Upload Ronald

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    1/22

    African J. Economic and Sustainable Development, Vol. 1, No. 1, 2012 27

    Copyright 2012 Inderscience Enterprises Ltd.

    Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per workerincome with a focus to agriculture: a study ofSub-Saharan Africa

    Ronald Ravinesh Kumar*

    School of Government, Development and International Affairs,

    Faculty of Business and Economics,

    FBE Green House, Laucala Campus,

    University of the South Pacific,

    Suva, Fiji

    E-mail: [email protected]*Corresponding author

    Radika Kumar

    Ministry of Foreign Affairs and International Cooperation,

    Economics Division, Level 2, South Wing BLV Complex,

    87 Queen Elizabeth Drive, Nasese,

    Suva, Fiji

    E-mail: [email protected]

    Abstract: In this study, we explore the contribution from sectoral sharetowards per worker income in the Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) region over the

    years, 1980 to 2009. Within the last three decades, agriculture and services didnot contribute positively towards growth in per worker income. Manufacturingsector on the other hand, had a transcending effect with a positive contributorypower (0.31%) towards the long-run growth and sustainability of theregion. Therefore, targeted sub-sectoral policy reforms to strengthenbackward-forward integration of agriculture and services sectors withmanufacturing operations whilst taking into account the historical diversity ofthe region are vital matters for development and growth discourse in the region.

    Keywords: agriculture; manufacturing; services; economic growth; ARDLbounds approach; Sub-Saharan Africa; SSA.

    Reference to this paper should be made as follows: Kumar, R.R. andKumar, R. (2012) Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per worker incomewith a focus to agriculture: a study of Sub-Saharan Africa, African J.Economic and Sustainable Development, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp.2748.

    Biographical notes: Ronald R. Kumar is affiliated with the School ofEconomics, Faculty of Business and Economics at the University of the SouthPacific, where he works as a Teaching Assistant. He was a recipient of theSasakawa Young Leaders Fellowship Foundation (SYLFF) award in20092010 by the School of Government, Development and InternationalAffairs under the auspices of Tokyo Foundation. He holds a MCom inEconomics and currently, he is pursuing MA in Development Studies. Hisspecific area of research includes migration, development and growtheconomics in developing countries.

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    2/22

    28 R.R. Kumar and R. Kumar

    Radika Kumar is affiliated with Ministry of Foreign Affairs and International

    Cooperation in the Government of Fiji Islands, where she works as anEconomic Planning Officer and she is currently pursuing her MCom inEconomics from the School of Economics at the University of the SouthPacific. Her area of research is on trade in services with particular focus toPacific Island countries.

    1 Introduction

    The African region is a composition of fifty-three individual countries of which 48

    countries comprise the Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) region. The countries within the

    African region have experienced varied level of progress which is characteristicallydistinguished by the pace of industrialisation, oil exports, and fragility due to

    socio-political events. Nevertheless, the challenges facing many of them are complex,

    ranging from low productivity to high unemployment and from undeveloped middle class

    to poor health and abject poverty.

    Although about a quarter of the regions economies are performing well, the

    majority of SSA countries are still lagging behind in growth, voice and democratic

    accountability, control of corruption, political stability, rule of law and lack of

    government effectiveness towards addressing environmental diversities and promoting

    social choices which are critical to social and economic progress (Sen and Scanlon, 2004;

    Sen, 1999, 1997). Further, as noted by many researchers and scholars (Nevile,

    2007; Alesina, 2003; Sen, 2000; Stiglitz and Squire, 1998; Rostow, 1985; Amin, 1972,

    among others), the exclusion from the credit market, gender related-related inequalitiesand unfavourable labour markets marred by elements and presence of colonialism and

    ethnic conflicts impinge on sectoral development and critical economic activities in the

    region.

    Subsequently, in the height of increasing food prices and the need to expedite

    productivity and economies of scale in agriculture viz. manufacturing and services

    sectors within the SSA region, the paper explores the contributory powers from these

    three key sectors within the augmented Solow model (Solow, 1956) framework with

    insights from the some of the prominent pioneers of growth theory (Domar, 1961, 1952;

    Harrod, 1959; Schumpeter, 1933). The study is of interest in at least three ways. First, the

    contribution of sectors towards the overall economic growth is underscored. Secondly,

    the study provides a sectoral approach to policy discourse which can be targeted for

    long-term development of the region. Thirdly, the study outcomes relooks, if not reminds

    the poignant history and development in agriculture vis--vis other sectors in the African

    region.

    The rest of the paper is set out as follows: a brief literature survey is provided

    exploring the development patterns in Africa with focus to agriculture development,

    followed by a short analysis on the trends and developments in sector performance. The

    fourth section discusses the data, methods and results. Finally, the paper is concluded

    with some policy directions for the SSA region.

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    3/22

    Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per worker income with a focus to agriculture 29

    2 A brief literature survey

    Agriculture development has been considered as the engine of growth for many low

    income and developing countries in terms of its contribution in providing cheap food,

    raw materials, labour, savings, and consequent spill over effect on demand for

    non-agricultural commodities (Staatz and Dembele, 2008; Diao et al., 2006; Tiffin and

    Irz, 2006; Bravo-Ortega and Lederman, 2005; Doward et al., 2004; Dorosh and

    Haggblade, 2003; Gollin et al., 2002; Timmer, 2002; Delgado et al., 1998; Lipton, 1977).

    Further, agriculture has the export generating capacity, particularly for economies that

    are in their early stages of development and heavily reliant on primary resources (Dethier

    and Effenberger, 2011; Johnston and Mellor, 1961; Lewis, 1954). It is also argued that

    the relationship between agriculture and overall economic growth is dependent on the

    degree of openness, productivity in agriculture sector versus non-agriculture, and the

    pace and effectiveness of industrialisation strategy (Gollin, 2010; Dercon, 2009).To emphasise the impact of agriculture on economic progress, various researchers

    (Bezemer and Heady, 2008; Diao et al., 2006; Mosley, 2002; Lipton, 1987) compare and

    differentiate the African agriculture development with the East Asian. They

    comparatively assess the agricultural expenditure with the price regimes, macroeconomic

    policies, political stability, health, education, and infrastructure in these regions. While

    few recent empirical analysis have shown contrary views (Gardner, 2005), quite a lot of

    studies have found agriculture as a catalyst to long run growth and development for many

    developing countries (De Janvry and Sadoulet, 2009; Self and Grabowski, 2007).

    However, balancing agriculture and industry (presumably manufacturing and

    services) is an important yet a difficult dimension of development policy given the fact

    that multi-dimensional causality between agriculture, manufacturing and services exists,

    which are largely influenced by pricing and elasticity of resources and products, relative

    differences in farm size, (incomplete) missing markets for insurance and credit or links to

    financial markets, limited market access and (imperfect) market information, insecure

    property and usage rights, unequal income distribution, access and availability of public

    goods, pace of research and innovation, labour market distortions, degree of rural-urban

    investment and climatic conditions (Dethier and Effenberger, 2011; Christiaensen et al.,

    2010; Restuccia et al., 2008; Binswanger and Deininger, 1997; Stiglitz, 1987; Bauer,

    1956, 1955).

