41
Federal Income Taxation 12/5/12 10:50 PM Introduction: Setting the Table Sources of Tax Law: Internal Revenue Code/ Title 26 of the US Code o Positive law Treasury Regulations o Not positive law, but explanations of the Code provisions o Highly regarded Revenue Procedures o Does not interpret or explain the code, but is there to do the mechanical calculations required by the IRS (e.g. inflation adjustments) Revenue Rulings o Advisory opinions o Designed to look and read like judicial opinions but without the names of any taxpayers o Released by Treasury lawyers o Usually given a great deal of deference Private Letter Rulings o A taxpayer writes to the IRS laying out the facts of their case and a question; the IRS answers that question o IRS says these deserve no deference because each decision only applies to that taxpayer; in practice, a PLR in your favor is very persuasive. Common Law o Intent of Congress is especially important for tax Committee Reports are often used to determine congressional intent

…  · Web view · 2014-11-19Introduction: Setting the Table. Sources of Tax Law: Internal Revenue Code/ Title 26 of the US Code. Positive law. Treasury Regulations. Not positive

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Federal Income Taxation 12/5/12 10:50 PM

Introduction: Setting the Table

Sources of Tax Law:

Internal Revenue Code/ Title 26 of the US Code

o Positive law

Treasury Regulations

o Not positive law, but explanations of the Code provisions

o Highly regarded

Revenue Procedures

o Does not interpret or explain the code, but is there to do the mechanical

calculations required by the IRS (e.g. inflation adjustments)

Revenue Rulings

o Advisory opinions

o Designed to look and read like judicial opinions but without the names of any

taxpayers

o Released by Treasury lawyers

o Usually given a great deal of deference

Private Letter Rulings

o A taxpayer writes to the IRS laying out the facts of their case and a question; the IRS

answers that question

o IRS says these deserve no deference because each decision only applies to that

taxpayer; in practice, a PLR in your favor is very persuasive.

Common Law

o Intent of Congress is especially important for tax

Committee Reports are often used to determine congressional intent

o Because the issues are statutory rather than constitutional, Congress rather than

SCOTUS has the last rule.

o Substance dominates form

Without this people would start to believe that if they had good lawyers

they could basically get away with tax evasion; this doctrine says the courts

are going to call BS where they see it, technicality or not.

Definitions:

Tax base: the “thing” that is taxed (e.g. income, property, sales, consumption, estates,

wealth)

Tax incidence: who really pays any given tax?

Tax gap: the difference between taxes legally owed and taxes actually paid

o Can only have estimates, but approx. $500B more could be collected if people paid

all the taxes they owe.

Cross reporting: two parties with opposing interests reporting tax-relevant data to the IRS

o The average worker is a classic example: employer and employee are at opposing

sides and are both reporting the income to the IRS

Income effects: changes in behavior induced by the fact that the tax reduces the money

available to the tax payer

Substitution effects: changes in the behavior that arise from a change in the relative

attractiveness of different commodities or activities

Head tax: a tax of an equal dollar amount on everyone, or at least each person above a

certain age

Ability to pay: the attribute that might justify requiring some people to pay more tax than

others.

o The broader view looks at people’s material well-being without regard to liquidity

Marginal utility of income: the wealthier you are, the less each dollar lost to the tax

collected diminishes your well-being.

Endowment or wage rate (the rate at which one can earn money): the opportunity to earn

wealth whether or not exercised.

o This is so as to avoid possibly discouraging the exercise of wage-earning ability to

avoid paying taxes.

Cash-flow consumption tax: simply an income tax with a deduction for savings and with the

inclusion in the tax base of amounts drawn down from savings and used for consumption, as

well as amounts borrowed for current consumption.

o Seen in IRAs (individual retirement accounts) – amounts set aside in an IRA for

retirement are currently deductible in computing the amount subject to taxation

and amounts withdrawn from the IRA account are included in the income in the

year of withdrawal.

Imputed income: the value of goods and services provided to oneself.

“To the extent”: by the amount

Stock variable: variable whose value is not determined with reference to the passage of time

Flow variable: variable whose value is determined with reference to the passage of time

Tax evasion is illegal

Tax avoidance is legal

Tax Facts:

Allowed by the 16th Amendment, adopted in 1913: “The Congress shall have the power o lay

and collect taxes on incomes, from whatever source derived, without apportionment among

the several States and without regard to any census or enumeration.”

Income taxes (corporate and individual) are expected to produce 56% of total federal

revenues

Income taxes are also an important source of revenue for state government

The most common filing statuses are consistently “unmarried individual” and “married

individuals filing a joint return”

In theory, income taxes should produce both income and substitution effects

Using the tax system to deliver a subsidy allows its advocates to label it a “tax cut” rather

than a “spending increase”

Major Areas of Cheating:

o Cash businesses: small businesses are a huge part of the tax gap (big businesses

have incentives to be careful with accounting; the largest corporations are under

permanent audit)

o Underreporting of gains on securities – there is no cross reporting on the difference

between bought and sold

Tax Expenditures (refer to chart on Table 1-2 on p.17)

o Tax expenditure budget: certain tax benefits are equated with direct subsidies

o General approach is to identify various exclusions, deductions, deferrals, and credits

that are seen as departures from a neutral concept on income taxation; then to

figure out the cost of these special provisions; then to attribute these costs t various

budget functions.

o This budget wholly ignores features of the current income tax that are arguably less

favorable to taxpayers than pure income tax.

o The net effect is the same if you have a subsidy or if you collect more, then spend

Tax Law:

What happens when people violate the tax law?

99% of actions and punishments are civil

It is very rare for people to actually go to prison for tax evasion, the mens rea is very high.

The punishment often boils down to how long it took you to correct the mistake and how

big the mistake was

o Interest ≠ punishment, it is just putting you in the position you would have been in

had you paid.

