Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    1/93

    The Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    Cristian Voicu

    Department of EconomicsStanford [email protected]

    May 2002

    Abstract

    Procurement contracts account for a large percentage of the US GDP. They are usually

    awarded by auctioning authorities through first-price sealed-bid auctions. Previous work in

    auction theory provides answers for the static equilibrium with one auction. This paper ex-

    tends the one-auction model to a dynamic model, introducing capacity constraints and con-

    tinuation values. I develop a comprehensive model for the dynamics of procurement auc-

    tions by proving a series of complex theorems and by analyzing the properties of the

    Markov-perfect equilibrium. Furthermore, I obtain a range of new results, relating the ex-

    pected markup and the present value to environment variables such as available capacities

    and costs of the bidders. Some results may seem counterintuitive and can only be under-

    stood in the dynamic setting. For example, there are instances when the present value of a

    firm increases when one of its competitors has more capacity. The law of diminishing

    marginal returns holds in general, although there is a notable discontinuity point when the

    project size is equal to the available capacity.

    Keywords: first-price auctions, asymmetric bidders, procurement contracts, independent

    private values, capacity constraints, and Markov-perfect equilibrium.

    Acknowledgements: I would like to thank Professors Susan Athey and Patrick Bajarifor suggesting the research topic and monitoring my progress.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    2/93

    Page 2

    INDEX

    Page 3 Section 1: IntroductionPage 10 Section 2: Literature ReviewPage 19 Section 3: Empirical ObservationsPage 19 3.1 Advertising, Bidding, and the Award ProcessPage 22 3.2 Description of the DataPage 25 3.3 County by County AnalysisPage 26 3.4 Regressions

    Page 30 Section 4: The Theoretical ModelPage 30 4.1 Markov-Perfect EquilibriaPage 32 4.2 Properties of the EquilibriumPage 48 4.3 The Infinite Time HorizonPage 52 4.4 Defining Aggressiveness MeasuresPage 54 4.5 Modeling as Discrete-Time Markov ChainPage 57 Section 5: Computer SimulationPage 57 5.1 Practical ConsiderationsPage 61 5.2 Nonlinear Least Squares OptimizationPage 64 5.3 The GamePage 70 Section 6: Results

    Page 79 Section 7: Final CommentsPage 81 BibliographyPage 85 Appendix: Computer Code

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    3/93

    Page 3

    1. INTRODUCTION

    Auctions are a part of our way of life. They fill the buying and selling needs for

    millions of people and products. Auction buying and selling are so widespread in the

    United States and overseas, that few individuals and companies can escape their effects.

    Auction theory is important because of its practical, empirical, and theoretical ramifica-

    tions.

    The practical significance is justified by the huge volume of economic transactions

    which are conducted daily through auctions. Houses, cars, agricultural produce and live-

    stock, art and antiques are commonly sold by auction. Other economic transactions, like

    takeover battles, are auctions in effect, if not in name. The government uses auctions for

    selling a variety of assets such as treasury bills, foreign currency, mineral rights including

    oil and gas fields, and also for privatizing state-owned firms. Most procurement contracts

    are awarded to private firms through auctions. In these cases, the procurement authority is

    seeking the bidder who is willing to perform the required goods or services for a minimal

    cost. There has recently been an explosion of interest in designing new forms of auctions,

    for example to sell radio spectrum licenses, or in using auctions to set up new markets, for

    example in electricity and transportation.

    The empirical importance of auctions is derived from their simple and well-defined

    economic environments. They provide valuable testing ground for many aspects of eco-

    nomic theory, and in particular game theoretical models with incomplete information. Ma-

    jor empirical research efforts have focused on auctions for oil drilling rights, timber and

    treasury bills, and there has been an increasing interest in experimental work on auctions.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    4/93

    Page 4

    Auction theory has been the basis of much fundamental work. First, it has been im-

    portant in developing understanding of the methods of price formation, such as posted

    prices, and negotiations in which both the buyer and the seller are actively involved in de-

    termining the price. Second, there are close connections between auctions and competitive

    markets. An important strand of the auction literature is concerned with the properties of

    auctions when the number of bidders becomes large. The question is whether the sale price

    converges to the true value, thus fully aggregating all the economys information even

    though each bidder has only partial information. If it does, then it would be attractive to

    think of an auction model as justifying some of the ideas economists have about perfect

    competition. Third, there is also a close analogy between the theory of optimal auctions

    and the theory of monopoly pricing, and auction theory can also help develop models of

    oligopolistic pricing. Auction-theoretic models also apply to non-price means of allocation.

    Examples include queues, lobbying contests, wars of attrition, or rationing.

    Bajari and Tadelis (1999) overviewed the building construction industry, and found

    there were 2 million establishments in the United States construction industry that com-

    pleted $528 billion dollars of work in 1992. The Bureau of the Census of the U.S. Depart-

    ment of Commerce documents that these firms directly employed 4.7 million workers and

    had a payroll of $118 billion dollars. In 1997, the construction industry comprised 8 per-

    cent of the U.S. GDP by itself, and the construction industry worldwide was a 3.2 trillion

    dollar market. The vast majority of procurement auctions were awarded by auctions.

    Most procurement contracts are variants of either simple fixed-price or cost-plus

    contracts. In fixed-price contracts, the buyer offers the seller a fixed price determined by

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    5/93

    Page 5

    auction for completing the project. A cost-plus contract stipulates a base fee, and then the

    contractor is reimbursed for costs that exceed projections. Bajari and Tadelis (1999) indi-

    cate that most of the simple projects are procured through fixed-price contracts. More

    complex projects or projects that need to be finished quickly are procured using cost-plus

    contracts and are accompanied by low levels of design completeness, which means that

    there is a high probability that adaptations are needed.

    There are four basic types of auctions widely used and analyzed: the ascending-bid

    auction (also called open, oral, or English auction), the descending-bid auction (tradition-

    ally used in the sale of flowers in the Netherlands, from which it derived the name of

    Dutch auction), the first-price sealed-bid auction, and the second-price sealed-bid auction

    (also called the Vickrey auction.) The model developed in this paper will use the first-price

    sealed-bid auction, where each bidder submits a single bid independently, without seeing

    others bids, and where the contract is awarded to the lowest bidder. The winner pays his

    or her own bid in first price auctions. My choice is consistent with the fact that most U.S.

    procurement auctions are awarded by sealed-bid first-price auctions. It should be noted

    however that the choice of auction type can generate important differences in bidding be-

    havior. For instance, Milgrom (1996) compares auction for the sale of radio spectrum fre-

    quencies in the United States, Australia and New Zeeland. Different rules of auctions were

    characterized by significantly different prices for similar bandwidths.

    A key feature of auctions is the presence of imperfect information. If the partici-

    pants had perfect information, the solution of auction model would be relatively trivial.

    From a game-theoretical perspective, the types of equilibria that deal with imperfect in-

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    6/93

    Page 6

    formation are Bayesian-Nash equilibria. That is, each firms strategy is a function of its

    own information, and it maximizes the expected payoff given the competitors strategies

    and given the beliefs about their information.

    In my model, bidders have private values. Each bidder knows precisely the cost of

    executing a contract, but the value is only privately known. In contrast, in the pure com-

    mon-value model the actual cost is the same for everyone, but bidders have different pri-

    vate estimates about what their cost will be. For example, the value of an oil-lease depends

    on how much oil is under the ground, and bidders may have access to different geological

    signals about that amount. In this case, a bidder would change the estimate of the value if

    he or she learnt of another bidders signal. In the private-value model, the bidders own

    cost would be unaffected by learning any other bidders preferences or information. A

    more general model encompassing both cases assumes that each bidder receives a private

    information or signal, but allows each bidders value to be a general function of all the sig-

    nals. However, it is safe to model the auctions by using the private-value model in simple

    procurement contracts. Departures from the private-values model may bring the question

    of collusion.

    I make a number of simplifying assumptions in my game in order to render the

    problem tractable. For example, I assume that it is costless to prepare a bid, and that the

    number of bidders is exogenously specified. There are major technical hurdles for theoreti-

    cal analysis when these assumptions are dropped. Few results can establish existence, not

    to mention uniqueness, outside these restrictive assumptions. Maskin and Riley (1996)

    showed that general existence and uniqueness results do not exist when the number of bid-

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    7/93

    Page 7

    ders is endogenous, when information acquisition is costly, or when bidders participate in

    more than a single auction. Without uniqueness and existence of the equilibrium distribu-

    tion of bids, game theory could not provide satisfactory answers.

    The dynamic game will extend existing work by Guerre, Perrigne and Vuong

    (2000), Bajari (2000b), and Jofre-Bonet and Pesendorfer (2000). Independent opinions

    from these authors suggest the need for further study. Bajari, Jofre-Bonet, and Pesendorfer

    suggest exploring the bidding behavior over time in a dynamic setting. This can be done by

    introducing capacity constraints. During our discussions, Professor Patrick Bajari ex-

    pressed his interest in the auctioneers optimal policy in procurement contracts under a dy-

    namic setting. The difficulty of achieving the goals above is of theoretical nature. The

    equilibrium equations have not yet been solved in closed form, not even for the single-unit

    auction with asymmetric bidders. Several algorithms exist for solving the equations nu-

    merically, but they are not very fast in practice. Bajari (2000) proposed a better algorithm,

    and I have obtained even faster computer runs by improving his algorithm. My model will

    extend Bajaris work to a multiple-period dynamic setting. The static model cannot fully

    explain the dynamics of bidding behavior because it ignores capacity constraints and the

    associated continuation values. I will explicitly include these variables in the equilibrium

    equations.