    Within the African context, Amin (2004, 2001, 1984, 1983) in his various studies

    provides the historical diversity of Africa highlighting a gamut of factors and issues

    explaining the (under)development of African region viz. agriculture development, many

    of which by and large, are tied to the colonial and (unfair) trade systems. Furthermore,

    looking at the historical diversity of Africa, Amin points out that African society cannot

    be reduced to a single mode of production and therefore, for better understanding, need tobe segmented as:

    1 primitive community

    2 tributary

    3 slave-based

    4 small-scale trade

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    4/22

    30 R.R. Kumar and R. Kumar

    5 the capitalist all of which overlapping across different times, to vividly characterise

    the African development, resource (gold, diamonds and copper) depletion, andexploitation of (forced) cheap labour which not only made modern Africa a

    dependent peripheral societies excluded at a global level but further exacerbated the

    polarisation of wealth at the centre.

    Moreover, the individual countries in the SSA region are too small, heterogeneous and

    many of them lack the necessary resources to achieve economies of scale in the

    production and marketing of their products and therefore need to work cooperatively,

    through economic and monetary integration, as a region if they are to achieve significant

    levels of economic growth and compete in the international markets with the super

    powers and other emerging regional blocs (Staatz and Dembele, 2008; Nnanna, 2006).

    Notably, a stable and credible policy environment, an open and competitive economy,

    and a focused public sector are instrumental to development but high levels of corruption,

    volatility in real exchange rate distortions, and a lack of rule of law are most detrimentalto investment and productivity (Stiglitz and Squire, 1998). Nnanna (2006) highlights that

    the demand management strategies paired with keeping an over-valued exchange rate

    regime have been equally detrimental to the development of agriculture in African

    countries.

    Despite the evidence of growth in aid inflows to SSA region (c.f., USAID, 2011), the

    share of aid for agriculture development has fallen dramatically since 1980s, much of

    which have been channelled in the areas of political reforms (Shleifer, 2009; Goldsmith,

    2001). Evidently, all SSA countries spend less than 10% of their aid budget on

    agriculture, thus further threatening the sustainability of total factor productivity (the

    amount of output per unit of input of total factors used in the production process) growth

    in the coming years (Fan et al., 2009).

    Noting the International Monetary Funds (IMFs) failure to support recovery of manydeveloping economies, Kapur (1998) points out that most of the IMF programs in Africa

    at the end of the 1970s were not only ill-advised but also overlooked the burgeoning

    problems which emerged from the adverse socio-political activities. Similarly, Plank

    (1993) highlights that the structural and sectoral policy reforms of IMF and World Bank

    have discredited traditional notions of sovereignty in many parts of Africa which had

    adverse effects on agriculture and other productions. Stiglitz (1999) also puts some blame

    on the World Banks failure to recognise that most low-income countries, particularly in

    Africa, did not have access to international capital markets, which resulted in funds

    flowing disproportionately to a few selected countries, sectors (excluding health and

    education) and farmers particularly to finance infrastructure from which cost (of lending)

    can be recouped. Moreover, Stiglitz (2002), using examples from SSA region among

    other developing countries, condemns the IMFs structural reform policies which further

    exacerbated the existing income inequalities and wealth distribution, poverty and slow

    progress towards growth. Thompson (2004) on the other hand, in the context of World

    Trade Organizations (WTO) promotion for free-trade with respect to African Growth

    and Opportunity Act (AGOA), highlights that the latter had no positive impact on the

    macroeconomic performance and economic conditions of workers in many of the of

    African countries.

    However, the criticisms and failures of multinational corporations highlighted by

    Stiglitz (2002) are challenged as well as explicated by Ghosh (2002). Ghosh, although

    acknowledging the negative effects some developing countries experienced in their effort

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    5/22

    Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per worker income with a focus to agriculture 31

    to recover, counter argues that the sources of these failures were mainly due to the

    inherent weak internal governance structure of the countries from the past, and thereforepropose that developing regions need to:

    a have an institutional framework for global macroeconomic management

    b have a new and better international financial architecture to deal with the problems

    of crisis management and prevention

    c integrate with the world economy with the aim to promoting development (c.f.,

    Lawrence, 2007) whilst disciplining the Trans National Corporations (TNCs)

    d have in place international rules and institutions that govern cross-border movement

    of people exacerbated by globalisation.

    In regards to the manufacturing sector development and growth, Rodrik (2008) highlights

    that the former has enabled skill upgrading, capital deepening and enhancement ofworker productivity and therefore has a positive contributory power to increase income

    and employment. Further, Rajan and Subramanian (2011) underscore the use of aid in

    developing the manufacturing sector and characterise manufacturing exports as a vehicle

    for growth take-off besides having a transcending effect on economic activities.

    Moreover, many researchers have identified services sector to have a critical role in

    economic development with greater benefits evident in cases where the services are

    relatively cheaper due to low wage cost and speedy development of key sectors in the

    economy (Banga and Goldar, 2004; Kongsamut et al., 2001; Francois and Reinert, 1996;

    Bhagwati, 1984; Chenery, 1960). However splintering effect (that is, when indirect

    production activities are outsourced thus raising the demand for producer services as

    intermediate input) has influenced the growth of services sector (Bhagwati, 1984).

    Further, in some small and low income economies where sectors such as banking andfinance are not fully developed or is affected by massive capital outflows due to large

    foreign ownership, the effect on growth is either negative or nil (Kumar, 2011a, 2011b).

    On the other hand, in some relatively well developed and developing and small

    economies, services like electricity, information and communications technology (ICT),

    tourism, financial development and remittance inflows (trade in services) are critical

    drivers of growth (Jayaraman et al., 2011, 2010, 2009; Jalava and Pohjola, 2008).

    3 Trends and patterns in sectoral trade

    Agriculture is critical for both human welfare and economic growth in Africa. In SSA,

    roughly two-thirds of the population live in rural areas and are dependent on agriculture

    for their livelihoods. However, agriculture sector overall had suffered poor performance

    over the last three decades despite having momentary trajectory of good performance.

    The growth in population and consequent demand for food has resulted in expansion of

    food, however at the cost of deforestation and land degradation. Low farm productivity in

    Africa also has been attributed to the use of traditional crop varieties, shrinking plots of

    land, scarce and unreliable water supply, crop losses from pests, diseases and

    natural disasters, inequitable land-distribution patterns besides high proportion of

    population being landlocked, inefficient and unfair markets and poor agricultural and

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    6/22

    32 R.R. Kumar and R. Kumar

    transportation infrastructures (Pratt and Yu, 2009; Toenniessen et al., 2008; Collier and

    Gunnings, 1999).Table 1 shows the key indicators of the SSA region. In Table 2 to Table 4, the top ten

    sectoral shares (agriculture, manufacturing and services) are listed with the SSA region as

    a whole.

    Table 1 Selected key indicators for SSA

    Land area (sq. km. 000) 23,613.4

    Agricultural land (% of land area) (20032007) 44.2

    Population (2009: millions) 840.3

    Rural population (% of total population) (20052009) 64.0

    Per capita GDP (US$) current prices (20052009) 1,062.0

    Annual growth rate in percent (20062010) 5.4

    Annual inflation in percent (GDP deflator) (20052009) 8.7

    Fiscal balance of Central Government as percent of GDP (20052009) 13.5

    Current account balance as percent of GDP (20072010) 0.9

    External debt as a percent of GDP 23.4

    Private financial flows (net in billions USD) (20062010) 22.4

    Reserves (in billions of USD) (20062010) 146.9

    Ratio of reserves to imports of goods and services (20062010) 46.1

    Source: World Bank (2010) and IMF (2011)

    Table 2 Agriculture share (% GDP)

    Year 19851994 19952004 2005 2006 2007 2008* 2009

    Central African Republic 46.9 53.1 54.4 55.0 53.9 52.9 55.5

    Sierra Leone 42.6 51.8 51.6 51.1 49.9 50.2 51.4

    Comoros 38.9 45.5 51.0 45.2 45.3 45.8 45.2

    Ethiopia 58.6 50.1 46.7 47.9 46.2 43.8 50.7

    Congo, Dem. Rep. 38.4 49.8 45.5 45.7 42.5 40.2 42.9

    Rwanda 37.8 41.2 38.7 38.6 35.6 37.4 38.7

    Malawi 43.4 36.2 32.9 34.2 34.3 34.3 35.9

    Ghana 46.5 40.7 40.9 30.4 29.0 31.0 31.7

    Mozambique 40.5 29.4 27.0 27.9 27.7 30.5 31.5

    Gambia 29.8 31.6 32.1 30.3 28.7 28.5 27.5

    Sub-Saharan Africa 18.6 17.9 16.9 16.2 14.9 11.9 12.3

    Note: *Ranked by 2008 figures. Figures in range of years are averages calculated by theauthors.

