36
WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL DID NOT?* OLIVIER BLANCHARD This essay argues that the history of macroeconomics during the twentieth century can be divided into three epochs. Pre-1940: a period of exploration, during which all the right ingredients were developed. But also a period where confusion reigned, because of the lack of an integrated framework. From 1940 to 1980: a period during which an integrated framework was developed—from the IS-LM to dynamic general equilibrium models. But a construction with an Achilles' heel, too casual a treatment of imperfections, leading to a crisis in the late 1970s. Since 1980: a new period of exploration, focused on the role of imperfections in macroeconomics. Exploration often feels like confusion. But behind it is one of the most productive periods of research in macroeconomics. The editors of the Quarterly Journal of Economics have commissioned a series of essays on the theme: what do we know aboutfieldx that Marshall did not? In the case of macroeconomics, Marshall is not the right reference. But if we replace his name with those of Wicksell and of Fisher, the two dominant figures in the field at the start of the twentieth century, the answer is very clear: we have learned a lot. Indeed, progress in macroeconomics may well be the success story of twentieth century economics. Such a strong statement will come as a surprise to some. On the surface, the history of macroeconomics in the twentieth century appears as a series of battles, revolutions, and counterrevo- lutions,fromthe Keynesian revolution of the 1930s and 1940s, to the battles hetween Monetarists and Keynesians of the 1950s and 1960s, to the Rational Expectations revolution of the 1970s, and the battles hetween New Keynesians and New Classicals of the 1980s. These suggest a field starting anew every twenty years or so, often under the pressure of events, and with little or no common core. But this would he the wrong image. The right one is of a surprisingly steady accumulation of knowledge. The most outrageous claims of revolutionaries make the news, hut are eventually discarded. Some of the others get bastardized and then integrated. The insights hecome part of the core. In this article I * I thank Daron Acemoglu, Ben Bernanke, Ricardo Caballero, Thomas Cool, Peter Diamond, Rudiger Dombusch, Stanley Fischer, Bengt Holmstrom, Lawrence Katz, David Laibson, N. Gregory Mankiw, David Romer, Paul Samuelson, Andrei Shleifer, Robert Solow, Justin Wolfers, and Michael Woodford for useful comments euid discussions. An earlier version was given as the Tinbergen lecture in Amsterdam in October 1999. © 2000 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. The Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, November 2000 1375

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    0

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICSTHAT FISHER AND WICKSELL DID NOT?*

OLIVIER BLANCHARD

This essay argues that the history of macroeconomics during the twentiethcentury can be divided into three epochs. Pre-1940: a period of exploration, duringwhich all the right ingredients were developed. But also a period where confusionreigned, because of the lack of an integrated framework. From 1940 to 1980: aperiod during which an integrated framework was developed—from the IS-LM todynamic general equilibrium models. But a construction with an Achilles' heel, toocasual a treatment of imperfections, leading to a crisis in the late 1970s. Since1980: a new period of exploration, focused on the role of imperfections inmacroeconomics. Exploration often feels like confusion. But behind it is one of themost productive periods of research in macroeconomics.

The editors of the Quarterly Journal of Economics havecommissioned a series of essays on the theme: what do we knowabout field x that Marshall did not? In the case of macroeconomics,Marshall is not the right reference. But if we replace his namewith those of Wicksell and of Fisher, the two dominant figures inthe field at the start of the twentieth century, the answer is veryclear: we have learned a lot. Indeed, progress in macroeconomicsmay well be the success story of twentieth century economics.

Such a strong statement will come as a surprise to some. Onthe surface, the history of macroeconomics in the twentiethcentury appears as a series of battles, revolutions, and counterrevo-lutions, from the Keynesian revolution of the 1930s and 1940s, tothe battles hetween Monetarists and Keynesians of the 1950s and1960s, to the Rational Expectations revolution of the 1970s, andthe battles hetween New Keynesians and New Classicals of the1980s. These suggest a field starting anew every twenty years orso, often under the pressure of events, and with little or nocommon core. But this would he the wrong image. The right one isof a surprisingly steady accumulation of knowledge. The mostoutrageous claims of revolutionaries make the news, hut areeventually discarded. Some of the others get bastardized and thenintegrated. The insights hecome part of the core. In this article I

* I thank Daron Acemoglu, Ben Bernanke, Ricardo Caballero, Thomas Cool,Peter Diamond, Rudiger Dombusch, Stanley Fischer, Bengt Holmstrom, LawrenceKatz, David Laibson, N. Gregory Mankiw, David Romer, Paul Samuelson, AndreiShleifer, Robert Solow, Justin Wolfers, and Michael Woodford for useful commentseuid discussions. An earlier version was given as the Tinbergen lecture inAmsterdam in October 1999.

© 2000 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute ofTechnology.The Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 2000

1375

Page 2: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1376 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

focus on the accumulation of knowledge rather than on therevolutions and counterrevolutions. Admittedly, this makes forworse history of thought, and it surely makes for worse theater.But it is the best way to answer the question in the title. ̂

Let me state the thesis that underlies this essay. I believe thatthe history of macroeconomics during the twentieth century canbe divided into three epochs, the third one currently playing.^

• Pre-1940. A period of exploration, where macroeconomicswas not macroeconomics yet, but monetary theory on oneside and business cycle theory on the other. A period duringwhich all the right ingredients, and quite a few more, weredeveloped. But also a period where confusion reigned,because ofthe lack of an integrated framework.

• From 1940 to 1980. A period of consolidation. A periodduring which an integrated framework was developed—starting with the IS-LM, all the way to dynamic generalequilibrium models—and used to clarify the role of shocksand propagation mechanisms in fluctuations. But a con-struction with an Achilles' heel, namely too casual atreatment of imperfections, leading to a crisis in the late1970s.

• Since 1980. Anew period of exploration, focused on the roleof imperfections in macroeconomics, from the relevance ofnominal wage and price setting, to incompleteness ofmarkets, to asymmetric information, to search and bargain-ing in decentralized markets, to increasing returns inproduction. Exploration often feels like confusion, andconfusion there indeed is. But behind it may be one ofthemost productive periods of research in macroeconomics.

Let me develop these themes in turn.

L PRE-1940: EXPLORATION

To somebody who reads it today, the pre-1940 literature onmacroeconomics feels like an (intellectual) witch's brew: many

1. Anice, largely parallel, review of macroeconomics in the twentieth century,taking the alternative, more historical, approach is given by Woodford [1999].

2. For the purpose of this article, I shall define macroeconomics as t;he study offluctuations, mundane—recessions and expansions—or sustained—sharp reces-sions, long depressions, sustained high unemployment. I shall exclude both thestudy of growth and of the political economy of macroeconomics. Much progresshas been made there as well, but covering these two topics would extend the lengthof this essay to unmanageable proportions.

Page 3: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1377

ingredients, some of them exotic, many insights, hut also a greatdeal of confusion.

The set of issues that would now he called macroeconomicsfell under two largely disconnected headings: Monetary Theoryand Business Cycle Theory.̂

At the center of Monetary Theory was the quantity theory—the theory of how changes in money lead to movements in outputand in prices. The focus was hoth on long-run neutrality and onshort-run nonneutrality. The discussion of the short-run eflFects ofan increase in money on output was not much improved relativeto, say, the earlier treatments hy Hume or hy Thornton. Somestressed the eflfects from money to prices and from prices tooutput: higher money led to higher prices; higher prices "excited"business and led in turn to higher output. Others stressed theeflfects from money to output, and from output to prices: highermoney increased demand and output, and the increase in outputin turn led to an increase in prices over time.

Business Cycle Theory was not a theory at all, hut rather acollection of explanations, each with its own rich dynamics.* Mostexplanations focused on one factor at a time: real factors (weather,technological innovations), or expectations (optimistic or pessimis-tic firms), or money (hanks or the central hank). When favorahle,these factors led firms to invest more, hanks to lend more, untilthings turned around, typically for endogenous reasons, and thehoom turned into a slump. Even when cast as general equilihrium,the arguments, when read today, feel incomplete and partialequilihrium in nature: it is never clear how, and in which markets,output and the interest rate are determined.

In retrospect, one can see the pieces of a macroeconomicmodel slowly falling into place.

At the center was the diflference, emphasized hy Wicksell[1898], hetween the natural rate of interest (the rate of return oncapital) and the money rate of interest (the interest rate onhonds). This would hecome a crucial key in allowing for the

3. The word "macroeconomics" does not appear until the 1940s. According toJSTOR (the electronic database that includes the articles from most majorjournals since their inception), the first use of "macro-economic" in the title of anarticle is by De Wolff in 1941, in "Income elasticity of demand, a micro-economicand a macro-economic interpretation;" the first use of "macroeconomics" in the titleof an article is by Klein [1946] in an article called, fittingly, "Macroeconomics andthe Theory of Rational Behavior."

4. The variety and the complexity of these explanations is refiected inMitchell [1923], or in the textbook of the time. Prosperity and Depression, byHaberler[1937].

Page 4: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1378 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

eventual integration of goods markets (where the natural rate isdetermined), and financial markets (where the money rate isdetermined). It would also prove to be the key in allowing for theeventual integration of monetary theory (where an increase inmoney decreases the money rate relative to the natural rate,triggering higher investment and higher output for some time),and business cycle theory (in which several factors, includingmoney, affect either the natural rate or the money rate, and thusthe difference between the two).

Where the literature remained confused, at least until Keynesand for some time after, was how this difference between the tworates translated into movements in output. Throughout the 1920sand 1930s the focus was increasingly on the role ofthe equality ofsaving and investment, but the semantic squabbles that domi-nated much ofthe debate (the distinctions between "ex ante," and"ex post," "planned" and "realized" saving and investment, thediscussion of whether the equality of saving and investment wasan identity or an equilibrium condition) reflected a deeper confu-sion. It was just not clear how shifts in saving and investmentaffected output.