Litigation is called “tax controversy”

o Always US v. Taxpayer

o Standard: preponderance of the evidence

o OIC – offer in compromise = a settlement

Jurisdictional Framework:

o Courts of original tax jurisdiction: US District Court, US Tax Court (created by

Congress under Art. I power), US Court of Claims

o If you want to appeal a Tax Court ruling, you go to the US Court of Appeals for your

circuit

o If you want to appeal a Claims Court ruling, you go to the Federal Circuit and then

SCOTUS

What is Income?

Y = C + S (Y is income, C is consumption, S is saving)

Haig-Simons: Y = C + ∆W (∆W is change in net worth) (each defined in terms of market value during

some specified accounting period)

Some characteristics of income

Noncash benefits

Why tax?

o Horizontal equity (treat likes alike)

o Our economy would move toward a barter system if noncash/ fringe benefits

weren’t taxed

Old Colony

o An employer’s payment of federal income tax on an employee’s behalf is income

o It’s the reason we have withholding – the employer Is paying on your behalf

o Grossing up: negotiating with your employer to pay income taxes – you have a

target after tax net income

N = G(1-t) where N = net pay; G = gross pay; t = tax rate

G = N/(1-t)

If you cross an upper limit of a bracket with the gross income, it becomes

more complex

Bengalia (p. 52)

o Tax years in question are the worst years of the Great Depression

o Bengalia was the manager for 2 hotels – he and his wife lived and took all their

meals at one of the hotels

o He was supposedly on constant duty and that is why he needed to live at the hotel

For the convenience of the employer

o Legal distinction: if you receive compensation that is valuable, there is a distinction

if it is for the convenience of the employer, it is not taxable

Comes from Reg. §77.

o Dissent: claims that the employee cared enough about living in the hotel that he

negotiated about it; Majority says the employer said he had to live at the hotel and

that’s good enough.

o Dissent looks at the fact that he’s managing multiple properties and can’t be at all

places at once, therefore convenience of the employer argument fails

o Both sides read “convenience” to mean requirement

o BTA creates common law by following the Reg – “convenience of the employer” test

is now law

Dissent holds that the question is really whether or not he benefitted from

the room and board. It doesn’t matter whether or not it was for the

convenience of the employer – the Bengalias received something with

market value.

Valuation under Bengalia

o If the dissent had won, the Bengalias would litigate the value of the benefit

conferred

Try for wholesale and not retail prices

Objective valuation of the horizontally equitable transaction – how much

would a 3P in an arm’s length transaction have had to pay for all the

Bengalias received?

Statutory aftermath

o §119: modifies the Bengalia ruling a little: the meals must be eaten on the business

premises; the lodging on business premises must be a requirement of employment.

More specific requirements are enumerated.

Illustration of §119(d)(2) in notes 17/9

o §132: Congress says the tax treatment of noncash benefits needs to be regularized

because it’s chaos – the give a list of fringe benefits that are not going to be taxed

Loss aversion

De minimis fringe is the default hail Mary to try to exclude

All have a non-discrimination rule

If you have a non-excludable fringe benefit, you use market value for

valuation

Look to Regs §1.61-21

Safe harbor rules: rough justice situation – you may not get FMV right, but if

you follow the rules, at least you won’t crash into the rocks

o §125: Cafeteria plans

Has a lot in common with §132, but must be properly organized into a plan

to be labeled as such

Doctrine of constructive receipt: substance over form rule

You don’t have to be taxed on the substance of the cafeteria plan because

you can always opt for cash instead

List is at the bottom of CB p. 62

“Use it or lose it” rule is a limitation on fringe benefits

o Turner

Family of four who won a radio contest for steamship tickets from New York

to Buenos Aires. Switched his two first class tickets for four couch tickets to

Rio for a small change fee

They wouldn’t have been able to take a trip like this but for the contest

The question is the value of the tickets to the Turners – neither IRS nor

Turners call it income.

Modern rule: objective valuation – not subjective because tax

administration should not “be based on anything so whimsical”

There is no Turner Rule

o Some unusual forms of income:

Realization:

Professors get free text books – no taxes unless they are turned into

cash

Catching historic home run balls – if you catch and keep or give

away, no tax; if you sell it, tax.

Specific employees can get freebies but turn them down – it is

income if you use the tickets

To solve the taxation problem for gifts/ promotions, you just need to gross

up

The other sure way to avoid taxation is not taking the prize

Imputed Income

Windfalls and Gifts

Glenshaw Glass (p. 78)

o Both companies received punitive damages and compensatory damages

o Compensatory damages are definitely taxable because they would have received

that income had they not been wronged

o In the lower courts, the taxpayer won against the IRS

o SCOTUS believed Congress was very broad in its definition of income and counted

the punitive damages as taxable income

Explicit exclusions: Gifts - §102 o Duberstein (p.83) (two consolidated cases trying to define gift)

Duberstein and Berman: professional relationship; D buys from B but often

offers advice on who might be a good customer when they don’t buy. B

gives D a Cadillac as a gift in recognition for all his help with extra clients. B

writes it off as a business expense even though he told D it was a gift.

Stanton: executive overseeing Trinity Church’s financial and real estate

holdings. He quits/ is forced out and the Church gives him a year’s salary

called a “gratuity” but says it’s for services rendered. Church says it’s giving

him the money because it likes him.

SCOTUS says in defining gift for tax purposes, they are going to use the

colloquial meaning.

It is the donor’s intent that controls

Gifts are when you don’t get something in return – can’t be a deal,

not services rendered or an anticipated benefit

It is from “detached and disinterested generosity” (p. 86)

IRS wants to make a per se rule that businesses can’t give gifts; SCOTUS

rejects this, and they won’t go so far as to say that the deduction by

businesses of the purported gifts is dispositive in making them non-gifts.

SCOTUS believes the donee should not have its tax consequences

based on what the donor did – instead it’s dependent on donor’s

intent

Duberstein: definitively not a gift.

Stanton: more complex because of the lower court’s ruling of “just a gift” –

SCOTUS willing to give a lot of deference but the trial court need to at least

explain. Stanton wins on remand.