    Source: World Bank (2010)

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    7/22

    Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per worker income with a focus to agriculture 33

    Table 3 Manufacturing share (% GDP)

    Year 19851994 19952004 2005 2006 2007 2008* 2009

    Swaziland 31.8 39.8 40.0 43.4 44.4 44.4 44.4

    Mauritius 23.8 23.0 19.8 20.0 19.8 20.1 19.4

    Lesotho 15.5 19.3 20.5 21.8 20.3 19.1 17.0

    Cote dIvoire 17.9 19.3 19.3 17.8 17.5 18.0 18.0

    South Africa 22.3 19.5 18.5 17.5 16.9 16.5 15.1

    Madagascar 10.7 11.7 14.0 14.2 15.5 15.3 15.4

    Malawi 17.2 13.4 13.9 13.6 14.1 14.2 14.5

    Mozambique 10.0 12.3 15.5 16.0 15.4 14.0 13.6

    Namibia 12.7 12.4 13.6 15.6 17.0 13.7 14.7

    Senegal 14.9 16.3 15.2 14.2 14.3 12.7 12.7

    Sub-Saharan Africa 16.9 14.7 13.1 12.6 13.9 13.4 12.8

    Notes: *Ranked by 2008 figures. Figures in range of years are averages calculated by theauthors.

    Source: World Bank (2010)

    Table 4 Services share (% GDP)

    Year 19851994 19952004 2005 2006 2007 2008* 2009

    Seychelles 77.7 70.1 75.6 77.1 77.7 77.7 78.3

    Cape Verde 65.2 71.8 74.0 73.2 73.0 72.1 70.7

    Mauritius 54.3 61.2 66.4 66.9 67.1 66.4 66.6South Africa 55.4 63.9 66.2 66.0 65.5 64.3 65.8

    Kenya 50.5 52.0 53.7 54.8 65.0 63.9 62.1

    Eritrea 60.2 59.3 56.9 57.2 56.5 63.3 63.4

    Senegal 56.6 57.3 59.5 62.2 63.0 62.8 61.7

    Madagascar 55.8 57.1 55.9 56.4 56.4 57.5 58.5

    Gambia 56.7 54.8 54.6 55.5 56.5 56.4 57.1

    Lesotho 42.7 46.0 56.3 53.5 52.8 54.3 57.5

    Sub-Saharan Africa 49.4 52.6 51.5 51.9 53.0 55.9 57.4

    Notes: *Ranked by 2008 figures. Figures in range of years are averages calculated by the

    authors.Source: World Bank (2010)

    The Table 2 to Table 4 shows the countries within the SSA region with different rankings

    for the sectoral shares to GDP. For instances, while agriculture (as a percent of GDP) is

    highest in countries like Central Republic Africa, Sierra Leone, Comoros and Ethiopia

    (Table 2), manufacturing (as a percent of GDP) is topped by Swaziland, Mauritius,

    Lesotho and Cote dIvoire among other countries (Table 3). Similarly services (as a

    percent of GDP) are highest in countries like Seychelles, Cape Verde, Mauritius and

    South Africa among others (Table 4). Overall, comparatively, manufacturing (as a

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    8/22

    34 R.R. Kumar and R. Kumar

    percent of GDP) has caught-up and even exceeded the agriculture (as a share of GDP)

    between 20072009 periods.The growth in GDP in the SSA region has been positive since 1995 and remained

    stable despite the current global economic downturn (Table 5). Similar trend is noticed in

    the growth of per capita GDP, except for 2009. In line with the positive trends in GDP

    growth, manufacturing growth remained positive and relatively higher than agriculture

    and services between the 1970 to 2006 periods. On the other hand, FDI inflows growth

    rate have been largely negative, supported by declining trends in investment. Urban

    population and overall population growth has been on the rise while growth in energy use

    indicates mixed trends.

    Table 5 Annual percentage growth of selected indicators for SSA region

    Year 19651974 19751984 19851994 19952004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

    Agriculture(%GDP)

    n.d. 1.3 2.4 3.5 4.4 3.1 3.9 3.6 3.5

    Domesticsavings(%GDP)

    1.3 2.1 1.9 0.0 0.9 0.7 5.3 3.5 3.8

    energy use percapita

    0.5 0.7 0.8 0.3 1.0 0.5 2.1 0.1 n.d.

    Exports(%GDP)

    1.0 1.0 1.0 1.1 4.5 2.2 1.4 6.2 18.8

    FDI, netinflows

    n.d. 9.9 9.8 5.1 35.7 8.1 23.1 4.8 10.3

    GDP 5.0 2.1 1.6 3.9 5.7 6.3 6.5 5.1 1.7

    GDP per capita 2.2 0.8 1.1 1.2 3.2 3.7 3.9 2.5 0.8

    Imports(%GDP)

    1.3 0.9 1.3 0.9 4.4 3.9 2.6 9.5 17.1

    Industry(%GDP)

    4.3 2.8 0.3 3.9 6.2 7.0 7.9 3.9 2.7

    Investment(%GDP)

    n.d. 2.7 1.5 0.1 4.4 3.7 7.3 7.0 2.4

    Manufacturing(%GDP)

    7.0 3.6 0.6 3.4 5.7 5.7 6.2 3.6 5.2

    Population (%) 2.6 2.9 2.8 2.6 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5 2.5

    Services(%GDP) 4.7 3.0 1.3 4.3 5.8 2.2 6.9 6.1 1.8

    UrbanPopulation

    5.1 4.8 4.5 4.1 3.8 3.9 3.9 3.9 3.8

    Source: World Bank (2010)

    Moreover, disaggregating public expenditure on various sub-sectors of the SSA region, it

    is evident that the largest share (as a percent) is attributed to fuel and energy production,

    manufacturing, construction and general administration, while the least is in transport and

    communication (services) and agriculture between 2000-2005 periods (Table 6).

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    9/22

    Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per worker income with a focus to agriculture 35

    Table 6 Composition of public expenditure (%)

    Year Agriculture Education HealthTransport andcommunication

    Socialsecurity

    Defence Other*

    1980 7.1 14.4 4.9 11.0 2.9 19.7 40.1

    1990 5.5 14.5 4.5 4.5 2.5 17.1 51.5

    2000 3.8 14.1 6.7 4.7 5.0 8.8 56.9

    SubSaharanAfrica

    2005 6.3 15.4 8.1 5.8 2.8 6.5 55.1

    Note: *Others include fuel and energy, manufacturing, and construction, and generaladministration.

    Source: Taken from World Bank as reported in Fan et al. (2009, p.4).