In that context, the methodological contributions of theGeneral Theory [1936] made a crucial difference.

• Kejmes explicitly thought in terms of three markets (thegoods, the financial, and the labor markets), and of theimplications of equilibrium in each.

• Using the goods market equilibrium condition, he showedhow shifts in saving and in investment led to movements inoutput.

• Using equilibrium conditions in both the goods and thefinancial markets, he then showed how various factorsaffected the natural rate of interest (which he called the"marginal efficiency of capital"), the money rate of interest,and output. An increase in the marginal efficiency ofcapital—coming, say, from more optimistic expectationsabout the future—or a decrease in the money rate—comingfrom expansionary monetary policy—both led to an in-crease in output.

A quote from Pigou's Marshall lectures, Keynes's GeneralTheory: A Retrospective View" [1950], puts it well:^ "Nobody before

5. Pigou's first assessment of The General Theory, in 1936, had been far lesspositive, and for understandable reasons: Keynes was not kind to Pigou in The

Page 5: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS'^ 1379

him, so far as I know, had brought all the relevant factors, real andmonetary at once, together in a single formal scheme, throughwhich their interplay could be coherently investigated."

The stage was then set for the second epoch of macroeconom-ics, a phase of consolidation and enormous progress.

II. 1940-1980: CONSOLIDATION

Macroeconomists often refer to the period from the mid-1940sto the mid-1970s as the golden age of macroeconomics. For a goodreason: progress was fast and visihle.

II.l. Establishing a Basic Framework

The IS-LM formalization hy Hicks [1937] and Hansen maynot have captured exactly what Keynes had in mind. But, hydefining a list of aggregate markets, writing demand and supplyequations for each one, and solving for the general equihhrium, ittransformed what was now hecoming "macroeconomics." It did notdo this alone. Equally impressive in their powerful simplicitywere, among others, the model developed hy Modighani in 1944,with its treatment of the lahor market and the role of nominalwage or price rigidities, or the model developed hy Metzler in1951, with its treatment of expectations, wealth effects, and thegovernment hudget constraint. These contrihutions shared acommon structure: the reduction of the economy to three sets ofmarkets—goods, financial, and lahor—and a focus on the simulta-neous determination of output, the interest rate, and the pricelevel. This systematic, general equilihrium, approach to thecharacterization of macroeconomic equihhrium hecame the stan-dard, and, reading the literature, one is struck hy how muchclearer discussions hecame once this framework had heen put inplace.

This approach was hrought to a new level of rigor in "Money,Interest, and Prices" hy Patinkin [1956]. Patinkin painstakinglyderived demand and supply relations from intertemporal optimiz-ing hehavior hy people and hy firms, characterized the equihh-rium, and, in the process, laid to rest many of the conceptualconfusions that had plagued earlier discussions. It is worth

General Theory. But, by 1950, time had passed, and Pigou clearly felt moregenerous.

Page 6: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1380 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OE ECONOMICS

making a—nonlimitative—list (if only hecause some of theseconfusions have a way of coming hack in new forms).

• "Say's law": False. In the same way as the supply of anyparticular good did not automatically generate its owndemand (the relative price of the good has to he right), thesupply for all goods taken together did not generate its owndemand either. The intertemporal price of goods, the realinterest rate, also had to he right.

• "Walras law": True. As long as each agent took all his or herdecisions under one hudget constraint, then equilihrium inall markets except one implied equilihrium in the remain-ing one.

• The "Classical Dichotomy" hetween the determination ofthe price level on the one hand, and the determination ofrelative prices on the other: False. "Neutrality," the proposi-tion that changes in money were ultimately reflected inproportional changes in the price level, leaving relativeprices unaffected, was true. But this was an equilihriumoutcome, not the result of a dichotomous model structure.

• "Value Theory versus Monetary Theory"—the issue ofwhether standard methods used in value theory could heused to think ahout the role and the effects of money in amonetary economy. The answer was: Yes. One could thinkof real money balances as entering either the indirectutiUty of consumers, or the production function of firms.One could then treat real money balances as one wouldtreat any other good.

• "Loanable Funds or Liquidity Preference"—the issue ofwhether the interest rate was determined in the goodsmarkets (through the equality of saving and investment),or in the financial markets (through the equaUty of thedemand and the supply of money). The answer, made clearhy the general equilihrium structure of the models, was, ingeneral, hoth.

11.2. Back to DynamicsKeynes himself had focused mostly on comparative statics.

Soon after, however, the focus shifted hack to dynamics. Little ifany of the old business cycle literature was used, and most of thework was done from scratch.

Key to these developments was the notion of "temporaryequilibrium," developed hy Hicks in Value and Capital [1939]. The

Page 7: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS'? 1381

approach was to think of the economy as an economy with fewfuture or contingent markets, an economy in which people andfirms therefore had to make decisions based partly on statevariahles—^variables reflecting past decisions—and partly on ex-pectations ofthe future. Once current equilihrium conditions wereimposed, the current equilihrium depended partly on history andpartly on expectations of the future. And given a mechanism forthe formation of expectations, one could trace the evolution oftheequilihrium through time.

Within this framework, the next step was to look more closelyat consumption, investment, and financial decisions, and theirdependence on expectations. This was accomplished, in a series ofextraordinary contrihutions, hy Modigliani and Friedman whoexamined the implications of intertemporal utility maximizationfor consumption and saving, hy Jorgenson and Tohin who exam-ined the implications of value maximization for investment, andhy Tohin and a few others who examined the implications ofexpected utility maximization for financial decisions. These devel-opments would warrant more space, hut they are so well-knownand recognized (in particular, hy many Nohel prizes) that there isno need to do so here.

The natural next step was to introduce rational expectations.The logic for taking that step was clear. If one was to explore theimplications of rational hehavior, it seemed reasonahle to assumethat this extended to the formation of expectations. That step,however, took much longer. It is hard to tell how much ofthe delaywas due to technical prohlems—which indeed were suhstantial—and how much to ohjections to the assumption itself. But this waseventually done, and hy the late 1970s, most of the models hadheen reworked under the assumption of rational expectations.^

With the focus on expectations, a new hattery of small modelsemerged, with more of a focus on intertemporal decisions. Thecentral model was a remake of a model first developed hy Ramseyin 1928, hut now reinterpreted as a temporary equilihrium modelwith infinitely lived individuals facing a static production technol-

6. This is where a more historical approach would emphasize that this wasnot a smooth evolution. . . . At the time, the introduction of rational expectationswas perceived as an attack on the received body of macroeconomics. But, with thebenefit of hindsight, it feels much less like a revolution than like a naturalevolution. (Some ofthe other issues raised by the same economists who introducedrational expectations proved more destructive, and are at the source ofthe crisis Idiscuss below.)

Page 8: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1382 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

ogy.̂ This initial structure was then extended in many directions.^Among them were the following:

• The introduction of costs of adjustment for capital, leadingto a well-defined investment function, and a way of think-ing about the role of the term structure of interest rates inachieving the equality of saving and investment.

• The introduction of money as a medium of exchange, andthe extension of the Baumol-Tobin model of money demandto general equilibrium.

• The introduction of some dimensions of heterogeneity, forexample, allowing for finite lives and extending the overlap-ping-generation model first developed by Samuelson andDiamond.

• The introduction of a leisure/labor choice, in addition to theconsumption/saving decision.

• The extension to an economy open both in goods andfinancial markets.

Initially, these models were solved under perfect foresight, asimplifying but rather unappealing assumption in a world ofuncertainty and changing information. That introducing uncer-tainty was essential was driven home in an article by Hall [1978],who showed that, under certain conditions, optimizing behaviorimplied that consumption should follow a random walk—a resultthat initially came as a shock to those trained to think in terms ofthe life-cycle model. Under the leadership of Lucas and Sargent(for example, Lucas and Stokey [1989], Lucas [1987], and Sargent[1987]), developments in stochastic dynamic programing togetherwith progress in numerical methods and the development of morepowerful computers, were used to characterize behavior underuncertainty. This in turn allowed the exploration of a new andimportant set of issues, the implications of the absence of somefuture or contingent markets in affecting consumption and invest-ment decisions, and, in turn, the macroeconomic equilibrium.

Compared with the first generation of models (the IS-LM,Metzler, and Modigliani models), these models, in either theirperfect foresight or their stochastic versions, were more tightlyspecified, less eclectic. In tbeir initial incarnation, they often

7. Ramsey had thought of his model as purely normative, indicating how acentral planner might want to allocate consumption over time.

8. The basic Ramsey model and many of these extensions form the core oftoday's graduate textbooks. See, for example, Blanchard and Fischer [1989] orObstfeld and Rogoff [1996].

Page 9: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1383

ignored imperfections that many macroeconomists saw as centralto an explanation of macroeconomic fiuctuations. But they pro-vided a hasic set of off-the-shelf structures on which to huild, andindeed, in which to introduce imperfections. Getting ahead of mystory: this is indeed what has happened since the early 1980s, andI shall return to it later.

II.3. From Models to Data

Starting in the 1940s, in macroeconomics as in the rest ofeconomics, research was radically transformed hy the increasingavailahility of data and the development of econometric methods.But another element, specific to macroeconomics, played a centralrole: the coincidence hetween the implications of linear dynamicmodels and the time series representation of economic variahles.