Makes trial court’s decisions essentially non-reviewable

§102(c) would make Stanton lose automatically

§274(b) would make Duberstein less likely to get the gift because Berman

would have only been able to deduct $25

o Harris (p. 91)

Question of whether the money he gives the twins is income or gifts

Harris was convicted of criminal tax evasion by the lower court

If Kritzik wasn’t paying them income then he should have paid a gift tax

Threshold issue for Conley is if she was required to file income tax returns if

this was her only money – then, because it’s criminal, did she have the mens

rea? The court finds it was a gift and not income, therefore she didn’t need

to file the forms

Court finds the USG didn’t meet its burden

Harris: again, mens rea is lacking – the correct question is the donor’s

intent, so if Harris believed K loved her and that’s why he gave her the

money, it’s a gift. Court dismissed criminal charges.

General takeaway: for longer term relationships with a mistress where

money is exchanged but not on a transactional basis, those tend to be gifts.

If money is the exchanged each time sex is exchanged, it’s income

(prostitution)

It doesn’t matter how Harris or Conley felt, it only matters how they

believe/ have reason to believe K felt about them (Duberstein: donor’s

intent)

o Tips and unusual gifts:

Ordinary tips: IRS issued Regs – tips are income in the ordinary course of

business, but they created a safe harbor (10% of gross receipts), but the

employer has to provide gross receipts for when the employee worked, so

they can get their safe harbor income

Gambling tips to dealers, etc at casinos are income, not gifts, because the

intent is not generosity, it’s hope for luck

Welfare payments are not income

§117: Scholarships: in almost every case there is a zero bracket question/

issue

o Taft (p. 104)

Taft maintains she only owes $3000, the difference between the price of the

stocks when she received them and when she sold them. IRS says it’s

$4000, the difference between the price when bought and when sold –

doesn’t matter who bought them or that they changed hands

The 16th Amendment does not prevent “surrogate taxation” – collecting

taxes from one person on another’s behalf

Whoever has the asset, if they sell it, they face the tax

consequences

Carryover (substituted) basis/ transfer basis

Gain = proceeds - adjusted basis

Basis is usually the purchase price

§1015:

You take the basis from whoever gave you the gift

Except if the basis is greater than FMV at the time of the gift

(so that people won’t give loss properties in tax strategic

ways)

Example:

o Donor paid $1500; FMV at date of gift: $1000

o If recipient sells later for $800

800 – 1000 = -200 (discourages the gifting

of loss properties)

o If recipient sells later for $1600

1600 – 1500 = 100 (even though there was

originally a loss, the exception is only used

to calculate if selling for a loss

o If recipient sells later for $1200

Answer is 0 gain because §1015 math

doesn’t work – paradox

If high tax bracket guy has a gain – lower tax bracket gift

If high tax bracket guy has a loss, he can realize it and absorb it

better than lower tax bracket guy.

o Transfers at Death

Vertical equity question: you need to collect the same amount of taxes but

you might be collection them from a different set of people

Current state of the law:

§1014

Inheritance tax ≠ estate tax

Base is the recipient – amount of money received from

dead people – US does not have that

Estate: base is measured by money left after creditors have

been paid – measured/ taxed at giver rather than recipient

level

§1014(a)(1) treats you as if you’d paid FMV that day – death is not a

realization event; “step up in basis at death”

Means the decedent wants to keep shares that have gone

up in value and sell shares that have gone down

Decedent can borrow against unrealized gains

All kinds of generous estate planning opportunities built

into the tax rules

Currently:

$5M per spouse exception

35% bracket above that (positive taxable estate)

Default:

$1M per spouse exception

45% and 55% brackets

Policy rationales:

Why have an estate tax?

The most progressive of US tax laws

Allows for lower rates on other things

Acts as a back up capital gains tax

Encourages high wealth people to give to charity

Helps reduce the transmission of dynastic wealth

Why collect the tax upon death?

It is not a tax upon death because 99.7% of people die

without paying it

We don’t tax this during life because there can be reversals

of fortune in life – can assess once and for all ability to pay

Unreasonable attacks:

Double taxation: taxing the same basis twice – it is not

about a dollar being taxed, it is about an activity being taxed

Breaks up family firms and businesses – no evidence

Death tax and therefore immoral

Plausible attacks:

Administratively burdensome

Wrong to tax wealth that has accumulated from saved

income (moral argument)

Taxing wealth creates bad incentives

o Sometimes when you tax things, you encourage

them – “the income effect”

o Compared to what? Vertical equity question –

income v. wealth

Alternatives:

Get rid of estate tax, but also eliminate §1014 and declare

death a realization event – this would collect about 50%

more revenue than the estate tax

Get rid of estate tax, elimitae §1014, but don’t make death

a realization (you only have to pay if you sell the stocks) –

this would be a revenue loser

Loans and Discharge of Indebtedness

Discharge of indebtedness is the same as cancellation of debt

Loans are not income

o Selling bonds is borrowing money

o Buying bonds is lending money

DoI income = the reduction in the amount to be paid by borrower to lender §61(a)(12)

When a business borrows and issues bonds and must pay interest on those bonds – the

interest is deductible as a normal cost of doing business

o Not deductible for individuals

Kirby Lumber (p. 147)

o Issued $12M in bonds in July 1923; later than year, they extinguished $1M of

principle by paying $826k

o IRS claims the $138k is DoI income

o Court says “accession to income in the year” – income is income, this is not a tough

question

o Kerbaugh Empire muddies the waters because it seems Kriby’s refenence brings in

the overall story/ fate of the enterprise matter

In order to answer the DoI question, you need to know what happens to the

business

Courts have not treated this as true. They make Kriby as simple as it seems.

Fate of of enterprise is irrelevant.