    The model assumptions are congruent with existing work. It describes an infinite-

    horizon discrete-time industry, in which risk-neutral firms choose strategies that maximize

    the expected discounted value of sealed-bid first-price auctions. The firms have private

    valuations of the auctioned contract, and they are differentiated in their cost structure and

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    8/93

    Page 8

    in their available capacity. The information about their available capacity at each decision

    node is summarized by a state, which in turn evolves as a Markovian transition process.

    The firms are asymmetric in their probability distribution of costs, but have the same cost

    interval ],[ maxmin cc (also called the support interval). Each firm observes its own cost, and

    then determines the bid which maximizes utility, given the continuation values of winning

    and losing, as well as the other firms strategies.

    I will focus on the properties of the equilibrium and the comparative statics results

    it predicts. As you will see, my model provides theoretical justification for many hypothe-

    ses specific to the dynamic setting. I will explore the changes in the expected bid, the ex-

    pected markup, and the present value, with respect to changes in the firms cost and capac-

    ity, as well as to a change in its competitors changes in costs and capacity. The model is

    consistent with economic intuition, since it predicts diminishing marginal returns to in-

    creases in capacity. I will also look into the interaction effects between a firms cost and

    capacity on the present value. In the light of the foregoing, the study has theoretical and

    practical significance. The model can explain intuitive our intuition of the bidding behavior

    in a dynamic context and it provides the tools to analyze many other aspects of the dy-

    namic of procurement auctions.

    Let me briefly describe what you will find in this paper. I will start with a fairly

    succinct review of the literature related to the dynamics of procurement auctions. Then, I

    will show the results I obtained from a dataset of bids from the Washington State Depart-

    ment of Transportation. The dataset inspires the main elements to be taken into considera-

    tion in the theoretical model, which is fully developed in section four. The model is pre-

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    9/93

    Page 9

    sented in great detail, so you may feel the need to skip some parts, especially the quite in-

    volved proofs given for a series of propositions. If you decide not to follow the proofs, I

    would like you to at least acknowledge their importance. The theoretical section discusses

    Markov-perfect equilibria, delves into the intricacies of the equilibrium properties, shows

    how the model can be turned into an infinite time-horizon game, introduces new measures

    for quantifying the dynamics of procurement auctions, and also shows how the system

    could be understood as a stochastic process. The computer simulation section outlines the

    assumptions made in implementing the very general theoretical results. It gives informa-

    tion about the most difficult issue I had to tackle in the computer simulation, the optimiza-

    tion of a non-linear objective function with a very large number of real variables. In the

    end, I will explain the comparative statics results predicted by the model.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    10/93

    Page 10

    2. LITERATURE REVIEW

    The review of relevant papers is organized by topic. Similar works are clustered

    around the topics which emerge in my paper, in order to enhance understanding. I have

    also attempted to provide a chronological progression and guide the reader through the de-

    velopments in auction theory which led to my interest in this particular subject. The topics

    covered in this section are: classical theoretical models, econometrical estimation models,

    asymmetrical bidders, competition and collusion, independent versus affiliated private val-

    ues, and other attempts towards a dynamic model of procurement auctions.

    2.1 Classical Theoretical Models

    Vickrey (1961) made an enormous progress in analyzing the game theoretical as-

    pects of the auction problems. Griesmer, Levitan and Shubik (1967) analyzed the equilib-

    rium of a first price auction in which contestants valuations are drawn from uniform dis-

    tributions with different supports. Wilson (1969) introduced the common-value model and

    developed the first closed-form equilibrium analysis of the winners curse. The full flower-

    ing of auction theory came with critical contributions from Riley and Samuelson (1981),

    Milgrom and Weber (1982), Maskin and Riley (1985), and McAfee and McMillan (1987).

    In the classical model, a given number of risk-neutral potential buyers of an object

    have privately-known information independently from each other, drawn from a common,

    strictly increasing, atom-less distribution. The Revenue Equivalence Theorem states that,

    under all types of auctions, the object always goes to the buyer with the highest signal,

    yields the same expected revenue, and results in each bidder making the same expected

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    11/93

    Page 11

    payment as a function of the signal. The expected revenue from an auction is shown to

    equal the expected marginal revenue of the winning bidder. Also, all the standard auctions

    are all optimal as long as the seller imposes the optimal reserve price.

    Milgrom and Weber (1982) develop a model of competitive bidding in which the

    winning bidders payoff may depend upon his personal preferences, the preferences of oth-

    ers, and the intrinsic qualities of the object being sold. In this model, the English ascending

    auction generates higher average prices than does the second-price auction. Also, when

    bidders are risk-neutral, the second-price auction generates higher average prices than the

    Dutch and first-price auctions. In all of these auctions, the seller can raise the expected

    price by adopting a policy of providing expert appraisals of the quality of the objects he or

    she sells.

    More advanced models deal with issues like risk-aversion, affiliation, asymmetries,

    entry, collusion, multi-unit auctions, double auctions, royalties, incentive contracts, budget

    constraints, externalities between bidders, and all-pay auctions. An elementary and non-

    technical survey of auction theory is provided by Klemperer (1999).

    2.2 Estimation Models

    Besides theoretical models, research on auctions has also generated an impressive

    body of experimental work, documented by Cox, Smith and Walker (1985, 1988). How-

    ever, according to Laffont, Ossard and Vuong (1995), only a few empirical studies have

    attempted to validate theoretical auction models using real auction data. Some examples

    include Hansen (1985, 1986), Hendricks, Porter and Boudreau (1987) and Hendricks and

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    12/93

    Page 12

    Porter (1988). Instead, most empirical studies have concentrated on testing some implica-

    tions of the theory of auctions using reduced-form econometrics models. An exception is

    Paarsch (1989, 1992) who estimates econometric models that are closely derived from the-

    ory. A possible reason for this gap between theoretical work and empirical work arises

    from the computational difficulties due to the non-linearity and numerical complexity as-

    sociated with the estimation of structural econometric models.

    Laffont, Ossard and Vuong (1995) propose an estimation method to fill this gap.

    They focus on first-price sealed bid and descending auctions, where each bidder is as-

    sumed to a have a different private value for the object that is auctioned. The method relies

    on simulated non-linear least square objective function appropriately adjusted as to obtain

    consistent estimates of the parameters of interest. The symmetric Bayesian Nash equilib-

    rium of the corresponding game of incomplete information was characterized by Riley and

    Samuelson (1981), among others. The equilibrium expresses the optimal bid as a function

    of the bidders private value, the reservation price of the object, the number of bidders, and

    the distribution of private values. In general, bids are observed, but actual private values

    are not observed. The preceding theoretical model leads to a closely related structural

    econometric model. Since optimal bids are functions of private values, which are theoreti-

    cally random, then observed bids are also random with a distribution that is uniquely de-

    termined by the structural elements of the model. Unfortunately, the equilibrium function

    relating optimal bids to private values is usually untractable. As a consequence, only very

    specific distributions of private values have been considered in empirical work. The esti-

    mation methods are based on simulations as proposed by Lerman and Manski (1981),

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    13/93

    Page 13

    McFadden (1989), Pakes and Pollard (1989), Laroque and Salanie (1989), and Gourieroux

    and Monfort (1990, 1993).

    2.3 Asymmetrical Bidders

    Auction situations provide many examples where the symmetry assumption is not

    tenable. This can be because of bidders difference in size, in geographic locations as in

    Bajari (1998), and Flambart and Perrigne (2000), and in capacity constraints as in Jofre-

    Bonet and Pesendorfer (2000). Other examples where asymmetry arises naturally are col-

    lusions, asymmetrically informed bidders, or firms bidding jointly. Cartels are described

    by Porter and Zona (1993), Baldwin, Marshall and Richard (1997) and Pesendorfer (2000).

    Asymmetrically informed bidders in the outer continental shelf drainage auctions are

    documented by Hendricks and Porter (1988) and Hendricks, Porter and Wilson (1994), and

    joint bidding in the outer continental shelf auctions are studied by Hendricks and Porter

    (1992). All these examples illustrate the necessity of developing general structural econo-

    metric models to deal with asymmetric auctions.

    2.4 Independent versus Affiliated Private Values

    Campo, Perrigne and Vuong (2000) confirm that the existence of cartels, collusion

    and heterogeneity across firms induces asymmetry in bidding games. A major difficulty

    when considering asymmetric auctions is that the equilibrium strategies are solutions of an

    intractable system of differential equations. Instead of focusing on the independent private

    values model, they make an extension to include the affiliated private values paradigm.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    14/93

    Page 14

    The attractive feature of their indirect procedure is that is does not require solving the dif-

    ferential equations for the equilibrium strategies. The method can be easily generalized to

    many types of bidders.

    2.5 Competition and Collusion

    Bajari and Ye (2000) study a class of econometric models derived from auction

    theory. They are useful for modeling both competitive and collusive bidding in many ap-

    plied settings. Their models allow for asymmetries and attempt to model the auction dy-

    namics. They develop a set of conditions that are both necessary and sufficient to rational-

    ize a distribution of bids with a model of competitive bidding. Their conditions can be

    tested empirically in a straightforward fashion. As a second stage, they explain how the

    choice between structural models of competition and structural models of collusion can be

    posed as a statistical decision problem. As an application, they apply their test to a data set

    of bidding by firms for construction contracts.