The old husiness cycle literature had heen groping towardnonlinear endogenous cycle models, models where the expansioncreated the conditions for the next recession, the recession theconditions for the next expansion, and so on. As early as 1933,however, Ragnar Frisch had argued that much simpler systems,linear difference systems with shocks, could provide a hetteraccount of aggregate fiuctuations. In an economy descrihed hysuch systems, one could think of fiuctuations as the result of thecomhination of impulses—random shocks constantly huffeting theeconomy—and propagation mechanisms, the dynamic effects ofthese shocks implied hy the linear system. This point wasreinforced hy Samuelson's 1939 analysis ofthe multiplier accelera-tor, which showed how a given shock to spending could generaterich dynamic responses of output. The convenience of the ap-proach, and its easy mapping to the data, quickly led to thedominance of linear models with shocks as the hasic approach tofiuctuations, and alternative nonlinear approaches largely fadedfrom the scene.

These early steps were followed hy the specification andestimation of structural models. Using the approach to identifica-tion developed hy Koopmans and others at the Cowles Commis-sion, individual equations for consumption, investment, andmoney demand were estimated and integrated into larger andlarger macroeconometric models, culminating, on the academicside, in models such as the MPS, developed hy Modigliani andcoauthors in the 1960s and early 1970s.

In the late 1970s the focus shifted, at least on the academicside, to smaller models. The feeling was that the immense effort to

Page 10: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1384 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

construct large structural models had heen overamhitious, thatthe identification conditions used in estimation of individualequations were often duhious, and that the equation-hy-equationconstruction of econometric models did not in any way insure thatthe reduced form of the estimated model fitted the basic character-istics of the data.

This was the motivation behind the return to smaller, moretransparent, structural models, whose limited size had the addi-tional advantage of making them solvable under rational expecta-tions. It was also the motivation behind the development of a newstatistical tool, vector autoregressions or VARs—namely thedirect estimation of the joint stochastic process descrihing thevariables under consideration. VAKs were then used in two ways:to obtain a set of stylized statistical facts that models had tomatch; and to see whether, under a minimal set of identificationrestrictions, the evidence was consistent with the djTiamic effectsof shocks implied by a particular theory or class of theories.

The constant back and forth hetween models and data, andthe increasing availability of macro and micro data, has mademacroeconomics a radically different field from what it was in1940. Samuelson once remarked that one of his disappointmentswas that econometric evidence had led to less convergence than hehad hoped when the first econometric steps were taken (inSnowdon and Vane [1999], p. 323). It is nevertheless true thatprogress has been nothing short of amazing. When Kahn [1931]first tried to get a sense of the value of the marginal propensity toconsume, all he had were a few observations on proxies foraggregate production, imports, and investment. When Modiglianiand Brumberg [1954] tried to assess the empirical fit of thelife-cycle hypothesis, they could use the time series recently puttogether for the National Income Accounts by Kuznets and others,and a few cross sections on income and saving. Today, studies ofconsumption have access to long repeated cross sections, or evenlong panel data sets (see, for example, Deaton [1992]). This allowsnot only for much sharper questions about consumption behavior,but also for a more convincing treatment of identification (throughthe use of "natural experiments," tracing the effects of changes inthe economic environment affecting some hut not all consumers)than was feasible earlier.

So far, the tone of this essay has heen that of a panegyric, thedescription of a triumphal march toward truth and wisdom. Let

Page 11: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1385

me now turn to the prohlem that macroeconomics largely ignored,and which led to a major crisis in the late 1970s.

II.4. The Casual Treatment of ImperfectionsFrom Keynes on, there was wide agreement that some

imperfections played an essential role in fluctuations.^ Nominalrigidities, along the lines suggested hy Keynes, and later formal-ized hy Modigliani and others, played an explicit and central rolein most formalizations. They were crucial to explaining why andhow changes in money and other shifts in the demand for goodsaffected output, at least in the short run.

These nominal rigidities, when comhined with later develop-ments such as rational expectations, proved to have rich smdrelevant implications. For example, in an extension of the Mundell-Fleming model (the version of the IS-LM model for an economyopen in hoth goods and financial markets), Dornhusch [1976]showed that the large swings in exchange rates, which had heenohserved after the adoption of flexihle exchange rates in the early1970s and were typically attrihuted to irrational speculation,could he interpreted instead as the result of arhitrage by specula-tors with rational expectations in an economy with a slowlyadjusting price level. The lesson was more general: nominalrigidities in some markets led to more volatility in others, here inthe foreign exchange market.

But, as the early models were improved in many dimensions,the treatment of imperfections remained surprisingly casual. Themost ohvious example was the treatment of wage adjustment inthe lahor market. In early models, the assumption was typicallythat the nominal wage was fixed, and that the demand for lahorthen determined the outcome. Later on, these assumptions werereplaced hy a Phillips curve specification, linking infiation tounemployment. But there was surprisingly little work on whatexactly lay hehind the Phillips curve, why and how wages were setthis way, and why there was little apparent relation hetween realwages and the level of employment. As a result, most macro

9. A semantic clarification: following tradition, I shall refer to "imperfections"as deviations from the standard perfect competition model. Admittedly, there ismore than just a semantic convention here. Why give such status to such an utterlyunrealistic model? The answer is because most current research is organized interms of what happens when one relaxes one or more assumptions in that model.This may change one day. But, for the tinie being, this approach provides acommon research strategy, and makes for easier communication among macroeco-nomic researchers.

Page 12: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1386 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

models developed in tbe 1960s and 1970s bad a scbizopbrenicfeeling: a careful modeling of consumption, investment, and assetdemand decisions on tbe one band, and an atbeoretical specifica-tion of price and wage setting on tbe otber.

Tbe only systematic tbeoretical attempt to explore tbe impli-cations of nominal rigidities, tbe "fixed price equilibrium" ap-proacb developed in tbe 1970s, turned out to be a dead end. Tbiswas for reasons intrinsic to tbe macroeconomic approacb at tbetime, and so it is wortb looking at tbe episode more closely.

Tbe approacb was based on tbe insigbts of Clower andPatinkin, and a systematic treatment was given by Barro andGrossman [1976]. Tbe strategy was to assume a competitiveeconomy, to allow tbe vector of prices to differ from tbe fiexibleprice equilibrium vector, and tben to characterize tbe determina-tion of output under tbese conditions. Equilibrium in eacb marketwas assumed equal to tbe minimum of supply and demand. Tbecomplexity and tbe ricbness of tbe analysis came from tbe facttbat, if people or firms were on tbe sbort side in one market, tbeytben modified tbeir supply and demand functions in otber markets.

Tbe results were tantalizing. Tbe analysis sbowed tbat, if tbeprice vector was sucb as to yield a state of generalized excesssupply (in botb goods and labor markets), tbe economy bebavedvery mucb as in tbe Ke3Tiesian model. Firms, constrained in tbegoods market, employed only as many workers as tbey needed: tbedemand for labor was determined by output, and was independentof tbe real wage. Workers, constrained in tbe labor market, tookemployment and labor income as given in taking consumptiondecisions. Tbe economy exhibited a demand multiplier: increasesin demand led to more production, more income, more demand,and so on.

Tbis was clearly good news for tbe prevailing view of fiuctua-tions. But tbe same approacb sbowed tbat, if tbe price vector wassucb as to yield instead a state of generalized excess demand,tbings looked very different, indeed mucb more like wbat one sawin tbe Soviet Union at tbe time tban in market economies: tbemultiplier was a supply multiplier. Tbe inability to buy goods ledpeople to cut down on tbeir labor supply, decreasing output,leading to even more rationing in tbe goods market, and so on. Anincrease in government spending led to more rationing of consum-ers, a decrease in labor supply, and a decrease in output. . . .

Tbis raised an obvious issue: witbout a tbeory of wby priceswere not rigbt in tbe first place, tbe second outcome appeared just

Page 13: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1387

as likely as the first. So, why was it that we typically observed thefirst outcome and not the second? The answer clearly required atheory of price setting, and so the explicit introduction of price

. setters (so that somebody other than the auctioneer was incharge). But if there were explicit price setters, there was then noparticular reason why the market outcome should be equal to theminimum of supply and demand. For example, if price setterswere monopolistic firms, and demand turned out larger than theyexpected, then they might well want to satisfy this higher level ofdemand, at least as long as their price exceeded marginal cost. So,to make progress, one had to think hard about market structure,and who the price setters were. But such focus on marketstructure, and on imperfections more generally, was altogetherabsent from macroeconomics at the time.^"

At roughly the same time (circa 1975), this intellectual crisiswas made worse by another development, the collapse of tradi-tional conclusions when rational expectations were introduced inotherwise standard Keynesian models. Working within the stan-dard model at the time (an IS-LM model plus an expectations-augmented Phillips curve), Sargent [1973] showed that, if oneassumed rational expectations of infiation, the effects of money onoutput lasted only for a brief moment, until the relevant informa-tion about money was released. So, even on its own terms, oncerational expectations were introduced, the standard model seemedunable to deliver its traditional conclusions (such as, for example,lasting effects of money on output).

Thus, by the end ofthe 1970s, macroeconomics faced a seriouscrisis. The reaction of researchers was to follow two initially verydifferent routes.

The first, followed by the "New Keynesians," was based on thebelief that the traditional conclusions were indeed largely right,and that what was needed was a deeper look at imperfections andtheir implications for macroeconomics.

The second, followed by the "New Classicals" or "Real Busi-ness Cycle" theorists, was instead to question the traditionalconclusions, and explore how far one could go in explainingfiuctuations without introducing imperfections [Prescott 1986].

At the time, macroeconomics looked (and felt) more dividedthan ever before (the intensity of the debate is well refiected in

10. As it was absent from general equilibrium theory, leading economistsworking on stability and formalizations of real time tatonnement processes intosimilar dead ends.