    4 Data, method and results

    For the purpose of this study, all three sectors are assumed to be critical for the economic

    growth of SSA region. However, at the outset, the impact of each sector on per worker

    income cannot be overly speculated and therefore largely depend on the overall

    performance from the sectors. For instances, the development in agriculture is largely

    influenced by myriad of factors constraining its growth as discussed in the literature

    earlier on. Similarly, low levels of investment and decline in exports and foreign direct

    investment are likely to have adverse impact on service sector performance.

    The analysis uses 30 years annual data for the period 19802009. The capital stock

    utilised for the study has been built up by a perpetual inventory method.1 Population is

    used as a proxy for labour stock since there is no consistent time series data on

    employment. All data including agriculture (AGRt)

    2

    , manufacturing (MANt)

    3

    and services(SERt)

    4 as a percent of GDP respectively, are sourced from the World Development

    Indicators and Global Development Finance, World Bank (2010) database.

    Subsequently, AGRt, MANt, and SERt are used in the conventional Cobb-Douglas

    production function, with the Hicksneutral technical progress. The per worker output

    (yt) equation is defined as:

    , where 0 1t t ty A k = < < (1)

    whereA = stock of technology and k= capital per worker, and is the profit share. The

    Solow model assumes that the evolution of technology is given by

    0T

    tA A e= (2)

    whereA0 is the initial stock of knowledge and Tis time.To capture the effect of,AGRt,MANt, and SERton total factor productivity (TFP),At

    is defined as:

    ( ), , ,t t t t A f T AGR MAN SER= (3)

    which is expanded as:

    0gT

    t t t t A A e AGR MAN SER = (4)

    and therefore:

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    10/22

    36 R.R. Kumar and R. Kumar

    ( )0gT

    t t t t t

    y A e AGR MAN SER k = (5)

    and finally, the above can be formulated as:

    ,t t t t t Ly g LAGR LMAN LSER = + + + (6)

    where, L denotes difference in logs of respective variables, and the intercept term gt isthe steady state growth rate of output (TFP) due to other likely growth factors not

    included in the analyses.

    Since the number of observations is small, the bounds testing approach under ARDL

    procedure developed by Pesaran et al. (2001) is deployed. In bounds testing approach,

    pre-testing of unit roots is not required and it is possible to investigate cointegration of

    the levels of the variables, irrespective of their order. However, with a view to meeting

    the criticism that it is difficult to accept that variables of different orders are cointegrated,the unit root tests first conducted to ensure they are of the same order before entering

    them into the analyses.

    In computing unit root tests to examine the time series properties of the variables, the

    ADF and Phillips-Perron test statistics are used. From the test results, all variables are

    non-stationary in their levels however they are stationary in their first differences

    (Table 7).

    Table 7 Results of unit root tests

    ADF Phillips and PerronVariable

    Level First difference Level First difference

    Ly 1.854 3.321 * 2.929 2.66 *Lk 1.606 3.869 *** 3.545 3.47 **

    LAGR 0.760 4.604 *** 0.746 4.55 ***

    LMAN 2.725 3.195 ** 2.653 5.39 ***

    LSER 1.853 4.907 *** 2.091 4.93 ***

    Notes: The ADF critical values are based on Mckinnon. The optimal lag is chosen on thebasis of Akaike Information Criterion (AIC). The null hypothesis for both ADFand Phillips-Perron tests is a series has a unit root (non-stationary). ***, **, and*denotes the rejection of the null hypothesis of unit root at 1%, 5%, and 10% levelof significance respectively.

    The next step is to examine the existence of a long run relationship between yt, kt,AGRt,

    MANtand SERtby using bounds test.The ARDL equations are specified as follows:

    10 11 1 12 1 13 1 14 1

    15 1 16 11 12

    1 0

    13 14 15 1

    0 0 0

    t t t t t

    p p

    t i t i i t i

    i i

    p p p

    i t i i t i i t i t

    i i i

    Ly Ly Lk LAGR LMAN

    LSER TREND Ly Lk

    LAGR LMAN LSER

    = =

    = = =

    = + + + +

    + + + +

    + + + +

    (7)

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    11/22

    Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per worker income with a focus to agriculture 37

    20 21 1 22 1 23 1 24 1

    25 1 26 21 22

    1 0

    23 24 25 2

    0 0 0

    t t t t t

    p p

    t i t i i t i

    i i

    p p p

    t i t i i t i t

    i i i

    Lk Ly Lk LAGR LMAN

    LSER TREND Ly Lk

    LAGR LMAN LSER

    = =

    = = =

    = + + + +

    + + + +

    + + + +

    (8)

    30 31 1 32 1 33 1 34 1

    35 1 36 31 32

    0 0

    33 34 35 31 0 0

    t t t t t

    p p

    t i t i i t i

    i i

    p p p

    i t i i t i i t i t i i i

    LAGR Ly Lk LAGR LMAN

    LSER TREND Ly Lk

    LAGR LMAN LSER

    = =

    = = =

    = + + + +

    + + + +

    + + + +

    (9)

    40 41 1 42 1 43 1 44 1

    45 1 46 41 42

    0 0

    43 1 44 1 45 1 4

    0 1 1

    t t t t t

    p p

    t i t i i t i

    i i

    p p p

    i t i t i t t

    i i i

    LMAN Ly Lk LAGR LMAN

    LSER TREND Ly Lk

    LAGR LMAN LSER

    = =

    = = =

    = + + + +

    + + + +

    + + + +

    (10)

    50 51 1 52 1 53 1 54 1

    55 1 56 51 520 0

    53 54 55 5

    0 1 1

    t t t t t

    p p

    t i t i i t ii i

    p p p

    i t i i t i i t i t

    i i i

    LSER Ly Lk LAGR LMAN

    LSER TREND Ly Lk

    LAGR LMAN LSER

    = =

    = = =

    = + + + +

    + + + +

    + + + +

    (11)

    Table 8 Results of bound tests

    Dependent variable Computed F-statistic

    Lyt 7.17*

    Lkt 3.24

    LAGRt 3.62

    LMANt 1.63

    LSERt 1.41

    Pesaran, Shin and Smith. (2001)a

    Critical value Lower bound value Upper bound value

    1% 4.40 5.72

    5% 3.47 4.57

    Notes: Table CI. v: Case V with unrestricted intercept and unrestricted trend, p.300;*indicates significance at 1% level.

    Source: aCritical values are obtained from Pesaran et al. (2001)

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    12/22

    38 R.R. Kumar and R. Kumar

    There are two steps in examining the relationship between Lyt, Lkt, LAGRt, LMANt and

    LSERt. First, equations (7) to (11) are estimated by ordinary least squares techniques.Second, the existence of a long-run relationship can be traced by imposing a restriction

    on all estimated coefficients of lagged level variables equating to zero. Hence, bounds

    test is based on the F-statistics (or Wald statistics) with the null hypothesis of no

    cointegration (H0: = i1 = i2 = i3 = i4 = i5 = 0) against its alternative hypothesis of a

    long-run cointegration relationship (H1: i1i2i3i4i5 0). The results of thebounds test are reported in Table 8, confirming the presence of a long run relationship

    amongst the variables when only real output per worker (Lyt) is set as the dependent

    variable. The computed F-statistics forLyt is 7.17, which is significant at 1% level.