    The approach suggested by Bajari and Ye (2000) is Bayesian. To describe the intui-

    tion behind the tests, one could imagine the limiting case that the structural cost parameters

    for all firms in the market are known with certainty. Then one would be able to compute

    the equilibrium distribution of bids that are consistent with the competitive model. If the

    empirical distribution of bids agrees with the computed distribution of bids then one cannot

    reject the hypothesis of competitive bidding. Porter and Zona (1993), and Baldwin, Mar-

    shall and Richard (1997) also propose econometric tests designed to detect collusive bid-

    ding. Baldwin, Marshall and Richard (1997) nest both competition and collusion with a

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    15/93

    Page 15

    single model to test for collusion. Their model is applicable for oral or second-price auc-

    tions with private values. Porter and Zona (1993) propose a procedure where two models

    of bidding are estimated. Bajari and Yes paper sheds now light on Porter and Zona (1993,

    1999). Observable differences across firms such as location and capacity play a key role in

    their identification. The analysis tightens the link between the economic theory and the

    econometrics of how asymmetries can be used to identify collusive bidding.

    Another feature of Bajari and Yes model is that the econometric approach can be

    used for any parametrically specified auction model. They specify a parametric distribution

    of costs and compute the equilibrium inverse bid functions for the structural model in order

    to evaluate the likelihood of the observed bids conditional on the covariates of the parame-

    ters. By considering asymmetric auction models, they extend the earlier work which dis-

    cussed parametric estimation of symmetric auction models such as Paarsch (1992), Laf-

    font, Ossard and Vuong (1995), Armantier, Florens and Richard (1997) and Hong and

    Shum (2000). The econometric techniques may provide an alternative to the important es-

    timation algorithms developed by Guerre, Perrigne and Vuong (2000) and Jofre-Bonet and

    Pesendorfer(2000) in at least three ways. Guerre et al (2000) and Jofre-Bonet et al (2000)

    use a two-step procedure that first estimates the empirical distribution of bids conditional

    on observed distribution of costs. The number of conditioning arguments grows exponen-

    tially in the number of bidders, while Bajari et al (2000) suggest an algorithm where the

    computational complexity grows linearly. They argue that in applications with a relatively

    small number of bidders, there exists insufficient data to apply the techniques of Guerre et

    al (2000) and Jofre-Bonet et al (2000). Unlike these two works, Bajari and Ye (2000) use a

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    16/93

    Page 16

    Bayesian rather than classical econometric methods in their estimation. A first advantage

    of the Bayesian procedure is that it allows them to impose a priori restrictions on the pa-

    rameter space in a natural fashion. It may not be possible to detect collusion with a priori

    restrictions of the parameters of the structural model. The Bayesian approach is also ap-

    pealing for testing non-nested models such as competition versus collusion.

    2.6 Dynamic Models and Capacity Constraints

    Jofre-Bonet and Pesendorfer (2000) estimate a repeated auction game under the

    presence of capacity constraints. The estimation strategy is computationally simple as it

    does not require solving for the equilibrium of the game. It uses a two-stage approach. In

    the fist stage the distribution of bids conditional on the state variable is estimated using

    data on bids, bidder characteristics and contract characteristics. In the second stage, an ex-

    pression of the expected sum of future profits based on the distribution of bids is obtained,

    and costs are inferred based on the first order conditions of optimal bids. They apply the

    estimation method to repeated highway construction procurement auctions in the state of

    California. They conclude that in this market, previously won uncompleted contracts re-

    duce the probability of winning further contracts. They quantify the effect of intertemporal

    constraints on bidders costs and on bids. Due to the intertemporal effect and also due to

    bidder asymmetry, the auctioning mechanism can be inefficient. Based on the estimates of

    costs, they quantify efficiency losses.

    Even though the works of Paarsch (1992), Laffont et al (1995) and Guerre et al

    (2000) develop an empirical approach to quantify informational uncertainty in static auc-

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    17/93

    Page 17

    tion games, there is little empirical work on dynamic auction games or dynamic oligopoly

    games. Some examples include Laffont and Robert (1999) and Donald, Paarsch and Robert

    (1997) who analyze finitely repeated auctions. Laffont and Robert (1999) consider a se-

    quence of auctions in which, at each stage, an identical object is sold. Their model gener-

    ates complex intra-day dynamics which are applied to data on eggplant auctions. Donald,

    Paarsch, and Robert (1997) consider a model in which a finite number of objects are sold

    in a sequence of ascending-price auctions. They estimate the model using data on the sales

    of Siberian timber-export permits. The literature on estimation in dynamic games is sum-

    marized by Pakes (1994).

    Jofre-Bonet and Pesendorfer (2000) propose an estimation method that infers costs

    based on the first order condition of optimal bids of the repeated bidding game. Their cru-

    cial idea is that the expected discounted sum of future profits can be written looking for-

    ward and depending entirely on the distribution of bidders bid choices. The resulting ex-

    pression can be written as a linear equation system which can be easily solved numerically,

    because they make a number of simplifying assumptions. In my model, the analysis is

    much more general.

    A related estimation strategy of the value function is employed by Hotz and Miller

    (1994). They approximate the value function with discrete choices using estimates of

    choice probabilities. Their framework differs from Jofre-Bonet and Pesendorfer (2000) be-

    cause the model considers only a single agent dynamic decision problem, attention is re-

    stricted to discrete actions, and informational constraints are not modeled. In work in pro-

    gress, Berry and Pakes (2000) consider a related estimation strategy for dynamic games.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    18/93

    Page 18

    The distinguishing feature of their approach is to consider an alternative representation of

    the value function in which the expected sum of future profits is replaced with a sequence

    of future profit realizations. However, their representation is less attractive in dynamic auc-

    tion games, because profits are not observed and cannot be expressed indirectly from ob-

    served bids, without knowing the equilibrium bid functions.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    19/93

    Page 19

    3. EMPIRICAL OBSERVATIONS

    This section deals with the results I obtained from a dataset of bids in the Washing-

    ton State highway construction industry. I begin by describing the advertising, bidding and

    awards process. The analysis gets more involved when the market structure and concentra-

    tion are analyzed; important observations are made from the data. I also confirm some of

    the previous comparative statics results, using a dataset that covers a different administra-

    tive area and has a longer time span relative to datasets in previous work.

    3.1 Advertising, Bidding and Award Process

    There are a number of steps that must be addressed to effectively advertise, award,

    execute, and document procurement contracts. A chronological order of phases is pre-

    sented below:

    Preparation for advertisement (technical reports, engineers estimate, risk determi-

    nation, funding authorization).

    Advertisement (usually done in trade journals for 2 to 4 weeks depending on the

    nature of the project, after which auction packages are sent to pre-qualified bidders).

    Bid opening (public opening and reading of bids, document verification).

    Contract execution.

    These detailed procedures presented in the Advertisement and Award Manual

    published by the Washington State Department of Transportation (August 1998) provide

    the framework for the award for all contracts, except emergency projects, which may be

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    20/93

    Page 20

    exempted. However, there are some exceptions for business enterprises owned by women

    and minorities.

    In Washington State, one of the conditions for awarding the contract is concerned

    with the amount of the winning bid relative to the engineers estimate. If the winning bid

    exceeds the engineers estimate by 10% or $50,000, whichever is greater, special guide-

    lines must be followed. First, the governmental office needs to determine if there was ade-

    quate competition. Second, it needs to document the impact of postponing the projects. Af-

    ter taking into consideration all pertinent aspects, the procurement authority needs to pro-

    vide justification for award or rejection.

    The number of project proposal holders and the actual number of bidders provide

    an indication of the level of competition. The Washington State Department of Transporta-

    tion considers that the winning bid should not exceed the engineers estimate by more than

    20% for 5 bidders or more, by 15% for 4 bidders, or by 10% for 3 bidders or less. How-

    ever, the department recognizes that these guidelines may not be appropriate for some

    specialized contracts and other factors should be considered. Also, it is important to know

    if an attempt was made to attract additional bidders, and to find the reasons why some pro-

    posal holders did not submit bids..

    Postponing and re-advertising the project may have a negative impact. The pro-

    curement authority takes into consideration constraints such as the urgency of the project

    completion, the ability to complete the work within the current construction season, and

    the potential for loss of construction season. There are direct costs related to re-advertising

    the project. There may be risks involved with postponement, such as potential damage and

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    21/93

    Page 21

    severe deterioration. Also, the timing of re-advertising may impact the project funding be-

    cause of budget constraints.

    These regulations have the same effect of setting a reservation price. In a sense, the

    auctioneer is a special bidder, whose bid is a direct function of the engineers estimate and

    of the number of firms bidding in the project. The amount of the reservation price may be

    uncertain because of the special circumstances surrounding a project. It can be modeled

    with a probability distribution on a closed support interval. The lower end of the interval

    depends on the engineers estimate and on the number of bidders.

    It is interesting to watch the efforts that go into insuring that all bidders are serious

    and that there is no collusion. To screen out unserious bids, the Washington State Depart-

    ment of Transportation requires a bid deposit (also called proposal guarantee or contract

    bond) which amounts to 5% of the submitted bid, and which must be sent before the bid

    can be taken into consideration. Other clauses are related to subcontractors. If some sub-

    contractors will execute more than 10% of the project, they must be mentioned on a sub-

    contractor list when the bid is submitted. The constraints I have just mentioned limit the

    contractors room of maneuver.

    The bidders are required to sign a non-collusion declaration. The issue is so impor-

    tant that the US Department of Transportation has a hotline that can be used to report bid

    rigging, bidder collusion, or other fraudulent activities. The non-collusion declaration con-

    tains the following statement: I, by signing the proposal, hereby declare, under penalty of

    perjury under the laws of the United States that the undersigned person, firm, association

    or corporation has not, either directly or indirectly, entered into any agreement, partici-

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    22/93

    Page 22

    pated in any collusion, or otherwise taken any action in restraint of free competitive bid-

    ding in connection with the project for which this proposal is submitted.