Was a profitable exchange on the currency exchange market, there was no

DoI (Kerbaugh)

§108o This section is explicitly excluded from §61(a)(12)

o Insolvency (defined in §108(d)(3): if you have a negative net worth), you may not

even know if you’re insolvent, as opposed to bankrupt.

o Qualified farm indebtedness §108(g) – Congress loves farms

o Qualified principal residence indebtedness – added in response to the housing

collapse because so many people were foreclosed upon. Really almost all of these

people were insolvent anyway, but this now takes precedence over the insolvency

solution

o (e)(5): purchase money debt reduction for solvent debtor treated as a price

reduction

I lend you money to buy something from me

You come back and tell me you can’t pay the full price, if I allow a lower

price, the agreed upon payment is treated as the original purchase price

o (f) student loans: as long as you follow certain rules, you can pay less than you owe

without DoI income tax.

Zarin (p. 150)

o Basic tax treatment of gambling:

You can never deduct net losses

You do get taxed on net winnings

Winnings/ losses on either side of the calendar year cannot be offset (if you

won $1M at 11:58 on Dec 31 and you lose $1.2M on Jan 1 – you get taxed

one the $1M and can’t offset with the loss.

o Z was $3.435M in debt which he settled for $500k; the IRS says the difference of

$2.935M is DoI income.

o Majority finds this does not represent DoI income in two ways:

Claim that this was not indebtedness at all (even though their definition of

indebtedness is taken from §108(d) and that plainly states it does not apply

to §61)

The fact that Z paid them $500k undermines the idea that he didn’t

owe them money

Property analysis: Casino chips are not property

Only USG can create money

Claim this was like the negotiated price of a product (negotiation fixes value)

$3.4M was never what was owed because the parties agreed and

accepted $500k, therefore that’s what was always owed and there

is no DoI income.

Liquidated damages – the amount was known; unliquidated

damages – the amount was not known

The majority acts like this distinction doesn’t matter theat

whatever the settlement is is the correct amount and

always was – this is not true.

Gain on sale of a home

Old rule, repealed in 1997: §1034 – could exclude all gain if you buy a house with a higher

price within 2 years; at age 55, there was a one time exclusion up to $125k

New rule: §121o $250k/ 500k exclusion (single/ joint) “every 2 years”

o Gains in excess of exclusion amount are taxed as capital gains (15%)

o Only applies to principal residences (totality of the evidence for determining

principal residence) – can only have one principal residence at a time

Safe harbors (§121(c)(2)(B)

o Unforeseen circumstances

Multiple births

Divorce

Inability to afford the residence

Adult child moving back in

o Preference for another location is NOT excludable

o The exclusion is not 250/500 though, it is:

N. of months as principal residence/ 24 months = allowable exclusion/

250k/500k

§121(f): election to have section not apply

o If you plan to sell multiple properties, you should elect not to deduct the smaller

gain

o It’s a planning tool

No deduction for losses on the sale

o You don’t want to encourage people to sell their house at a loss for tax purposes

Congress sees houses as piggy banks – unless it grows by too much, it’s tax free

Perverse incentives

o If you have a vacation home, you have incentive to turn it into your principal

residence for §121 purposes

o Planning which home to take a deduction on

o If you’re in an expensive region during a boom, you are incentivized to just jump

from one expensive house to another because they were at or near the exclusion

mark.

Annual accounting and its consequences

Sanford & Brooks

o Dredged the Delaware River

o S&B stopped work; USG says they won’t pay for any of the work done so far because

the k is breached

S&B hit rock on the bottom of the riverbed, that breached the warranty

In 1920, S&B wins its suit against USG – they are awarded $192k, which

includes their work and interest (the interest is definitely income)

o S&B argues that the payment for work just makes them whole, it’s not income, it’s

just counterbalancing their losses in 1913, 15 and 16

o SCOTUS distinguishes between transactional and annual accounting

Transactional: you don’t determine taxability until the transaction is

completed

Annual: you just account for each year’s revenue

o SCOTUS holds that when you receive money in a year, it is taxable in that year

That is what Congress meant to do – not saying it was the right choice, just

that it was their choice

o Huge horizontal inequity

o S&B is a constitutional challenge

We never earned income, so you can’t charge us income tax

SCOTUS says they can

Congressional reaction:

o Refundable or negative taxes: Congress decided not to pursue this option. Instead,

they act as if business expenses are much higher than they are.

Accelerated depreciation schedules: in no way reflect reality but that’s the

purpose.

o §172: net operating loss deduction

If you find you’ve got a loss in a given year, it takes your taxes down to zero

Says you can take your loss and utilize it to offset gains in another year. You

can either go back 2 years or forward 20 years

Supposed to allow businesses to reflect how well/ poorly it is

actually doing over its life rather than over a year

(d)(3) says you can’t include personal exemptions

(d)(4) says you can’t include non-business deductions – it’s designed to help

businesses

(b)(3) gives you two options:

Go back to years then forward until you run out of money

(sequentially) – default option

Only go forward

North American Oil Consol. (p. 132)

o Trying to pay taxes early because the tax rate went up substantially

o NAO drills and extracts oil on USG-owned land

o USG sues for ouster, receiver holds the money pending the outcome of suit; in 1916

NAO is awarded $172k, but USG continues appeals until 1922 when they lose.

o IRS sues NAO for 1917 returns, NAO had amended its 1916 returns in 1918 and filed

them appropriately

o BTA says 1916 is the right ear and the receiver should pay the taxes; Appeals says

1917 is the right year and it’s taxable to NAO – SCOTUS says it’s not taxable to the

receiver in this case (the receiver was an unimportant middleman) – it is income for

NAO.

o It’s not income in 1916 because the suit was ongoing and its outcome uncertain.

NAO is trying to make an accrual-like statement, but court finds both the cash and

the accrual transactions took place in 1917.

o If USG had won in 1922, NAO could have taken a deduction for the award

o Two part test: (harsh rule, similar to S&B) (p. 134)

Claim of right – receives without restriction as to its disposition, he has

received income, even though it might be taken away later

Cash

§1341: Claim of right

o You don’t have to worry about statute of limitations

o Basically is the exact opposite of Lewis

Lewis (p. 136)

o Lewis receives a $22k bonus in 1944, then he realizes the mistake and pays back

$11k in 1946. He wants to take the loss reduction from his 1944 taxes; IRS says no,

he can deduct from 1946

o Lewis wins below, but NAO test clearly states IRS is right (claim of right and cash)

o Douglas’ dissent appeals to equality; he says you can either be final or be right, and

in this case they can be right.

