Warsh Essay WSJ

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/30/2019 Warsh Essay WSJ

    1/2

    The 'Financial Repression' Trap

    In Capitals Worldwide, Policy Makers Deliberately Obscure Market Prices and Prevent InformedJudgments

    By Kevin M. Warsh

    The Wall Street JournalTuesday, December 6, 2011

    http://online.wsj.com/article/SB1000142405297020477040457708018138491792...

    Financial markets are in a precarious place, with European banks and sovereign balancesheets in the cross-hairs. Bank regulators are becoming increasingly aggressive, and euro-zone borrowing costs are rising as the debts of years past are coming due.

    In this environment, policy makers are finding their authority, credibility and firepower beingtested. In turn, they are finding it tempting to pursue "financial repression" -- suppressingmarket prices that they don't like. But this is bad policy, not least because it signalsdiminished faith in the market economy itself.

    Markets are not always efficient, but the market-clearing prices for stocks, bonds, currenciesand other assets (like housing) are critical to informing judgments, in good times and bad.Market-determined asset prices often reveal inconvenient truths. But the sooner the truth isrevealed, the sooner judgments can be rendered and action taken.

    In environments of financial repression, businesses are keener to retrench than recommit theirtime, energy, and capital to new projects. Trillions of dollars of private capital remains on thesidelines. And the private-sector engine that drives prosperity sputters.

    Consider a few recent examples of this policy in practice:

    In Europe, share prices are falling among the largest banks, but these prices are little morethan a symptom. European banks suffer from a lack of capital to offset future losses, and a

    lack of transparency that makes it futile to try to judge their financial wherewithal. The bankproblem is not some unfounded attack by greedy speculators, so a leading proffered solution -- extending the ban on short-selling shares in big banks -- obfuscates rather than informs. Italso delays the necessary private-sector recapitalization.

    Second, when firms buy insurance to reduce risks in their portfolio, the insurance has to beworth the bargain or else hedging becomes unreliable and risks are exacerbated. That's whathappened with the negotiated settlement in the Greek market for credit-default swaps, whennegotiators "voluntarily" agreed on principal reductions. Such policies give rise to default byanother name. Counterparties aren't fooled. Neither should policy makers be. Firms' exposuresto their counterparties require more transparency and better tools for risk-reduction.

    Third, ratings agencies have been rightfully criticized for assigning higher ratings to variousfinancial products than were justified by their fundamentals, yet now we see a dangerous

    irony: Governments are trying to persuade ratings agencies to assign higher ratings tosovereigns than deserved or justified by market prices. Blaming the ratings agencies for thedysfunction in funding markets will not lower funding costs. After all, the largest globaleconomies do not have debt-rating problems. They have debt problems.

    Financial repression is sometimes the effect of policy even if it is not the intent. It manifestsitself, for example, when policy makers react more forcefully to declines in asset prices than toincreases. Price increases tend to be treated with benign indifference. But declines often leadpolicy makers to respond with force, deploying fiscal stimulus and monetary accommodation.Market participants then conclude that governments have their backs.

    http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970204770404577080181384917926.htmlhttp://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970204770404577080181384917926.htmlhttp://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052970204770404577080181384917926.html
  • 7/30/2019 Warsh Essay WSJ

    2/2

    Consider the fiscal trajectory of the United States. However well-intentioned, the FederalReserve's continued purchase of long-term Treasury securities risks camouflaging thecountry's true cost of capital. Private investors are crowded out of the market when the Fedshows up as a large and powerful bidder. As a result, the administration and Congress maketax and spending decisions -- with huge implications for our standard of livingwithheightened risks around future funding costs.

    As measured against the administration's budget, every 1-percent increase in interest ratesabove the current baseline would translate into another $1 trillion of debt service over 10years. And with financial repression at play, we risk missing early warning signs from marketsthat our debt burden is intolerable.

    Efforts to manage and manipulate asset prices are not new. But history provides little comfort

    that these practices work. Interfering with market prices occasionally buys time, but rarely dopolicy makers seize the window of opportunity to enact structural reform. Financial repressionembeds the wrong incentives -- obfuscation begets delay, and a robust recovery becomesunattainable.

    The path to prosperity requires taking the long road. It requires policy reforms that make theeconomy less reliant on the preferences of government and more responsive to the market.That means prioritizing long-term growth over fleeting market stability, and giving precedence

    to structural reforms over temporary stimulus and market manipulation. Financial repressionis a tactic that may help get us through the week or month or year. But it will come at asubstantial cost to our long-term prosperity.

    -----

    Mr. Warsh, a former Federal Reserve governor, is a distinguished visiting fellow at StanfordUniversity's Hoover Institution and a lecturer at its Graduate School of Business.