    Table 9 Autoregressive distributed lag estimates

    ARDL (1, 1, 0, 0, 0) selected based on Akaike information criterion

    Dependent variable is LY

    30 observations used for estimation from 1980 to 2009

    Regressor Coefficient Standard error t-Ratio

    LY(1) 0.3543 *** 0.0956 3.706

    LK 1.1594 *** 0.2613 4.437

    LK(1) 0.9740 *** 0.1984 4.909

    LAGR 0.1722 *** 0.0364 4.728

    LMAN 0.2033 *** 0.0489 4.156

    LSER 0.7129 *** 0.0825 8.638

    C 5.4576 *** 0.6643 8.215

    T 0.0060 *** 0.0008 7.289

    R2 = 0.99182 2R

    = 0.98220

    S.E. of regression = 0.00722 F-statistics [F( 7, 22)] = 381.085

    Mean of dependent variable = 6.28910 S.D. of dependent variable = 0.06952

    Residual sum of squares = 0.00115 Equation Log-likelihood = 109.998

    Akaike info. criterion = 101.998 Schwarz Bayesian criterion = 96.3931

    DW-statistic = 1.74340 Durbins h-statistic = 0.82480

    Diagnostic tests

    Test statistics LM version F version

    p-value p-value

    (A): Serial correlation 2(1) = 0.5891 0. 443 F(1, 21) = 0.4206 0.524

    (B): Functional form 2(1) = 0.5853 0. 444 F(1, 21) = 0.4179 0.525

    (C): Normality 2(2) = 0.2997 0. 861 Not applicable

    (D): Heteroscedasticity 2(1) = 0.0195 0.889 F( 1, 28) = 0.01820 0.894

    Notes: ***Acceptance of coefficient at 1% level of significance;Rejection of null hypothesis of (A)(D) biasness at 1% level of significance.

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    13/22

    Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per worker income with a focus to agriculture 39

    Having confirmed the existence of a long-run relationship between output (yt) with

    capital stock (kt), AGRt, MANt, and SERt, a number of diagnostic test results (see thelower panel of Table 9), such as Lagrange multiplier test of residual serial correlation,

    Ramseys RESET test using the square of the fitted values for correct functional form,

    normality test based on a test of skewness and kurtosis of residuals, and

    heteroscedasticity test based on the regression of squared residuals on squared fitted

    values, showed that the equation performed well as the disturbance terms are normally

    distributed and serially uncorrelated with homoscedasticity of residuals, duly confirming

    the model has a correct functional form. Besides, the CUSUM and CUSUM of Squares

    plot (Figure 1 and Figure 2) shows the parameters of the model are relatively stable over

    time.

    Figure 1 Plot of cumulative sum of recursive residuals

    -5

    -10

    -15

    0

    5

    10

    15

    1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

    Note: The straight lines represent critical bounds at 5% significance level

    Figure 2 Plot of cumulative sum of squares of recursive residuals

    -0.5

    0.0

    0.5

    1.0

    1.5

    1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

    Note: The straight lines represent critical bounds at 5% significance level

    The ARDL estimate (Table 9) indicates a positive lagged effect of income to long run

    growth (0.35), which is plausibly due to effective overall growth policies in the SSA

    region. The high capital share in the equation is offset by the negative share in the

    lag-one period, which is plausibly due to poor use of technology and capital stock

    depletion in later periods. Further, agriculture and services have negative income

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    14/22

    40 R.R. Kumar and R. Kumar

    elasticity, which implies that as income increased, the contribution from agriculture and

    services declined.

    Table 10 Dependent variable:RGDP/Labour(Ly) ARDL(1, 1, 0, 0, 0)

    Long-run coefficients Short-run coefficients

    Regressor CoefficientStandard

    erort-ratio Regressor Coefficient

    Standarderror

    t-ratio

    Lk 0.2870 *** 0.07409 3.8734 Lk 1.1594 *** 0.26127 4.4374

    LAGR 0.2668 *** 0.06355 4.1990 LAGR 0.1723 *** 0.03644 4.7278

    LMAN 0.3149 *** 0.07789 4.0433 LMAN 0.2033 *** 0.04893 4.1555

    LSER 1.1042 *** 0.16972 6.5064 LSER 0.7130 *** 0.08254 8.6382

    C 8.4527 *** 1.15820 7.2980 C 5.4576 *** 0.66431 8.2155

    T 0.0093 *** 0.00186 5.0109 T 0.0060 *** 0.00827 7.2894ECT(1) 0.6457 *** 0.09561 6.7532

    Short-run equation statistics

    R2 = 0.90608 2R

    = 0.87619

    S.E. of regression = 0.00722 F-statistics [F(6, 23)] = 35.3723

    Mean of dependentvariable

    = 0.00213 S.D. of dependent variable = 0.02053

    Residual sum of squares = 0.00114 Equation Log-likelihood = 109.998

    Akaike Info. Criterion = 101.998 Schwarz Bayesiancriterion

    = 96.3931

    DW-statistics = 1.74340

    ECT = Ly 0.2870Lk + 0.2668LAGR 0.3149LMAN + 1.1042LSER 0.0093T 8.4527

    Note: ***Significant at 1% level

    The long-run estimation (Table 10) shows similar outcomes as Table 9. The capital stock

    share is about 0.29 which is close to the stylised value of one-third (c.f., Rao, 2010; Ertur

    and Koch, 2007). Furthermore, the elasticity for agriculture is 0.27 and services is 1.10

    while the manufacturing sector has the elasticity of 0.31, all significant at 1% level. Time

    trend5, is positive and significant, both in the long run (0.009) and the short-run (0.006),

    however having a marginal contributory power towards per worker income, indicating

    weak response to supply side shocks. The trend captures (positively) the supply side

    responses such as investment decisions, labour market distortions and credit expansions

    in the short and long run respectively.

    Further, in the short-run, the manufacturing sector elasticity coefficient is 0.20 whichis positive and significant at 1% level. On the other hand, the agriculture and services

    have a negative elasticity of 0.17 and 0.71 accordingly. These results underscore the

    production shift towards manufacturing as the economy grows relative to agriculture and

    services. Evidently, the long-run elasticity is larger than the short-run because prices are

    not completely flexible and hence (labour) markets are slow to clear in the short run.

    Further, the Granger causality test was conducted to identify the causation effect

    (Table 11). The results show unidirectional relationship running from output to capital,

    from manufacturing to output, and from manufacturing to capital stock. Therefore, it is

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    15/22

    Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per worker income with a focus to agriculture 41

    evident that growth in output Granger-cause growth in capital; growth in manufacturing

    base Granger-cause growth in output and growth in capital stock accordingly.

    Table 11 Granger causality tests with ECT from bounds test

    F-statistics

    Ly Lk LAGR LMAN LSER

    ECT(t-statistics)

    Ly 2.33458* 1.78771 0.5001 0.7734 0.6457

    (6.7532)

    Lk 1.0100 1.7635 0.1206 1.1776 0.20208

    (15.6453)

    LAGR 0.5171 0.7046 0.7266 1.5920 1.4445

    (7.9702)

    LMAN 3.4005** 2.5609* 1.8715 0.8065 0.62023

    (3.1603)

    LSER 1.3591 1.6301 1.2196 0.5643 1.2832

    (6.0297)

    Notes: *, **, and *** indicates rejection of the null hypothesis of no causality at 10% and5% respectively;and indicates significance level at 1% and 5% respectively based ont-statistics and correct sign.

    5 Conclusions and policy discussion

    We have shown that agriculture and services sectors had negative elasticity coefficients,

    whilst manufacturing sector had positively contributed towards improving per worker

    income in the SSA region. The study resonates, if not underscores, some of the

    concerning and long-standing poignant issues in agricultural and other production sectors

    in the African region highlighted by some of the prominent scholars (Sen, 2000; Stiglitz

    and Squire, 1998; Rostow, 1985; Amin, 1972; among others).

