Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    1/66

    LectureQuantitative Risk Management

    Rudiger FreyUniversitat Leipzig

    Wintersemester 2010/11 Universitat [email protected]

    www.math.uni-leipzig.de/~frey

    c2010 (Frey)

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    2/66

    I: Foundations

    Introduction and regulatory background Risk management for a financial firm

    Modelling Value Change

    Risk Measurement Stylized facts of financial time series

    c2010 (Frey) 1

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    3/66

    A. Introduction and Regulatory Background

    c2010 (Frey) 2

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    4/66

    A1. The Road to Basel

    Risk management: one of the most important innovations of the

    20th century. [Steinherr, 1998]

    The late 20th century saw a revolution on financial markets. Itwas an era of innovation in academic theory, product development(derivatives) and information technology and of spectacular

    market growth.

    Large derivatives losses and other financial incidents raised banksconsciousness of risk.

    Banks became subject to regulatory capital requirements,internationally coordinated by the Basle Committee of the Bank

    of International Settlements.c2010 (Frey) 3

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    5/66

    The Regulatory Process

    1988. First Basel Accord takes first steps toward internationalminimum capital standard. Approach fairly crude and insufficiently

    differentiated.

    1993. The birth of VaR. Seminal G-30 report addressing for firsttime off-balance-sheet products (derivatives) in systematic way. At

    same time JPMorgan introduces the Weatherstone 4.15 daily market

    risk report, leading to emergence of RiskMetrics.

    1996. Amendment to Basel I allowing internal VaR models formarket riskin larger banks.

    2001 onwards. Second Basel Accord, focussing on credit risk but

    c2010 (Frey) 4

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    6/66

    also puttingoperational riskon agenda. Banks may opt for a more

    advanced, so-calledinternal-ratings-basedapproach to credit.

    2009 onwards Discussion about regulatory consequences from thecurrent financial crisis

    c2010 (Frey) 5

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    7/66

    A2. Basel II:

    Rationale for the New Accord: More flexibility and risk sensitivity

    Structure of the New Accord: Three-pillar framework:

    Pillar 1: minimal capital requirements (risk measurement)

    Pillar 2: supervisory review of capital adequacy

    Pillar 3: public disclosure

    c2010 (Frey) 6

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    8/66

    Basel II Continued

    Two options for the measurement ofcredit risk: Standard approach

    Internal rating based approach (IRB)

    Pillar 1 sets out the minimum capital requirements (Cooke Ratio):total amount of capital

    risk-weighted assets 8%

    MRC (minimum regulatory capital) def= 8% of risk-weighted assets

    Explicit treatment ofoperational riskc2010 (Frey) 7

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    9/66

    A3. QRM: the Nature of the Challenge

    Extremes Matter

    From the point of view of the risk manager, inappropriate use

    of the normal distributioncan lead to an understatement of risk,

    which must be balanced against the significant advantage ofsimplification. From the central banks corner, the consequences

    are even more serious because we often need to concentrate on

    the left tail of the distribution in formulating lender-of-last-resort

    policies. Improving the characterization of the distribution of

    extreme valuesis of paramount importance.

    [Alan Greenspan, Joint Central Bank Research Conference, 1995]

    c2010 (Frey) 8

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    10/66

    The Interdependence and Concentration of Risks

    Themultivariatenature of risk presents an important challenge. Weare generally interested in some form ofaggregate riskthat depends

    on high-dimensional vectors of underlyingrisk factors.

    Examples:

    individual asset values in market risk

    credit spreads and counterparty default indicators in credit risk.

    A particular concern in multivariate risk modelling is the phenomenon

    of extremal dependence when many risk factors move against ussimultaneously.

    c2010 (Frey) 9

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    11/66

    Dependent Extreme Values: LTCM

    Extreme, synchronized rises and falls in financial markets occur

    infrequently but they do occur. The problem with the models is

    that they did not assign a high enough chance of occurrence to the

    scenario in which many things go wrong at the same timethe

    perfect stormscenario.

