146
Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral Economics Test of Tillage Decisions in Nebraska and Kansas by Robert J. Sheeder A THESIS Presented to the Faculty of The Graduate College at the University of Nebraska In Partial Fulfillment of Requirements For the Degree of Master of Science Major: Agricultural Economics Under the Supervision of Professor Gary D. Lynne Lincoln, Nebraska December, 2008

Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    7

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral Economics Test of Tillage

Decisions in Nebraska and Kansas

by

Robert J. Sheeder

A THESIS

Presented to the Faculty of

The Graduate College at the University of Nebraska

In Partial Fulfillment of Requirements

For the Degree of Master of Science

Major: Agricultural Economics

Under the Supervision of Professor Gary D. Lynne

Lincoln, Nebraska

December, 2008

Page 2: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral Economic Test of Tillage

Decisions in Nebraska and Kansas

Robert Sheeder, M.S.

University of Nebraska-Lincoln, 2008

Adviser: Dr. Gary D. Lynne

The intent of this research is to discover what factors motivate farmers to adopt

conservation technologies that help reduce or eliminate non-point surface water pollution.

Particular attention is paid to the role that tillage decisions play in improving surface

water quality in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake Watershed located in Nebraska and

Kansas.

Data for this research was collected via a survey instrument sent to farm operators

located in a four county target area situated upstream of Tuttle Creek Lake in

southeastern Nebraska and northeastern Kansas. These farmers were asked several

questions regarding personal beliefs and attitudes regarding the usage of conservation

tillage measures and other soil BMPs. Also, respondents were asked to provide more

technical information regarding farm processes, such as how many acres are farmed

under conservation tillage technologies.

Using the data obtained from the farmers in the watershed, logit and Heckman

(Heckit) models were constructed in order to empirically test an emerging theory in

Behavioral Economics that has been named “Metaeconomics.” This emerging theory

looks to transcend traditional microeconomic theory by incorporating not only financial

concerns, but also proxies for self-interest and shared other-interest psychological

tendencies, measures of autonomous and heteronomous control, and habitual tendencies.

Page 3: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

Results from the logit models indicate that farmers who condition their pursuit of

self-interest with shared other-interest as represented in empathy and sympathy are more

likely to adopt conservation tillage strategies. We also find that farmers that believe they

cannot maintain autonomous control over farming practices when using conservation

tillage are less likely to use the technology. Also, habitual tendencies are found to be a

large driver in the conservation tillage adoption decision. Finally, results from Heckman

models show that preferences for control impact the conservation tillage intensity

decision. These findings, then, lend credence to the idea that an intricate mix of financial

incentives and moral suasion may be required in order to convince farmers to incorporate

conservation tillage strategies on working farms

Page 4: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

i

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Table of Contents ________________________________________________________ i

List of Tables __________________________________________________________ iii

List of Figures __________________________________________________________ iv

Introduction

1.1.Questioning the Role of Profit-Maximization in Conservation Decisions _______ 1

1.2. View of Human Behavior from Neursoscience and Evolutionary Biology ______ 5

1.3. Parental Models and Overview of Metaeconomic Theory ___________________ 9

Review of Literature

2.1. Financial Motives for Adopting Conservation Practices ___________________ 17

2.2. Non-Financial Motives for Adopting Conservation Practices _______________ 21

2.3. Multiple-Motive/Multiple Utility Studies of Conservation Adoption _________ 24

Theoretical Model

3.1. Graphical Representation of Standard Production Economics _______________ 28

3.2. Mathematics of Standard Production Economics _________________________ 30

3.3 Graphical Representation of Metaeconomics ____________________________ 31

3.4 Mathematics of Metaeconomics ______________________________________ 36

Toward Empirical Testing

4.1. Physical Description of Study Area ___________________________________ 45

4.2. Description of Institutional Arrangements in Study Area __________________ 46

4.3. Empirical Models _________________________________________________ 50

4.4. Development of Survey Instrument and Data Collection ___________________ 52

4.5. Description of Variables ____________________________________________ 54

Page 5: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

ii

Results and Discussion

5.1. Summary Descriptive Statistics ______________________________________ 68

5.2 Correlations _____________________________________________________ 75

5.3 Results of Logit Test of Microeconomic and Metaeconomic Theory _________ 79

5.4 Results of Heckman Test of Conservation Tillage Intensity ________________ 88

Conclusions, Implications, and Recommendations ____________________________ 99

Reference List ________________________________________________________ 110

Appendix A __________________________________________________________ 118

Page 6: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

iii

LIST OF TABLES

Table Page

1. Mean Responses to Question 24 (Selfism Scale) 68

2. Mean Responses to Question 22 (Davis Empathy Scale) 69

3. Mean Responses to Question 23 (Sympathy Scale) 69

4. Mean Responses to Question 19 (Empathy/Others Water User) 69

5. Mean Responses to Question 19 (Empathy/Others Farm Entity) 70

6. Mean Responses to Question 19 (Empathy/Others Family) 70

7. Mean Responses to Question 15 (Farm Control Scale) 70

8. Mean Responses to Question 15 (Other Control Scale) 71

9. Mean Responses to Question 15 (Nature Control Scale) 71

10. Mean Results of Final Selfism Variable 71

11. Mean Results of Final Empathy/Sympathy Variables 72

12. Mean Results of Final Control Variables 72

13. Mean Results for Final Selfism*Emapthy/Sympathy Variables 72

14. Mean Results for Final Selfism*Control Variables 72

15. Mean Results of Final Income Variable 73

16. Mean Results of Final Soil Slope Variable 73

17. Mean Results of Final Habit Variable 73

18. Correlations between Various Behavioral Proxies 77

19. Logistic Estimation of No-Till Adoption Decision (Empathy Proxy) 80

20. Logistic Estimation of No-Till Adoption Decision (Sympathy Proxy) 81

21. Logistic Estimation of No-Till Adoption Decision (Empathy/Others Proxy) 82

22. Probit Estimation of No-Till Adoption Decision (Empathy Proxy) 89

23. Semi-Log Estimation of Individual No-Till Intensity (Empathy Proxy) 90

24. Probit Estimation of No-Till Adoption Decision (Sympathy Proxy) 91

25. Semi-Log Estimation of Individual No-Till Intensity (Sympathy Proxy) 92

26. Probit Estimation of No-Till Adoption Decision (Empathy/Others Proxy) 93

27. Semi-Log Estimation of Individual No-Till Intensity (Empathy/Others Proxy) 94

Page 7: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

iv

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure Page

1.1 The Major Ranges/Modes of the CSN Model 16

3.1 Traditional Microeconomic Self-Interest Isoquant Curves 42

3.2 Metaeconomic Isoquant Curves 43

3.3 Metaeconomic Interests Frontier 44

4.1 Blue River/Tuttle Creek Watershed 67

5.1 Distribution of Mean Empathy Scale Responses 98

5.2 Distribution of Mean Sympathy Scale Respones 98

Page 8: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

1

INTRODUCTION

1.1. Questioning the Role of Profit-Maximization in Conservation Decisions

Since the destruction and despair caused by the dust bowl of the 1930‟s,

Americans and their government have taken a keen interest in natural resource

conservation policy on agricultural land throughout the country. As a reflection of this,

the farm bill of 1936 entitled the “Soil Conservation and Domestic Allotment Act”

included for the first time provisions that provided payments and support to farmers

willing to employ soil conservation measures on their farms (Cain and Lovejoy, 2004).

While the main purpose of this bill was to provide financial support to impoverished

farmers dealing with low commodity prices, the fact remains that natural resource

conservation was starting to become an important issue for the American public.

Over time, conservation titles in the farm bill have evolved into legislation that

not only protect soil from erosion, but they now include incentives for improving water

quality and water quantity problems, provisions that prohibit draining wetlands for

agricultural production, land retirement programs such as the Conservation Reserve

Program (CRP), and working land programs like the Environmental Quality Incentives

Program (EQIP). Expenditures for conservation measures have also significantly

increased over time. For example, the United States Department of Agriculture (USDA)

provided nearly 4.5 billion dollars for conservation programs in the farm bill for fiscal

year 2005, compared to 500 million dollars for the 1983 fiscal year (ERS, 2007). It also

appears this trend of increased conservation expenditures will continue, as the 2008 farm

bill will double the level of conservation funding under the previous farm bill if all

Page 9: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

2

provisions are approved. Of this new money, nearly two thirds is scheduled to be

allocated to working land programs like EQIP (ERS, 2007).

While giving monetary payments to individual producers engaging in

conservation activities is ultimately a policy decision, the underlying assumption for

these payments is one borne out of traditional microeconomic theory. Specifically,

microeconomics theory assumes that all producers are rational agents engaging in

activities that will maximize profits. However, most conservation activities are not

inherently profitable to the individual farmer; so, conservation payments are provided

under the assumption that the only way to increase participation in conservation programs

is to increase profits received by the individual farmer. In effect, conservation payments

can be seen as incentives or “bribes” that should make conservation activity more

attractive to the individual producer.