    In light of the results, it is clear that SSA countries need to increase their budgetary

    allocations to agriculture. A big challenge looming ahead for the countries is the recent

    surge in world food prices, the recent financial crisis and the series of disasters affecting

    the horn of Africa which threatens to reverse any past gains in poverty reduction. Higher

    food prices will severely affect rural and urban consumers, especially among the poor. By

    increasing spending in agriculture and rural development now, the region can avert this

    threat by rapidly increasing agricultural productivity and ensuring a long term and stable

    supply of affordable food to millions (Fan et al., 2009).

    Our results also coincides with the notion that agriculture-led path out of poverty does

    not occur automatically simply if the agricultural sector grows. It will require that

    agricultural growth be spread among a broad class of smallholder entrepreneurs to

    broaden the demand for labour-intensive goods and that some of that growth be tapped

    for investment in education, health, infrastructure and better-functioning labour markets

    (Ulimwengu and Sanyal, 2011; Staatz and Dembele, 2008).

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    16/22

    42 R.R. Kumar and R. Kumar

    Subsequently, each country within the SSA region should focus on key sector reforms

    that are most likely to have the largest impact at every stage of economic development.For example, the agriculture and land use policy can be reviewed to promote clear flow

    of benefits from the ownership of land. Fostering sustained growth through domestic and

    foreign investment, private sector development, improved public sector management and

    sectoral development within the overarching framework of good governance are vital.

    Additionally, voice and accountability, political stability, corruption control and rule

    of law are critical for equitable growth. Countries in North Africa that experienced high

    growth such as Tunisia and Egypt have also experienced social unrest and undergone

    regime change, stemmed by highly inequitable growth and unproductive or non-existent

    job prospects and corrupt institutions, making some of the SSA countries highly

    susceptible to unrest. Further, such social unrests and prolonged civil wars divert

    resources, including human capital, away from productive income generating activities.

    Poor infrastructure and high cost of transportation impose substantial barriers to entry,thus allowing transport companies to maintain a monopoly and charge prohibitively high

    prices. Gender equality and female empowerment and participation in all sectors, backed

    by increased health expenditure towards improving well being and reducing child and

    maternal mortality are required so as to freeing up and strengthening resources for

    productive activities which can be deployed to critical sectors of the economy.

    Natural disasters quite often hit hard the horn of Africa creating a grave concern on

    the staple food security and sustainable livelihood of many besides population

    displacement. Therefore, disaster and crisis management need to be organised and aid

    from donors need to focus more on investing in technologies to anticipate and formulate

    strategies to manage these crisis and support agriculture. Moreover, noting that

    development aid flows to Africa from multinational corporations (IMF and World Bank)

    have resulted in controversial, if not contrary outcomes, the donor and recipient (SSA)

    countries need to explore better mechanism to channel aid which is linked to solid

    growth initiatives and projects to have a welfare enhancing effect.

    Further, projects related to agro-marketing need to be promoted and monitored so that

    benefits reach the small holder farmers. The drive need to come from relevant

    government bodies such and non-government organisation with an inclusive approach to

    dialogue. Ensuring the availability of investment fund to buy land and other capital inputs

    for agricultural production, effective coordination of agri-business with financial services

    and integrating private sector participation including manufacturing and services sector

    operations with agriculture development initiatives will create the environment for

    overall growth and development. For instance, linking tourism (service) and food

    processing (manufacturing) with locally produced commodities will boost domestic

    agriculture. Further, encouraging private sector and non-government organisation

    partnership in sub-sectors like fisheries, forestry, cash-crop industries among others aresome important areas to look at. Among other things, the focus need to be more on

    branding, promoting and diversifying domestically produced commodities both in local

    and international markets to reduce dependency on imported items, and tax incentives

    and subsidies need to be defined and engineered to support growth in sectoral

    (agriculture, manufacturing and services) productivity.

    In addition, specific sub-sector based (scientific and non-scientific) research, training

    and capacity building in areas of agriculture development, financial literacy and the use

    of technology and media to access and penetrate local and international markets for new

    and existing commodities need to be promoted.

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    17/22

    Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per worker income with a focus to agriculture 43

    The legal aspects governing the sectoral investment need to be scrutinised so that

    (new) investors are incentivised to invest in without compromising the law and order.Therefore, the right institutional environment and infrastructure need to be in place so

    that various key sector performances can be enhanced at operational and managerial

    levels.

    Finally, the effective participation of the SSA countries in the multilateral rules of

    trade via WTO and other regional trade bodies are vital. In order for the agricultural

    sector to expand and gain efficiency, bringing competition in the sectors is imperative.

    Active negotiations by the countries for its offensive and defensive tariff are vital, whist

    striving to suss out ways in which trade can promote their development optimally. Sub

    sectors within the agricultural sector which are inefficient need to be liberalised (if not

    reformed) as well as Green box subsidies can be provided to ensure that the sector

    improves over time. In contrast to this, the more productive sectors such as

    manufacturing which are duly competitive can offset the effects of preference erosionthrough tariff reductions in agriculture. It is imperative that the countries also identify

    precisely their special and sensitive products in the agricultural sector for the agricultural

    modality in the recent Doha rounds and also make targeted cuts in non-agricultural

    market access (NAMA) commodities or choose the best mix of tariff cuts, whilst

    providing the countries more room for policy space on one hand (c.f., Stiglitz and

    Charlton, 2005) and having a binding mechanisms which ensures monetary compensation

    in cases where poor countries lose out as a result of subsidies and preference erosion, on

    the other. Moreover, the need for solidifying North-South cooperation, particularly in

    relation to investment in agriculture, energy, raw materials, reforestation, and disaster and

    crisis management, in order to have resource foundations for growth in both regions and

    to assure resources are priced reasonably to permit growth in both regions are critical for

    long-run growth and sustainable development.

    Acknowledgements

    The corresponding author would like to thank the SYLFF for the opportunity to pursue

    this research. Further, the authors would like to sincerely thank the anonymous reviewers

    and referees for their invaluable comments and suggestions.

    References

    Alesina, A. (2003) Joseph Schumpeter lecture: the size of countries: does it matter?, Journal ofthe European Economic Association, Vol. 1, Nos. 2/3, pp.301316.

    Amin, S. (1972) Underdevelopment and dependence in black Africa-origins and contemporaryforms,Journal of Modern African Studies, Vol. 10, No.4, pp.503524.

    Amin, S. (1983) Expansion or crisis of capitalism?, Third World Quarterly, Vol.5, No. 2,pp.361385.

    Amin, S. (1984) Democracy and national strategy in the periphery, Third World Quarterly,Vol. 9, No. 4, pp.11291156.

    Amin, S. (2001) World conference on racism: asking the real questions,Economic and PoliticalWeekly, Vol. 36, No. 49, pp.45234534.

    Amin, S. (2004) On China: market socialism, a stage in the long socialist transition or shortcut tocapitalism?, Social Scientist, Vol. 32, Nos. 11/12, pp.320.

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    18/22

    44 R.R. Kumar and R. Kumar

    Banga, R. and Goldar, B. (2004) Contribution of services to output growth and productivity in

    Indian manufacturing: pre and post reforms, Working Paper No. 139, July, Indian Council forResearch on International Economic Relations, India, available athttp://www.etsg.org/ETSG2004/Papers/banga.pdf (accessed on 09 March 2011).

    Bauer, P.T. (1955) The economic development of Nigeria,Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 63,No. 5, pp.398411.

    Bauer, P.T. (1956) The economic development of Nigeria: a reply,Journal of Political Economy,Vol. 64, No. 5, pp.435441.