    3.2 Description of the Data

    The data used here was obtained from the Washington State Department of Trans-

    portation at no cost. As a matter of fact, the Department of Transportation saves all the bid

    information and can provide it at public request. This fact may reduce the bidders infor-

    mational costs of the bidders. With certainty, it helped reducing the costs for my project,

    since the other (much more costly) alternative would have been to purchase the data set

    from a private firm such as Construction Market Data Group. The advantage of receiving

    the data directly from the original source (the Department of Transportation) had the addi-

    tional advantage of covering a larger time span, due to thee access to older bid archives.

    The data1 covers an almost five year period from January 1, 1997 to July 11, 2001.

    The dataset itself included a wealth of information, organized around each project,

    each firm, and each submitted bid. Project-specific data included contract number, region

    number, work order, bid date, award date, highway number, project description, and pro-

    ject county. Firm-specific data included contractor name, contractor number, contractor

    address and phone number. Bid-specific data was broken down item by item and included

    the following categories: item, standard item, item description, unit of measure, estimated

    quantity, estimated unit price, estimated total, contractor unit price, and contractor total.

    1 WSDOT provides project by project information online at the following Web address:http://www.wsdot.wa.gov/biz/contaa/BIDSTATS/bidresults.htm

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    23/93

    Page 23

    Among all available projects, I focused attention on those involving asphalt fixing

    or resurfacing, because they are smaller in size and do not require the use of subcontrac-

    tors. The projects can be finished in a single season and there is no expectation that the

    specifications will be changed during the execution of the contract.

    Let me briefly provide the main statistics. There were a total of 325 projects involv-

    ing repairs of asphalt surface, with an average project size of $1,423,616. The total value

    of the projects was $462,675,065 for a period of approximately 5 years. The average num-

    ber of bids per project was 2.55, indicating that the level of competition was not too fierce,

    especially in the more isolated areas of Washington state. There were 32 firms who sub-

    mitted successful bids during that period, with the largest firm Lakeside Industries control-

    ling 18.69% of the market with 59 projects own and $86,491,604 in revenues. There were

    also a number of firms that submitted bids, but never won any project. It appears that some

    of these firms did not have asphalt repair as their core competency. In any case, they are

    examples of unsuccessful attempts of entering the asphalt repair industry.

    One issue of interest is the level of concentration in the industry measured by the

    Herfindahl index. The HH index was 761.90 in Washington State, with the concentration

    of each firm being computed as a percentage of revenues from the total volume of con-

    tracts. The HH index indicated an adequate level of competition at state level. There were

    only four out-of-state firms that submitted bids, and among them only two were able to

    win any project at all. The most successful out-of-state bidder was Poe Asphalt Paving

    from the neighboring Idaho state, with only 3.62% market share. Viewed from this per-

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    24/93

    Page 24

    spective, it is difficult to enter the highway construction market unless the bidder has its

    headquarters and equipment in the state where it does business.

    Firm Bids Wins Total Contracts Percentage

    LAKESIDE INDUSTRIES 142 59 $86,491,604 18.69%SUPERIOR PAVING CO 47 33 $50,481,739 10.91%ACME MATERIALS & CONSTRUCTION CO 53 19 $33,388,269 7.22%INLAND ASPHALT COMPANY 48 16 $32,064,480 6.93%ASSOCIATED SAND AND GRAVEL CO 21 11 $31,161,610 6.74%

    WILDER CONSTRUCTION COMPANY 79 31 $24,693,088 5.34%TRANSTATE PAVING CO 27 15 $19,251,219 4.16%WESTERN STATES PAVING CO 13 10 $17,217,087 3.72%POE ASPHALT PAVING, INC. 35 11 $16,745,262 3.62%CSR WEST, LLC DBA CSR ASSOCIATED 27 13 $15,123,337 3.27%ACE PAVING CO., INC. 16 13 $15,066,175 3.26%BASIN PAVING CO 26 12 $15,026,485 3.25%MORRILL ASPHALT PAVING 38 11 $13,744,653 2.97%TUCCI & SONS, INC. 19 10 $12,894,625 2.79%COLUMBIA ASPHALT & GRAVEL, INC. 36 9 $11,975,311 2.59%VALLEY ASPHALT & PAVING, INC. 8 6 $9,873,917 2.13%CENTRAL WASHINGTON ASPHALT, INC. 35 6 $8,215,847 1.78%

    ARC MATERIALS CORPORATION 13 7 $6,995,098 1.51%WATSON ASPHALT PAVING 28 7 $6,943,958 1.50%WOODWORTH & COMPANY, INC. 24 7 $6,505,445 1.41%JC COMPTON CONTRACTOR INC 4 2 $6,388,873 1.38%WILDISH STANDARD PAVING CO. 5 2 $6,355,138 1.37%QUAD-CITIES CONSTRUCTION, INC. 6 3 $4,534,370 0.98%R EXCAVATING, INC 2 1 $2,891,740 0.63%ICON MATERIALS, INC. 6 3 $2,518,306 0.54%OLDCASTLE NORTHWEST, INC. 10 1 $2,390,830 0.52%GOODFELLOW BROS., INC. 2 1 $1,121,627 0.24%KRIEG CONSTRUCTION, INC. 4 1 $646,465 0.14%STEELMAN-DUFF, INC. 2 1 $627,271 0.14%MURPHY BROTHERS, INC. 5 1 $599,727 0.13%

    WESTWAY CONSTRUCTION, INC. 2 1 $432,898 0.09%RAY POLAND AND SONS, INC. 4 2 $308,612 0.07%A AND B ASPHALT, INC. 2 0 - -DOOLITTLE CONSTRUCTION CO., INC. 12 0 - -FRANKLIN CONSTRUCTION, INC. 5 0 - -GRADY'S, INC. 1 0 - -KIEWIT PACIFIC CO 8 0 - -M.A. SEGALE, INC. 11 0 - -PACK AND CO. 1 0 - -VANCOUVER PAVING COMPANY 2 0 - -WALKERS' PAVING, INC 1 0 - -

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    25/93

    Page 25

    3.3 County by County Analysis

    The study of market concentration by county reveals more about the market struc-

    ture in the highway construction industry. I ignored the counties with less than five pro-

    jects because of their lack of statistical significance. The remaining counties had an aver-

    age of 4.17 firms per county being able to win projects. Thus, the bidding dynamics in a

    small region could be modeled as a repeated auction game with s small number of bidders.

    The implicit assumption is that if the fringe bidders were unable to win any bid for a period

    of almost five years, it would be very difficult for them to enter the industry in that particu-

    lar county. Even the county with the largest number of projects, King County with 31 pro-

    jects (including the Seattle area), had a Herfindahl index of 2323, which would be more

    County Projects Winners HH

    Adams 15 5 3101Benton 19 4 3325Chelan 10 5 2309Clallam 6 1 10000Clark 11 3 5349

    Douglas 10 3 3641Ferry 9 4 3449

    Franklin 11 5 2470Grant 16 5 3536

    Grays Harbor 8 2 5381King 31 12 2323

    Kitsap 11 3 6901Kittitas 9 2 5809Lewis 9 4 3059

    Lincoln 7 3 3616Pierce 14 3 5155

    Snohomish 22 6 1872Skagit 11 4 3211

    Spokane 15 4 4450Thurston 8 3 5428

    Walla Walla 11 4 3395Whatcom 24 5 3924Whitman 12 7 2063Yakima 17 3 5159

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    26/93

    Page 26

    than the maximum of 1800 legally allowed for a reasonable level of competition. In King

    county, the leader Lakeside Industries controlled approximately 50% market share. The

    industry is even less competitive in other counties. For example, Clallam county had ex-

    actly one bidder for all of its 6 projects during the five-year time span; the single bidder

    and winner for all of these projects was again Lakeside Industries. The firms bids were

    about 10% above the engineers estimate, which was basically the maximum allowed by

    the Washington State Department of Transportation. The bottom line is that the Herfindahl

    index exceeded 1800 in all of the counties in Washington State in our industry. Although

    the FTC guidelines regarding competition refer to the market concentration for the whole

    country, it shows that the firms location and the project location are very important in the

    highway construction industry. Distance from the firm to the location of the project will be

    shown to be a significant factor in bidding behavior. When we focus to a smaller adminis-

    trative region such as a county, the industry can be modeled as an oligopolistic or even

    monopolistic game. It is thus interesting to see what happens when a few firms compete

    against each other.