Embezzler is allowed to deduct restored income if it’s in the same year – but if you don’t get

caught until a later year, there is no deduction

o Tax incentive to fess up if things look like they’re going downhill

Income averaging: would have people keep track on an ongoing basis so that if there is

something that affects other years it’s taken into account

o Lifetime income averaging: cumulative income over the whole earning lifetime

o Based on a concept of horizontal equity – because some years fluctuate income, so

people may be treated as rich when they aren’t or poor when they aren’t

o Vertical equity also implicated

Tax benefit rule (p. 139)

o Deduction in an earlier year that later becomes clear you didn’t deserve

o §111 want to rule out the worst injustice

If you got any benefit at all §111(a) isn’t going to help you

o There are times when a deduction is alive in an NOL - §111(c)

If it’s alive, you don’t get the benefit of TBR

o Administrative convenience rule: taxpayer takes deduction he shouldn’t have, the

question is when to take it and how much to deduct

Alice Phelan (p. 140) – just include the amount you deducted before

Claim of right doctrine:

o NAO says income in year received and under claim of right is taxable

o Loss in an earlier year, income in a later year? S&B court says tough luck

Congress passes §172: NOLs (2 years back, 20 years forward)

o Income in an earlier year and loss in later year? Lewis court says tough luck

Congress passes §1341: choice of deduction now or recomputation of an

earlier year

o Deduction in an earlier year, restoration in a later year?

Congress passes §111 (a) if no earlier tax reduction, then no later reduction;

(c) keep track of NOLs

When is income taxed?

Timing questions having to do with earning income but not having to pay tax on it yet

Why delay/ defer paying taxes?

Procrastination

Liquidity restraints

Time value of money: taxpayer has the use in the interim of the amount that would

otherwise have been paid in taxes

o You will always gain if you van put off paying your taxes and aren’t charged interest

o FV = PV(1+r)n (r = interest rate; n = number of years; FV = future value; PV = present

value) PV=FV/(1+r)n

Rule of 72 (doubling rule): how long will it take your money to double if interest rate stays

the same: 72/ I (where I = interest rate expressed as a percentage)

Why have realization and recognition doctrines?

Liquidity

Valuation difficulties (e.g. no one really knows how much their house is worth until they sell

it)

Nature of the asset is the same

Capital mobility (even though you’ve experienced a gain, the IRS does not want to stop you

from reinvesting in the best area for the general economy)

The realization doctrine

Income is realized when you sell an asset for cash

Eisner v. Macomber (p. 197)

o Constitution was amended in 1913 and 1916 with Revenue Amendments (16th

Amendment)

o Macomber has 2200 shares with a par value of $100/ share; FMV of between $360 –

380/ share

o Stock split: she was issued another 1100 shares, but the value was now between

$234 – 260/ share

o There is no change in wealth, it is simply a bookkeeping matter

o Government wanted to impose a tax on the par value of the new shares from the

stock split

o USG argument:

Stock dividend is income because it increased her wealth (clearly wrong,

she’s no richer)

Stock dividend is a realization event (Brandeis agrees)

Income that has not been taxed can taxed at any time (correct at the time,

but not true now)

o Court says income is a term of usage, not a term of art

They latch onto the word “derived” in “from any source derived” – they

decide it means for separate use and benefit

They focus on “separate” and say the stocks are the wealth – they would say

it’s not income until it’s realized income.

o Brandeis’ dissent: Macomber’s lawyers admitted the functional equivalent of the

stock dividend would be a realization event, therefore the stock dividend is a

realization event.

o It is not unconstitutional to tax unrealized gains

Under Macomber:

o Accrual based would mean Macomber would have to pay taxes every year on her

earnings

o Instead, Congress chose to create a realization requirement statute

Reasons for realization:

o Liquidity

o Valuation difficulties

o Divisibility – if you have property that taxes would force you to sell, general

speaking, you alter the nature of the asset if you divide it

o Variability – fluctuations in value would cause payments to go back and forth

between taxpayer and government if there was taxation every year

Helvering v. Bruun (p. 208) – non-sale realization event

o Realization is more than just selling something for money

o Lease for commercial property begins in 1915 and is supposed to go for 99 years

o In 1929, the old building is knocked down and a new building worth ~ $50k more

than the old one is built (income of $50k but not taxable to Bruun because he didn’t

have access)

o In 1933, lessee defaults and Bruun takes possession of the improved lot

o The Court holds that realization doesn’t just have to be a cash sale of assets

transaction

If it’s not a cash transaction then you need to look for “meaningful

moments”

Gain may occur as a result of:

Sale of an asset

Exchange of property

Payment of taxpayer’s indebtedness

Relief from liability

Other profit realized from the completion of a transaction

o Court holds Bruun had a “meaningful moment” in getting his land back with at $62k

improvement – it was a realization event and therefore was taxable in 1933 when

he got access.

Bruun Aftermath:

o §109: a direct reaction and a reversal of the Court’s decision

Buildings intended as rent have to be treated differently than a Bruun-type

building §1.61-8o §1019: you don’t get to adjust your basis upward as if you had taxes

o See chart on p. 212

Woodsam Associates (p. 213)

o Mrs. Wood bought the property with a mortgage that had recourse to her personal

assets. Years later, she refinances the mortgage without personal recourse.

o She calls that a realization event because the only thing the bank can take now is

the house (a $100k gain on selling to the bank)

o When she sells later she claims her basis is what she should have been taxed before

and she now has a loss

o Court basically says “you’ve got to be kidding” – the house was clearly hers and not

the bank’s – there is a limit to non-sale realization events

Cottage Savings (p. 216)

o S&L crisis

o Cottage Savings wants to deduct a loss – normally, to realize a loss you just sell your

assets at a loss. They have to book their loss and report it to the FHLBB, which

cannot then ignore their insolvency. Regulators don’t want the S&Ls to be insolvent

but they want them to get the tax advantage of deducting losses. FHLBB issues

Memorandum R-49 to allow S&Ls to recognize tax losses but not to properly report

them, exposing insolvency.