If the profit-maximization theory of standard microeconomics is correct in

predicting individual farmer behavior, it would then be expected that the rapid expansion

in government expenditures for conservation payments to individual producers would

lead to great improvements in environmental quality throughout the country. Recent

empirical evidence, though, is showing that this is not the case. For example, modeling

of conservation behavior in the upper Mississippi River region indicated that increasing

conservation payments at the individual producer level would produce minimal change in

rates of soil erosion, nitrate leaching, and nitrate runoff in the area (Wu, Adams, Kling,

and Tanaka, 2004). These authors concluded that conservation payments, which were

modeled as an increase in profits to individual farmers, are not likely to be cost effective

on their own for addressing pollution problems in the Mississippi River and the Gulf of

Page 10: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

3

Mexico. Evidence from Nebraska also indicates that increases in conservation program

expenditures do not necessarily lead to improved environmental quality. A recent report

released by the Nebraska Department of Environmental Quality noted that surface water

quality in the state did not improve from 2001 to 2005, and a higher percentage of lakes

in the state are not meeting environmental quality criteria established for their intended

uses (Link, 2005). While the report also indicates that surface water quality has not

deteriorated in Nebraska from 2001 to 2005, the evidence still suggests that increases in

conservation payments may have a minimal impact on improving water quality in the

state. Finally, a survey of eight Nebraska counties found increases in income, while

statistically significant, provided very little power in explaining what motivates farmers

to adopt conservation tillage technologies (Sheeder and Lynne, 2007). Therefore, as Wu

et al (2004) also conclude in their study of the upper Mississippi River region, the

acreage response to increases in conservation payments is, at best, highly inelastic, and in

absolute terms, the impact of conservation payments is extremely small.

Based on anecdotal evidence and the research cited above, it appears that

individual farmers are motivated to engage in (or not engage in) conservation strategies

by a multitude of factors. While it is undeniable that profits do play a role in

conservation decisions, the assumption that it plays the only role in economic decision

making is highly contentious. For instance, work by Nowak and Korsching (1998)

indicates that inadequacies in U.S. soil and water conservation policies can be attributed

to a misunderstanding of the human dimension (sociological and psychological factors)

of farmers, and not a lack of conservation expenditures. Work from Sen (1977) also

concludes that individuals may ultimately make choices based on sympathy and

Page 11: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

4

commitment to others, even if the outcomes do not maximize a person‟s self-interest. He

even writes that a person pursuing only selfish interests, as is modeled in

microeconomics, is nothing more than a “rational fool” and a “social moron” (Sen, 1977).

Even the writings of Adam Smith indicate that there are fundamental elements of human

nature that transcend that of pursuing individual self-interest. Smith writes:

How selfish soever man may be supposed, there are evidently some

principles in his nature, which interest him in the fortune of others, and

render their happiness necessary to him, though he derives nothing from it,

except the pleasure of seeing it…That we often derive sorrow from the

sorrows of others, is a matter of fact too obvious to require any instances to

prove it; for this sentiment, like all the other original passions of human

nature, is by no means confined to the virtuous and humane, though they

perhaps may feel it with the most exquisite sensibility. The greatest ruffian,

the most hardened violator of the laws of society, is not altogether without it

(Smith, 1790, Part I, Section I, Chapter I, Paragraph 1; cited in Lynne, 2006a,

102).

While Smith obviously did not discount the role that individual self-interest plays in

motivating consumer and producer choice (see Smith‟s The Wealth of Nations, 1776), he

also recognized the duality of human nature and believed that a person could temper their

self-interest by empathizing with those affected by his or her choices. However, it is

important to note that Smith believed that the act of empathizing occurs within the self

and arises not because of concern for others, but rather concern with others for the self.

This is similar to the view held by Solomon (2007). He writes “We do not just have our

own interests. We share interests with others. Empathy is neither altruistic nor self-

interested. It rather exemplifies the implicit solidarity of human nature.” So, it appears

that both Smith and Solomon have the same understanding of human choice behavior:

individuals use empathy to temper their self-interest and then act in their own- interest

that accounts for the desires of the self and that shared with others.

Page 12: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

5

1.2. View of Human Behavior from Neuroscience and Evolutionary Biology

Philosophers and other behavioral scientists (excluding traditional economists)

have been writing about the aforementioned alternative view of human behavior for

years. Yet, recent findings in neuroscience and evolutionary biology lend credence to the

idea that humans are, by nature, motivated by much more than maximizing individual

self-interest. For instance, Cory (2006b), who appropriately updated the work of

evolutionary neuroscientist MacLean (1990), developed the theory of the human triune

brain. In this theory, it is documented that the human brain has evolved into a three level

interconnected, modular structure. The three levels are named the reptilian complex, the

paleomammalian (or “old mammalian”) complex, and the neocortex.

According to Cory, the reptilian complex is the primal and innermost core of the

human brain. In ancestral fishes, amphibians, and reptiles, this portion made up the entire

brain. Today, this protoreptilian circuitry or self-preservation program, serves much the

same purpose as it did in our ancestral vertebrates. Namely, it governs the fundamental

life-support operations, including blood circulation, heartbeat, respiration, food

collection, reproduction, and defensive behavior (Cory, 2006b).

The next developmental stage of the human brain, referred to as the

paleomammalian brain or affectional program, can be identified with the structures

collectively designated as the human limbic system (Cory, 2006b). This portion of the

brain, which developed from gene-based continuities preexisting in the reptilian complex,

led to the development of distinctly mammalian features. Specifically, this complex led

humans to develop warm-bloodedness, nursing, infant attachment, and parental care. As

Page 13: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

6

Cory (2006b, p. 26) notes, “these circuits became the basis of family life and our capacity

for extended social bonding.”

The most recent stage of human brain development is referred to as the neocortex,

or as MacLean (1990) names it, the neomammalian brain. The neocortex is a large mass

of brain tissue that dominates the skull case of all higher primates and humans. It has

evolved by “…elaborating the preexisting continuities present in the brains of early

vertebrates” (Cory, 2006b, 26). While the neocortex overgrew and encased the reptilian

and paleomammalian brain tissue, it did not replace them. It did, however, allow for the

evolution of greater complexity within the older parts of the brain, and it facilitated an

advanced interconnected circuitry between all three brain complexes. This produced

behavioral adaptations necessary for humans to deal with their increasingly sophisticated

circumstances (Cory, 2006b).

Once the triune brain had evolved, the unique features of the human brain were

refined over a period of several million years in kinship-based foraging societies. In

these societies, sharing and reciprocity were essential to human survival. This sharing in

society only served to strengthen the adaptive evolution of the now combined mammalian

characteristics of self-preservation and affection (Cory, 2006b). Ego and empathy, which

provide the basis of self-interest and shared other-interest, respectively, became key

features of our individual and social behavior.

While Cory and MacLean were able to determine the neurophysiological make-up

of the human triune brain, this strict biological view of the brain does very little to

explain actual human behavior in any given situation. For this reason, the Conflict

Systems Neurobehavioral (CSN) model of the human brain was developed (Cory,

Page 14: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

7

2006b). In this model, the self-preservation and affective programs are interconnected,

and the core motivational (and emotional) circuits are cognitively represented in the

frontal regions of the neocortex, or executive program (Cory, 2006b). It is further shown

that empathetic and other-interested motivations and behaviors are born out of the

affectional program, while egoistic and self-interested acts are derived from the self-

preservation program. The executive program, then, is designed to cognitively represent

these egoistic and empathetic inputs, “…making what may be thought of as our moral as

well as rational choices among our conflicting, impulsive, and irrational or nonrational

motivations” (Cory, 2006b, 28).

The relationship between ego and empathy in the CSN model is very dynamic

(Figure 1.1). Both egoistic and empathetic motivations can trigger a range of behaviors

that can be brought out in the individual. In the egoistic range, behavior is dominated by

the self-preservational circuitry of the triune brain. The behaviors exhibited here are self-

centered in nature, and may tend to be dominating, power-seeking, or possibly attacking

(Cory, 2006b). However, it must be remembered that the behavioral programs of ego and

empathy are joint and non-separable, so empathy is in fact present in the egoistic range,

but to a much lesser degree. As empathy increases, though, behavior in the egoistic range

may become much less harsh, and could possibly be described as moderately

competitive, controlling, or assertive (Cory, 2006b). Still, the fact remains that in the

egoistic range of behavior the individual is putting his or her selfish interests ahead of the

interests of others.

In the empathetic range of the CSN model, behavior is weighted in favor of

shared other-interested, empathetic acts. Here, extreme behaviors may be characterized

Page 15: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

8

as self-sacrificial and submissive (Cory, 2006b). Again, though, it must be remembered

that the egoistic and empathetic circuitry of the triune brain is inseparable. Therefore,

ego is present in the empathetic range, even if it exists in miniscule quantities.

Nevertheless, as ego increases in the empathetic range, other-interested behavior

moderates and can be described as “…supportive, responsive, or any of a variety of

„others first‟ behaviors” (Cory, 2006b, 29).

Due to the jointness of ego and empathy within the CNS model, behavioral

tension and stress can arise within the individual. Essentially, ego and empathy are

constantly engaging in a neurological “tug of war,” with each neurological circuit

subjectively evaluating a situation and seeking to express itself through objective

behaviors. If a single expression of ego or empathy is blocked, or if simultaneous but

mutually exclusive urgings of ego and empathy arise, the individual will experience

tension and stress, usually resulting in a subjective experience of frustration, anxiety, or

anger (Cory, 2006b). Therefore, it is up to the individual to strike a rough balance

between the expression of ego and empathy in order to reduce this behavioral tension.

When ego and empathy are balanced, the individual will engage in behavior

located within the dynamic balance range. Here, the individual‟s behavior is

characterized by equality, justice, sharing, and other acts that show respect for the self

and others. As Cory (2006b, 29) writes, “…respect for the self and others is the keynote

of the range of dynamic balance.”

1.3. Parental Models and an Overview Metaeconomic Theory

Page 16: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

9

While writings in neuroscience and biology are increasingly recognizing that

behavior may be motivated by several tendencies or interests, mainstream

microeconomics continues to assume that the individual is motivated solely by profit or

utility maximization. Implicitly, then, traditional microeconomics also assumes a Strict

Father moral order (See Lakoff, 1996; cited in Lynne, 1999). In this moral order, the

world is modeled as inherently dangerous, with survival being the major concern.