    3.4 Regressions

    Two other empirical studies shed light on the basic comparative statics results of

    bidding behavior in the highway construction industry. Therefore, I will not insist too

    much on this aspect. My regressions use a different dataset, and they reassert the validity

    of the previous results. The dataset from Washington State has the advantages of being

    more recent and of covering a longer time span.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    27/93

    Page 27

    Bajari and Ye (2000b) use a data set purchased from CMD which contains bid in-

    formation for Minnesota, North Dakota and South Dakota for the period 1994-1998. They

    use the following reduced form bid functions for each firm and each project:

    ++++

    ++++=

    )capacityMax(*)distanceMin1ln(*

    Capacity)Own(*)DistanceOwn1ln(*Estimate

    Bid

    43

    210

    bb

    bbb

    Jofre-Bonet and Pesendorfer (2000) use a data set which consists of all contract

    awards for highway and street construction in California from 1996 to 1998. The probit

    estimates of the bid submission decision followed the following equation:

    ++++

    ++++=

    )regiontheinCapacity(*)CapacityOwn(*)DistanceOwn(*

    )biddersFringe(*)daysWorking(*)Estimate(*Bid

    985

    4210

    bbb

    bbbb

    I decided to follow the regression model used by Bajari and Ye(2000b), and I inde-

    pendently confirmed their results. Some clarifications are necessary to fully understand the

    regression. The free capacity is computed as the percentage of projects won before the bid

    over the total number of projects won during a season (May to September). The logarithm

    of distance was used to account for the possibility that firms may have equipment at vari-

    ous sites in the state. The variables Min distance and Max capacity refer to the firms

    competitors minimum distance and maximum capacity. Other factors have been taken into

    consideration, such as the correlation effects between the variables, and the individual ef-

    fect of each bid and each project. Due to the large number of dummy variables for each

    firm and each project, the parameter estimates were obtained in SAS. There were 829 ob-

    servations and 074742 =R . The parameter estimates are summarized in the table:

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    28/93

    Page 28

    The significant variables at 5% confidence are the own distance to the project site

    and the own free capacity. The results imply that an increase of one order of magnitude in

    the distance will increase the bid by approximately 2%, whereas an increase of 10% in ca-

    pacity would reduce the bid by approximately 1%, keeping everything else constant. The

    interaction effects between competitors do not seem to be too strong. We would expect that

    competitors with higher distances would reduce the level of competition and increase the

    bid (confirmed by the positive sign of the regression), whereas competitors with more free

    capacity would increase the level of competition and reduce the bid (again confirmed by

    the negative sign of the regression parameter.)

    These empirical results indicate that distance, as a factor that affects transportation

    costs, is positively correlated with the bid level. The effect caused by the available capacity

    is more subtle. At the beginning of the season, firms submit what we could call normal

    bids, but at the end of the season they may submit ridiculously high bids since their capac-

    ity is already filled up and they are not actively looking for projects. This explains why

    bids are negatively correlated with available capacity. The knowledge that a competitor has

    a higher distance or a lower capacity level indicates they will have a high bid, which in

    Coefficient of Estimate Std Error Significant at 5%

    Intercept 1.03424 0.10647 yesLn(1+Own Dist) 0.01743 0.00876 yes

    Ln(1+Min Dist) 0.00143 0.01156 no

    Own Capacity -0.09466 0.02265 yes

    Max Capacity -0.01865 0.03193 no

    Parameter Estimates

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    29/93

    Page 29

    turn makes the firm with this knowledge bid higher. This also agrees with the signs of the

    parameter estimates in the table.

    The purpose of looking at the empirical data was to get a better understanding of

    the bidding behavior in the highway construction industry. In the next section, we will de-

    velop a comprehensive mathematical model of the dynamics of procurement auctions. Not

    only that it will verify the results observed in the real world, but it will also make a set of

    new predictions regarding other indicators such as the expected markup and the expected

    present value.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    30/93

    Page 30

    4. THE THEORETICAL MODEL

    Before developing the theoretical model, I discuss the Markov-perfect equilibria. It

    will be necessary to give complex proofs to a series of propositions, in order to justify the

    differential equations I will obtain. The model can be used either for a finite or infinite

    game. Several measure for quantifying the aggressiveness level are introduced. At the end

    of this section, I develop a framework for understanding repeated auctions as a stochastic

    process.

    4.1 Markov-Perfect Equilibria

    A Markov-perfect equilibrium is a refinement of the Nash equilibrium. Game theo-

    rists are interested in refinements because the class of Nash equilibria can be very large in

    complex games. In the case of dynamic auctions, the Nash equilibria include many types

    of collusive equilibria. These self-sustaining collusions would be interesting to discuss and

    analyze, but the solution space is probably huge. The refinements are an attempt to sim-

    plify the game and, ideally, reduce it to a unique equilibrium.

    The technical definition of the Markov-perfect equilibrium is given by Fudenberg

    and Tirole (1991): A Markov-perfect equilibrium is a profile of strategies that are a per-

    fect equilibrium and are measurable with respect to the payoff-relevant history.

    The graph below shows successive refinements of the Nash equilibrium.

    Equilibria

    Nash

    Equilibria

    Perfect(Subgame-)

    Equilibria

    PerfectMarkov

    Markov-perfect equilibria are suited to dynamic games in which the environment or

    state changes from period to period. In repeated auctions, the past has a direct influence on

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    31/93

    Page 31

    the present, because it determines the current available capacity. Markov-perfect equilibria

    ignore past actions that did not change the environment, and take into consideration only

    the current state. This refinement is necessary to deal with very complex games such as the

    repeated auction game. Markov-perfect equilibria do not discriminate between different

    histories that led to the same present state. Since the current state summarizes the influence

    of past play on the strategies and payoff functions for each subgame, there is no profitable

    deviation from the Markov strategies if all the other players are using Markov strategies.

    Examples of games that are suitable to a Markov perfect equilibrium analysis are bequest

    games, extraction of a common resource, or capital accumulation games. In the bequest

    game, intergenerational family transfers give raise to situations in which each generation

    cares about its own consumption and the consumption of future generations. The succes-

    sion of generations does not behave like a single decision maker, because of differences in

    preferences among generations. The bequest game is the ideal example for a Markov-

    perfect equilibrium analysis.

    Markov-perfect equilibria may be inappropriate in environments that are more

    psychological in nature, such as those characterized by threats and commitments. It is

    perfectly possible that firms care about being consistent to previous course of action. The

    idea of forward induction is that past actions will be interpreted as signals of future inten-

    tions even when those actions may not influence payoffs in the continuation game.

    Markov-perfect equilibria take a somewhat contrary perspective, since backward induction

    is used to find the optimal course of action. In Markov-perfect equilibria we start with the

    future and end with the current state.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    32/93

    Page 32

    It should be noted that dynamic games can be modeled with discrete time or with

    the analogue continuous time. Due to the technical difficulties in continuous-time games

    (also called differential games,) I will focus on the discrete-time game. Another issue is

    whether one should consider pure-strategy or mixed-strategy equilibria. I will work only

    with pure-strategy equilibria. In a repeated auction game, the optimal response is pure-

    strategy if all the other players are also playing pure-strategies.

    An important issue is the existence of the equilibrium. Ignoring existence will lead

    to nonsensical results, without logical foundation. Fudenberg and Tirole (1991) have

    shown that Markov perfect equilibria exist in stochastic games with a finite number of

    states and actions. Furthermore, the existence theorem was extended to countable state

    spaces by Parthasarathy and Rieder. Existence theorems for uncountable or continuous

    state spaces were much harder to obtain, but this is beyond the current paper anyway. In

    my model, capacity is represented as an integer. Even for cases that require more granular

    capacity intervals (i.e. percentage of available capacity), smaller countable intervals can be

    used. Either way, the existence of Markov perfect equilibria can be easily met by setting

    the granularity of the intervals at the required level.

    4.2 Properties of the Equilibrium

    I will develop here a dynamic model for procurement auctions. It describes an in-

    dustry in which firms choose strategies that maximize the expected discounted value of

    sealed-bid first-price auctions. My approach takes into consideration the dynamic behavior

    in auctions, where the number of periods can be either finite or infinite.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    33/93

    Page 33

    The firms have private valuations of the auctioned contract, and they are differenti-

    ated in their cost structure. At each time period, the environment is a state characterized by

    the information about the firms available capacity. In an industry withNfirms, the state is

    a vector ofN available capacities Ns . The state evolves over time according to a

    Markovian transition process.

    At the beginning of each period, firms observe their own costs, drawn from an

    atomless probability distribution with density )(if and with cumulative distribution

    ]1,0[],[: max,min, iii ccF . The firms are asymmetric in their probability distribution of

    costs. Each firm observes only its own cost, and then determines the bid which will maxi-

    mize utility, given the other firms strategies and the continuation values of winning and

    losing.

    The total utility function is time-additive and exhibits constant time preference

    (with discount factor ). The one-period utility function for firm i in state s and at time tis

    tsiu ,, . The expected discounted utility for firm i in state s and at time 0t is:

    [ ]

    =

    =

    0

    0|E ,,

    t

    ,,tt

    tsitsi suV t for an infinite number of periods / auctions, or

    [ ]=

    =

    T

    tt

    tsitsi suV t0

    0|E ,,

    t

    ,, for a finite number of T periods / auctions.

    The firms are risk neutral. If a firm submits a winning bid, then its utility for the

    current state is ii cb . If it fails to submit the lowest bid, the utility of the current state is 0.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    34/93

    Page 34

    In the model, firm is strategy is a bid function ],[: max,min,,, iitsi ccB which maps

    the cost draw to a bid. The bid function depends on three parameters: the identity of the

    firm, the current state, and the current time period. Let ))((inf ,,],[

    min,max,min,

    itsiccc

    i cBbiii

    = and

    ))((sup ,,],[

    max,max,min,

    itsiccc

    i cBbiii

    = . The bid function can then be written as:

    ],[],[: max,min,max,min,,, iiiitsi bbccB .

    Since the utility function is time-additive, the total utility will be equal to the utility

    of the current state plus the utility of all future states. The utility of all future states is

    times the expected discounted utility in the following period, contingent on the state. If the

    current state is s, I will define is be the state in the next period if firm i wins the auction.

    For each particular auction, the firm faces the following dilemma. If it bids too low

    for the project, the profit will also be low. However, if it increases the bid too much, the

    probability of winning decreases to the point where the firm is guaranteed to lose the auc-

    tion. Let )(,, itsj bQ denote the probability that firm j wins, from the perspective of firm i,

    and where i could be equal toj. In case of a tie, the winning firm is chosen at random with

    equal probability. Firm i assumes that all other firms play their optimal equilibrium strate-

    gies. The formula for these probabilities will be spelled out later in this section.