Page 14: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1388 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

Lucas and Sargent [1978]). Yet, nearly twenty years later, tbe tworoutes bave surprisingly converged. Tbe metbodological contribu-tions of tbe Real Business Cycle approacb, namely tbe develop-ment of stocbastic dynamic general equilibrium models, baveproved important and bave been widely adopted. But tbe initialpropositions tbat money did not matter, tbat technological sbockscould explain fiuctuations, and tbat imperfections were not neededto explain fiuctuations, bave not beld up. Tbe empirical evidencecontinues to strongly support the notion tbat monetary policyaffects output. And tbe idea of large, bigb frequency, movementsin tbe aggregate production function remains an implausibleblack box; tbe relation between output and productivity appearsmore likely to refiect reverse causality, witb movements in outputleading to movements in measured total factor productivity,ratber tban tbe otber way around.

For tbose reasons, most, if not all, current models, in eitbertbe New Keynesian or tbe New Classical mode (tbese two labelswill soon join otbers in tbe trasb bin of bistory of tbougbt) nowexamine tbe implications of imperfections, be it in labor, goods, orcredit markets. Tbis is tbe body of work to wbicb I now turn.

III. POST-1980: I. WORKING OUT THE QUANTITY THEORY

In discussing tbe role of imperfections in macroeconomics, itis useful to divide tbe set of questions into two.

• Tbe old Quantity Tbeory questions: Wby does money affectoutput? Wbat are tbe origin and tbe role of nominalrigidities in tbe process? Tbese may be tbe central ques-tions of macroeconomics, not because sbifts in money aretbe major determinant of fiuctuations (tbey are not), butbecause tbe nonneutrality of money is so obviously at oddswitb tbe predictions of tbe bencbmark, fiexible price,model.

• Tbe old Business Cycle questions: Wbat are tbe majorsbocks tbat affect output? Wbat are tbeir propagationmechanisms? Wbat is tbe role of imperfections in tbatcontext?

Tbis section focuses on tbe first set of questions, tbe next ontbe second.

Most macroeconomists would, I believe, agree today on tbe

Page 15: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1389

following description of what happens in response to an exogenousincrease in nominal money. ̂ ^

• Given the price level, an increase in nominal money leadsto an increase in the aggregate demand for goods. At givennominal prices—and so at given relative prices—this trans-lates into an increase in the demand for each good. ("Prices"is used generically here. I do not distinguish betweenwages and prices).

• Increasing marginal cost/disutility implies that this in-crease in the demand for each good leads each price setterto want to increase his price relative to others.

• If all individual prices were set continuously, the attemptby each price setter to increase his price relative to otherswould clearly fail. All prices, and by implication, the pricelevel would rise until the price level had adjusted inproportion to the increase in nominal money, demand andoutput were back to their original level, and there was nolonger any pressure to increase relative prices. This wouldhappen instantaneously. Money would be neutral, even inthe short run.

• Individual prices, however, are adjusted discretely ratherthan continuously, and not all prices are adjusted at thesame time. This discrete, staggered, adjustment of indi-vidual prices leads to a slow adjustment of the averagelevel of prices—the price level. ̂ ^

• During the process of adjustment ofthe price level, the realmoney stock remains higher, and aggregate demand andoutput remain higher than their original value. Eventually,the price level adjusts in proportion to the increase innominal money. Demand, output, and relative prices re-turn to their original value. Money is neutral, but only inthe long run.

This story feels simple and natural. Indeed, it is not verydifFerent from the account given by the quantity theorists of thenineteenth century. What the recent research has done has been

11. Most but not all. While other explanations, for example, based ondistribution ("limited participation") effects of open market operations, have untilnow turned out to be dead ends, a number of macroeconomists remain skeptical ofnominal rigidities as the source ofthe real efFects of money.

12. An earlier hypothesis for slow adjustment of individual prices, developedby Lucas [1973], and based on incomplete infonnation rather than staggering, hasbeen largely abandoned. It is perceived to rely on implausible assumptions aboutthe structure of information on macroeconomic aggregates.

Page 16: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1390 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

to clarify various parts of tbe argument, and to point to a numberof unresolved issues.

111.1. Staggering, and the Adjustment of the Price Level

A tempting analogy to tbe proposition tbat staggered adjust-ment of individual prices leads to a slow price level adjustment isto tbe movements of a cbain gang. Unless gang members cancoordinate tbeir movements very precisely, tbe cbain gang willrun slowly at best. Tbe sborter tbe length of tbe cbain betweentwo gang members, or tbe larger tbe number of members in tbegang, tbe more slowly it is likely to run.

Research on tbe aggregate implications of specific price rulesand staggering structures bas sbown tbat tbe analogy is typicallyrigbt. In most cases, discrete adjustment of individual pricesindeed leads to a slow adjustment of tbe price level.̂ ^ And themore eacb desired price depends on otber prices, tbe slower tbeadjustment. But tbis researcb bas also come witb a number ofwarnings. In a celebrated counterexample to tbe general proposi-tion, Caplin and Spulber [1987] bave sbown tbat, under someconditions, tbe reverse proposition may in fact bold: discreteadjustment of individual prices may still lead to a completelyfiexible price level." Tbe conditions under wbicb tbeir conclusionbolds are more likely to be satisfied at bigb infiation, and tbis basan important implication: tbe effects of money on output are likelyto be sborter, tbe bigber tbe average rate of money growtb and tbeassociated rate of infiation.

777.2. Real and Nominal Rigidities

If individual price cbanges are staggered, tbe price level willincrease only if at least some individual price setters want toincrease tbeir relative price. Once tbe price level bas fullyadjusted to tbe increase in money, and demand and output areback to tbeir original level, desired relative prices end up tbe sameas tbey were before tbe increase in money; but tbis is true only intbe end.

Tbis observation bas one important implication: tbe speed ofadjustment of tbe price level depends on tbe elasticity of desired

13. The most influential model here is surely Taylor [1980]. See Taylor [1998]for a recent survey.

14. Their result requires two conditions: that prices be changed according toan Ss rule, and that each desired nominal price be a nondecreasing function oftime. Caplin and Leahy [1991] show what happens when only the flrst conditionholds. Money is then typically nonneutral.

Page 17: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1391

relative prices in response to shifts in demand. The higher thiselasticity, the more each individual price setter will want toincrease his price when he adjusts, the faster the price level willincrease and the shorter will be the effects of money on output.Research suggests that, to generate the slow adjustment of theprice level one observes in the data, this elasticity must indeed besmall, smaller than one would expect if, for example, the price setby firms reflected the increase in marginal cost for firms, and thewage reflected the increase in the marginal disutility of work forworkers. 1̂

This proposition is sometimes stated as follows: "Real rigidi-ties" (a small elasticity of the desired relative price to shifts indemand) are needed to generate substantial "nominal rigidity" (aslow adjustment of the price level in response to changes inmoney). The terminology may be infelicitous, but the conclusion isan important one and points to an interaction between nominalrigidities and other imperfections. If these other imperfections aresuch as to generate real rigidities (a big if), they can help explainthe degree of nominal rigidity we appear to observe in moderneconomies.

III.3. Demand versus OutputSuppose that the price level responds slowly, so an increase in

money leads to an increase in the demand for goods for some time.In the absence of further information on the structure in goodsand labor markets, there is no warranty that this increase indemand will lead to an increase in output. It will do so only ifsuppliers of both labor and goods are willing to supply more. Thiswas indeed the main unresolved issue in the flxed price equilib-rium approach. For increases in demand to translate into in-creases in output, the market structure must be such that theprice setters are willing to supply more even at the existing price.

There are market structures where this will be the case.Suppose, for example, that the goods markets is composed ofmonopolistically competitive price setters. At the initial equilib-rium, monopoly power implies that their price is above theirmarginal cost. This implies in turn that, even at an unchangedprice, they will be willing to satisfy an increase in demand, at leastas long as marginal cost remains smaller than the price. So, under

15, See Blanchard and Fischer [1989, Chapter 8] and Chari, Kehoe, andMcGrattan [1998] for a recent discussion.

Page 18: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1392 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

this market structure, shifts in demand, so long as they are not toolarge, will lead to an increase in output.

For this reason, a typical assumption in recent research hasbeen one of monopolistic competition. In the goods market, theassumption that price setters have some monopoly power and somay be willing to increase output in response to a shift in demandseems indeed reasonable. The assumption of monopolistic compe-tition in the labor market is clearly much less appealing, and thequestion of whether the same conclusion will derive from morerealistic descriptions of wage setting remains open. More gener-ally, this points to yet another interaction between nominalrigidities and other imperfections. To understand why output andemployment respond to shifts in demand, we need a betterunderstanding of the structure of both goods and labor markets.

777.4. Money as Numeraire and Medium of Exchange

The argument underlying nonneutrality relies on two proper-ties of money, money as the medium of exchange and money as thenumeraire.

Staggering of individual price changes delivers slow adjust-ment of the average price of goods in terms of the numeraire. If, inaddition, the numeraire is also the medium of exchange—which itneed not be as a matter of logic, but typically is—slow adjustmentof the average price of goods in terms of the numeraire means slowadjustment of the average price of goods in terms of the medium ofexchange. It is these two features which, when combined, implythat changes in the stock of nominal money lead to changes in thevalue of the stock of money in terms of goods, leading in turn tomovements in the interest rate, the demand for goods, and output.