    [Business Week, September 1998]

    In a perfect storm scenario the risk manager discovers that thediversification he thought he had is illusory; practitioners describe this

    also as a concentration of risk.

    c2010 (Frey) 10

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    12/66

    Concentration Risk

    Over the last number of years, regulators have encouraged

    financial entities to use portfolio theory to produce dynamic

    measures of risk. VaR, the product of portfolio theory, is used

    for short-run, day-to-day profit and loss exposures. Now is the

    time to encourage the BIS and other regulatory bodies to support

    studies onstress test and concentration methodologies. Planning

    for crises is more important than VaR analysis. And such new

    methodologies are the correct response to recent crises in the

    financial industry.

    [Scholes, 2000]

    c2010 (Frey) 11

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    13/66

    QRM and the current crisis

    What happened

    Starting in late 2006 high interest rates and falling house prices inUS large scale default of sub-prime mortgages

    Sub-prime defaults collapse of MBS (mortgage-backed securities)market

    Collapse of MBS market collapse in CDO market

    Collapse in market for securitized debt write-offs and generalnervousness in banks

    Nervousness about bad debt in banks drying up of interbanklending market and increase in cost of debt financing

    c2010 (Frey) 12

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    14/66

    Increase in cost of debt financing liquidity problems at banks

    Liquidity problems bank runs and (near) default of many financialinstitutions such as Northern Rock, Bear Stearns, Lehman , AIG,

    Citi, Hypo real Estate; end of traditional American investment banks

    general financial malaise leading to a global recession (fuelled

    further by global economic imbalances) ; nationalization of banks

    and various

    rescue packages for financial institutions of unprecedented size;

    discussion about regulatory reform

    c2010 (Frey) 13

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    15/66

    Critical comments on quantitative methods

    The Economist: With their snappy name and flashy mathematicalformulae quants were the stars of the finance show before the credit

    crisis

    Colin Creevy (Europ. Kommission) the irresponsible lending, blindinvesting, bad liquidity management, excessive stretching of ratingagency brands anddefective Value at Risk Modellingthat prompted

    the turmoil of recent months[the subprime credit crisis]

    Financial Times It is a worry, though, that Merrill Lynch can justifya write-down of $4.5bn one week and $7.9bn just three weeks later.It seems that valuation is still a matter ofpick a number and divide

    by the chief traders golf handicap . . .

    From Black Scholes to black holes. . .

    c2010 (Frey) 14

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    16/66

    Picture from H. Fllmer

    c2010 (Frey) 15

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    17/66

    My view

    Quantitative methods are here to stay: They provide importantconcepts, tools and techniques for dealing with financial risk

    There is room for improved mathematical modelling and advancedstatistical techniques that can help in building better risk

    management systems Nonetheless we have to be aware of the inherent limitations of

    mathematical models in the financial world

    RM is like driving a car through the back mirror.

    (J. Longerstay)In physics there may one day be a model of everything. In

    finance one is fortunate if there is a usable theory of anything

    (E. Derman)

    c2010 (Frey) 16

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    18/66

    B. Basic Concepts in Valuation and Risk

    Management

    c2010 (Frey) 17

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    19/66

    B1. Risk Management for a Financial Firm

    A good way to understand the risks faced by a financial institution(bank / insurance company) is to look at a stylized balance sheet.

    Key concepts.

    assets (Aktiva). Describes the investments of the institution liabilities (Passiva). Describes how the institution is funding itself

    equity (Eigenkapital.) Defined by thebalance sheet equation

    value of assets = value of liabilities + equity

    Equity consists of equity capital raised by share issues etc, augmented

    by retained profits and reduced by dividends and losses.c2010 (Frey) 18

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    20/66

    solvency. A firm is called solvent if equity > 0 and otherwiseinsolvent. Distinguish from default that occurs if firm misses a

    payment to debtholders.