Allows asset swapping for “substantially identical” mortgages – identical in

substance

Ten criteria for classification (p. 217)

o Is this a realization event? (They swapped baskets of substantially identical

mortgages in order to realize a loss) §1001

Is this a disposition of property?

Is there a material difference requirement?

If so, is there a material difference in this transaction?

o Treasury Regs: In order to be a realization event, the assets must be materially

different (since 1934)

Differ in economic substance

o Court says yes, there is a material difference requirement

IRS says you look at what the regulator (FHLBB) says: they say the assets

must be substantially identical therefore they cannot be materially different

IRS also looks at the evaluation of the interests by the secondary mortgage

market

o Court finds the IRS’s test “complex and unworkable”; they find that different =

materially different

“distinct legal entitlements” satisfies the materially different test – as long

as the entitlements are not identical, the realization event Is allowed (which

is good for determining valuation)

o §1031: Like-kind doctrine – these properties can be very different, they don’t need

to be substantially identical

Court says if they used the IRS’s reading, §1031 would be moot and

surplusage

o §165 discussion: in the court below, the IRS won by arguing Cottage Saving’s losses

were not in the taxable year – Court is correct here.

o Dissent:

Look at what a rational investor would think looking at this investment/

basket of mortgages

“materially different” doesn’t matter to investors

FHLBB created this rule so as not to be indifferent to which basket

they had

In this case, the parties didn’t even keep track of the borrowers, the

borrowers kept paying the same rate

If there was a material difference, someone would have cared!

Cottage Savings Aftermath:

o “Hair trigger” standard: you love it if you want something to happen quickly and

easily; you don’t if you want to be careful/ deliberate

o Debt workouts: where distressed borrowers and their creditors agreed to certain

modifications of the underlying debt instruments.

Do they have to be treated as a sale or other disposition and count as a

recognition event post-CS?

o Taxpayer savings

o This decisions glories in form over substance – it set a very bad present

o Treasury Dept. had to clean up the mess “CS Regulation”

DOI income

They basically overrule CS

New TOA: “significant modification” – legal definition

Regs had to dial back the hair trigger

Nonrecognition provisions

Congress steps in and says, under certain circumstances, you can avoid paying taxes on

Haig-Simons income and realized gains.

Realization v. Recognition

o Realization: did something of significance happen to this property?

Sale or other disposition

o Non-recognition: you don’t have to pay tax yet if:

Realization transaction doesn’t generate cash

Gain/ loss might be difficult to measure (valuation problem)

Nature of asset is not significantly changed

Want to avoid discouraging mobility

§1031: Like-kind Exchanges – not substantially identical, but alike enough to merit non-

taxation at the time

o Exceptions:

Stock in trade or other property held primarily for sale

Stocks, bonds or notes

Other securities or evidences of indebtedness or interest

Interests in partnerships

Certificates of trust or beneficial interests

Choses in action

o What does it mean?

References nature or character, not quality or grade

Reg. §1.1031(a)-1: it is when the nature or property is the same (gives

examples)

Transfers incident to marriage and divorce

Transfers of cash (alimony) v. transfers of property

o Transfers of cash (child support) treated differently

Davis (p. 291)

o Divorcing spouses – husband transfers ownership of stock that has appreciated in

value during his ownership – is that a taxable event?

o IRS says yes, he was buying his rights out of the marriage – it had a lot of value for

him.

o He is buying inchoate marital rights – Davis says yes, but because they are inchoate

that value is unknown

It’s hard to know what she would have gotten in divorce court but we know

what he paid, so that is the value of getting his rights back

o Davis has a taxable income in the year of the sale/ transfer of stock and his basis. It

is NOT a gift.

o Treat transfers of property as a realization event for the one transferring to get

something in return.

o What is Mrs. Davis’ basis?

The FMV of the stocks the day they were transferred to her.

If Davis had won, Treasury would not have gotten its money, so Mrs. Davis’

basis would be whatever Davis’ had been – treat it like a gift with carryover

basis.

§1041: mirrors §1015 – a non-recognition rule that treats the divorce property transfer as a

gift

Farid-Es-Sultaneh (Mercer) (p. 296)

o Pre-nup requires her to relinquish all rights to support and other marital rights (she

cannot sue him in divorce court). Mercer gives up “really inchoate marital rights” –

she gives them up even though she doesn’t yet own them because it’s pre-nuptual

o Pre-nup identifies the stock as a “gift in consideration of . . .”

o When Kresge transferred his shares, they were worth $10/ share (he had a basis of

$.15), when she sold them they were $19/share

She claims a $9/ share gain; IRS wants her to have an $18.85/ share gain

o IRS says this looks like a transaction contract rather than a gift

o Court find that the IRS should have taxed Kresge $9.85/ share when he transferred

them but they didn’t, now Mercer has a basis of only $10/ share.

o Grossly inadequate consideration – she sold ~$125M of really inchoate marital

rights for less than $1M. If looking at this as a contract issue, this is important but

the rights are really inchoate, so they might have become non-existent without this

agreement.

o The rest of the taxpaying public did get cheated, but not beasue or Mercer, because

the IRS did not tax Kresge when he transferred the shares to her.

What’s wrong with the Davis/ Mercer logic?

o Tracking basis becomes more and more absurd

o What are inchoate marital rights? Who has them? What are they worth?

Look at chart in class notes 5/11 ***

How can taxable income and taxes be reduced?