This coincidence is crucial to the story. It suggests thatdelinking the numeraire and the medium of exchange would leadto very difFerent effects of changes in nominal money—and moregenerally, of shifts in the demand for goods—on output. Put morestrongly, it might change the nature of short-run fluctuations. Theidea of having a numeraire separate from the medium of exchangeis an old idea in macroeconomics, an idea explored by IrvingFisher in particular. But, despite some recent work (for example,Shiller [1999]), we still lack a good understanding of whatmacroeconomic implications, and by implication what potentialbenefits, could come from such a separation.

The set of results I have described above is sometimes called

Page 19: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1393

the "menu costs" explanation of the short-run nonneutrality ofmoney. 1̂ The expression correctly captures the notion that smallindividual costs of changing prices can have large macroeconomiceffects. At the same time, the expression may have been a publicrelations disaster. It makes the explanation for the effects ofmoney on output look accidental, when in fact the effects appear tobe intrinsic to the workings of an economy with decentralizedprice and wage setting. In any economy with decentralized priceand wage setting, adjustment of the general level of prices interms ofthe numeraire is likely to be slow relative to a (fictional)economy with an auctioneer.

IV. POST-1980: II. THE ROLE OF OTHER IMPERFECTIONS

Leaving aside nominal rigidities, there are three main rea-sons why macroeconomists working on fluctuations should careabout imperfections. 1̂

• Imperfections lead to very different efficiency and welfarecharacteristics ofthe equilibrium, and thus modify the waywe think about fluctuations and the role of policy. Forexample, think of the question of whether the equilibriumrate of unemplo3mient is too high or too low, and itsimplications for macroeconomic policy. ̂ ^

• Imperfections may lead to very different propagation mecha-nisms of shocks. For example, think of the role of theinteractions of nominal and real rigidities in determiningthe persistence of changes in money on output that Idiscussed in the previous section.

• Imperfections may lead to new sources of shocks. Forexample, think of bank runs, which may affect not only thesupply of money, but also the functioning of the financialintermediation system, leading to long-lasting effects onoutput.

These are the motivations behind the research on imperfec-tions and macroeconomics which has developed in the last twenty

16. See, in particular, Mankiw [1985] andAkerlof and Yellen [1985].17. The arguments would be even stronger if the focus of this article were

extended to cover growth. Much ofthe recent progress in growth theory has comefrom looking at the role of imperfections and institutions (externalities from R&Dand patent laws, bankruptcies and bankruptcy laws, restrictions to entry by newfirms, institutions governing corporate governance, etc.) in growth.

18. For example, the implications for monetary policy emphasized by Barroand Gordon [1983].

Page 20: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1394 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

years or so. As I indicated in the introduction, this phase is stillvery much one of exploration. The thousand flowers are stillhlooming, and it is not clear what integrated macroeconomicmodel will emerge, if any. Let me describe four major lines alongwhich substantial progress has already been made.

IV. 1. Unemployment and the Labor MarketThe notion that the labor market was somehow special was

reflected in early Keynesian models by the crude assumptionsthat the nominal wage was given, and employment was deter-mined by the demand for labor. It was reflected in the confuseddebates about whether unemployment was involuntary or volun-tary. It was reflected by the continuing use of an ad hoc formaliza-tion of wage behavior—the Phillips curve—even in theoreticalmodels. It was reflected by the unease with which the neoclassicalformulation of labor supply, developed by Lucas and Rapping[1969], with its focus on intertemporal substitution, was receivedby most macroeconomists.

For a long time, the basic obstacle was simply how to think ofa market where, even in equilibrium, there were some unsatisfledsellers—there was unemployment. The basic answer was given inthe early 1970s, in a set of contributions to a volume edited byPhelps [1970]: one should think of the labor market as a decentral-ized market, in which there were workers looking for jobs, andfirms looking for workers. In such a market there would alwaysbe, even in equilibrium, both some unemplo3rment and somevacancies.

Research started in earnest in the 1980s, based on a numberof theoretical contributions to search and bargaining in decentral-ized markets, in particular by Diamond [1982], Mortensen [1982],and Pissarides [1985]. The conceptual structure that has emergedis known as the flow approach to the labor market. ̂ ^

• The labor market is a decentralized market. At any point intime, because of shifts in the relative demand for goods, orchanges in technology, or because a firm and a worker nolonger get along, a number of employment relations areterminated, and a number of new employment relationsare started.The workers wbo separate from firms, because they quit or

19. For recent surveys, see Pissarides [1999] or Mortensen and Pissarides[1998].

Page 21: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1395

are laid off, look for new jobs. The firms, which need to fillnew jobs or replace the workers who have left, look forworkers. At any point in time, there are both workerslooking for jobs—unemployment—and firms looking forworkers—^vacancies.

• When a worker and a firm meet and conclude that thematch seems right, there is typically room for bargaining.The wage is then likely to depend on labor market condi-tions. If unemployment is high, and vacancies are low, thefirm knows it will be able to find another worker easily, andthe worker knows it will be hard to find another job. This islikely to translate into a low wage. If unemployment is lowand vacancies are high, the wage will be high.

• The level of the wage in turn affects the evolution of bothvacancies and unemployment. A high wage means moreterminations, less starts, and so a decrease in vacanciesand an increase in unemployment. Conversely, a low wageleads to an increase in vacancies and a decrease in unem-ployment. Given these dynamics, the economy typicallyconverges to a set of equilibrium values for unemploymentand vacancies. One can then think of the natural rate ofunemplo3maent as the value to which the unemplojonentrate converges.It is clear that in such an economy, there should be andalways will be some unemployment (and some vacancies).Operating the economy at very low unemployment wouldbe very ineflScient. But the equilibrium level of unemploy-ment tjT)ically has no claim to being the efficient level. Theequilibrium level, and its relation to the efficient level,depend on the nature of the process of search and match-ing, as well as on the nature of bargaining between workersand firms.

One way of assessing progress is to go back to a famous quoteby Friedman [1968] about the natural rate of unemployment:

The natural rate of unemployment is the level which would beground out by the Walrasian system of general equilibriumequations, provided that there is imbedded in them the actualstructural characteristics of the labor and commodity markets,including market imperfections, stochastic variability in demandsand supplies, the cost of gathering information about job vacanciesand labor availabilities, the costs of mobility, and so on.

Page 22: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1396 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

What we have done is to go from this quote to a formalframework in which the role of each of these factors (and manyothers) can be understood and then taken to the data.^° Today, wehave a much better sense ofthe role and the determinants of jobcreation and job destruction, of quits and layoffs, ofthe nature ofthe matching process between firms and workers, ofthe effects oflabor market institutions from unemployment benefits to employ-ment protection, on unemployment. This line of research hasshown, for example, how higher employment protection leads tolower fiows in the labor market, but also to longer unemploymentduration. Lower fiows and longer duration unambiguously changethe nature of unemployment. But because, in steady state,unemployment is the product of fiows times duration, togetherthey have an ambiguous effect on the unemployment rate itself.Both the unambiguous effects on fiows and duration are indeedclearly visible when looking across countries with different de-grees of employment protection.

Many extensions of this framework have been explored.While the basic approach focuses on the implications of thespecificity of the product being transacted (labor services by aparticular worker to a particular firm), and the room for bargain-ing that this creates, a number of contributions have focused onother dimensions, such as the complexity of the product beingtransacted, and the information problems this raises. For ex-ample, how much effort a worker puts into his job can be hard for afirm to monitor. If the firm just paid this worker his reservationwage, he would not care about being found shirking and beingfired. One way the firm can induce him not to shirk is by payinghim a wage higher than his reservation wage, so as to increase theopportunity cost of being found shirking and being fired. Thisparticular effect has been the focus of an infiuential paper byShapiro and Stiglitz [1984], who have shown that, even absentissues of matching, the implication would be positive equilibriumunemplojTnent. As they have argued, in this case, equilibriumunemployment plays the role of a (macroeconomic) "disciplinedevice" to induce effort on the part of workers.

So far, however, our improved understanding of the determi-nants ofthe natural rate of unemployment has not translated intoa much better understanding of the dynamic relation betweenwages and labor market conditions. In other words, we have not

20. For a more detailed assessment see Blanchard and Katz [1997].

Page 23: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1397

made much progress since the PhiUips curve. In particular,current theoretical models appear to imply a stronger and fasteradjustment of wages to lahor market conditions than is the case inthe data. One reason may he the insufficient attention paid to yetanother dimension of lahor transactions, namely that they tjT)i-cally are not spot transactions, hut rather long-term relationshetween workers and firms. Long-term relations often allow forhetter outcomes, for reasons emphasized hy the theory of repeatedgames. For example, they may allow the wage to play less of anallocational role and more of a distrihutional or insurance role.̂ ^There may lie one of the keys to explaining ohserved wagehehavior. That firms might want to develop a reputation for goodhehavior and, hy so doing, achieve a more efficient outcome, isindeed one ofthe themes ofthe research on "efficiency wages." Butafter much work in the 1980s, this direction of research hastapered off, without the emergence of a clear picture or anintegrated view.̂ ^ This is a direction in which more work is clearlyneeded.

TV.2. Saving, Investment, and CreditIssues of financial intermediation, from "credit crunches" to

"liquidity scramhles," figured heavily in the early accounts offiuctuations.^^ With the introduction of the IS-LM, the focusshifted away. Issues of financial intermediation were altogetherahsent from the IS-LM model and most of its descendants. Thetreatment of financial intermediation in larger models was oftenschizophrenic: asset markets were typically formalized as competi-tive markets, with a set of arhitrage relations determining theterm structure of interest rates and stock prices. Among financialintermediaries, typically only hanks, hecause of their relevance tothe determination of the money supply, were treated explicitly.Credit prohlems were dealt with implicitly, hy allowing for thepresence of current cash fiow in investment decisions, and ofcurrent income in consumption decisions.̂ ^ One can therefore seerecent research as returning to old themes, hut with hetter tools(asymmetric information) and greater clarity.