Children in this model learn self-discipline through “tough love” by the Strict Father, and

a mature adult can only become self-reliant by applying this self-discipline while

pursuing their self-interest. Survival is assumed to be a matter of competition, and only

through self-discipline can a child compete successfully in life. Once the child of the

Strict Father reaches maturity, it is up to them whether they survive of perish. It is

assumed that the child knows what is good for themselves and their families, and that

they have the competancy to make their own decisions. Any meddling by the parents in

the lives of the child is highly resented (Lakoff, 1996).

It is relatively easy to see how this moral order fits into conventional

microeconomics. As noted by Lynne (1999):

It is but a small jump to microeconomics: A single, strict decision-maker in a

hosehold or firm, wherein the pursuit of self-interest is disciplined by the

market. Individuals maximize utility and profit in a constrained

maximization …Survival is through entry and exit in highly competitive

markets. The market rewards for good decisions, and it punishes for bad

mistakes…Also, reward and punishment, in itself, is moral: „Competition is

the crucial ingredient in such a moral system.‟ Without competition, the

motivation to be self-disciplined is removed. Restraints on competition…are

immoral.

Page 17: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

10

By keeping the Strict Father moral order hidden in the invisible hand, traditional

economic theory carries an inherent bias within its framework. It seems as though any

kind of analysis or policy created within this traditional framework endorses only the

Strict Father moral order, “…even in cases where the invisible hand of the Strict Father is

directed toward a bad…” (Lynne, 1999, 271). By recognizing only self-interest and not

making the moral dimension explicit within its framework, microeconomics does not

allow for the expression of the multiple motives of ego and empathy within the

individual.

In contrast, the recent theory of Metaeconomics (Lynne, 1999, 2006ab) looks to

transcend, or “go beyond” the framework of conventional microeconomic theory.

Metaeconomics seeks to make explicit the moral and ethical order within its framework.

In doing so, the theory assumes that the individual is dually motivated by egoistic and

self-interested tendencies as well as empathetic and shared other-interested tendencies.

These egoistic and empathetic tendencies, though, may in fact be incommensurable.

Creating metaeconomics in this fashion allows the moral order of the Strict Father and

the moral order of the Nurturant Parent, which is rooted in being cared for and being

cared about (again, see Lakoff, 1996; cited in Lynne, 1999), to coexist in one model.

Intriguingly, metaeconomics now allows for more than one explanation as to what

drives human economic behavior. In standard microeconomics, every action, regardless

of how altruistic the act appears to be, is deemed to be caused by the pursuit of the

individual‟s self-interest. Meanwhile, metaeconomic theory, rooted in the

neurophysiological makeup described by Cory (2006b), can more realistically attribute

behavior to the pursuit of individual self-interest, the pursuit of an

Page 18: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

11

empathetic/sympathetic shared other-interest, or both. In fact, the pursuit of self-

interested and other-interested tendencies is present in every situation that a choice must

be made. The degree to which each domain is pursued, though, is a subjective choice

within the individual in any given circumstance. For this reason, it is certainly possible

to see some actions based almost entirely on hedonistic tendencies, other actions rooted

almost entirely in other-interested tendencies, and still other decisions based not on

maximizing, but satisfying, both domains (Lynne, 1999).

It must be noted that metaeconomics does not entirely discount the value of

conventional microeconomics. In fact, the pursuit of individual utility/profit, which is a

core microeconomic principal, is still the foundation of metaeconomics. However, unlike

conventional microeconomics, metaeconomics realizes that utility or satisfaction may be

gained in the self-interest domain as well as in the shared other-interest domain. This

allows the theory to be analytically implemented under the guidance of methodological

individualism, yet still recognize the holism of the human experience, a component of

methodological holism (Lynne, 1999). This configuration of dual methodologies may

ultimately allow for the possibility of synergism, in that attempting to satisfy both

egoistic and empathetic domains may provide a solution or behavior that leads to a “sum

greater than the sum of the parts.” This allows the individual to move to a higher plane

that arises out of the symbiotic potential of ego and empathy (Lynne, 1999, 2006ab).

By integrating empathy and other-interested tendencies into the metaeconomic

framework, metaeconomics, by default, becomes a much more social theory than its

conventional counterpart. Nevertheless, the act of empathizing with others is still a

process that happens within the individual. This is to say, metaeconomics does not use

Page 19: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

12

the construct of interdependent utility. The person making a decision may use empathy

to temper the self-interest, and possibly reach a conclusion that is different than when

self-interest is pursued for its own sake, but another person‟s utility (which is

unobservable) has no bearing on the decision to be made. All utility, whether in the

egoistic or empathetic domain, is pursued within the individual.

While it is true that metaeconomic theory puts the burden of choice on the

individual, we must be careful not to assume that economic choice occurs within a

vacuum. Economic choices impact citizens other than the individual making the

decision. These choices also take place in the context of “positive and negative”

freedoms (Sen, 1987), meaning that some people are allowed to do this or that, while

others have to do this or that. These freedoms are analogous in nature to the liberation

and restraint characteristics of economic institutions (Bromley, 2006). Therefore, it

seems that gaining insights into society‟s institutional makeup may also provide

information that can be useful in explaining economic choice behavior.

The primary goal of this research is to determine what tendencies, factors, and

internal characteristics or dispositions influence farmers to engage in conservation

strategies that enhance surface water quality, with particular attention being given to to

the role that empathy/sympathy plays in economic decision making. Antecdotal evidence

suggests that farmers are motivated to use conservation technologies by a heterogeneous

mix of factors that include both financial and non-finacial considerations. Specifically,

these factors include, but are not limited to, a need for profit, influences from friends and

family, information provided by equipment dealers, information from chemical and seed

Page 20: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

13

suppliers, a desire for control over their farms, and a desire to “do the right thing” for the

environment, with the latter being borne out of empathy.

While it has long been realized that both financial and non-financial factors

motivate farmer behavior, the theoretical literature has been unable to evolve a settled

and unified account of egoistic-financial and non-financial social motives that ultimately

drive human behavior (Chouinard, Paterson, Wandschneider, and Ohler, 2008).

However, it seems that the theoretical framework of metaeconomics (Lynne, 1999,

2006ab) can provide a new and integrating theory that connects both financial and non-

financial motives into one coherent theory of human behavior. Therefore, this new

framework will be used to analyze farmer conservation behavior in the context of a water

quality conflict between upstream farmers and downstream water suppliers in the Blue

River/Tuttle Creek Watershed of Nebraska and Kansas.

The policy implications of this research extend nationwide. All regions of the

United States, especially those that rely heavily on traditional farm based economies,

experience problems with surface water quality. More accurately modeling farmer

conservation behavior could potentially lead to improved regional conservation programs

based on personality and behvioral characteristics of the region (this idea is also

suggested by Willock et al., 1999). A regional conservation strategy that accounts for

both behavioral and institutional characteristics of the area could ultimately yield greater

results in improving water quality than the “blanket” national conservation policy that is

currently in place.

Understanding the factors that motivate farmers to engage in conservation

behaviors may also lead to enhanced educational programs that target specific traits in

Page 21: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

14

individual farmers and could lead to behavioral change. This, in conjunction with

improved conservation programs, may enhance surface water quality at a reduced cost.

These educational programs would also indicate that policy makers are willing to engage

and work with the farming community in order to solve water quality problems. It would

seem that this strategy may work much better than mandating change for the farming

community at large, as mandates are largely resisted and resented. Regardless of the final

outcome, though, it seems that a greater understanding of the factors that influence the

decision-making process of the individual farmer will help to yield better designed and

implemented conservation programs throughout the country.

While this research may have implications for overall conservation policy in the

United States, there may also be implications for both the farmers and water users located

in Blue River and Tuttle Creek Lake watershed. Specifically, by using metaeconomic

theory, we may find that farmers in the watershed have the ability to build shared other-

interest tendencies with those downstream that use the water in the Blue River and Tuttle

Creek Lake. This may suggest active involvement and engagement by conservationists,

farmers and downstream water users in groups, and organizations that work to build unity

with the causes of conservation, perhaps built upon a shared vision for better quality

rivers and lakes witin the region of interest, with each participant entering ever more in

sympathy with others then working to temper and condition the pursuit of self-interests.

The potential to build the described shared other-interest above can then be

determined by measuring the amount of empathy/sympathy present in farmers situated

above the Lake. If empathy/sympathy exists in ample quantities, it is possible that

farmers may condition their behavior and use conservation measures that can help

Page 22: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

15

improve the water quality in the Blue River and Tuttle Creek Lake for the benefit of those

downstream. So, this research may in fact have the potential to help resolve an emerging

conflict between upstream farmers and downstream water users in the region.

Page 23: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

16

Figure 1.1 The Major Ranges/Modes of Behavior of the CSN Model

(From Cory, 2006b)

Page 24: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

17

REVIEW OF LITERATURE

The conservation literature is extensive and diverse, and would be impossible to

cover in its entirety. However, a sampling of the conservation literature is provided with

emphasis placed on studies that use financial, non-financial, and multiple-

motive/multiple-utility frameworks to explain conservation behavior.

2.1 Financial Motives for Adopting Conservation Practices:

Financial motives are the most widely cited account for conservation adoption on

farms. These motives most generally include a desire for greater profits, but may also

include other financial attributes including asset growth, risk reduction, and financial

liquidity (Chouinard et al, 2008). For instance, a model used by Cary and Wilkinson

(1997) hypothesized that five factors could explain the planting of trees and deep rooted

grasses on farms and pastures in south eastern Australia. Of these factors, the idea that

the conservation practice in question must be perceived as economically profitable before

adoption will occur was of paramount importance. In fact, the independent variable

measuring the degree to which a farmer believes tree and grass planting increases profits

in the long-run provided the largest positive coefficients in logistic regression models

constructed by the authors. In the end, the authors concluded that, in general, “…the best

way to increase the use of conservation practices to overcome land degradation…will be

to ensure the practices are economically profitable” (Cary and Wilkinson, 1997, p. 20).