    Valuation principles

    Fair value accounting. Value an item on the balance sheet by (anestimate of) its market value. Special case: risk neutral valuation asin mathematical finance.

    Book value. In finance typically nominal value - risk provision (e.g.for a loan)

    c2010 (Frey) 19

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    21/66

    Balance sheet of a bank

    c2010 (Frey) 20

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    22/66

    Balance sheet of an insurer

    c2010 (Frey) 21

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    23/66

    Risks faced by a financial firm

    Risks faced by a typical bank

    Decrease in value of investments on the asset side (market risk andcredit risk)

    Funding and maturity mismatch. (long-term illiquid assets fundedby short-term liabilities)

    Key risk of an insurer is insolvency. Sources:

    asset side: decrease in value of investments.

    liability side: reserves insufficient to cover future claim payments.Note that for life insurers liabilities are long-term.

    We conclude that funding of positions plays a crucial role and that the

    two sides of the balance sheet have to be looked at jointly.

    c2010 (Frey) 22

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    24/66

    B2. Loss Distributions

    To model risk we use language ofprobability theory. Risks arerepresented byrandom variablesmapping unforeseen future states of

    the world into values representingprofits and losses.

    The risks which interest us areaggregaterisks. In general we consider

    aportfoliowhich might be

    a collection ofstocks and bonds;

    a book ofderivatives;

    a collection of riskyloans;

    a financial institutionsoverall positionin risky assets.c2010 (Frey) 23

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    25/66

    Portfolio Values and Losses

    Consider a portfolio and let Vt denote itsvalueat time t; we assumethis random variable is observableat time t.

    Suppose we look at risk from perspective of time t and we consider

    the time period [t, t + 1]. The value Vt+1 at the end of the time

    period is unknown to us.

    The distribution of(Vt+1 Vt) is known as the profit-and-loss orP&Ldistribution. We denote thelossbyLt+1= (Vt+1 Vt). By thisconvention, losses will be positive numbers and profits negative.

    We refer to the distribution ofLt+1 as the loss distribution.

    c2010 (Frey) 24

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    26/66

    Risk Factors and mapping

    Generally the value of the portfolio at time t will depend on time anda set of observablerisk factors Zt= (Zt,1, . . . , Z t,d)

    . Formally,

    Vt=f(t,Zt) forf: R+ Rd R, .

    This representation is termedmapping. Examples for risk factors

    include logarithmic stock prices or index values, yields and exchange

    rates.

    c2010 (Frey) 25

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    27/66

    Loss Distributions

    Denote the time series ofrisk factor changesbyX

    t+1=Zt+1 Zt.Then the loss can be written as

    Lt+1= (f(t + 1,Zt+ Xt+1) f(t,Zt). (1)

    As of time t only random part is the risk factor change Xt+1. Henceloss distribution is determined by fand by the distribution of risk

    factor change. Sometimes we use a linearizedversion of (1).

    Lt+1 ft(t,Zt)t + di=1

    fZi(t,Zt)Xt+1,i=:Lt+1, (2)where subscripts denote partial derivatives and where t is the risk

    management horizon.

    c2010 (Frey) 26

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    28/66

    Example: Portfolio of Stocks

    Considerd stocks; let i denote number of shares in stock i at time tand let St,i denote price.

    The risk factors: following standard convention we take logarithmic

    prices as risk factors Zt,i= log St,i, 1

    i

    d.

    The risk factor changes: in this case these are

    Xt+1,i= log St+1,i log St,i, which correspond to the so-calledlog-returnsof the stock.

    The Mapping

    Vt=

    di=1

    iSt,i=

    di=1

    ieZt,i. (3)

    c2010 (Frey) 27

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    29/66

    Example Continued

    The Loss

    Lt+1 =

    di=1

    ieZt+1,i

    di=1

    ieZt,i

    = Vtdi=1

    t,i

    eXt+1,i 1 (4)wheret,i=iSt,i/Vt is relative weight of stock i at time t.