21. See, for example, Espinosa and Rhee [1989].22. For a survey of work up to 1986, see Katz [1986].23. See, for example, the 1949 survey by McKean.24. A notable exception liere is tbe work by Eckstein and Sinai (summarized

in Eckstein and Sinai [1986] and reflected in the DRI niodel). With its focus onbalance sheets of flrms and intermediaries, it was surprisingly at odds with thelanguage and the other models ofthe time. But many of its themes have come backinto fashion since.

Page 24: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1398 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OE ECONOMICS

The starting point, when thinking about credit, must be thephysical separation between borrowers and lenders. Lendingmeans giving funds today in anticipation of receiving funds in thefuture. Between now and then, many things can go wrong. Thefunds may not be invested but squandered. They may be investedin the wrong project. They may be invested, but not paid back.This leads potential lenders to put limits on how much they arewilling to lend, and to ask borrowers to put some of their ownfunds at risk. How much borrowers can borrow therefore dependson how much cash or marketable assets they have to start with,and on how much collateral they can put in—including thecollateral associated with the new project.

This fact alone has a number of implications for macroeco-nomic fluctuations.

• The distribution of income and marketable wealth betweenborrowers and lenders matters very much for investment.

• The expected future matters less, the past and the present—through their effect on the accumulation of marketableassets by flrms—matter more for investment. Transitoryshocks, to the extent that they affect the amount ofmarketable assets, can have lasting effects. Higher profltstoday lead to a higher cash flow today, and thus moreinvestment today and more output in the future, a mecha-nism emphasized by Bernanke and Gertler [1989].

• Asset values play a different role than they do in theabsence of credit problems. Shocks that affect the value ofmarketable assets can affect investment even when they donot have a direct effect on future profltability—a channelexplored, for example, by Kiyotaki and Moore [1997].

In such a world, the importance of having marketable assetsleads in turn to a demand for marketable, or "liquid," assets byconsumers and flrms. Because consumers flnd it hard either toinsure against idios3nicratic income shocks or to borrow againstfuture labor income, consumers save as a precaution againstadverse shocks [Carroll 1997; Deaton 1992]. Here, theoretical andempirical research on saving has made clear that both life-cycleand precautionary motives play an important role in explainingsaving behavior. Similar considerations apply to flrms. Becauseflrms may need funds to start a new project, or to continue with anexisting project, they also have a demand for marketable assets, ademand for liquidity. A new set of general equilibrium questions

Page 25: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1399

arises: will the economy provide such marketable assets? Can thegovernment, for example, improve things by issuing such liquidinstruments as T-bills?̂ ^

In such a world also, there is clearly scope for flnancialintermediaries to alleviate information and monitoring problems.But their presence raises a new set of issues. To have the rightincentives, flnancial intermediaries may need to have some oftheir own funds at stake. Thus, not only the marketable assets ofultimate borrowers, but also the marketable assets of intermediar-ies matter. Shocks in one part of the economy that decrease thevalue of their marketable assets can force intermediaries toreduce lending to the rest of the economy, resulting in a creditcrunch [Holmstrom and Tirole 1997]. And to the extent thatflnancial intermediaries pool funds from many lenders, coordina-tion problems may arise. An important contribution along theselines is the clariflcation by Diamond and Dybvig [1983] of thenature and the necessary conditions for bank runs.

Because some of their liabilities are money, banks play aspecial role among flnancial intermediaries. In that light, recentresearch has looked at and clarifled an old question, namelywhether monetary policy works only through interest rates (thestandard "money channel"), or also by affecting the amount ofbank loans and cutting credit to some borrowers who do not haveaccess to other sources of funds (the "bank lending" channel).̂ ^The tentative answer at this point: the credit channel probablyplayed a central role earlier in time, especially during the GreatDepression. But, because of changes in the flnancial system, itsimportance may now be fading.

Research on credit is one of the most active lines of researchtoday in macroeconomics. Mucb progress has already been made.This is already reflected, for example, in the (ex post) analyses ofthe Asian crisis, and in the analysis of the problems of flnancialintermediation in Eastern Europe.

Let me turn to the two remaining themes. I shall be moresuccinct because less progress has been made, in the flrst casebecause the evidence remains elusive and in the second becausemuch remains to be done.

25. See, for example, Holmstrom and Tirole [1998].26. Bernanke and Gertler [1995] give a general discussion of the way credit

market imperfections can modify the effects of monetary policy on output.

Page 26: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1400 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

IV.3. Increasing ReturnsThe potential relevance of increasing returns to fluctuations

is another old theme in macroeconomics. The argument is straight-forward.

• If increasing returns to scale are sufficient to offset theshort-run flxity of some factors of production such ascapital, short-run marginal cost may be constant or evendecreasing with output. Eirms may be willing to supplymore goods at roughly the same price, leading to longerlasting and larger effects of shifts in aggregate demand onoutput (a version of the interaction between nominal andreal rigidities discussed earlier).

• Indeed, if returns are increasing enough, the economy mayhave multiple equilibria, a low-efficiency low-output equi-librium and a high-efficiency high-output equilibrium.IVIany examples of such multiple equilibria bave beenworked out. Some have been based on increasing returns inproduction [Kiyotaki 1988], and others on increasing re-turns in exchange [Diamond 1982a].

A related line of research bas focused on countercyclicalmarkups (of price over marginal cost). Just like increasingreturns, countercyclical markups may explain why flrms arewilling to supply more output at roughly the same price. Likeincreasing returns, countercyclical markups imply tbat tbeeconomy may operate more efficiently at bigber output, in thiscase not because productivity is bigber but because distortions(the gap between price and marginal cost) are lower. A number ofmodels of markups, based on imperfect competition, have beendeveloped, some indeed predicting countercyclical markups (forexample, Rotemberg and Woodford [1991]), others, bowever,predicting procyclical markups [Phelps 1992].

Turning to the empirical research gives tbe same feeling ofambiguity. It appears to be true that, in response to exogenousshifts in demand, flrms are willing to supply more at nearly thesame price (for example. Shea [1993]). How mucb is due to flatmarginal cost or to countercyclical markups is still unclear.Countercyclical markups indeed appear to play a role (for ex-ample, Bils [1987]). But the source of such countercyclicality(nominal rigidities, lags in the adjustment of prices to cost,changes in the desired or in the sustainable markup if tbe markupis thought to result from a game among oligopolistic flrms)remains to be established. Eor the time being, tbe possibility of

Page 27: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS^ 1401

multiple equilibria due to either increasing returns or countercy-clical markups, remains an intriguing but unproven hypothesis.

IV.4. Expectations as Driving Forces

This last theme, movements in expectations as an importantsource of fluctuations, is once again an old one. It was a dominanttheme of pre-1940 macroeconomics. It was a major theme inKejTies, and beyond. But, with the introduction of rationalexpectations in the 1970s, expectations became fully endogenous,and the theme was lost.

To most macroeconomists, rational expectations is the rightbenchmark. But this only means that the burden of proof is onthose who insist on the presence of deviations from rationalexpectations, on their relevance for asset prices, and in turn foroutput fluctuations. This is indeed where a lot of research on"behavioral flnance"has recently taken place.

Research has taken place along two fronts.̂ ^ The flrst haslooked at the way people form expectations. A substantial body ofempirical—often experimental—evidence has documented thatmost people form their expectations in ways which are notconsistent with the economists' deflnition of full rationality, forexample in ways inconsistent with Bayes' rule. Some sequences ofrealizations are more "salient" than others, and have more effecton expectations than they should. For example, there is someevidence that a sequence of positive past returns leads people torevise expectations of future returns more than they should. Thisappears potentially relevant in thinking about phenomena suchas fads or bubbles in asset markets.

For deviations from rationality by some investors to lead todeviations of asset values from fundamentals, another conditionmust be satisfied: there must be only limited arbitrage by theother investors. This is the second front on which research hasadvanced. The arguments it has made are simple ones. First, therequired arbitrage is typically not riskless: what position do youtake if you believe the stock market is overvalued by x percent?Second, professional arbitrageurs do not have unlimited funds.This opens the same issues as those we discussed earlier whendiscussing credit. Asjmimetric information implies a limit on how

27. For a review see Shleifer [2000].

Page 28: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1402 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

much these arbitrageurs can borrow, and thus on how much theycan arbitrage incorrect asset prices.̂ ^

Empirical research has shown that this line of research canaccount for a number of apparent puzzles in asset markets. Butother explanations, not based on such imperfections, may alsoaccount for these facts. At this stage, the question is far fromsettled. At issue is a central question of macroeconomics, the roleof expectations, of bubbles and fads, as driving forces for at leastsome macroeconomic fluctuations.

V. MACRO IN THE (NEAR) FUTURE

Let me briefly restate the thread of my argument. Relative toWicksell and Fisher, macroeconomics today is solidly grounded ina general equilibrium structure. Modern models characterize theeconomy as being in temporary equilibrium, given the implica-tions of the past, and the anticipations of the future. They providean interpretation of fluctuations as the result of shocks workingtheir way through propagation mechanisms. Much of the currentwork is focused on the role of imperfections.

What happens next? Predicting the evolution of research isvery much like predicting the stock market. Like flnancial arbi-trage, intellectual arbitrage is not perfect, but it is close. Let menevertheless raise a number of questions and make a few guesses.

Which imperfections? Part of the reason current researchoften feels confusing comes from the diversity of imperfectionsinvoked in explaining this or that market. To caricature, but onlyslightly: research on labor markets focuses on decentralizationand bargaining; research on credit markets focuses on asymmet-ric information; research on goods markets on increasing returns;research on flnancial markets on psychology.