    The model allows for firms to have various capacities.

    Define=

    otherwise0,bidnextfor thecapacityfreeenoughhasfirmif,11 free

    ii

    Define the profit function as the profit in the current state plus the profit in all fu-

    ture states:

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    35/93

    Page 35

    ( ) ( ) )(1)|(

    ij

    free1,,,,,,1,,free,,

    ++++=

    jtsiitsjitsitsiiiiiitsi ji

    VbQbQVcbcb

    )|,(max)(,,,, iitsibitsi

    cbscVi

    =

    A Markov-perfect equilibrium is the natural solution which would emerge from the

    game, assuming no coordination between bidders, and no other commitments to a certain

    course of action. The equilibrium is subgame-perfect because the firms maximize in all

    future periods. The equilibrium follows the recurrent Bellman equations below:

    ( ) ( ) )(1max)(

    ij

    free

    1,,,,,,1,,free,,

    ++++=

    j

    tsiitsjitsitsiiii

    b

    itsi jii

    VbQbQVcbcV

    For the rest of the analysis, I will assume that firm i has sufficient capacity to par-

    ticipate in the auction. Otherwise, )()(

    ij

    free1,,,,,,

    +=

    jtsiitsjitsi j

    VbQcV and the discounted util-

    ity does not depend on firm isdecision in period t.

    It is very useful to make a few observations about the endpoints of the bid distribu-

    tions. I have defined the bid functions as ],[],[: max,min,max,min,,, iiiitsi bbccB . Let

    min,min min ii

    bb = and max,max min ii

    bb = [sic]. Suppose maxmax,such that bbi i > . This shows

    that 0)( max,,, =itsi bQ and firm i could change its bid on in the interval ),( max,max ibb without

    affecting the profit function

    )()|(

    ij

    free1,,,,,,

    +=j

    tsiitsjiitsi jVbQcb

    This implies that, if an equilibrium solution exists, it is not unique. From now on, I

    will focus attention on the particular case ibbi = maxmax, . The second observation refers to

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    36/93

    Page 36

    the minimum bid. There must be at least two firms who bid minb . Assume only firm i bids

    minb . Then firm i could strictly increase profits by bidding slightly higher that minb , which

    contradicts the optimality of minb , as explained in the proof of Proposition 2. These two

    observations show that in the caseN=2 firms, both firms have identical distribution of bids

    ].,[ maxmin bb

    I will make some general assumptions about the cost distribution. The probability

    distribution functions+

    ],[: max,min, iii ccf are atomless, continuous and 0)( >ii cf

    ],[ max,min, iii ccc . The cumulative distribution functions ]1,0[],[: max,min, iii ccF are dif-

    ferentiable. With these considerations in mind, I will provide a series of complex proposi-

    tions. The goal is to show that the bid functions are invertible and that the inverses are dif-

    ferentiable, which is crucial for the first order conditions of the equilibrium. The proofs

    that will follow are quite involved. If the reader feels they are too detailed, the next few

    pages could be skipped.

    Proposition 1. The probability of winning )(,, itsi bQ is monotonically decreasing,

    while )(,, itsk bQ with ik is monotonically increasing.

    Proof. After observing its cost independently, each firm chooses and submits a

    sealed bid. Firm i doesnt know what its competitors will bid, but it knows their joint dis-

    tribution of bids )}({ ijjbg . Consider any set of bids ijjb }{ from the joint distribution and

    let 12 ii bb > .

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    37/93

    Page 37

    >

    =

    ==

    )}{,min(if,0

    bidslowequal),}{,min(if,1

    )}{|(,,

    ijjik

    ijjik

    ijjitsk

    bbb

    pbbbpbbQ

    ijjijjitskijjisk bbbQbbtQ }{)}{|()}{|(, 1,,2,

    ijjijjijjitskijjijjijjitsk bbgbbQbbgbbQ }{d)}{()}{|(}{d)}{()}{|( 1,,2,,

    )()( 1,,2,, itskitsk bQbQ

    Therefore )(,, itsi bQ is monotonically decreasing and )(,, itsk bQ is monotonically in-

    creasing.

    Proposition 2. The functions )(,, itsi bQ are strictly decreasing on the interval

    ),[ maxmin bb when 1)(0 ,,

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    38/93

    Page 38

    Proof. Let )(,, itsii cBb = for some ic such that ),[ maxmin bbbi and 1)(0 ,, such that no other firms bid in the interval ],[ +ii bb with strictly posi-

    tive probability. This shows that )()( ,,,, += itsjitsj bQbQ , including the case ij = .

    ++++=

    free

    ,,1,,,,1,,,, )()()()|(

    j

    ijitsjtsiitsitsiiiiitsi

    bQVbQVcbcbji

    )|()()|()|( ,,,,,,,, iitsiitsiiitsiiitsi cbbQcbcb >+=+

    Firm i could strictly increase its profit by bidding +ib instead of ib . However,

    this would contradict the optimality condition for ib . Therefore, there is at least one firm

    that bids in the interval ],[ +ii bb with strictly positive probability 0> . So

    )()( ,,,, +> itsiitsi bQbQ 0> . This indicates that the functions )(, isi bQ are strictly de-

    creasing on the interval ),[ maxmin bb .

    Proposition 3. The equilibrium bid functions ],[],[: max,min,max,min,,, iiiitsi bbccB are

    monotonically increasing on the interval ),[ maxmin bb .

    Proof. Let 21 ii cc < and suppose )()( 2,,1,, itsiitsi cBcB >

    ( ) ( ) ))(()()(1)|)((

    ij

    free1,,2,,,,2,,,,1,,12,,free

    12,,,,

    =++=

    =

    ++

    jtsiitsitsjitsitsitsiiitsii

    iitsitsi

    jiVcBQcBQVccB

    ccB

    ( ) )()-())((

    )()(1

    2,,,,12

    ij

    free1,,2,,,,

    2,,,,1,,22,,free

    =++

    ++=

    +

    +

    itsitsiii

    j

    tsiitsitsj

    itsitsitsiiitsii

    cBQccVcBQ

    cBQVccB

    j

    i

    ( ))()-()|)(( 2,,,,1222,,,, itsitsiiiiitsitsi cBQccccB +=

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    39/93

    Page 39

    By the optimality of the bid function, it must be that

    )|)(()|)(( 21,,,,12,,,, iitsitsiiitsitsi ccBccB , so

    ( ) =+ )()-()|)(()|)(( 2,,,,1221,,,,12,,,, itsitsiiiiitsitsiiitsitsi cBQccccBccB

    ( ) =++

    =

    +

    +

    )()-())((

    )()(1

    2,,,,12

    ij

    free1,,1,,,,

    1,,,,1,,21,,free

    itsitsiiij

    tsiitsitsj

    itsitsitsiiitsii

    cBQccVcBQ

    cBQVccB

    j

    i

    ( ) ( )

    ( ) ( )[ ] =+

    +++=

    ++

    )()()-(

    ))(()()(1

    1,,,,2,,,,12

    ij

    free1,,1,,,,1,,,,1,,11,,free

    itsitsiitsitsiii

    j

    tsiitsitsjitsitsitsiiitsii

    cBQcBQcc

    VcBQcBQVccBji

    ) ))()()-()|)(( 1,,,,2,,,,1211,,,, itsitsiitsitsiiiiitsitsi cBQcBQccccB +=

    Since )(,, itsi bQ is a strictly decreasing function (Proposition 2) and >)( 1,, itsi cB

    )( 2,, itsi cB , it follows that ))(())(( 2,,,,1,,,, itsitsiitsitsi cBQcBQ < .

    Therefore )|)(()|)(( 11,,,,12,,,, iitsitsiiitsitsi ccBccB > which contradicts the optimality

    of )(1,, itsi

    cB . It must be that )()(2,,1,, itsiitsi

    cBcB 21 ii

    cc .

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    40/93

    Page 40

    According to Proposition 1, the probability functions )(,, tsjQ are monotone. This

    implies the existence of left and right limits around 0b . A further implication is that one

    can take right and left limits of the profit function in the neighborhood of 0b .

    ++=++

    ))(1()()()|( 1,,11),2(,11,,11,,11111,,1 1 bQVbQVcbcb tststststs

    ++=+++ 1,,11,,11,,11,,11111,,1 221

    )()()|( tststststs VbQVVcbcb

    +++

    +++=

    ++

    +++

    )()())()(()(

    )()()|(

    1,,1010,,11,,11,,11,,110

    1,,10,,11,,11,,11011,,1

    21

    221

    bQbbbQbQVVcb

    VbQVVcbcb

    tststststs

    tststststs

    )()())()(()(

    )|()|(

    1,,1010,,11,,11,,11,,110

    10,,111,,1

    21bQbbbQbQVVcb

    cbcb

    tststststs

    tsts

    +++

    +=

    ++

    Case 1: 1,,11,,101 21 ++ +< tsts VVbc

    Since firm 2 bids 0b with positive probability, the following inequalities hold:

    0)()(lim 0,,11,,10

    01

    01

    >=

    ++= ++

    .

    Case 2: 1,,11,,101 21 ++ += tsts VVbc .

    The profit function becomes )()()|()|( 1,,10100,,101,,1 bQbbcbcb tststs +=

    Observe that )|()|( 00,,101,,1 cbcb tsts > whenever 01 bb > . By a similar argument,

    )|()|( 00,,101,,1 cbcb tsts < whenever 01 bb < . Firm 1 is strictly better off by bidding higher

    than 0b : 01,,11,,10,, )( 21 bVVbB tststsi >+ ++ . Again, firm 1 does not bid in the interval

    ],[ 00 +bb for ))(,0( 01,,11,,10,, 21 bVVbB tststsi + ++ .