Several other writings attempt to estimate the cost responsiveness of a farmer‟s

adoption of soil-conserving and/or runoff- reducing practices using data from surveys on

stated preferences. For example, Lohr and Park (1995) attempt to determine the cost

Page 25: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

18

responsiveness of planting filter strips under the filter strip provision of the Conservation

Reserve Program (CRP) for farmers in Michigan and Illinois. Using a contingent

valuation (CV) framework, mail surveys were sent to farmers in Newyago County,

Michigan and Fayette County, Illinois. The surveys, which provided a hypothetical

payment offer to farmers for participation in the filter strip program, sought to evaluate

whether a respondent would participate in the program and determine the percentage of

eligible land that each willing participant would enroll in the program in response to the

proposed payment. Results of the study indicated that the “payment” variable, which was

defined as the per acre offer to farmers as inducement to join the filter strip program

(Lohr and Park, 1995, p. 485), had a positive and significant effect on the probability of a

farmer joining the filter strip program. Analysis also estimated that an $80 per acre

payment in Fayette County, Illinois and a $38 per acre payment in Newaygo County,

Michigan would be required to entice farmers to participate in the program.

Like the study conducted by Lohr and Park (1995), Cooper and Keim (1996) also

use a CV framework in order to determine farmers‟ cost responsiveness to five different

practices that protect water quality. Mail surveys were sent to farm operators in four

critical watershed regions: the Eastern Iowa and Illinois Basin areas, the Albermarle-

Pamlico Drainage Area in Virginia and North Carolina, the Georgia-Florida Coastal

Plain, and the Upper Snake River Basin Area. Again, survey participants were asked to

divulge their current usage of preferred practices (if at all) as well as their willingness to

adopt these practices in response to a stated hypothetical bid price if they do not currently

use the practice in question. The authors then used the data obtained from the survey to

develop a model of conservation practice participation as a function of bid price. The

Page 26: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

19

authors modeled only the data from those respondents that did not use the preferred

conservation practices, and results indicate that incentive payment offers ranging between

35 and 65 dollars would be required to entice 50 percent of the sample to participate in

the surveyed conservation practices. Intriguingly, though, about 12 to 20 percent of the

sample indicated that they would participate in conservation programs in the absence of

an incentive payment (Cooper and Keim, 1996, p. 62). The authors did not elaborate or

attempt to substantively explain this result, but it does perhaps suggest that motives other

than considerations of cost and profit influence the conservation adoption decision in

farmers.

Cooper (1997) extended the work of Cooper and Keim by adding data on the

actual users of conservation practices (i.e. farmers who use the BMPs with no incentive

payments) to the contingent behavioral analysis produced by Cooper and Keim (1996).

The results of this work show that adoption rates of the selected conservation practices

are significantly higher over a wide range of incentive payment offers than the results

predicted form the hypothetical CVM data only. Nonetheless, the results still indicate

that government expenditures would need to increase substantially over current levels in

order to obtain much higher levels of conservation practice adoption in the survey areas

(Cooper, 1997).

All three of the aforementioned studies find a significant degree of cost

responsiveness and downward sloping demand for conservation practices. This suggests

that subsidies for conservation technologies applied on working farmland are likely to

yield substantial increases in the use of such practices. However, models of stated

preferences do not always provide good predictors of actual behavior, making it desirable

Page 27: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

20

to validate the results with studies using revealed preference data. Lichtenberg (2004)

uses such a study to analyze conservation decisions by farmers in Maryland. The

analysis conducted by Lichtenberg (2004) uses survey data combined with information

on standard unit costs of installing the following seven soil-conserving and/or runoff-

reducing conservation practices as identified by a Maryland state cost-sharing program:

critical area seeding, contour farming, strip-cropping, cover crops, waterways, terraces,

and diversions. Latent demand models for each of the seven practices were developed

and all exhibit a downward slope, suggesting that cost sharing could have a strong impact

on the adoption of these conservation practices in Maryland. The results also show

strong complementarity among critical area seeding, cover crops, waterways, and

terraces, indicating that increases in incentive payments for one of these practices could

ultimately yield greater adoption of the other three practices without subsequent increases

in incentive payments. In the end, though, the conclusions provided by Lichtenberg

(2004) do not differ substantially from the conclusions drawn by Lohr and Park (1995),

Cooper and Keim (1996) and Cooper (1997). Specifically, all of these studies proffer

that increases in conservation incentive payments should lead to substantial increases in

the adoption of conservation practices by farmers.

2.2 Non-Financial Motives for Adopting Conservation Practices:

While the conservation literature appears to be dominated by work citing financial

motives as the primary driver of the adoption of conservation practices, a considerable

amount of work shows that other, non-financial factors can play a role in the conservation

Page 28: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

21

decision made by farmers. For example, a study of Missouri farmers conducted by Ervin

and Ervin (1982) indicates that personal factors attributed to the individual farmer may

have a substantial impact on the number of adopted conservation practices. In fact, the

authors note that the two most important variables in explaining the number of

conservation practices employed on an individual farm were “…either personal

characteristics or related to personal characteristics: education and perception of the

degree of erosion problem” (Ervin and Ervin, 1982, p. 286). The results of this study

show that higher education levels yield a greater likelihood of perceiving an erosion

problem, and thus younger and more educated farmers will be more willing to engage in

conservation technologies that prevent erosion. This finding also suggests that

governmental assistance to farm operators in erosion prone areas should possibly vary

depending upon operator characteristics. The authors note that younger farmers, on

average, tend to be more receptive to a wider range of conservation practices than older

operators, but probably require cost sharing in order to accomplish high levels of farm

conservation effort. On the other hand, in lieu of financial incentives, older and/or less

educated farmers may require technical information programs to explain the

consequences and benefits of unfamiliar conservation practices.

Similarly, work from Gould, Saupe, and Klemme (1989) applies the model used

by Ervin and Ervin (1982) to explain the use of conservation tillage schemes in

southwestern Wisconsin. Like Ervin and Ervin, the authors find that farmer

characteristics are critically important in explaining the adoption of alternative tillage

technologies. Specifically, age and education of the farmer were found to be significant

variables, with younger and more educated farmers being more likely to adopt

Page 29: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

22

conservation tillage measures. However, they also indicate that because younger

operators have less farm experience, they may also be less likely to perceive the existence

of an erosion problem in their fields. Therefore, it is suggested that educational efforts

regarding conservation tillage should be directed at these younger, less experienced

farmers (Gould, Saupe, and Klemme, 1989).

Finally, a study of the Central Platte River Valley of Nebraska conducted by

Supalla (2003) suggests that the best way to convince producers of irrigated agriculture to

use conservation practices that protect water quality is through expanded educational

programs. In this study, Supalla notes that producers in the area have developed a

stewardship ethic and are willing to forego profits in order to use best management

practices (BMPs) that enhance water quality in the region. In fact, it was discovered

through an attitudinal survey that 85 percent of producers in the region were willing to

voluntarily accept lower net returns in exchange for reduced groundwater pollution

(Supalla et al., 1995, cited in Supalla, 2003, p. 96). This seems to indicate that producers

care about the environment and are willing to sacrifice profits in order to be stewards of

the land. In other words, farmers in the Platte Valley region of Nebraska have been able

to evolve shared values (i.e. a shared other-interest) regarding the use of BMPs in the

watershed. Therefore, it appears that a lack of knowledge concerning BMPs, not income,

may be the deciding factor in the decision to adopt conservation technologies along the

Central Platte River Valley. Thus, policy instruments that stress education may be more

likely to increase conservation technology adoption rates than policies that stress

financial incentives or direct regulation.

Page 30: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

23

In addition to human capital studies that stress general farmer characteristics like

age and education levels, several studies have been completed that analyze the

importance of farmer values and attitudes when making a decision regarding the adoption

of conservation practices. Wallace and Clearfield (1997) examine the reasons why

producers adopt stewardship practices and determine that many voluntarily install

conservation practices on their land because it is the “right thing to do.” They also

indicate that many farmers and ranchers see private ownership not as a right to do what

they please with the land, but as a right to be stewards of the land. Therefore, it is their

responsibility to protect the land and pass it on in a condition that will benefit future

generations. Finally, the researchers show that, even when facing difficulties, many

agricultural producers have maintained an attitude and ethic that treats farming and

ranching as “a way of life,” and not a venture to maximize profits (Wallace and

Clearfield, 1997, p. 4).

Maybery, Crase, and Gullifer (2005) also show the importance that values and

attitudes can have in shaping conservation behavior. Survey responses from farmers in

New South Wales, Australia showed that producers in this region had three distinct

values in regard to their farming operations: economic, conservation, and lifestyle. Also

of importance was the fact that a clear separation existed between economic and

conservation values, as well as economic and lifestyle values. This suggests that

“…ideologically different policy approaches may have separate pathways of influence

within landholder decision making” (Maybery, Crase, and Gullifer, 2005, p 68).

Therefore, it can be reasonably inferred that those with strong conservation goals and

weak economic goals are unlikely to respond to financial incentives as motives to engage

Page 31: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

24

in conservation practices. Conversely, those with weak conservation values are not likely

to buy into volunteer conservation practices that will sacrifice profit. Yet, this study still

shows that financial motives alone cannot entirely predict participation in conservation

programs in this region.

2.3 Multiple-Motive/Multiple-Utility Studies for Adopting Conservation Practices:

As evidenced from the studies cited above, it is clear that farmers can be

motivated to adopt conservation practices by both financial and personal/attitudinal

considerations that are not directly related to profit or financial capacity considerations.