    Here there is no explicit time dependence in the mapping (3). The

    partial derivatives with respect to risk factors are

    fZi(t,Zt) =ieZt,i, 1 i d,

    c2010 (Frey) 28

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    30/66

    and hence the linearized loss (??) is

    Lt+1= di=1

    ieZt,iXt+1,i= Vt d

    i=1

    t,iXt+1,i, (5)

    wheret,i=iSt,i/Vt is relative weight of stock i at time t. This

    formula may be compared with (4).

    Moments of linearized loss

    Assume that X has mean vector and covariance matrix . Then

    E(Lt+1) = Vt var(Lt+1) =V2t

    c2010 (Frey) 29

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    31/66

    An example with BMW and Siemens shares

    Respective prices on evening 23.07.96: 844.00 and 76.9. Considerportfolio of one BMW share and 10 Siemens shares. We get the

    following results

    Lt+1=

    (844(ex1

    1) + 769(ex2

    1))

    Lt+1= (844X1+ 769X2)

    c2010 (Frey) 30

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    32/66

    The dataBMW

    Time

    300

    500

    700

    9

    00

    02.01.89 02.01.90 02.01.91 02.01.92 02.01.93 02.01.94 02.01.95 02.01.96

    Siemens

    Time

    50

    60

    70

    80

    02.01.89 02.01.90 02.01.91 02.01.92 02.01.93 02.01.94 02.01.95 02.01.96

    BMW and Siemens Data: 1972 days to 23.07.96.

    c2010 (Frey) 31

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    33/66

    BMW

    Time

    -0.

    10

    0.

    00

    .05

    02.01.89 02.01.90 02.01.91 02.01.92 02.01.93 02.01.94 02.01.95 02.01.96

    Siemens

    Time

    -0.

    10

    0.

    0

    0.

    05

    02.01.89 02.01.90 02.01.91 02.01.92 02.01.93 02.01.94 02.01.95 02.01.96

    BMW and Siemens Log Return Data: 1972 days to 23.07.96.

    c2010 (Frey) 32

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    34/66

    Example: European Call Option

    Consider portfolio consisting of one standard European call on anon-dividend payingstock Swithmaturity T andexercise price K.

    We assume that Black-Scholes formula is used to value the option.

    Recall that Black-Scholes price of a European call on S is given by

    CBS(t, S; r, ) =S(d1) Ker(Tt)(d2), where

    is standard normal df, r represents risk-free interest rate, the

    volatility of underlying stock, and

    d1=log(S/K) + (r+ 2/2)(T t)

    T t andd2=d1

    T t.

    c2010 (Frey) 33

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    35/66

    Example Continued

    Canonical risk factor: log-price of underlying asset. In reality interestrates and volatilities tend to fluctuate over time; they should be added

    to the set of risk factors.

    The risk factors: Zt= (log St, rt, t)

    .

    The risk factor changes: Xt= (log(St/St1), rt rt1, t t1). The mapping: Vt=CBS(t, St; rt, t).

    Remark. In practice t would be computed as implied volatility fromobserved option prices.

    c2010 (Frey) 34

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    36/66

    Linearized loss and Greeks

    For derivative positions it is quite common to calculate linearized loss.Lt+1=

    ft(t,Zt)t +

    3i=1 fZi(t,Zt)Xt+1,i

    .

    It is more common to write the linearized loss as

    Lt+1= CBS t + CBSS StXt+1,1+ CBSr Xt+1,2+ CBS Xt+1,3 ,

    in terms of the derivatives of the BS formula.

    CBSS is known as thedeltaof the option. CBS is thevega. CBSr is therho. CBS is thetheta.c2010 (Frey) 35

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    37/66

    Valuation methods and fair value

    Thefair valueof an asset is an estimate of the price one would receivein selling the asset on an active market.