Hierarchy of tax reduction techniques (from most to least taxpayer friendly – keep in mind that above

the line is always better than below the line, and both are available for the last four):

Credit (refundable is better than non-refundable)

Expensing – deduct the cost of things in the year in which they happen

Depreciation (accelerated methods preferred)

Addition to basis

Nonrecoverable

Personal deductions

Zero bracket is more complex

Extraordinary medical expenses

o §213: sets a high threshold (7.5% of AGI) and only deductible to the extent that it

exceeds 7.5%

o Can plan for extraordinary medical expenses with a flex account, but if you don’t use

it, you lose it

o Employer can deduct employee’s health insurance and the employee doesn’t need

to count it as income

o Taylor (p. 351)

Has some allergy for which him MD told him not to mow the lawn. He hired

a service and tries to deduct the cost under §213.

§262 says no personal deductions and IRS finds that §262 trumps §231

Taylor’s burden to prove that he wouldn’t have hired someone to mow the

lawn anyway – he didn’t meet that burden

The court is trying to police a very blurry line due to the very broad

definition of “medical care” in §213

Just because an MD prescribes it doesn’t mean it counts as a

medical expense

o Ochs (p. 352)

Mother is very sick, so they sent their children away to boarding school and

tried to deduct tuition as a medical expense. The tuition was roughly ¼ of

the family’s income, so they were unlikely to have sent this children away

but for the mother’s illness.

IRS says the tuition was a personal family expense and is non-deductible

The school is replacing the mother’s caregiving role

The whole family benefited, therefore it was not a medical expense

Dissent:

Says the ruling seems to indicate the expenses for sending the

mother away from the children rather than vice versa would have

been deductible.

Judges should use their common sense

Says test should be:

Would the taxpayer, considering his income and living

standard, normally spend money in this way regardless of

illness?

Has he enjoyed such luxuries or services in the past?

Did a competent physician prescribe this specific expense as

an indispensible part of treatment?

Has the taxpayer followed the physician’s advice in the most

economical way possible?

Are the so-called medical expenses over and above what

the patient would have had to pay anyway for his living

expenses (that is room, board, etc.)?

Is the treatment closely geared to a particular condition and

not just to the patient’s general health or well-being?

Limit the deduction to the least expensive option – for example,

only have the deduction for when the children would have been

around their mother.

Charitable Contributions

o §170: Deductions (for the use of the donor)

(c) defines charitable contributions – donations abroad are not wholly

deductible

(f)(12) used motor vehicles, boats, and airplanes

o §501: Charitable organizations (they don’t have to pay tax)

(c)(3) almost exactly the same as §170 definition

Private inurement restriction

No electioneering

o §527: organization is taxable on the income it receives but the contributions people

give are not taxable

o What happens when the contribution isn’t money:

Capital gain that has been neither realized nor recognized (or just not

recognized)

If the piece of property has been held for more than a year, you can

donate it without realization or recognition (long term capital gain

rule) – can deduct the full fair market value

If held for less than a year, you can only deduct the basis (short

term capital gain)

o Corporations get deductions for charitable giving too, they are very important

sources for charitable giving.

Ottawa Silica Co.

Donated 50 acres to the school district with the expectation that

they’d be able to utilize the roads the school would build.

The local government is a charity under §170(c)(1)

IRS claims it is not a charitable deduction because they did it with

the expectation of a return benefit to such an extent that the

benefit was probably their motivation

Ottawa Silica received more benefit than anyone else in the

community – it was a substantial benefit

Was it quid pro quo?

Relevance of intent? Intent is not required

If a supposed charitable giver receives or expects to receive

substantial benefit

DuVal says the test is not substantial benefit but dominant or primary intent

test

If you fail the test (either DuVal or Ottawa Silica) there is no deduction – it’s

all or nothing

o Private benefits: (for non-businesses)

Not all or nothing like with corporations – there is a partial reduction rule –

you can still deduct the amount of your contribution that didn’t get you a

substantial benefit.

De minimis rule: trivial benefits don’t count (e.g. the swag from PBS

won’t be counted against your deduction)

o Special case for college athletics §170(l)

Universities are basically charging seat licensing fees – donors have to make

a contribution to a scholarship fund in order to get on the list to buy season

tickets

The buyers/ donors can deduct 80% of their contribution even though it’s

clearly a quid pro quo contributions

o Bob Jones University

Has had very limited practical impact on the tax law

Racial bias in education and they want to keep their charitable status

District court says the IRS exceeded its authority by issuing the rule, that it

violates the first amendment . . .

Court of Appeals says charities with §501(c)(3) status must not go against

public policy

Bob Jones argues there is no public policy requirement in the law

SCOTUS finds there has always been an understanding that public policy

benefits are required as part of being a charitable organization

By giving them §501(c)(3) status, we are giving them public money

to play with, therefore they need to not violate public policy – their

charitable deduction implicates all taxpayers.

If the Establishment Clause was brought in as part of public policy, then no

religious organization could be a charitable organization

Powell’s concurrence ends up winning: There must be no doubt that the

charity violates a fundamental public policy (in this case Brown v. Board)

IRS always has the power and authority to make the kinds of decisions made

in this case (denial of §501(c)(3) status based on their interpretation

Also, Congress had the ability to change the IRS’s decision/

interpretation and they didn’t, therefore they agreed with the IRS.

Personal exemptions and credits

Mixed business and personal deductions (open to a lot of fraud)

§162: businesses can deduct the cost of doing business

§212

§262: disallows deduction for personal expenditures

§67: basically transfer §162 to the individual, creates a 2% of AGI threshold – miscellaneous

itemized deductions can be aggregated, except for those listed in (b)

§183: hobbies

o Nickerson – very fact specific

§280(A): deductablity of the use of one’s home for business use

o Popov

Earned Income Tax Credit (p. 384 – 386)

Office Decoration: Henderson

o She got a bare bones office from the state. She bought a plant and art for her office

and bought a parking spot (for the times she couldn’t use a car service)

o Claimed the office decorations were for the good of both her and her clients

o There needs to be sufficient nexus between petitioner’s expenses and the carrying

on of petitioner’s trade or business in order to qualify for §162 deduction – it must

trump §262 in order to qualify

Must be more than a little helpful in carrying out the business and cannot be

for the personal enjoyment of the taxpayer

o If she was in private practice it would almost always be deductible.

o Court found they were not deductible.