However, as shown by Chouinard, Paterson, Wandschneider, and Ohler (2008), the

literature has largely stepped around using a systematic integration of these two types of

goals to describe conservation behavior, either by assuming that only maximum profits

and/or minimum costs matter, or by adding social and stewardship factors in an ad hoc

way. However, a recent subset of the conservation literature has started to use such an

integrated approach in an attempt to substantively explain a wide variety of conservation

behaviors.

Lynne, Shonkwiler, and Rola (1988) were among the first researchers to use a

multiple-motive framework and apply it to an analysis of conservation decision-making.

They collected attitudinal data, as well as context variable data including income and

farm terrain, from farmers in the panhandle of Florida. Results from the study showed

that attitudes toward conservation, perception of environmental problems, farm

ownership, current profitability, income per effort, and risk were all important in

predicting the effort of conservation adoption in the region.

Page 32: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

25

In a study similar to that of Lynne, Shonkwiler, and Rola (1988), Cutforth,

Francis, Lynne, Mortensen, and Eskridge (2001) use a multiple motive framework to

model crop diversity decisions on farms in Saunders County, Nebraska. The authors

used an ordinary least squares (OLS) regression model to measure crop diversity in the

county for the 1998 growing season. The model included independent variables that

measured both attitudes toward using crop rotations and social norms in the region, as

well as economic variables like net household income. In the end, the full regression

model was determined to be significant and explained 24 percent of the total variance of

crop diversity. The economic variable “net household income” proved to be significant

and indicated that those farmers with higher incomes were more specialized in their

cropping decisions. However, results also show that positive attitudes toward the use of

rotations were significantly associated with crop diversity in 1998. Obviously,

respondents in Saunders County are motivated (and conflicted) by both economic and

diversity concerns on their farms.

As an evolution to multiple-motive studies like those cited above, Lynne (1995)

developed a new behavioral economic model in which a farmer (or person in general) is

proposed to pursue multiple-utilities or multiple interests. Taking cues from Sen (1977)

and Etzioni (1986), Lynne proposed that individuals pursue not only a self-interest utility

as modeled in microeconomics, but also a shared other-interest utility rooted in social

norms and the ideas of sympathy, meta-ranking, and commitment (Sen, 1977). He labels

each of these utilities as “I” and “We” utilities, respecitvely. It was hypothesized that the

addition of the “We” utility to conventional economic models could greatly improve the

explanatory power of studies intended to describe farmer conservation behavior.

Page 33: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

26

Over time, the multiple-utility model proposed by Lynne has been refined and

given the name “metaeconomics” (Lynne, 1999, 2006a). The metaeconomic model,

which will be described in greater detail in the next chapter, has been tested in several

different settings. Lynne (1995) used this model in an attempt to detail the adoption of

irrigation technologies that improve water use efficiency by strawberry growers in

Florida; Lynne and Casey (1998) and Casey and Lynne (1999) test the model in order to

understand the adoption of drip irrigation technology by Florida tomato farmers; and

Sautter, Ovchinnikova, Kruse, and Lynne (2008) use the meateconomic framework to

explain the adoption of conservation tillage in portions of Nebraska. The theory has been

applied in areas oustide of the conservation literature as well, suggesting that it may be

applicable in describing many different types of behavior. For instance, Artikov and

Lynne (2005) use metaeconomics to elucidate farmers‟ use of weather information, and

Kalinowski, Lynne, and Johnson (2006) use the theory to explain recycling behavior by

citizens in Nebraska. In all of the examples cited above, empirical results indicate the

presence of joint self-interest (“I”) and shared other-interest (“We”) utilities or interests,

together forming an internalized own-interest. Also, as hypothesized, the predictive

capacity of the behaviroal models significantly improved with the inclusion of variables

that served as proxies for a shared other-interested utility.

In sum, it appears reasonable to hypothesize that egoistic-financial and social-

moral factors can influence conservation decisions made by farmers. However, it is the

contention herein that models that integrate selfish and social motivations into one

coherent behavioral theory may ultimately provide a better model for explaining

conservation adoption on farms than models proposed by standard microeconomic

Page 34: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

27

theory. Therefore, the next chapter of this paper presents the theoretical models of both

standard microeconomic theory and metaeconomic theory. Then, after examining both

theoretical engines, the theory that best explains conservation behavior in the Blue River

watershed can be pragmatically chosen.

Page 35: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

28

THEORETICAL MODEL

Metaeconomics, as first proposed by Lynne (1999), is an emerging theory in

behavioral economics that looks to transcend the traditional framework of standard

microeconomics (Lynne, 2006ab). Traditional microeconomic theory assumes that an

individual pursues only one interest, which is ultimately derived from pursuing selfish

and hedonistic tendencies. Conversely, metaeconomics, which uses a framework similar

to that introduced by Etzioni (1986), proposes a dual-motive, dual-utility model of the

individual. Specifically, metaeconomics proposes that an individual jointly pursues both

an egoistic-hedonistic based self-interest utility/tendency and an empathy-sympathy

based other-interest utility/tendency, with the latter being shared with others.

Importantly, these dual interests are viewed as non-separable and are jointly internalized

within the own-interest of an individual (Sautter, Ovchinnikova, Kruse, and Lynne,

2008). So, given the similarities and differences exhibited between metaeconomic and

traditional economic theory, it appears that an overview of both theoretical models is

necessary in order to be pragmatic in choosing which theoretical engine may be best in

explaining farmer conservation behavior. Therefore, graphical and mathematical

representations of both economic theories are provided.

3.1 Graphical Representation of Standard Production Economics

The essence of the traditional microeconomic production model is illustrated in

Figure 3.1. There is only one set of isoquants, as the individual producer is assumed to

have only one interest (IG) that is rooted in egoistic-hedonistic tendencies. It is further

assumed that the individual producer intends to maximize these selfish interests, and

Page 36: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

29

therefore will move along the expansion path 0G in response to price ratios. It must also

be noted that this model cannot address behaviors that require self-sacrifice or altruism

depicted at points B and C because a producer cannot maximize profit at these points

(Lynne, 2006b); this is to say, one cannot simultaneously sacrifice and maximize profits

A producer pursuing the self-interest path 0G can be characterized as Homo

economicus as described in traditional microeconomics. A person portrayed in this

fashion is presumed to be motivated only by egoistic-hedonistic tendencies and to pursue

maximum profits while minimizing costs. This quest for profit is assumed to provide the

decision-maker with maximum satisfaction. Therefore, the pursuit of the shared other-

interest is ignored entirely, even though as argued earlier, there is generally a strict father

ethical system operating in the background. In the context of farming, this presumes that

producers will only modify their behavior in response to monetary payments along path

0G, with the possibility for changing the underlying ethical system (e.g. introducing parts

of the nurturant parent family system) not considered. Therefore, farmers settle upon

point A, the point of tangency of the highest self-interest isoquant IG and their budget

constraint RoR

o. This leads to growing a substantial amount of crops while using

relatively few conservation techniques e (conservation tillage, buffer strips, etc.) and

relatively high amounts of industrial inputs d (intensive tillage, chemicals, etc.) on

cropland. Notice, too, that in the case of extreme free riding, no conservation techniques

would be used and the expansion path 0G would be the vertical axis.

Page 37: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

30

3.2 Mathematics of Standard Production Economics

While the above graphical representation is useful in understanding conventional

microeconomic producer theory, it is also important to add mathematical precision to the

model. Consider the following production and objective functions:

(1) 1 2( , )Y Y X X

(2) 1 2 1 1 2 2( , ) ( )L pY X X R r X r X

where rj refers to the input prices paid for attributes Xj by the individual farmer; and p is

the market generated price for providing the product or crop; and R is the capital/budget

constraint.

Next, we obtain the first order conditions (FOC):

(3) 1

1 1

L Yp set r

X X

(4) 2

2 2

L Yp set r

X X

(5) 1 1 2 2 0L

R r X r X set

The least cost condition is found by dividing Equation (3) by Equation (4):

(6) 1 1

2 2

( )( )

( )( )

p Y X r

p Y X r

Finding the expansion path 0G in Figure 3.1 from equation (6):

(7) 2 2 1 2( , , , )X X r r p R

The derived demand function for an input becomes:

(8) 1 1 1 2( , , , )X X r r p R

Page 38: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

31

Unlike other types of firms or producers, though, the individual farmer must also

account for the general physical characteristics of the ground being farmed when making

production input decisions. These characteristics include, but are not limited to, soil

slope, soil slope length, and organic matter. Therefore, the final derived demand function

for the input decision becomes:

(9) 1 1 1 2( , , , , )X X r r p R N

where the input demand of factor X1 is a function of both input prices (r1 and r2), the

market generated price for the produced crop (p), the capital/budget constraint (R), and

the physical characteristics of the individual farmer‟s land (N).

3.3 Graphical Representation of Metaeconomics

The essence of the metaeconomic framework is presented in Figure 3.2. Careful

inspection of the figure reveals several major differences from the traditional

microeconomic production model (Figure 3.1). First, note that there are two sets of

isoquants that represent both the egoistic-hedonistic self-interest (IG) and the empathetic-

sympathetic shared other-interest (IM). Also note the absolute overlap of the dual self-

interest and shared other-interest isoquants. The intersection of both interests at every

point in the space is represented at points A, B, and C. This overlap of the dual interests

represents the foundation of the metaeconomic model. In the context of the farming

community, traditional profit-bearing outputs like corn and soybeans are represented in

the IG isocurves, whereas shared, more community based outputs like less chemical and

sediment loadings to nearby water sources, enhancement of ecosystems, and long-term

farm sustainability are represented in the IM isocurves.