    For many assets active markets are rare 3 different levels.

    Level 1. Value is obtained from quoted price for the same instrumentin active market (typical example: stock portfolio) Level 2. Value is obtained from quoted price of similar but not

    identical assets or from pricing models where all necessary inputs

    are observable market data (typical example: European option withnon-standard strike or maturity).

    Level 3. Value is obtained from pricing model where some inputs aresubjective estimates instead of market observables. (typical example:

    c2010 (Frey) 36

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    38/66

    loan portfolio where credit spread has to be estimated via a subjective

    scoring technique since there are no traded bonds or CDS related to

    the borrower)

    The three levels are also known as mark to market, mark to model

    with objective inputs and mark to model with subjective inputs.

    c2010 (Frey) 37

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    39/66

    B3. Evaluating loss distributions

    Recall that

    Lt+1= (f(t + 1,Zt+ Xt+1) f(t,Zt)). (6)

    Hence finding the distribution ofLt+1 involves two tasks:

    specify/estimate a model for risk factor changes Xt+1 evaluate distribution of the rv f(t + 1,Zt+ Xt+1).Three approaches:

    Analytical methods such as variance-covariance method historical simulation method (bootstrap), Simulation methods (Monte Carlo).c2010 (Frey) 38

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    40/66

    Variance-Covariance Method

    Assumptions

    Xt+1 ismultivariate normallydistributed, Xt+1 Nd(, ). The linearized loss Lt+1 is a sufficiently accurate approximation of

    Lt+1. Determine the distribution of

    Lt+1=

    c +di=1

    wixi

    = (c + wx)

    (compare the stock-portfolio (5)). Recall that linear combinations of

    multivariate normally distributed random vectors are multivariate

    normal. HenceLt+1 N(cw,ww).

    c2010 (Frey) 39

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    41/66

    Implementing the Method

    1. The constant terms in c and w are calculated from the mapping f.

    2. The mean vector and covariance matrix are estimated from

    data Xtn+1, . . . ,Xt to give estimates and.3. Inference about the loss distribution is made using distribution

    N(cw

    ,ww)

    4. Estimates of risk measures such as VaR are calculated from the

    estimated distribution ofL.

    c

    2010 (Frey) 40

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    42/66

    Pros and Cons, Extensions

    Pro. Variance-covariance offers analytical solution with nosimulation.

    Cons. Linearization may be crude approximation. Assumption of

    normality may seriouslyunderestimate tailof loss distribution.

    Extensions. Instead of assuming normal risk factors, the methodcould be easily adapted to use multivariate Student t risk factors or

    multivariate hyperbolic risk factors, without sacrificing tractability.(Method works for all elliptical distributions.)

    c

    2010 (Frey) 41

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    43/66

    Historical Simulation Method

    Instead of estimating the distribution ofLt+1) under some explicit

    parametric model for Xt+1, one estimates distribution of the loss

    corresponding to thecurrentportfolio usingempirical distributionof

    past risk factor changes Xtn+1, . . . ,Xt (n data points):

    1. Construct thehistorical simulation data{Ls= f(t,Zt+ Xs) f(t,Zt): s=t n + 1, . . . , t} (7)

    2. Approximate loss distribution using historically simulated data:

    P(Lt+1 ) 1n

    nj=1

    1{Ltj+1}.

    c

    2010 (Frey) 42

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    44/66

    Discussion

    Theoretical Justification. IfXtn+1, . . . ,Xt are iid or moregenerally stationary, convergence of empirical distribution to true

    distribution is ensured by suitable version of law of large numbers.

    Pros and Cons.

    Pros. Easy to implement. No statistical estimation of the distributionofX necessary.