    Case 3: 1,,11,,101 21 ++ +> tsts VVbc

    According to Proposition 1, 01,,11,,10,,1,, )()( 21 bVVbBcB tststsitsi >+> ++ .

    The outcome for these three cases completely justifies the assertion that firm 1 does

    not bid in the interval ],[ 00 +bb for a small enough 0> . However, this could never be

    an equilibrium solution. Firm 2 could strictly increase its profits by increasing its bid from

    0b to +0b , following the argument made in the proof of Proposition 2. This contradicts

    the optimality of 0b .

    In conclusion, no firm bids a certain bid ),[ maxmin0 bbb with strictly positive prob-

    ability for the caseN=2.

    Proposition 5. The functions ]1,0[],[:)( maxmin,, bbbQ itsi are strictly decreasing

    and continuous for the caseN=2.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    42/93

    Page 42

    Proof: It follows directly from Propositions 2 and 4.

    Proposition 6. The image of the bid functions ],[],[: maxminmax,min,,, bbccB iitsi is

    connected for the caseN=2.

    Proof. Suppose firm 1 never bids ],[ maxmin0 bbb .

    Let )(sup 1)(

    0

    01,1

    ccbcB s

    += .

    Case 1:+ < 00 cc . Then ),()( 00101,,1 += cccbcB ts contradiction.

    Case 2:+

    > 00 cc . Then 01,,1 )( bcB ts > and ),()( 00101,,1 +< cccbcB ts . Absurd.

    Case 3: 000 ccc == + . If 00,,1 )( bcB ts > , firm 1 never bids in the interval

    +

    2

    )(,

    00,,1

    0

    bcBb

    ts. If 00,,1 )( bcB ts < , firm 1 never bids in the interval

    +0

    00,,1,

    2

    )(b

    bcB ts.

    Either way, there exists a closed interval in the neighborhood of 0b where firm 1 never

    bids. The contradiction arises by using the same argument as in proposition 2.

    Proposition 7. The inverse functions ],[],[: max,min,maxmin,1

    ,,,, iiitsitsi ccbbB =

    ex-

    ist and are continuous for the caseN=2.

    Proof. Propositions 3 and 5 imply that the bid functions :,, tsiB ],[ max,min, ii cc

    ],[ maxmin bb are strictly increasing. Propositions 3 and 5 imply they are continuous. There-

    fore, these functions are invertible and the inverse functions are also continuous.

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    43/93

    Page 43

    Proposition 8. The functions ]1,0[],[:)( maxmin,, bbbQ itsi are differentiable on the

    interval ),[ maxmin bb for the caseN=2.

    Proof. The proof is very similar to the one given by Maskin and Riley (1996), ex-

    cept for the existence of positive continuation values.

    I will prove the proposition for firm 1. The same logic can be used for firm 2. Let

    ),[, maxmin10 bbbb , 01 bb . Since the bid functions are invertible, let )( 0,,1 bts and

    )( 1,,1 bts be the corresponding costs. First observe that:

    1,,11,,11,,11,,11,,111,,11,,1 221 )())(())(|( +++ ++= tststststststs VbQVVbbbb and

    1,,11,,1max,,1 2))(|(

    += tststs Vbb

    The choice of 1b is maximal only if ))(|())(|( 1,,11,,11,,1max,,1 bbbb tstststs

    .0)( 1,,11,,11,,11 21 + ++ tststs VVbb

    However, the inequality must be strict because otherwise firm 1 could strictly in-

    crease its profit by bidding slightly above 1b . But this would contradict the maximal choice

    of 1b .

    Therefore .0)( 1,,11,,11,,11 21 >+ ++ tststs VVbb

    ))(|())(|( 1,,11,,11,,10,,1 bbbb tstststs

    ++

    ++

    +++

    +++

    1,,11,,11,,11,,11,,11

    1,,10,,11,,11,,11,,10

    221

    221

    )())((

    )())((

    tststststs

    tststststs

    VbQVVbb

    VbQVVbb

    +++

    )()())()(())(( 1,,1011,,10,,11,,11,,11,,10 21 bQbbbQbQVVbb tstststststs

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    44/93

    Page 44

    1,,11,,11,,10

    1,,1

    01

    0,,11,,1

    21)(

    )()()(

    +++

    tststs

    tststs

    VVbb

    bQ

    bb

    bQbQ

    Similarly, I will show that

    ))(|())(|( 0,,11,,10,,10,,1 bbbb tstststs

    ++

    ++

    +++

    +++

    1,,11,,11,,11,,10,,11

    1,,10,,11,,11,,10,,10

    221

    221

    )())((

    )())((

    tststststs

    tststststs

    VbQVVbb

    VbQVVbb

    +++

    )()())()(())(( 0,,1011,,10,,11,,11,,10,,10 21 bQbbbQbQVVbb tstststststs

    1,,11,,10,,10

    1,,1

    01

    0,,11,,1

    21)(

    )()()(

    ++ +

    tststs

    tststs

    VVbb

    bQ

    bb

    bQbQ

    Take the two equations above to the limit for 01 bb ; this is a legal operation be-

    cause tsQ ,,1 and ts ,,1 are continuous functions.

    1,,11,,10,,10

    0,,1

    01

    0,,11,,1

    1,,11,,10,,10

    0,,1

    2101

    21)(

    )()()(lim

    )(

    )(

    ++

    +++

    +

    tststs

    tststs

    bbtststs

    ts

    VVbb

    bQ

    bb

    bQbQ

    VVbb

    bQ

    This shows that1,,11,,10,,10

    0,,1

    01

    0,,11,,1

    2101 )(

    )()()(lim

    ++ +

    =

    tststs

    tststs

    bb VVbb

    bQ

    bb

    bQbQ

    , which

    means the functions ]1,0[],[:)( maxmin,, bbbQ itsi are differentiable on the interval

    ),[ maxmin bb .

    Proposition 9. The inverse bid functions ],[],[: max,min,maxmin,,, iiitsi ccbb are dif-

    ferentiable for the caseN=2.

    Proof. Observe that ))((1)( 1,,221,,1 bFbQ tsts = ))(1))(( 1,,11,,22 bQbF tsts =

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    45/93

    Page 45

    The right hand side is differentiable by Proposition 8.

    Therefore ]1,0[],[: maxmin,,22 bbF ts is differentiable. By Assumption (A2), 2F is

    differentiable, so therefore )(,,2 ts is differentiable. By a symmetrical proof, )(,,1 ts must

    also be differentiable.

    Conjecture: Propositions 4-9 are true in general for 2N . The inverse bid func-

    tions ],[],[: max,min,maxmin,1

    ,,,, iiitsitsi ccbbB =

    exist and they are continuous and differen-

    tiable.

    Comment. I proved the statement above for the particular case of two firms.

    Maskin and Riley (1996, 1999) have shown the general result holds for the static problem,

    where all continuation values are 0. However, they note that even for the static case, the

    problem is significantly more complex for 3N . Accepting that the bid functions are con-

    tinuous and differentiable allows me to find the equilibrium conditions.

    The equilibrium analysis continues from now on for the general case 2N .

    In order to win the auction, a firm must submit a bid that is lower than its N-1 com-

    petitors bids. This occurs exactly when )(,, itsjj bc > for all ij , which means that all

    firms ij have cost draws greater than )(,, itsj b .

    The probability that firm i wins is computed as:

    ))

    =ijj

    itsjjitsi bFbQfree,

    ,,,, )(1)(

    From the perspective of firm i, the expected probability that another firm wins is:

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    46/93

    Page 46

    ( )( )

    =

    ==

    i

    iisj

    b

    b kjtsjjjtskkitsj

    b

    b

    jtsjjjtsjj

    b

    c

    jjjtsjtsjitsj

    bdFbFbQ

    bdFbQcdFcBQbQ

    min

    min

    ,

    min

    jki,k

    free ,,,,,,

    ,,,,free

    )(

    ,,,,,,

    ))(()(1)(

    ))(()(1)())(()(

    Lets plug this formula into the Bellman recurrent equations:

    ( ) ( ) ++=

    ++)(11max)(

    ij

    free,,free1,,,,1,,free,,

    jitsjjtsiitsitsiiii

    bitsi

    bQVbQVcbcVji

    i

    ( ) ( )( )( )

    ( )( )

    +

    +

    +

    ++=

    i

    j

    j

    ii

    b

    b k

    jtsjjjtskk

    j

    tsi

    j

    itsjjitsiitsiib

    itsi

    bdFbFV

    bFVbbcV

    min,

    jki,k

    free,,,,

    ij

    free1,,

    ij

    free,,free1,,,,,,

    ))(()(1

    11)(max)(

    The expected discounted utility in state s is )(,, itsi cV after the cost is known and

    == maxi,

    mini,

    c

    c

    ,,,, )()( iiitsitsi cdFcVV max

    mini,

    ))(())(( ,,,,,,

    b

    b

    itsiiitsitsibdFbV before the cost is known.