Page 39: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

32

Figure 3.2 also demonstrates that, due to the jointness and non-separability of the

dual interests, a farmer is unable to pick a certain level of self-interest without

simultaneously choosing a level of shared other-interest. Yet, the tendency within the

conservation literature is to treat the choice behavior of farmers as separable independent

effects involving mere tradeoffs (Sautter et al, 2008). Thus, the two interests are

implicitly modeled as separate components in the literature, and not like the interrelated

paths 0G and 0M.

As noted in section 3.1, a farmer that pursues path 0G, or, in the extreme case the

vertical axis, is described as Homo economicus, and is assumed to have his or her

behavior arise only out of self-interested tendencies. In contrast to a farmer that pursues

only self-interest, though, metaeconomics proposes that a farmer may also wish to pursue

the shared other-interest on expansion path 0M. A person that pursues this path can be

characterized as Homo sociologicus, akin to the nature of human behavior presumed in

standard sociology. A farmer portrayed in this fashion is assumed to be motivated in

their behavior by empathetic-sympathetic tendencies such as roles in the farming

community, interdependence and identifying with place and others, and community

norms and traditions. Pursuing these community oriented tendencies would again

maximize outcomes (i.e. maximize profit and the utility it can buy), but it is maximized

in the other-interest domain by achieving shared community oriented goals at point C.

By settling upon point C in the space, a farmer uses many conservation techniques and

will use relatively small amounts of industrial inputs. Control over farming processes is

also desired less at this point. Also, drawing upon philosophy, we find that farmers

maximizing the shared other-interest are choosing to buy more completely into a

Page 40: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

33

conservation ethic, which is all about “feeling with” or being “in sympathy with”

(Solomon, 2007, p. 64) other conservation farmers and downstream water users valuing

higher quality water. Without first identifying with and walking in the same space as

others, though, a shared conservation ethic could not evolve.

As noted, the conservation literature assumes that the self-interest and shared

other-interest tendencies are considered independently by the individual decision maker.

Metaeconomics, meanwhile, proffers that both dispositions must be considered jointly

and simultaneously when making a decision. Instead of choosing to maximize either the

self-interest or shared other-interest tendency, metaeconomics posits that the individual

strives to integrate both interests on path 0Z in order to make a choice that satisfies both

domains and provides peace of mind to the decision maker. This is represented by point

B in the space. At point B, the conflict between the self-interest and shared other-interest

within the individual has been resolved and integrated into an own-interest that considers

both the self and others.

Closer examination of point B also leads one to recognize that metaeconomics

allows for the individual farmer to engage in self-sacrifice in both domains of interest. At

this point, we find that the farmer has settled upon the intersection of IG2, IM

2, and the

budget/capital constraint RoR

o. Yet, if a farmer intended to maximize while acting on

the self-interest tendency or other-interest tendency, he or she would orient themselves to

the intersection of the budget constraint with either isoquant IG3 or IM

3, respectively. By

locating at point B, farmers are choosing to give up a little in both domains. This is to

say, the producer may give up some profit in order to install conservation measures on

their farms and do the right thing for the environment, yet they also give up some of the

Page 41: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

34

outcomes from pursuing less in the way of shared other-interest in order to earn enough

profit to remain viable. Thus, point B becomes a type of “satisficing” choice for the

farmer, and as noted, provides a certain peace of mind. We have a kind of Homo

satisficicus state of being on path 0Z.

Not only does metaeconomics make the role of self-sacrifice explicit when

describing choice behavior, it also describes how control and self-control play an

important role in decision making. For example, a farmer moving along path 0G will

likely use intensive tillage practices on crop acres in order to help facilitate deeper root

penetration, help maintain soil fertility, and destroy weeds. In contrast, a person moving

along path 0M is much more willing to use reduced or conservation tillage systems on his

or her farm and to give more control to the natural ecological system. A farmer on this

path is also more likely to give in to more control coming out of regulations, or other

kinds of external controls (i.e. landlords). Thus, we find that a farmer on path 0M may

integrate the need for less control over his or her farm processes with the desire to give

more control to the shared other-interest (Sautter et al, 2008). This integration results in

the farmer helping to eliminate soil erosion while also buying into a conservation or

sustainability ethic.

It follows that making the role and need for self-control explicit is also an

important feature of metaeconomics. Farmers that are on the satisficing path 0Z will be

tempted by both inward desires and outside influences (i.e. the “Freedom to Farm” Act)

to move back to path 0G and maximize the egoistic-hedonistic interest, or they may

ultimately succumb to social and community norms and the conservation ethic exhibited

by path 0M and attempt to maximize the empathetic-sympathetic interest. So, self-

Page 42: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

35

control is needed by the individual in order to act independently and with courage in

order to achieve satisfactory outcomes in the two parts of the individual‟s own-interest as

demonstrated by path 0Z. Thus, as noted by Sautter et al (2008), “the preference for

control and the ability to take control also temper the self-interest in moving toward path

0Z.”

Finally, it is important to note that metaeconomics posits that the isoquant sets IG

and IM as well as the expansion paths 0G and 0M tend to be in the subconscious of the

individual and are not often considered. While paths 0G and 0M may frame the space

that cognitive and conscious individual thought occurs within, the paths themselves come

to be through “instinct” or intuition (Kahneman, 2003). It is also likely that even 0Z,

once cognitively considered, may become part of an individual‟s intuition. This is

especially true if the decision to be made is one that occurs on a routine basis. In fact,

this is a major theme woven throughout a recent piece written by McCown (2005). In his

writing, McCown, who is building upon the idea of phenomenology in decision making

submitted by Schutz and Luckmann (1973), notes that “in normal routine activity,

commitments are made, and action is taken without conscious deliberation” (p. 22,

emphasis added); so, commitments to the shared interest represented in 0M lead to

tempering the pursuit of self-interest 0G, leading to routine on path 0Z. An example of

this type of decision in the farming context is determining what type of tillage system to

use on crop acres. While a farmer must consciously decide what type of tillage system to

use when starting his or her farming operation, once the decision has been made it

becomes much easier to rely on intuition and subconscious feelings about past tillage

decisions when making choices.

Page 43: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

36

3.4 Mathematics of Metaeconomics

While the metaeconomic model of decision making provides a more accurate

reflection of actual choice behavior, it is also a more complex model than that of standard

microeconomics. By allowing for two joint and non-separable interests to motivate

behavior, metaeconomics has effectively changed the mathematical assumptions of

conventional microeconomics. However, the mathematics is workable, and brings

precision to metaeconomic theory that is on par with that achieved in mathematical

microeconomics.

In the case of farmers living in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake watershed, the

implementation of conservation practices on farms in the region can be represented as an

input in the individual producer‟s production function. Therefore, the mathematical

representation of metaeconomics in this case is an elaborated version of the individual

firm presented by standard microeconomics. In order to demonstrate the elaborated

production mathematics, we draw upon Lynne (2006b). For mathematics concerning the

consumer case, see Lynne (2006a).

Metaeconomics proposes two production functions, with one representing the

production of a product of commercial interest that can be sold in markets in the pursuit

of self-interest (i.e. corn, soybeans, etc.). The other production function represents the

more subjective result from producing a product in a way that satisfies the shared sense

of producing the product in the “right way” (i.e. use conservation measures that reduce

non-point surface water pollution, farming in a more organic manner, etc). There is self-

interest in producing a crop, in that the crop can be taken to market and sold for profit, as

Page 44: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

37

represented in the IG production function. However, we must account for the fact that

suppliers also react with empathy to the needs, wants, and desires of their potential

buyers and others (e.g. downstream water users), which is represented in the IM

production function. So, there are always two production functions that must be

accounted for:

(10) IG = IG(X1, X2)

(11) IM = IM(X1, X2)

This is a form of the multi-ware production process presented by Frisch (1965, pp. 269-

281), a powerful jointness model form that has had virtually no success in making its way

into mainstream economic thought (for one attempt to bring it into the literature, though,

see Lynne, 1988). Frisch cited two examples of the multi-ware production process, with

the most prominent example being that of wool and mutton production. Wool and

mutton are non-separable and jointly produced outputs in which the sheep itself, along

with the environmental and social system that the sheep is raised within, largely

determines the relative amounts of each output produced in an “unconscious” way

(Kruse, 2003). This type of production function is represented in Figure 3.2 as two

overlapping sets of isoquants, with the IG set representing the egoistic-hedonistic

tendencies and the IM set representing the empathetic-sympathetic tendencies that also

motivate production and supply behavior. The overlapping isoquants demonstrate that

there is little to no substitution between the more objective market recognized egoistic-

hedonistic output and the more subjective empathetic-sympathetic output. This is the

main feature of a joint, multi-ware production process.

Page 45: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

38

To illustrate the metaeconomic model, the following form of an objective function

that balances the egoistic-hedonistic and empathetic-sympathetic tendencies is assumed

(although there are many other possibilities):

(12) 2 21 2 1 2 1 1 1 2( , ) ( , ) ( )GG M MpI X X I X X I I R r X r X

where rj refers to the input prices paid for attributes Xj by the individual farmer; and p is

the market generated price for the egoistic interest in providing the product or crop.

Also, notice that there is a subjective element to cost represented in κ1 and κ2; there is

also a subjective payoff, τ, from empathizing, or “walking-in-the-shoes,” of both the

consumer and input supplier. Notice, too, that both outputs arise from the same cost R

such that the joint cost cannot be allocated.