    Cons. It may be difficult to collect sufficient quantities of relevant,synchronized data for all risk factors. Historical data may not containexamples of extreme scenarios. Sensitivity wrt. sample period.

    c

    2010 (Frey) 43

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    45/66

    Monte Carlo Methods

    Here one estimates the distribution ofLt+1 under some parametricmodel for Xt+1 using Monte Carlo methods, which involves

    simulationof new risk factor data:

    1. With the help of the historical risk factor data Xtn+1, . . . ,Xt

    calibrate a suitable statistical model for risk factor changes and

    simulatemnew dataX(1), . . . ,X(m) from this model.2. Construct the Monte Carlo dataLi= {f(t,Zt+X(i)) f(t,Zt) : i= 1, . . . , m.3. Make inference about loss distribution using the simulated data

    L1, . . . ,

    Lm.

    c

    2010 (Frey) 44

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    46/66

    Pros and Cons

    Pros. Very general. No restriction in our choice of distribution forXt+1.

    Cons. Can be very time consuming if mapping f is difficult to

    evaluate, which depends on size and complexity of portfolio.

    Note that MC approach does not address the problem of determining

    the distribution ofXt+1.

    c

    2010 (Frey) 45

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    47/66

    B4. Risk Measures

    Risk measures attempt to quantify the riskiness of a portfolio.Applications:

    Determination of risk capital

    Management tool eg. in limit systems Pricing, eg. premium principles in insuranceMost risk measures arestatistics of the loss distributionsuch as

    variance or Value at Risk. Sometimes so-calledscenario-basedrisk

    measures are used as-well.

    In the sequel we denote the loss distribution by P(L ) =FL()whereL is a generic loss variable such as Lt+1) orL

    t+1.

    c

    2010 (Frey) 46

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    48/66

    VaR

    Given a confidence level 0< ) 1 } (8)

    = inf{ R : FL() }. (9)

    In probabilistic terms VaR is thus the -quantileq(FL), where for

    an arbitrary dfF on R and

    (0, 1)

    q(F) = inf{x R : F(x) .}

    c

    2010 (Frey) 47

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    49/66

    VaR in Visual Terms

    Loss Distribution

    probability

    dens

    ity

    -10 -5 0

    5

    10

    0.0

    0

    .05

    0.

    10

    0.

    15

    0.

    20

    0.2

    5Mean loss = -2.4

    95% VaR = 1.6

    5% probability

    95% ES = 3.3

    c

    2010 (Frey) 48

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    50/66

    Losses and Profits

    Profit & Loss Distribution (P&L)

    probability

    dens

    ity

    -10 -5 0

    5

    10

    0.0

    0

    .05

    0.

    10

    0.

    15

    0.

    20

    0.2

    5 Mean profit = 2.495% VaR = 1.6

    5% probability

    c

    2010 (Frey) 49

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    51/66

    Expected Shortfall

    ProvidedE(|L|)< expected shortfallis defined asES=

    1

    1 1

    qu(FL)du. (10)

    For continuous loss distributions expected shortfall is the expected

    loss, given that the VaR is exceeded:

    Lemma. For any (0, 1) we have

    ES=E(L; L q(L))

    1 =E(L | L VaR) ,

    whereE(X; A) :=E(X1A).c

    2010 (Frey) 50

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    52/66

    Expected Shortfall ctd.

    Remark. For a discontinuous loss df we have the more complicatedexpression

    ES= 1

    1

    E(L; L q) + q(1 P(L q)).

    Advantages ofES.

    ES takes the whole tail of the distribution beyond VaR into

    account; in particular ES>VaR. ES has better properties regarding aggregation of risk. This is

    related to so-calledcoherenceof risk measures.

    c

    2010 (Frey) 51

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    53/66

    Expected shortfall: Examples

    Normal losses. Suppose that L N(, 2) and fix (0, 1).Denote by the density of the standard normal distribution. Then

    ES= + (1())

    1

    . (11)

    Student t losses. Suppose that (L )/ t for >1, where thedensity of standard tdistribution is given by

    g(x) =C(1 + x2/)(+1)/2. Then

    ES(L) = + g(t

    1 ())

    1 + (t1 ())2

    1

    , (12)

    c

    2010 (Frey) 52

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    54/66

    VaR versus ES: an example

    Consider daily losses on position in some stock; current value of theposition equals Vt= 10 000.