To some extent, the differences in focus must be right. Theproblems involved in spot transactions are different from thoseinvolved in intertemporal ones; the problems involved in one-timetransactions are different from those involved in repeated transac-tions, and so on. Still, if for no other than aesthetic reasons, onemay hope for an integrated macro model, based on only a few

28. One of the small victories of this line of research has been the descriptionof an LTCM-type crisis before it happened. In 1997 Shleifer and Vishny arguedthat it was precisely at the time when asset prices deviated most from fundamen-tals that arbitrageurs might be least able to get the external funds they needed toarbitrage and may need to liquidate their positions, making things worse. This iswhat happened one year later at LTCM.

Page 29: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1403

central imperfections (say, those that give rise to nominal rigidi-ties, and one or two others).

There indeed exists a few attempts to provide such anintegrated view. One is by Phelps in "Structural Slumps" [1994],which is based on implications of asymmetric information in goodsand labor markets. Another is by Caballero and Hammour (forexample [1996]), based on the idea that most relations, either incredit or in labor markets, require some relation-specific invest-ment, and therefore open room for holdups ex post. These areimportant contributions, but I see them more as the prototypecars presented in car shows but never mass produced later: theyshow what can be done, but they are probably not exactly whatwill be.

Policy and welfare. One striking implication of recent modelsis how much more complex the welfare implications of policy are.To take one example, in a model with monopolistic competition(small), increases in output due to the interaction of money andnominal rigidities improve welfare to a first order. This is becauseinitially marginal cost is below the price and the increase inoutput reduces the wedge between the two. Under other distor-tions, the effects of output fluctuations on efficiency and welfarecan be much more complex. For example, recent research hasrevisited the question of whether recessions "cleanse" theeconomy—by eliminating firms that should have been closedanyway—or weaken it—by destroying perfectly good firms. Theanswer so far is both, in proportions that depend on the precisenature of imperfections in labor and credit markets. This clearlyhas implications for how one views fluctuations.^^

The medium run. There has been a traditional conceptualdivision in macroeconomics between the short run—the study ofbusiness cycles—and the long run—the study of growth.̂ o Abetterdivision might actually be between the short run, the mediumrun, and the long run. Phenomena such as the long period of highunemployment in Europe in the last 25 years, or the behavior ofoutput during the transition in Eastern Europe, do not fit easilyinto either business cycles or growth. They appear to involvedifferent shocks from those generating business cycle—changes inthe pace or the nature of technological progress, demographicevolutions, or in the case of Eastern Europe, dramatic changes in

29. See, for example, Caballero and Hammour [1999].30. More than the rest of this essay, this reflects my views rather than some

assessment of the consensus. See, for example, Blanchard [1997].

Page 30: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1404 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

institutions. Tbey also appear to involve different imperfections—with imperfections in labor, credit, and goods markets rather thannominal rigidities playing the dominant role—than businesscycles.

Research on imperfections has allowed us to make substan-tial progress here. Our understanding of the evolution of Euro-pean unemployment, for example, is still far from good; but it ismuch better than it was ten or twenty years ago.

Macroeconomics and institutions. The presence of imperfec-tions tjrpically leads to the emergence of institutions designed,more or less successfully, to correct them. Examples range fromantitrust legislation, to rules protecting minority shareholders, tounemployment insurance. Which institutions emerge is clearlyimportant in understanding medium-run evolutions. Think of therole of labor market institutions in explaining European unemploy-ment, the role of legal structures in explaining the evolution ofoutput in transition economies. Institutions also matter for short-run fluctuations, with different institutions leading to differentshocks and propagation mechanisms across countries. For ex-ample, a recent paper by Johnson et al. [1999] argues that, duringthe recent Asian crisis, those Asian countries that had theweakest governance institutions (such as poor protection ofminority shareholders) were also those that suffered the largestexchange rate declines. Identifying the role of differences ininstitutions in generating differences in macroeconomic short-and medium-run evolutions is likely to be an important topic ofresearch in the future.

Current debates. In the early 1980s macroeconomic researchseemed divided into two camps, with sharp ideological andmethodological differences. Real business cycle theorists arguedthat fluctuations could be explained by a fully competitive model,with technological shocks. New Keynesians argued that imperfec-tions were of the essence. Real business cycle theorists used fullyspecified general equilibrium models based on equilibrium andoptimization under uncertainty. New Keynesians used smallmodels, capturing what they saw as the essence of their argu-ments, without the paraphernalia of fully specifled models.

Today, the ideological divide is gone. Not in the sense thatunderlying ideological differences are gone, but in the sense thattrying to organize recent contributions along ideological lineswould not work well. As I argued earlier, most macroeconomicresearch today focuses on the macroeconomic implications of some

Page 31: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1405

imperfection or another. At the frontier of macroeconomic re-search, the field is surprisingly a-ideological.

The methodological divide is narrower than it was, but it isstill present. Can macroeconomists use small models such as tbeIS-LM model or the Taylor model—the model of aggregate de-mand and supply witb wage staggering developed by John Taylor?Or sbould they use only fully specified dynamic general equilib-rium models, now that sucb models can be solved numerically?^^Put in tbese terms, it is obvious that tbis is an incorrectly frameddebate. Intuition is often obtained by playing witb small models.Large explicit models then allow for furtber checking and refin-ing. Small models tben allow conveying of the essence of tbeargument to otbers. At tbis stage, I believe that small models areindeed underused and undertaugbt.^^ Small, back-of-tbe enve-lope, models are much too useful to disappear, and I expect tbatmetbodological divide will also fade away.

One way to end is to ask: of bow much use was macroeconomicresearch in understanding, for example, and belping resolve tbeAsian crisis of tbe late 1990s?

Macroeconomists did not predict either tbe time, place, orscope of tbe crisis. Previous excbange rate crises bad involvedeither fiscal misbebavior (as in Latin America), or steady realappreciation and large current account deficits (as in Mexico).Neitber fiscal policy, nor, given tbe very bigb rate of investment,tbe current account position of Asian countries, seemed particu-larly worrisome at tbe time.^^

So, when tbe crisis started, macroeconomic mistakes (sucb asfiscal tightening, tbe rigbt recommendation in previous crises, butnot in this one) were made. But, fairly quickly, tbe nature of tbecrisis was better understood, and tbe mistakes were corrected.And most of tbe tools needed were tbere to analyze events andbelp tbe design of policy, from micro-based models of bank runs, tomodels of financial intermediation, to variations on tbe Mundell-Fleming model allowing, for example, for an eflfect of foreign-

31. This debate is about models used in research, not about the apphedeconometric models used for forecasting or policy.

32. Paul Krugman recently wondered how many macroeconomists stillbelieve in the IS-LM model. The answer is probably that most do, but many ofthem probably do not know it well enough to tell.

33. Anotable exception here is the work of Calvo (for example, Calvo [1998]),who, before the crisis took place, emphasized the potential for maturity mismatch(short-term foreign debt, long-term domestic loans) to generate an exchange ratecrisis, even absent fiscal or current account deficits.

Page 32: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1406 QUARTERLY JOURNAL OF ECONOMICS

currency-denominated debt on the balance sheet, and in turn onthe behavior of firms and banks.

Since then, a large amount of further research has takenplace, leading to a better understanding of the role of financialintermediation in exchange rate crises. Based on this research,proposals for better prudential regulation of financial institu-tions, for restrictions on some forms of capital fiows, for aredefinition of the role of the IMF, are being discussed. A passinggrade for macroeconomics? Given the complexity of the issues, Ithink so. But it is for the reader to judge.

MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY AND

NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH

REFERENCES

Akerlof, George, and Janet Yellen, "A Near-Rational Model of the Business Cyclewith Wage and Price Inertia," Quarterly Journai of Economics, C (1985),823-838.

Barro, Robert, and David Gordon, "A Positive Theory of Monetary Policy in aNatural Rate Model," Jouma/ of Political Economy, XC (1983), 589-610.

Barro, Robert, and Herschel Grossman, Money, Employment, and Inflation(Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1976).

Bemanke, Ben, and Mark Gertler, "Agency Costs, Net Worth and BusinessFluctuations " American Economic Review, LXXIX(1989), 14-31.

Bemanke, Ben, and Mark Gertler, "Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel ofMonetary Policy Transmission," JournaZ of Economic Perspectives, IX (1995),27-48.

Bils, Mark, "The Cyclical Behavior of Marginal Cost and Price," AmericanEconomic Review, XXVII (1987), 838-855.

Blanchard, Olivier, "The Medium Run," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2(1997), 89-158.

Blanchard, Olivier, and Stanley Fischer, Lectures on Macroeconomics (Cambridge,MA: MIT Press, 1989).

Blanchard, Olivier, and Lawrence Katz, "What we Know and Do not Know aboutthe Natural rate of Unemployment," Journal of Economic Perspectives, XI(1997), 51-72.

Caballero, Ricardo, and Mohamad Hammour, "The 'Fundamental Transformation'in Macroeconomics,"Americon ficoreomic iJeuJeii), LXXXVI (1996), 181-186.

Caballero, Ricardo, and Mohamad Hammour, "The Cost of Recessions Revisited: AReverse-Liquidationist View," rnimeo, MIT, 1999.

Calvo, Guillermo, "Varieties of Capital Market Crises, in G. Calvo and M. King,eds.. The Debt Burden and its Consequences for Monetary Policy Macmillan,(London; 1998).

Caplin, Andrew, and John Leahy, "State-Dependent Pricing and the Dynamics ofMoney and Output," Quarterly Journal of Economics, CVI (1991), 683-708.