Next, we obtain the first order conditions (FOC):

(13) 1

1 1

1 1

( ) ( ) setMG

M GI I

p I I rX X X

(14) 2 2

2 2 2

( ) ( ) setM

M GIG I

p I I rX X X

(15) 1 1 1 1 2 2set0R r X r X

The least cost condition shows:

(16) 1 1 1 1

2 2 2 2

( )( ) ( )( )

( )( ) ( )( )

M G G M

M G G M

p I I X I I X r

p I I X I I X r

Finding the expansion path 0Z in Figure 3.2 from equation (16):

(17) 2 2 1 1 2 2( , , , , , )G MX X r r p I I R

Intriguingly, notice how the microeconomics expansion path 0G is the default case, when

τ = 0; γ = 0; ι = κ1 = κ2 = 1; this traditional path does not include either integration or

Page 46: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

39

balancing of the egoistic-hedonistic and empathetic-sympathetic interests. In fact, path

0G only considers egocentric tendencies, as empathy and sympathy are not considered

motives for behavior in standard microeconomics. Also, notice the peculiarity of

equation (17), in that product and input prices as well as the IG and IM interest variables

all impact the expansion path. The derived demand function for an input is similarly

influenced (i.e. the individual firm has tempered both the self-interest and other-interest)

along some path 0Z:

(18) 1 1 1 1 2 2( , , , , , , )D D G MX X r r p I I R N

We now see from equation (18) that, unlike the conventional microeconomics case,

empathy (IM), as well as egocentric tendencies (IG), affect input demand (and also product

demand, if this was a product demand curve). The fact that the IG and IM interest

variables impact input demand also suggests the need to measure these interests, either

directly or indirectly, when trying to explain behavior. Kahneman has called for similar

research, suggesting that it is possible to measure an individual‟s experienced utility

(Kahneman, Wakker, and Sarin, 1997). Based on this insight, then, various proxies for

the IG and IM interests will be used in explaining conservation behavior in the Blue

River/Tuttle Creek watershed.

By inserting equation (17) and then equation (18) into the objective function (12),

we can also derive the ego-empathy frontier represented in Figure 3.3. Staying on the

budget line RRo we can trace the curve in Figure 3.3 represented in:

(19) , 1 1 2 2( , , , , )G MI I r r p R

With equation (19), we can now define and explore the mutual benefit associated with

reciprocity (Cory, 2006a; cited in Lynne, 2006b) by examining the extent to which there

Page 47: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

40

is a “bulge” in the curves, i.e. the extent to which the distances across the isocurves

increases as we move along path 0Z.

Figure 3.3 also allows for the examination of the ego/empathy ratio, a concept

that has been emphasized by Cory (2006a). This occurrence is represented in the

derivative dIG/dIM, calculated from equation (19) and given by:

(20) //

/M

G MG M

G

dI IT

dI I

We see, then, that the dynamic balance between ego and empathy occurs somewhere in

the region AC where TG/M = -1 (Cory, 2006b). As Cory (2004) notes, though, it is not the

particular value of TG/M that is of importance, but rather the orientation and divergence on

either side of this point. So, a person with an orientation toward the other-interest (TG/M <

-1) would be observed exhibiting behavior that contributes to the provision of public

goods and participating in activities like crop rotations and farm conservation strategies.

On the other hand, those with an orientation toward the egoistic-hedonistic self-interest

(0 < TG/M < -1) would tend to live a more material lifestyle (Lynne, 2006b). So, the trade-

off balance that provides peace of mind in decision making is likely in and around TG/M =

-1. However, this is ultimately an empirical question.

Given the graphical and mathematical representations of standard and

metaeconomics production theory shown above, the task now at hand is to empirically

estimate the equivalent of Equations (9) and (18), with both representing the demand for

conservation tillage This will be done with the use of various proxy measures collected

from survey respondents in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake watershed. In the end,

Page 48: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

41

these empirical results will provide the basis for comparison of the standard

microeconomic production model and the metaeconomic model.

Page 49: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

42

Figure 3.1. Self-interest (G) isoquant curves for conservation tillage (e) and all other

industrial inputs (d)

Page 50: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

43

Figure 3.2. Joint Interests. Relationship between the farmer‟s pursuit of a joint self-

interest (IG) on path 0G and an internalized yet shared other-interest (IM) on path 0M with

the path 0Z showing sacrifice in both domains of interest.

Page 51: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

44

Figure 3.3. Interests Frontier. Frontiers of interest illustrating the need for balance and the

possibility for synergy, sum greater than the sum of the parts kinds of outcomes, in the

pursuit of two joint and non-separable interests in conservation.

Page 52: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

45

TOWARD EMPIRICAL TESTING

4.1. Physical Description of Study Area

Tuttle Creek Lake, Kansas, is a 14,000 acre reservoir located in northeast Kansas

at the lower end of the Big Blue River. The watershed consists of a total area of 9,682

square miles with approximately three-quarters of the drainage area located in soutcentral

and southeast Nebraska. The remaining drainage area is located in northeast Kansas (See

Figure 4.1). The lake, built in 1962 under the direction of the U.S. Army Corps of

Engineers (USACE), provides flood control, irrigation, water supply, recreation, fish and

wildlife management, low flow augmentation, and navigation flow supplementation to

the region (Shea, Burbach, Lynne, Martin, and Milner, 2006). Outflow from Tuttle

Creek Lake enters the Big Blue River about nine miles above its confluence with the

Smoky Hill and Republican rivers near Manhattan, Kansas. At this location, all three

rivers join together to form the Kansas River.

Land use within the Tuttle Creek Lake watershed is primrily agricultural, with

approximately 72 percent of the land used to grow corn, grain sorghum, and other crops.

Another 10 percent of the land is pastureland and another 10 percent is wooded area

(Shea et al, 2006). Herbicides are used extensively throughout the region to control

weeds.

The topography of the watershed varies widely, with slopes ranging anywhere

from 1 percent to greater than 10 percent. In general, the land within the northern and

western portions of the Big Blue and Little Blue River basins is relatively flat, with

slopes of 3 percent or less. In contrast, the remainder of the watershed exhibits extensive

soil dissection which results in slopes of 10 percent or greater (Shea et al., 2006).

Page 53: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

46

The predominate soil types in the watershed are silty clay loams, which allow

water infiltration rates in the region to vary from moderate to very slow. Thus, most soils

possess a moderate to very high potential of transporting chemical contaminatnts to

surface water in solution, or bound to eroded soil particles.

4.2. Description of Institutional Arrangements in Study Area

The current institutional situation in the Tuttle Creek Lake watershed has given

rise to water quality problems throughout the region. The historical presumption in the

watershed has been that farmers upstream of Tuttle Creek Lake have the right to allow

chemicals and sediments to runoff and deposit into rivers and streams. Traditionally,

upstream farmers have not been obligated to be concerned with downstream water users‟

rights to clean water. Both state laws and the Federal Clean Water Act put the burden of

cleaning contaminated water on those that are currently using the water, unless the water

users can definitively show which entities are creating the water pollution; and since

agricultural runoff is a non-point source of pollution, those downstream of Tuttle Creek

Lake can not show precisely who is causing the poor water qualtiy in the Lake. So, in

effect, the downstream water users have the duty to accept substandard water quality.

This institutional setup has led to water quality problems for both the Big Blue

River and Tuttle Creek Lake. In fact, Tuttle Creek Lake is listed on the Clean Water Act

Section 303(d) list as impaired for siltation, eutrophication, atrazine, and alachlor.

Extremely large loads of suspended solids and nutrients enter the lake during spring and

summer storm events and excessive siltation has impacted the upper third of the

reservoir‟s conservation pool (Shea et al, 2006). Recent estimates have shown that

Page 54: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

47

siltation has reduced the volume of the reservoir‟s conservation pool by 30 to 50 percent

(Barnes, 2006). There are also many observations during the period of record where

atrazine concentrations in Tuttle Creek Lake exceed both the aquatic life and public

drinking water standards of 3 μg/L as mandated by the Clean Water Act. Observations of

the lake also show phosphorous levels to be excessively high at the deep water site,

which could potentially lead to eutrophication. Records also indicate that water quality in

the Big Blue River, a major tributary of Tuttle Creek Lake, is impacted by excessive

amounts of E. Coli and fecal coliform bacteria, nutrients, and atrazine (O'Brien, 2008).

In recent years, the current institutions in the Tuttle Creek Waterhed have been

called into question by downstream water users (instututions are defined as working

rules, norms, traditions, and property relations; see Bromley, 2008). Thus, irritation has

started to build within and between the upstream agricultural producers and downstream

water users of the region. The questioning and evolution of the institutional makeup of

the watershed has been brought on for several reasons, including the desire for clean

water for recreational purposes, general concern for plants and animals that use the water

in the region, and aesthetics. However, of paramount concern to downstream water users

is the quality and quantity of potable water sources in the region. As noted earlier,

outflow from Tuttle Creek Lake helps to provide water flow to the Kansas River. Shea et

al (2006) note that approximately 50 percent of the flow in the Kansas River can be

directly attributed to supplies from Tuttle Creek Lake. This is important to note, as the

Kansas River provides drinking water to major population centers in northeast Kansas,

including Kansas City, Topeka, and Lawrence. Therefore, polluted water from Tuttle

Page 55: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

48

Creek Lake is infiltrating the Kansas River and jeopardizing the quality of the water

supply for these areas in northeast Kansas.

Water quantity is also of concern to the region due to the fact that cities in

northeast Kansas are growing rapidly. Margaret Stafford of the Topeka Capital-Journal

(2003) reported that the population of Johnson County, Kansas had grown by 27 percent

between 1990 and 2000, and that the city of Olathe alone had grown by 47 percent

(nearly 30,000 people). Obviously, this rapid population expansion has strained the

ability of municipalities to provide water to their citizens. For example, Water District 1

in Johnson County, Kansas currently provides about 200 million gallons of water per day

to its customers, but projections show that the supply will need to grow to 330 million

gallons of water per day in the next 40 years in order to accommodate population growth

in the county (Stafford, 2003). As the population and demand for water continues to

grow in the region, Tuttle Creek Lake will become an ever more important source for

water supply. However, as cited earlier, the capacity for the reservoir to hold water has

been reduced due to siltation. Therefore, practices upstream that contribute to soil

erosion and siltation are now looked upon in a negative light by water suppliers

downstream.