    Loss for this portfolio is given byLt+1= VtXt+1forXt+1the dailylog-returns.

    Assume that Xt+1 has mean zero and standard deviation= 0.2/

    250, (annualized volatility of 20%.)

    Two different models for the distribution ofXt+1: (i) Xt+1 N(0, 2) (ii) Xt+1=

    2Lfor

    L tand >2 ( var(L) =2).

    c

    2010 (Frey) 53

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    55/66

    Numerical results

    0.90 0.95 0.975 0.99 0.995VaR (normal model) 162.1 208.1 247.9 294.3 325.8

    VaR (t model) 137.1 190.7 248.3 335.1 411.8

    ES (normal model) 222.0 260.9 295.7 337.2 365.8

    ES (t model) 223.4 286.3 356.7 465.8 563.5VaR and ES in normal and t4 model for different values of.

    Thet model is in principle more dangerous than the normal model.

    UsingVaR this is seen only for very close to one; ES shows this

    already for = 0.95.

    c

    2010 (Frey) 54

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    56/66

    Scenario-based risk measures

    Idea. Considers a number of possible future risk-factor changes calledscenarios; risk of portfolio is given asmaximal lossunder all scenarios;

    extreme or implausible scenarios may be down-weighted.

    Formal description. Fix a setX = {x1, . . . ,xn} of scenarios and avector w= (w1, . . . , wn) [0, 1]n of weights. Denote the portfolioloss caused the risk factor change x by

    l[t](x) := (f(t + 1,Zt+ x) f(t,Zt)).

    The risk of the portfolio is then measured as

    [X,w]:= max{w1l[t](x1), . . . , wnl[t](xn)}. (13)

    c

    2010 (Frey) 55

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    57/66

    Applications and Examples

    The approach is frequently used formargin requirementsat exchangesand instress tests.

    CME-example. [Artzner et al., 1999] :

    simple portfolios consisting of a position in a futures contract and

    options on this contract.

    16 different scenarios: First 14 consist of an up move or a downmove of volatility combined with no move, an up or down move of

    the futures price by 1/3, 2/3 or3/3. Moreover 2 extreme scenarios. The weights: w1 = = w14 = 1.. Extreme scenarios are down-

    weighted: w15=w16= 0.35. Margin requirement is then computed

    according to (13).c

    2010 (Frey) 56

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    58/66

    Coherent Measures of Risk

    There are many possible measures of the risk in a portfolio such as

    VaR, ES or stress losses. To decide which are reasonable risk

    measures a systematic approach is called for.

    New approach ([Artzner et al., 1999], [Follmer and Schied, 2004]):

    Give a list of properties (Axioms) that a reasonable risk measureshould have; such risk measures are calledcoherentorconvex.

    Study coherence of standard risk measures (VaR, ES, etc.).

    More theoretical: characterize all convex/coherent risk measures.Here we view a risk measure as amount of capital that needs to be

    added to a position with loss L, so that the position becomes

    acceptableto a risk controller.c

    2010 (Frey) 57

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    59/66

    The Axioms

    Acoherent risk measureis a realvalued function on some spaceMof rvs (representing losses) that fulfills the following 4 axioms:

    1. Monotonicity. For two rvs with L1 L2 we have (L1) (L2).

    2. Translation invariance. Fora R we have (L + a) =(L) + a.

    3. Subadditivity. For anyL1,L2we have(L1 + L2) (L1) + (L2).Most debated, sinceVaRis in general not subadditive. Justifications:

    Reflects idea that risk can be reduced by diversificationand thata merger creates no extra risk.