    Bezemer, D. and Headey, D. (2008) Agriculture, development, and urban bias, WorldDevelopment, Vol. 36, No. 8, pp.13421364.

    Bhagwati, J.N. (1984) Splintering and disembodiment of services and developing nations, TheWorld Economy, Vol. 7, No. 2, pp.133143.

    Binswanger, H.P. and Deininger, K. (1997) Explaining agricultural and agrarian policies indeveloping countries,Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, No. 4, pp.19582005.

    Bravo-Ortega, C. and Lederman, D. (2005) Agriculture and national welfare around the world:causality and international heterogeneity since 1960, World Bank Policy Research PaperNo. 3499, The World Bank, Washingtom DC.

    Chenery, H.B. (1960) Patterns of industrial growth, American Economic Review, Vol. 50, No. 4,pp.624654.

    Christiaensen, L., Demery, L. and Kuhl, J. (2010) The (evolving) role of agriculture in povertyreduction an empirical perspective, Worker Paper No. 2010/36, UNU-WIDER, available athttp://www.wider.unu.edu/publications/working-papers/2010/en_GB/wp2010-36/_files/83339553673248837/default/wp2010-36.pdf (accessed on 4 March 2011).

    Collier, P. and Gunning, J.W. (1999) Why has Africa grown slowly?, The Journal of EconomicPerspectives, Vol. 13, No. 3, pp.322.

    De Janvry, A. and Sadoulet, E. (2009) Agriculture growth and poverty reduction: additionalevidence, The World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 25, No. 1, pp.120.

    Delgado, C., Hopkins, J., Kelly, V.A. and Hazell, P.B.R. (1998) Agricultural growth linkages inSub-Saharan Africa, Research Report 107, International Food Policy Research Institute,Washington, D.C.

    Dercon, S. (2009) Rural poverty: old challenges in new contexts, The World Bank ResearchObserver, Vol. 24, No. 1, pp.128.

    Dethier, J. and Effenberger, A. (2011) Agriculture and development a brief review of theliterature,Policy Research Working Paper WP5553, World Bank, Washington D.C.,available at http://www-wds.worldbank.org/servlet/WDSContentServer/WDSP/IB/2011/01/31/000158349_20110131131635/Rendered/PDF/WPS5553.pdf (accessed on 4 March 2011).

    Diao, X., Hazell, P.B.R., Resnick, D. and Thurlow, J. (2006) The role of agriculture indevelopment: implications for Sub-Saharan Africa, IFPRI Development Strategy and PolicyDivision Discussion Paper No. 29, International Food Policy Research Institute, WashingtonD.C., available at http://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/publications/rr153.pdf (accessed on18 March 2011).

    Domar, E.D. (1952) Economic growth: an econometric approach, American Economic Review,Vol. 42, No. 2, pp.479495.

    Domar, E.D. (1961) On the measurement of technological change, Economic Journal, Vol. 71,No. 284, pp.709729.

    Dorosh, P. and Haggblade, S. (2003) Growth linkages, price effects and income distribution inSub-Saharan Africa,Journal of African Economies, Vol. 12, No. 2, pp.207235.

    Doward, A., Kydd, J., Morrison, J. and Urey, I. (2004) A policy agenda for pro-poor agriculturalgrowth, World Development, Vol. 32, No. 1, pp.7389.

    Ertur, C. and Koch, W. (2007) Growth, technological Interdependence and spatial externalities:theory and evidence,Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 22, No. 6, pp.10331062.

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    19/22

    Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per worker income with a focus to agriculture 45

    Fan, S., Omilola, B. and Lambert, M. (2009) Public spending for agriculture in Africa: trends and

    composition, regional strategic analysis and knowledge support system (ReSAKSS),Working Paper No. 28, April, Washington, D.C., ReSAKSS, available athttp://www.resakss.org/index.php?pdf=42375 (accessed on 3 April 2011).

    Francois, J.F. and Reinert, K.A. (1996) The role of services in the structure of production andtrade: stylized facts from a cross-country analysis, Asia-Pacific Economic Review, Vol. 2,No. 1, pp.3543, available at http://www.i4ide.org/people/~francois/docs/text9505.pdf(accessed on 10 March 2011).

    Gardner, L.B. (2005) Causes of rural development, Agricultural Economics, Vol. 32, No. 1,pp.2141.

    Ghosh, D.N. (2002) Globalization, the IMF and governance, Economic and Political Weekly,Vol. 37, No. 39, pp.39803982.

    Goldsmith, A.A. (2001) Donors, dictators and democrats in Africa, The Journal of ModernAfrican Studies, Vol. 39, No. 3, pp.411436.

    Gollin, D. (2010) Agricultural productivity and economic growth, in Evenson, R. and Pingali, P.(Eds.):Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 4, North Holland, Amsterdam.

    Gollin, D., Parente, S. and Rogerson, R. (2002) The role of agriculture in development, TheAmerican Economic Review, Vol. 92, No. 2, pp.160164.

    Harrod, R.F. (1959) Domar and dynamic economics, The Economic Journal, Vol. 69, No. 275,pp.451464.

    International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2011) Tensions from the two-speed recovery unemployment,commodities, and capital flows, World Economic Outlook, April, IMF, available athttp://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2011/01/pdf/text.pdf (accessed on 12 April 2011).

    Jalava, J. and Pohjola, M. (2008) The roles of electricity and ICT in economic growth,Exploration in Economic History, Vol. 45, No. 3, pp.270287.

    Jayaraman, T.K., Choong, C.K. and Kumar, R. (2009) Role of remittances in economic growth inPacific Island Countries: a study of Samoa, Perspectives on Global Development andTechnology, Vol. 8, No. 17, pp.611627.

    Jayaraman, T.K., Choong, C.K. and Kumar, R. (2010) Role of remittances in Tongan economy,Migration Letters, Vol. 7, No. 2, pp.224230.

    Jayaraman, T.K., Choong, C-K. and Kumar, R. (2011) Role of remittances in small Pacific Islandeconomies: an empirical study of Fiji, International Journal of Economics and BusinessResearch, Vol. 3, No. 5, pp.526542.

    Johnston, B.F. and Mellor, J.W. (1961) The role of agriculture in economic development,American Economic Review, Vol. 51, No. 4, pp.566593.

    Kapur, D. (1998) The IMF: a cure or a curse?, Foreign Policy, No. 111, pp.114129, available athttp://www.jstor.org/stable/1149382 (accessed on 28 October 2011).

    Kongsamut, P., Rebelo, S. and Xie, D. (2001) Beyond balanced growth, The Review of EconomicStudies, Vol. 68, No. 4, pp.869882.

    Kumar, R.R. (2011a) Chapter 26. Role of trade openness, remittances, capital inflows, andfinancial development in Vanuatu in Ibrahim Sirkeci, in Cohen, J.H. and Ratha, D. (Eds.):

    Migration and Remittances during the Global Financial Crisis and Beyond, the World Bank,Washington D.C., ISBN: 978-0-8213-8826-6.

    Kumar, R.R. (2011b) Do remittances, exports and financial development matter for economicgrowth? A case study of Pakistan using bounds approach,Journal of International AcademicResearch, Vol. 11, No. 1, pp.1827.

    Lawrence, R.Z. (2007) Review: a true development round? A review of Joseph E. Stiglitz andAndrew Chartons fair trade for all: how trade can promote development, Journal ofEconomic Literature, Vol. 45, No. 4, pp.10011010.

    Lewis, A.W. (1954) Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour, The ManchesterSchool, Vol. 28, No, 2, pp.139191.