    ( ) ( ) ))(()()(max ,,ij

    free1,,,,,,1,,,,

    )(,,

    max

    mini,,,

    itsii

    b

    b jtsiitsjitsitsiitsiitsi bdFVbQbQVbbV ji

    tsi

    ++=

    ++

    ( ) ( )( )( )

    ( )( )))((

    ))(()(1

    11)(

    max ,,

    jki,k

    free,,,,

    ij

    free1,,

    ij

    free,,free1,,,,

    )(

    ,,

    max

    mini,

    min,

    ,,

    itsii

    b

    b

    b

    b k

    jtsjjjtskk

    j

    tsi

    j

    itsjjitsiitsii

    tsibdF

    bdFbFV

    bFVbb

    Vi

    j

    j

    i

    tsi

    +

    ++

    =

    +

    +

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    47/93

    Page 47

    It is important to see there are two possible cases here. In the first case firm i has

    enough capacity to participate. In the second case, firm i doesnt have sufficient capacity to

    participate, but its continuation value depends on the outcome of the auction nevertheless.

    The model implicitly assumes that at least one firm has enough capacity to bid and win,

    otherwise the auction would not take place and the outcome would be trivial.

    If the firm does not have enough capacity, there will be no benefit from the current

    period, and the discounted present value depends only of future auctions. There is no

    maximization problem for firm i in case 2; the discounted value is inferred from other

    firms strategies.

    +=

    ij

    free1,,max,,,, )(

    jtsitsjtsi j

    VbQV

    ( )( )

    +

    =

    ij

    free

    jki,k

    free,,,,1,,,,

    max

    min,

    ))(()(1j

    b

    b k

    jtsjjjtskktsitsi

    j

    jbdFbFVV

    The first order conditions will help establish the optimal bid function when firm i

    has sufficient capacity. I worked on the equation by equivalence and I am showing only the

    main steps below:

    ( )( )( )

    ( ) ( )( )

    +=

    =

    ++

    )(1)('))(()(

    1

    ij

    free

    jki,k

    free,,,,,,1,,1,,,,

    ij

    free,,

    j k

    itskkitsjitsjjtsitsiitsii

    j

    itsjj

    bFbbfVVbb

    bF

    ji

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    48/93

    Page 48

    ( )( )( )( )

    0))((1

    )()('))((11

    ij

    free ,,

    1,,1,,,,,,,,

    ij

    free,, =

    +

    ++

    j itsjj

    tsitsiitsiiitsjitsjj

    j

    itsjjbF

    VVbbbbfbF

    ji

    ( ) ( )),[1

    ))((1

    )()(')(maxmin,

    ij

    free ,,

    1,,1,,,,,,,, bbbbF

    VVbbbbfii

    j itsjj

    tsitsiitsiiitsjitsjj ji =

    +

    ++

    The bordered formula above will play a crucial role in computing the equilibrium

    solution. After carefully analyzing all the mathematical assumptions that went into the

    model, I found the first order conditions of the equilibrium solution. Notice that the condi-

    tion does not apply to the maximum value of the bid maxb because the fractions would not

    be correctly defined.

    4.3 The Infinite Time Horizon

    I analyzed the Markov perfect equilibrium by looking at successive time periods

    and by finding relationships between current and continuation values. The model can be

    used directly to a game with a finite number of periods or auctions. I will show here that it

    can also be used to get an insight into the bidding behavior when the number of periods is

    infinite.

    In the infinite time horizon problem, it is crucial to understand the behavior of the

    continuation values0,, tsi

    V in the limiting case when the number of periods Tgoes to infin-

    ity T . For a fixed player i and state s, three possible cases are conceivable: (1) the

    sequence1,, 0 Ttsi

    V is convergent and thus we can write the limit as0,,

    lim tsiT

    V

    , (2) the se-

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    49/93

    Page 49

    quence1,, 0 Ttsi

    V leads to some sort of cyclical behavior in the long run, or (3) the se-

    quence fails to converge or lead to a cyclical behavior.

    The computer simulations that were run for this project suggest that the sequence

    1,, 0 TtsiV is strongly convergent. For terminal values of 0 in the last period T, sequence

    converged to %1 accuracy after less than 100 iterations. In other words, strong conver-

    gence is expected for 100T . As I will immediately show, convergence of the sequence

    1,, 0 TtsiV has profound implications on the repeated auction game with infinite periods,

    and it is an important milestone in getting a better understanding of the underlying dynam-

    ics.

    Besides the convergence results mentioned above, the simulation has also shown an

    interesting situation. If sufficiently large termination values are chosen, it is possible to

    achieve a different solution in the limit. A careful analysis suggests the existence of multi-

    ple Markov-perfect equilibria in the infinite time horizon case. Various beliefs of the con-

    tinuation values can be sustained in equilibrium. However, the equilibria generated from

    non-zero terminal values do not exhibit an unusual degree of degeneracy. As a matter of

    fact, they share the same common results in terms of bidding aggressiveness. It almost

    seems as if two sets of equilibrium continuation values differ only by a constant. The fact

    that various long run equilibria exhibit common characteristics allows me to study the case

    of zero terminal values as being representative. From now on, I will focus on the long run

    equilibrium that is an outcome of the repeated game with zero terminal values. At least

    from an empirical point of view, computer simulations suggest the Markov-perfect equilib-

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    50/93

    Page 50

    rium of this particular game exists and it is unique. Let0,,,

    lim tsiT

    si VV

    = for any player i and

    state s. This is great, because it implies a series of other results related to bidding behavior

    in the long run.

    One of the important findings relating continuation values was that

    ( ) ( )( )( )

    ( )( )))((

    ))(()(1

    11)(

    max ,,

    jki,k

    free,,,,

    ij

    free1,,

    ij

    free,,free1,,,,

    )(,,

    max

    mini,

    min,

    ,,itsii

    b

    b

    b

    b kjtsjjjtskk

    jtsi

    jitsjjitsiitsii

    tsi bdF

    bdFbFV

    bFVbb

    Vi

    j

    j

    i

    tsi

    +

    ++

    =

    +

    +

    After I replace the continuation values for period t+1 with their continuation values

    in the limit, I achieve the following result:

    ( ) ( )( )( )

    ( )( )))((

    ))(()(1

    11)(

    max ,,

    jki,k

    free,,,,

    ij

    free,

    ij

    free,,free,,,

    )(,

    max

    mini,

    min,

    ,,

    itsii

    b

    b

    b

    b kjtsjjjtskk

    jsi

    jitsjjisiitsii

    si bdF

    bdFbFV

    bFVbb

    Vi

    j

    j

    i

    tsi

    +

    ++

    =

    Thus, the maximization problem in the long run is the same for all time periods.

    Since the same problem is solved every period and it generates the same maximal value,

    the repeated auction game becomes time-homogeneous in the long run. Observe that the

    sequence of functions1,,

    )(0

    Ttsi converges to a unique value for T , because it is the

    argmax of the maximization problem. Thus, convergence of the current continuation val-

    ues for T implies the convergence of bidding behavior over time, with the limit

    )()(lim ,,, 0 = sitsiT . Please keep in mind we are not taking a sequence of real numbers to

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    51/93

    Page 51

    the limit, but a sequence offunctions with their entire structure: the domains and the actual

    transformation.

    Since the inverse bid functions are known to be stationary in the long run, lets take

    a look at the measures that quantify the probability of winning. From the perspective of

    firm i, the probability of winning after the costs are revealed are:

    ( )( )

    =ijj

    itsjjitsi bFbQfree,

    ,,,, )(1)( for i, and

    ( )( )

    =ib

    b kjtsjjjtskkitsj

    bdFbFbQ

    min

    jki,k

    free,,,,,, ))(()(1)( for ij .

    Since the probabilities of winning are direct functions of the bid functions, they are

    also stationary in the long run. Let )(lim)(0,,,=

    tsi

    Tsi QQ and )(lim)( 0,,, = tsjTsj

    QQ for

    ij . With the implications shown so far, the convergence of the continuation values im-

    plies that the auctions are time homogeneous for any given player i and state s, in other

    words they are stationary over time.

    For reasons that will become clear immediately, I am interested in the probability

    of winning not only after the costs are revealed, but also before the observation is made.

    This follows easily from the previous results:

    ( )( )= ijj

    itsjjitsibFbQ

    free,

    ,,,, )(1)(

    ( )( ) ( )=

    )(d)(1 ,,free,

    ,,,,

    max

    min,

    itsii

    b

    b ijj

    itsjjtsibFbFQ

    i

    ( )( ) ( ) iitsiitsiib

    b ijj

    itsjjtsi bbbfbFQ

    i

    d)()()(1 ' ,,,,free,

    ,,,,

    max

    min,

    =

  • 8/3/2019 Voicu Dynamics of Procurement Auctions

    52/93

    Page 52

    Since )()(lim ,,, 0 = sitsiT for any firm i, it follows that the long run probability of

    winning before the costs are revealed is:

    ( )( ) ( ) iisiisiib

    b ijj

    isjjtsiT

    si bbbfbFQQ

    i

    od)()()(1lim ',,

    free,

    ,,,,

    max

    min,

    ==

    Just as an exercise, I show analytically that the probabilities add up to one. That is,

    11

    ,, ==

    N

    i

    tsiQ for the finite game and 11

    , ==

    N

    i

    siQ for the infinite game. First, define the func-

    tion ( ) =free

    ,,, 1i

    tsiits F with the following derivative:

    ( ) ( )

    =

    free free,

    ,,,,,,, 1i ijj

    tsjjtsitsiits Ff . Then observe that:

    1)()()(d)( max,min,,,1

    ,,

    max

    min

    max

    min

    ==== =

    bbbbbQ tstsb

    bts

    b

    b

    ts

    N

    i

    tsi .

    An analogous proof leads to 1

    1

    , ==

    N

    i

    siQ for the infinite game.

    4.4 Defining Aggressiveness Measures

    Aggressiveness in procurement auctions can be under