    Makesdecentralizedrisk management possible.c

    2010 (Frey) 58

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    60/66

    The Axioms II

    4. Positive homogeneity. For 0 we have that (L) = (L). Ifthere is no diversification we should have equality in subadditivity

    axiom.

    Sometimes subadditivity and positive homogeneity are replaced by theweaker axiom of convexity [Follmer and Schied, 2004]:

    5. Convexity. (L1+ (1 )L2) (L1) + ( 1 )(L2) for all [0, 1].

    A risk measure that satisfies monotonicity, translation invariance

    and convexity is called aconvex measure of risk

    c

    2010 (Frey) 59

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    61/66

    Comments

    VaR is in general not subadditve and hence not coherent (otheraxioms are satisfied)

    ES is coherent, in particular subadditive.

    coherent convex. The converse is wrong. If is positive homogeneous, subadditivity and convexity are

    equivalent.

    c

    2010 (Frey) 60

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    62/66

    Non-Coherence of VaR: an Example

    Setup. Consider portfolio of 2 defaultable bonds with independentdefaults. Default probability identical and equal to p= 0.9%. Current

    price of bonds equal to 100, face value equal to 105, recovery rate =0.

    Li loss of one unit in bond i. We have

    Li=

    (105 100) = 5 (no default, probability1p= 0.991)(0 100) = 100 (default, probabilityp= 0.009) .

    Set= 0.99. We have P(Li< 5) = 0 andP(Li 5) = 0.991> so that VaR(Li) = 5.

    c

    2010 (Frey) 61

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    63/66

    Non-Coherence of VaR: an Example ctd.

    Consider now L=L1+ L2, i.e. a portfolio of one bond from eachfirm. Since defaults are independent we get

    L=

    10 (no default, probability(1p)2 = 0.982)

    (105

    200) = 95 (exactly 1 default, probability 2p(1

    p) )

    200 (2 defaults, probabilityp2)

    In particular P(L 10) = 0.9820.99sothat VaR(L) = 95 Hence VaR is non-coherent in this example.

    Remark. In the example VaR punishes diversification, as

    VaR(0.5L1+ 0.5L2) = 0.5 VaR(L) = 47.5>VaR(L1)

    c

    2010 (Frey) 62

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    64/66

    Dual Representation

    Theorem Consider a general probability space (,F, P) and takeMto be the set of all bounded measurable functions on (,F, P).Suppose that : M R is a risk measure with the followingcontinuity property:

    For Ln M with Ln L M one has (Ln) (L). (14)

    Suppose moreover that iscoherent. Then it has the representation

    (L) = sup{EQ(L) : Q Q} (15)for some set Q= Q() S1(,F) (the set of all probabilitymeasures on (,F)).c

    2010 (Frey) 63

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    65/66

    Example: expected shortfall

    Recall that ES(L) = 11 1qu(L)du, L L1(,F, P) and that ESis coherent.

    The dual representation is given by

    ES(L) = maxEQ(L) :Q VaR(L)}+ L1{L=VaR(L)}, (17)

    for some constant L such that E(dQLdP ) = 1.

    c

    2010 (Frey) 64

  • 8/10/2019 Vorlesung-Ws10_Teil 1.pdf

    66/66

    Bibliography

    [Artzner et al., 1999] Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J., and Heath, D.(1999). Coherent measures of risk. Math. Finance, 9:203228.

    [Follmer and Schied, 2004] Follmer, H. and Schied, A. (2004).

    Stochastic Finance An Introduction in Discrete Time. Walter de

    Gruyter, Berlin New York, 2nd edition.

    [Scholes, 2000] Scholes, M. (2000). Crisis and risk management.

    Amer. Econ. Rev., pages 1722.

    [Steinherr, 1998] Steinherr, A. (1998). Derivatives. The Wild Beast of

    Finance. Wiley, New York.

    c 2010 (Frey) 65