Travel and entertainment expenses

o Rudolph

Reward trip to NYC for TX salesman and his wife.

IRS finds the trip is income – basically a non-cash fringe benefit –

compensation for a job well done (§61). Rudolph gets no deduction.

Primary purpose test: District court found that the primary purpose was

pleasure, as such, it falls under §262 as a personal expense.

Crucial question is whether or not it was related to business

Rudolph claims he was required to go in order to further his career

Court found no compulsion

Harlan basically says §162 can be satisfied without trumping §262

Dissent:

Claims programs like this have no rational connection with services

rendered

There are no earmarks of a sham

Wives:

Currently, §274(m) expressly denies deduction for the dependent’s

travel expenses

This was easily deductible for the company.

Clothing expenses

o Pevsner

Worked at YSL and was required to buy YSL clothing for her job. She wants

to deduct the purchase of the clothes.

Tax Court said yes; 5th Circuit says no.

Three prong test (clothing is deductible if):

Specifically required for employment

Not adaptable for general usage

Not worn for general usage

There is an objective test and a subjective test – the subjective test is not

administratively feasible and it is not fair (horizontally inequitable)

Courts always prefer objective tests

They don’t want the deduction to depend on the taxpayer’s lifestyle

It doesn’t matter that she never wore them outside of work, it matters that

she could

Expenses of Education

o Carroll

Chicago PD detective tried to deduct his college tuition as a business

expense

CPD encouraged its police force to get a college degree – they created

special flexible schedules to allow them to go to class

Carroll was a pre-law, philosophy major

Reg. §1.162 determines whether tuition is a deductible expense

Establishes a more objective test: maintains or improves required

skills for the employment or trade

Must prove it is required, not just encouraged

Court says it is not their job to carve out exceptions – that is for Congress

o Congress’ Response (p. 463)

§222: provides an above the line deduction for “qualifying higher education

expenses” such as tuition, paid by the taxpayer during a taxable year

Subject to notch and cliff: Maximum deduction of $4,000 for

taxpayers with an AGI of $65,000 or less ($130,000 for joint

returns); maximum deduction of $2,000 for taxpayers with an AGI

between $65,000 and $80,000 ($130 – 160,000 for joint returns).

Above that, you cannot deduct.

Depreciation

Definitely a deduction – you want to correctly measure income

Some assets waste over time (they wear out) so you want to measure the decline in value to

better accurately report income.

Expensing means you can deduct all of the costs of a wasting assets as if it would be gone

over a year

§168 - Accelerated Cost Recovery System: allows businesses to understate their income and

be undertaxed (this is a subsidy of investment in manufacturing/ capital assets)

o Deliberately measure it incorrectly so as to hopefully fund further investment and

growth

Determine:

o The useful life of the asset

o The salvage value (what it is worth at the end of its useful life? – generally speaking,

the salvage value is 0)

o Set an allocation method

Allocation Methods:

o Straight line method = (initial cost – salvage value)/ useful life

o Double declining balance method (front loading) = 2(straight line method) but only

on remaining undeducted value

This method recognizes that the asset declines in value in a non-linear way

Congress has chosen this useful life of most things with §168(e)(3)

Investment tax credit directly rather than indirectly subsidized some kind of investment –

basically, if you buy certain assets, the government will give you a tax rebate for a certain

percentage of it.

The Alternative Minimum Tax (§55-58)

A backup tax system

Not indexed to inflation, so Congress has to deal with it annually – needs constant “care and

feeding” or it does crazy things, Congress has gotten less good at regular care and feeding.

It takes a lot tax preferences used to reduce income then subjects that taxpayer to either

26% or 28% taxation – broadens the base

There is a large zero bracket

o $72,450 for couples filing jointly

o $48,450 for singles

Phase out of the zero bracket above $150,000 AMT Income

Two brackets:

o 26% for up to $175,000 AMTI

o 28% above (to the extent that is exceeds $175k AMTI)

AMT = TMT – regular tax, if positive

Preferences giving rise to AMT liability:

o Tax-exempt interest

o Percentage depletion

o Intangible drilling costs

o Research and experimentation costs

o Incentive stock options

o Itemized deductions: The amount of the preference is determined by disallowing

certain itemized deductions, including the deduction for state and local taxes, the

deduction for interest on home equity loans, and certain job related outlays, and by

limiting the deduction for medical expenses to the excess over 10% of AGI (as

opposed to 7.5% for normal tax)

o Credits denied: Certain tax credits, though technically not listed as preferences, are

lost for purposes of computing the AMT. This is accomplished by disallowing these

credits when computing the regular tax as a prelude to computing the AMT. The

limitations are found not in the AMT rules but the rules relating to credits (e.g. §26).

Beginning in 2012, the lost credits will include child and education credits.

o Heads of households

Taxpayers, going in, don’t know whether the AMT will increase their taxes

Klaassen (1999)

o Because they can’t deduct for all their children under the AMT, they qualify for

additional taxation

o They argue their rights (1st and 5th Amendments) are being violated

o AGI = $83,056

After deducting state and local taxes, medical expenses, charity, personal

exemptions, and medical expenses, their taxable income was $34,092 and

their tax bill was $5,111.

AMT doesn’t allow some of those deductions (and changes the allowance

for medical expenses from 10% to 7.5%), so their AMTI was $68,832

o Taxable excess = $68,832 – 45,000 = 23,832

o TMT = .26(23,832) = $6,196

o AMT = TMT – regular tax = $6,196 – 5,111 = 1,035

o Klaassens claim they shouldn’t have to pay because they aren’t the target – court

rejects this because Congress was very specific about who gets hit by the AMT

o Klaassens’ constitutional claims – the law has a general application that happens to

burden some religious dictates but does not violate their free exercise

o Dissent offers Congress a road map for fixing the AMT

12/5/12 10:50 PM

12/5/12 10:50 PM