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    20/22

    46 R.R. Kumar and R. Kumar

    Lipton, M. (1977) Why Poor People Stay Poor: A Study of Urban Bias in World Development,

    Temple Smith, London.Lipton, M. (1987) Improving Agriculture Aid Impact on Low-Income Countries, Institute of

    Development Studies, Sussex.

    Mosley, P. (2002) The African green revolution as a pro-poor policy instrument, Journal ofInternational Development, Vol. 14, No. 6, pp.695724.

    Nevile A. (2007) Amartya K. Sen and social exclusion,Development in Practice, Vol. 17, No. 2,pp.249255.

    Nnanna, O.L. (2006) Economic and monetary integration in Africa, Presented at the G24Meetings in Singapore, 14 September 2006, available at http://www.wami-imao.org/english/doc/MONETARY%20AND%20ECONOMIC%20INTEGRATION%20IN%20AFRICA.FINAL.pdf (accessed on 26 July 2011).

    Pesaran, M.H., Shin, Y. and Smith, R. (2001) Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of levelrelationships,Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 16, No. 3, pp.289326.

    Plank, D.N. (1993) Aid, debt, and the end of sovereignty: Mozambique and its donors, Journal ofModern African Studies, Vol. 31, No. 3, pp.407430.

    Pratt, N.A. and Yu, B. (2009) An updated look at the recovery of agricultural productivity inSub-Saharan Africa, Paper presented at theInternational Association of AgriculturalEconomists Conference, 1622 August, Beijing, China,http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/51731/2/Nin-Pratt_%23485-IAAE09.pdf (accessed on3 April 2011).

    Rajan, R.G. and Subramanian, A. (2011) Aid, Dutch disease, and manufacturing growth,Journalof Development Economics, Vol. 94, No. 1, pp.106118.

    Rao, B.B. (2010) Estimates of the steady state growth rates for selected Asian countries with anextended Solow model,Economic Modelling, Vol. 27, No. 1, pp.4653.

    Restuccia, D., Yang, D.T. and Zhu, X. (2008) Agriculture and aggregate productivity: aquantitative cross-country analysis, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 55, No. 2,pp.234250.

    Rodrik, D. (2008) Understanding South Africas economic puzzles, Economics of Transition,Vol. 16, No. 4, pp.769797.

    Rostow, W.W. (1985) The World Economy since 1945: a stylized historical analysis, EconomicHistory Review, Vol. 38, No. 2, pp.252275.

    Schumpeter, J. (1933) The common sense of econometrics,Econometrica, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp.512.

    Self, S. and Grabowski, R. (2007) Economic development and the role of agriculture technology,Agricultural Economics, Vol. 36, No. 3, pp.395404.

    Sen A. (1997) From income inequality to economic inequality, Southern Economic Journal,Vol. 64, No. 2, pp.383401.

    Sen, A. (1999) The possibility of social choice, American Economic Review, Vol. 89, No. 3,pp.349378.

    Sen, A. (2000) Social exclusion: concept, application and scrutiny, Social Development PaperNo. 1, Manila Asian Development Bank, available athttp://www.adb.org/documents/books/social_exclusion/Social_exclusion.pdf (accessed on27 July 2011].

    Sen, A. and Scanlon, T. (2004) Whats the point of democracy?, Bulletin of the AmericanAcademy of Arts and Sciences, Vol. 57, No. 3, pp.811.

    Shleifer, A. (2009) Peter Bauer and the failure of foreign aid, Cato Journal, Vol. 29, No. 3,pp.379390.

    Solow, R.M. (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth, Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, Vol. 70, No. 1, pp.6594.

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    21/22

    Exploring sectoral elasticity vis--vis per worker income with a focus to agriculture 47

    Staatz, J.M. and Dembele, N.N. (2008) Agriculture for development in Sub-Saharan Africa,

    Background Paper No. 41378, World Development Report, available athttp://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWDR2008/Resources/2795087-1191427986785/StaatzJ&DembeleN_AgriForDevtInSSA_ve19.pdf(accessed on 3 April 2011).

    Stiglitz J.E. (2002) Globalization and Its Discontents, W.W. Norton and Company, New York,USA.

    Stiglitz, J.E. and Squire, L. (1998) International development: is it possible?,Foreign Policy,No. 110, pp.138151, available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/1149282 (accessed on28 October 2011).

    Stiglitz, J.E. (1987) Some theoretical aspects of agricultural policies, World Bank Observer,Vol. 2, No. 1, pp.4360.

    Stiglitz, J.E. (1999) The world at the millennium, Economic Journal, Vol. 109, No. 459,pp.F577F597.

    Stiglitz, J.E. and Charlton, A. (2005) Fair Trade for All: How Trade Can Promote Development,Oxford University Press, New York.

    Thompson, C.B. (2004) US trade with Africa: African growth & opportunity?, Review of AfricanPolitical Economy, Vol. 31, No. 101, pp.457474.

    Tiffin, R. and Irz, X. (2006) Is agriculture the engine of growth?, Agricultural Economics,Vol. 35, No. 1, pp.7989.

    Timmer, C.P. (2002) Agriculture and economics development, in Gardner, B. and Rausser, G.(Eds.):Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 2A, pp.14871546, Elsevier, Amsterdam.

    Toenniessen, G., Adesina, A. and DeVries, J. (2008) Building an alliance for a green revolution inAfrica, Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences, Vol. 1136, No. 1, pp.233242,available at http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1196/annals.1425.028/pdf (accessed on3 April 2011).

    Ulimwengu, J. and Sanyal, P. (2011) Using a spatial growth model to provide evidence ofagricultural spillovers between countries in the NEPAD CAADP framework,IFPRI Working

    Paper No. 01069, IFPRI, available athttp://www.ifpri.org/sites/default/files/publications/ifpridp01069.pdf (accessed on3 April 2011).

    USAID (2011) Horn of Africa-Drought, Fact Sheet #3, Fical Year 2011, available athttp://www.usaid.gov/our_work/humanitarian_assistance/disaster_assistance/countries/horn_of_africa/template/fs_sr/fy2011/hoa_ce_fs03_07-21-2011.pdf (accessed on 27 July 2011).

    World Bank (2010) World Development Indicators and Global Development Finance, World Bank,Washington D.C., available at http://databank.worldbank.org/ddp/home.do?Step=1&id=4(accessed on 24 February 2011).

    Notes

    1 The capital stock is computed for the period of 19602008, using perpetual inventory method,where investment is proxied by gross fixed capital formation, initial capital stock is estimatedto be 1.5 times the real GDP of 1960 and the depreciation rate of 10.5% is used. Dataset from1980 onwards was used in the analysis to maintain consistency.

    2 Agriculture value added corresponds to ISIC divisions 15 and includes forestry, hunting, andfishing, as well as cultivation of crops and livestock production (see World Bank, 2010) forfull definition).

    3 Manufacturing value added refers to industries belonging to ISIC divisions 1537 [see WorldBank (2010) for full definition].

  • 8/2/2019 Upload Ronald

    22/22

    48 R.R. Kumar and R. Kumar

    4 Services value added correspond to ISIC divisions 5099 and they include value added in

    wholesale and retail trade (including hotels and restaurants), transport, and government,financial, professional, and personal services such as education, healthcare, and real estateservices. Also included are imputed bank service charges, import duties, and any statisticaldiscrepancies noted by national compilers as well as discrepancies arising from rescaling [seeWorld Bank (2010) for full definition].

    5 The trend captures the supply side responses such as investment decisions, labour, marketdistortions and credit expansion in the short and long run, accordingly.