decisions to become

    involved in influencing trade nego-

    tiations in order to level the barriers

    that inhibit corporate alliances. This

    involvement ranges from lobbying

    government e i ther di rect ly or

    through business associations to the

     provision o f managers or consultants

    to assist governments with the trade

    negotiations or public encourage-

    ment o f support for trade goals. This

    support is widespread throughout

    the business community.

    In short, that is corporate m ercan-

    tilism.

    Corporate agenda may dominate

    From an economic perspective, to

    search for intellectual property

    rights, free the flow of investment

    and open trade in services are not

     justi fied. If the GA TT is forced to

    encompass these issues, the efforts

    to realize the gains from trade byresolving the agricultural trade wars,

    lowering tariffs, and controlling

     NT Bs might be jeopardized.

    Furthermore, the citizens of many

    nation states would lose as national

    economic progress gets overwhelmed bythe corporate mercantilist agenda.

    Many economists agree that in the fast

    moving economic world, the most

    mobile factors of production gain the

    most (or lose the least) from economic

    change. In other words, highly skilled

    labor (mostly firstworld business

    managers and professionals) and

    capital are the big winners of change.

    Currently, companies are partly

    restricted from shuffling their operations between countries by restrictions on

    the movement of labor, capital, and

    services. This effectively spreads the

    gains (and losses) between all factors of

     production. If companies are allowed

    to operate freely in all markets, then

    they will be able to play off one country

    against another. In this situation, if

    countries were to attempt to imple-

    ment progressive (or regressive) social

    or economic development programs,

    companies would be able to movequickly. In short order, the corporate

    agenda would rule,

    GATT should stick to what it was

    designed to do, namely work toward

    realizing the gains from trade.

    Peter W.B. Phillips

    Economist , Regina , Canada

    author of Wheal , Europe, an d the GATT 

    The Grea t  Market  Debate  in Soviet 

    Economics

    Arthornr 

    WVamMouo4

    TheGreatMarketDebateinSovietEconomics

    AnAnthology Anth ony J ones a nd Wi ll iam Mos ko ff ,

    Editors

    ISBN0-873332-868-XHardcover$59.95ISBN0-973322-869-8Paper$19.95

    Propertyreformhasremainedthelasttabooaseconomistsgrapplewiththequestionofequality,efficiency,andthe“bigtradeoff.”Thisanthologysurveysthekeyissuesinthemarketdebate.

    OriginsoftheCrisisintheUSSREssaysonthePolit icalEconomy

    ofaDisintegratingSystem

    Hillel Ticktin

    ISBN0-87332-861-2Hardcover$45.00ISBN0-87332-888-4Paper$19.95

    Forover25yearsTicktinhasarguedthattheSovietsystemcouldneitherevolve norberestructured— itwould disintegrate, atwhichtimetheworkerswouldholdthebalance. Isheontarget?

    LaborandDemocracy

    intheTransitiontoaMarketSystemU.S.andPost-SovietPerspectivesBertram Silverman, Robert Vogt, and  

    Murray Yanowitch,Editors

    ISBN1-56324-037-8Hardcover$59.95ISBN1-56324-038-6Paper$19.95

    ThesepapersfromapathbreakingU.S.-Sovietconferenceonlaborissuesrevealaconsiderablediversityofviewsonquestionswhoseresolutionwillbeessentialtosocialpeaceinthisperiodoftransition.

    e»s

    Labor

    • n d

    De moc ra c y

    in the

    T r a n s i t i o n t o

    a M a r k e t S y s t e m

    TOORDERCALLTOLLFREE1-800-541-6563

    or FAX914-273-2106

    VISA, MASTERCARD and AMERICAN EXPRESS acccplcd 

  • 8/13/2019 Whether Free or Fair Trade, Corporate Mercantlism Rules the Day - Peter W .B . Phillips

    4/4

    Copyrightof Challengeisthepropertyo fM.E.Sharpe Inc..The copyrightinan

    individualarticlemaybe maintainedbytheauthorin certaincases.Contentmaynotbe

    copiedoremailedtomultiplesitesorpostedtoalistservwithoutthecopyrightholder's

    expresswrittenpermission.However, usersmayprint, download,oremaila rticlesfor

    individualuse.