Caplin, Andrew, and Dan Spulber, "Menu Costs and the Neutrality of Money,"Quarterly Journal of Economics, CII (1987), 703-726.

Carroll, Christopher, "Buffer-Stock Saving and the Life Cycle/Permanent IncomeHypothesis," Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXII(1997), 1-56.

Chari, V. V., Patrick Kehoe, and Ellen McGrattan, "Sticky Price Models of theBusiness Cycle: Can the Contract Multiplier Solve the Persistence Problem?"FRB of Minneapolis staff paper. No. 217, 1998.

De Wolff, Piet, "Income Elasticity of Demand, a Micro-Economic and a Macro-economic Interpretation,"ficoreomJcc/our/iaZ, LI (1941), 140—145.

Page 33: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1407

Deaton, Angus, Understanding Consumption (Oxford: Oxford Universitv Press1992). ^

Diamond, Douglas, and Philip Dybvig, "Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, andLiquidity," Jourrea/ of Political Economy, XCI (1983), 401-419.

Diamond, Peter, "Aggregate Demand Management in Search Equilibrium," Jour-nal of Political Economy, XC (1982a), 881-894., "Wage Determination and Efficiency in Search Equilibrium," Review ofEconomic Studies, XCIX (1982b), 217-227.

Dornbusch, Rudiger, "Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics," Journal ofPolitical Economy, LXXXIV (1976), 1161-1176.

Eckstein, Otto, and Allen Sinai, "The Mechanisms of the Business Cycle in thePostwar Era," in The American Business Cycle. Continuity and Change, R.Gordon, ed. (Chicago: NBER and the University of Chicago Press, 1986), pp.39—122.

Espinosa, Maria, Eind Changyong Rhee, "Efficient Wage Bargaining as a RepeatedGame," Quarterly Journal of Economics, CIV (1989), 565-588.

Fisher, Irving, The Purchasing Power of Money (NewYork: Macmillan, 1911).Friedman, Milton, "The Role of Monetary Policy," American Economic Review

LVIII (1968), 1-21.Frisch, Ragnar, "Propagation Problems and Impulse Problems in Dynamic Econom-

ics," in Readings in Business Cycles (New York: Irwin, 1965, first published in1933), pp. 155-185.

Haberler, Gottfried, Prosperity and Depression. A Theoretical Analysis of CyclicalMovements (Geneva: League of Nations, 1937).

Hall, Robert, "Stochastic Implications of the Life-Cycle Permanent Income Hy-pothesis: Theory and Evidence," Journal of Political Economy LXXXVI(1978), 971-987.

Hicks, John, "Mr Keynes and the Classics. A Suggested Interpretation," Economet-rica, V (1937), 147-159., Value and Capital (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1939).

Holmstrom, Bengt, and Jean Tirole, "Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds,and the Real Sector," Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXII (1997), 663-692.

Holmstrom, Bengt, and Jean Tirole, "Private and Public Supply of Liquidity,"Journal of Political Economy, CVI (1998), 1-40.

Johnson, Simon, Peter Boone, Alasdair Breach, and Eric Friedman, "CorporateGovernance in the Asian Financial Crisis, 1997-1998," mimeo, MassachusettsInstitute of Technology, January 1999.

Kahn, R. F., "The Relation of Home Investment to Unemployment," EconomicJoamai, XLI (1931), 173-198.

Katz, Lawrence, "Efficiency Wage Theories: A Partial Evaluation"ArBJSiJ Macroeco-nomics Annual (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1986), pp. 235-276.

Keynes, John M., The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (NewYork: Harcourt, 1964, first published 1936).

Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, "Multiple Expectational Equilibria under Monopolistic Com-petition," Quarterly Journal of Economics, CII (1988), 695-714.

Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro, and John Moore, "Credit Cycles," Journal of Political EconomyCV (1997), 211-248. ^'

Klein, Lawrence, "Macroeconomics and the Theory of Rational Behavior " Econo-metrica, XIV (1946), 93-108.

Lucas, Robert E., "Some Intemational Evidence on the Output-Inflation Trade-off," A/nericara Economic Review, LXIII (1973), 326-334., Models of Business Cycles (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1987).

Lucas, Robert, and Leonard Rapping, "Real Wages, Employment, and Inflation "Journal of Political Economy, LXXVII (1969), 721-754.

Lucas, Robert, and Thomas Sargent, "After Keynesian Economics," in After thePhillips Curve: Persistence of High Inflation and High Unemployment (Bos-ton, MA: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1978).

Lucas, Rohert, and Nancy Stokey, Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics(Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1989).

Mankiw, N. Gregory, "Small Menu Costs and Large Business Cycles: A Macroeco-nomic Model," Quarterly Journal of Economics, C (1985), 529-539.

McKean, Roland, "Liquidity and a National Balance Sheet," Journal of PoliticalEconomy, LVII (1949), 506-522.

Page 34: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

1408 Q UARTERLY JO URNAL OF ECONOMICS

Metzler, Lloyd, "Wealth, Saving, and the Rate of Interest," Journal of PoliticalEconomy, LIX(1951), 93-116,

Mitchell, Wesley, Business Cycles and Unemployment (New York: National Bureauof Economic Research and McGraw-Hill, 1923),

Modigliani, Franco, "Liquidity Preference and the Theory of Interest and Money,"Econometrica, XII (1944), 45-88,

Modighani, Franco, and Richard Brumberg, "Utility Analysis and the Consump-tion Function: An Interpretation of Cross-Section Data," in Post KeynesianEconomics, K, Kurihara, ed, (New Jersey: Rutgers University Press, 1954),pp, 388-436,

Mortensen, Dale, "The Matching Process as a Noncooperative/Bargaining Game,"The Economics of Information and Uncertainty J, J, McCall, ed, (Chicago:University of Chicago Press, 1982), pp, 233-254,

Mortensen, Dale, and Christopher Pissarides, "Job Reallocation, EmploymentFluctuations, and Unemployment," Chapter 18 in Handbook of Macroeconom-ics, John Taylor and Michael Woodford, eds, (Amsterdam; Elsevier Science B,V,), pp, 1171-1228,

Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth RogofF, Foundations of International Macroeconom-ics (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1996),

Patinkin, Don, Money, Interest, and Prices. An Integration of Monetary and ValueTheory (New York: Harper and Row, 1965), first edition, 1956,

Phelps, Edmund, Microeconomic Foundations of Employment and Inflation Theory(New York: W, W, Norton, 1970),, "Customer Demand and Equihbrium Unemployment in a Working Model ofthe Incentive-Wage Customer-Market Economy," Quarterly Journal ofEeonom-ics, CVII (1992), 1003-1033,, Structural Slumps. The Modern Equilibrium Theory of Unemployment,Interest, and Assets (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1994),

Pigou, A, C, "Review oiThe General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money byJ, M, Keynes," Economica, III (1936), 115-132,, Keynes'General Theory. A Retrospective View (London: Macmillan, 1950),

Pissarides, Christopher, "Short-Run Equilibrium Dynamics of Unemployment,Vacancies, and Real Wages," American Economic Review LXXV (1985),676-690,, Equilibrium Unemployment Theory, second edition (Cambridge: MIT Press,2000),

Prescott, Edward, "Theory Ahead of Business Cycle Measurement," QuarterlyReview, Minneapolis Fed (1986), 9-22,

Ramsey, Frank, "A Mathematical Theory of Saving," Economic Journal, XXXVIII(1928), 543-559,

Rotemberg, Julio, and Michael Woodford, "Markups and the Business Cycle,"NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Olivier Blanchard and Stanley Fischer, eds,(Cambridge: MIT Press, 1991), pp, 63-128,

Samuelson, Paul, "Interactions between the Multiplier Analysis and the Principleof Acceleration," iJeuieu; of Economic Statistics, XXI (1939), 75-78,

Sargent, Thomas, "Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest, and theNatural Rate of Unemployment," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2(1973), 429-472,, Dynamic Macroeconomic Theory (Cambridge: Harvard University Press,1987),

Shapiro, Carl, and Joseph Stiglitz, "Equilibrium Unemployment as a DisciphneDevice," American Economic Review, LXXIV(1984), 433-444,

Shea, John, "Do Supply Curves Slope up?" Quarterly Journal ofEeonomics, CVIII(1993), 1-32,

Shiller, Robert, "Designing Indexed Units of Account," NBER Working Paper No,7160,1999,

Shieifer, Andrei, Inefficient Markets. An Introduction to Behavioral Finance,Clarendon Lecture Series (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000),

Shieifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny, "The limits of Arbitrage," Journal of Finance,LIII (1997), 35-55,

Snowdon, Brian, and Howard Vane, Conversations with Leading Economists.Interpreting Modern Macroeconomics (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar, 1999),

Page 35: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL

WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS? 1409

Taylor, John, "Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contrsicts" Journal of PoliticalEconomy, LXXXVIII (1980), 1-24., "Staggered Price and Wage Setting in Macroeconomics," Chapter 15 inHandbook of Macroeconomics, John Taylor and Michael Woodford, eds.(Amsterdam: Elsevier B. V., 1999), pp. 1009-1050.

Wicksell, Knut, Interest and Prices (London: Macmillan, 1898), first published inGerman in 1898.

Woodford, Michael, "Revolution and Evolution in Twentieth-Century Macroeconom-ics," mimeo, 1999.

Page 36: WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER …hassler-j.iies.su.se/courses/riksbank/Papper/BlanchardQJE2000.pdf · WHAT DO WE KNOW ABOUT MACROECONOMICS THAT FISHER AND WICKSELL