In an effort to reduce water quality problems and alleviate tension between

agricultural producers and water users, the USDA has continued to expand programs and

funding for conservation programs in the agricultural midwest. The USDA Economic

Research Service (ERS) notes that policy makers have been devoting ever more attention

to conservation policies and programs that promote greater environmental quality

throughout the nation. Expenditures on conservation practices started increasing rapidly

Page 56: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

49

around 1986. However, starting around 1995, these expenditures began increasing at a

much slower pace. Eventually, in 2001, expenditures on conservation programs in the

U.S. settled at about 2.5 billion dollars per year. The vast majority of money spent during

this time period was used in land retirment programs such as the Conservation Reserve

Program (CRP). Starting in 2002, though, a dramatic shift in both overall funding and

types of conservation programs funded was employed by policymakers. In fact, from

2001 to 2005, expenditures on conservation has increased from approximately 2.5 billion

dollars to nearly 4.5 billion dollars. Also, much more money was spent on working land

programs like the Environmental Quality Incentive Program (ERS, 2007).

While policymakers have continued to increase funding for conservation

programs, the method used to administer this funding to farmers participating in the

programs has remained relatively unchanged. Policymakers have shown a distinct

preference for administering conservation payments on a volunteer basis (ERS, 2007).

Therefore, willing participants enroll in programs at their local Farm Service Agency

(FSA) office in order to receive conservation payments. This approach, though, does not

lead to targeting of areas most succeptible to non-point agricultural pollution. It also

leads to problems in verifying that conservation measures are being administered

appropriately and that they lead to improved environmental conditions.

Over the past several years, an increasing amount of emphasis has been placed on

conservation issues in U.S. Farm Bill legislation. Yet, the main purpose of the bill is to

provide financial support and stability to those working in the agricultural field. To this

end, the U.S. Farm Bill has undergone several changes. According to ERS (2008), U.S.

farm policy had focused on price and income supports since the 1930‟s; also, until 1996,

Page 57: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

50

farm policy relied in part on supply management in the form of acreage limits and storage

programs. However, starting in 1985 and reinforced by the so-called “Freedom to Farm

Act” of 1996, agricultural commodity policy has shifted toward a greater market-based

orientation and has relied less on government intervention (ERS, 2008).

These new policies administer commodity payments based on the calculation base

farm yields. This means that a farmer with a large base yield will receive a larger

commodity payment. Thus we find incentives created that encourage increased

agricultural production. This could potentially produce greater amounts of non-point

agricultural pollution. So, it appears that policies regarding commodity prices may

produce results counter to results that may be produced by conservation policies.

Regardless, though, both commodity and conservation policies are rooted in traditional

economic rationale and assume that farmer behavior is motivated solely by financial

incentives.

4.3. Empirical Models

As noted in Section 3.4, the task at hand is to estimate Equations (9) and (20)

using various proxy measures. Proxies for outside influences and preferences for control

in the context with which the farmer operates within are also used in empirical models.

The ultimate goal of this research is to use the information and insights gained in

order to promote increased usage of conservation measures in the four county critical

area of the Blue River watershed and influence conservation policy in the United States.

For this reason, models that are probabilistic in nature are best suited to analyze

conservation behavior in the study area. In other words, we seek to understand how

Page 58: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

51

changes in independent variables impact the probablility of adopting conservation

technologies on working farms, with particular attention being focused on the individual

farmer‟s decision regarding tillage strategies. Therefore, models of the probit and logit

variety will be used to test conservation behavior in the four county target area.

Four logit models of the following functional forms will be used to compare the

results produced from standard microeconomic theory and metaeconomic theory:

(21) 1 0 1 2Pr(0, ) ( ) ( )i i iX R N

(22) 0 1 2 3Pr(0, 1) ( ) ( ) ( * )i i Gi Mi iX R N I I

(23) 0 1 2 3 4Pr(0, 1) ( ) ( ) ( * ) ( )i ii i M G i iX R N I I H

(24) 0 1 2 3 4Pr(0, 1) ( ) ( ) ( * ) ( ) 5( * )i ii i M G i Gi i iX R N I I H I V

where Ri = the income (as a proxy for financial and capital capacity) of the ith

farmer; Ni

= the physical characteristics of the ith

farmer‟s crop land; IGi = proxy for self-interest of

the ith

farmer; IMi = proxy for the shared other-interest of the ith

farmer; Hi = proxy for

habitual tendencies of the ith

farmer; and Vi = proxy for preference for control by ith

farmer. Notice that equation (21) represents the standard empirical derived demand

equation given in standard production microeconomics, whereas equation (22) reqresents

the empirical derived demand equation offered by metaeconomic theory. Equations (23)

and (24) build upon the metaeconomic model by adding important variables that account

for habitual tendencies and preferences for control exhibited by the individual farmer.

Results from the aforementioned logit models should assist researchers and policy

makers to pragmatically choose which theoretical model best characterizes a farmer

making the conservation technology adoption decision. While this information is

extremely valuable, it is also important to understand what factors influence the

Page 59: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

52

conservation intensity decision (i.e. proportion of farm under conservation technology) a

farmer makes once he or she chooses to utilize conservation strategies. For this reason,

Heckman or “Heckit” empirical models (Heckman, 1979) have also been constructed in

order to better understand the conservation intensity decision.

4.4. Development of Survey Instrument and Data Collection

As previously presented in Figure 4.1, the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake

watershed covers a large portion of southcentral and southeast Nebraska, as well as

northeast Kansas. However, the use of natural resource assesment maps and empirical

surface water quality data allowed physical scientists from the University of Nebraska-

Lincoln to identify a critical four county area of nonpoint source runoff that may impact

Tuttle Creek Lake near the Nebraska-Kansas border (Shea et al, 2006). This critical area

includes Jefferson and Gage counties in Nebraska, as well as Washington and Marshall

counties in Kansas. Therefore, efforts to promote behavioral modification involving

conservation measures on farms have been targeted to this four county area.

A total of 4,191 surveys were mailed to known farm operators in the four county

target area of the watershed. Names and addresses of operators were obtained from farm

operator lists maintained by the local county offices of the Farm Service Agency, U.S.

Department of Agriculture. According to the FSA, the population of the four county area

consists of 3,731 total operators. In the original survey mailing, operators were offered

$40 to complete the survey. A subsequent mailing of the survey commenced a few

weeks after the first mailing was complete. This mailing included a random subsample

of 460 non-respondents of the original 3,731 operators. This time, respondents were

Page 60: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

53

offered $80 for their completed questionairres. Intriguingly, the response rate from

operators offered $80 for responses was lower (10.2 percent) than the response rate from

operators that were offered $40 for their completed surveys (15.8 percent). Overall, the

response rate from the 3,731 operators was 17.1 percent (639 survey responses). Due to

missing responses on the proposed dependent variables, 498 surveys were used for

statistical analysis.

While a survey response rate of 17.1 percent is considered respectable, some may

choose to argue that the response is too low to make generalizations about the farming

population in the four county target area. However, there is evidence to suggest that the

survey response rate may in fact be larger than 17.1 percent. First, the survey created

was intended to be administered to farm operators in the target area, as the operators are

the individuals most likely to be in the field making conservation decisions. However,

the primary investigators listed on the cover page of the administered survey received

several phone calls and e-mail correspondences from individuals that had received the

survey that do not participate in day-to-day farming operations. Thus, this antecdotal

evidence suggests that both operators as well as owners/landlords may have received the

survey. The potential exists that the FSA farm operator lists obtained were not properly

maintained and oversampling may have occurred.

There is other evidence to suggest that oversampling may have occurred. As

noted, FSA operator lists indicated that there were 3,731 operators located in the four

county target area in the watershed. Yet, according to the National Agricultural Statistics

Service (NASS) census for 2002, there is only a total of 3,184 farms in the four county

target region. Therefore, if it is assumed that each farm has one principal operator,

Page 61: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

54

oversampling by nearly 550 individuals occurred in the sample. If we remove these 550

surveys from the overall sample, the survey response rate is 20 percent. If we further

assume that the trend of shrinking farm nubers in the target area has continued during the

period from 2002 to 2007 (census statistics from 2007 will not be released until February,

2009), it is possible that the actual response rate could be around 23 to 25 percent.

3.4. Description of Variables

Dependent Variables

Two dependent variables were created for the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake

watershed dataset: no01 and noratio_1. The no01 variable is a binary (0,1) variable used

to explain the adoption of conservation tillage in the logit analyses, whereas the noratio_1

variable is used in the continuous ordinary least squares (OLS) portion of Heckman

models used to explain conservation tillage intensity. Both of these variables were

created by using information obtained from Questions 2a and 2b of the survey instrument

entitled “A Soil and Chemical Management Survey of Kansas and Nebraska Farmers”

(See Appendix A).

Questions 2a and 2b use a matrix format in order to ascertain the number of acres

under various types of tillage regimes. Respondents reported the number of acres under

conventional tillage (less than 15 percent crop residue), reduced tillage (15 percent to 30

percent crop residue), and conservation tillage/no-till (greater than 30 percent crop

residue) cropping schemes. Respondents were also asked to break this information down

by dryland and irrigated acres, as well as practices on highly erodible land (HEL) and Not

Erodible land.

Page 62: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

55

The computation of the no01 dependent variable is fairly straight forward: those

respondents that use any amount of conservation tillage/no-till received a score of 1 for

the no01 variable, and those that use no conservation tillage/no-till received a score of 0.

The computation of the noratio_1 variable, on the other hand, required a bit of simple

arithmatic. As the variable name implies, noratio_1 gives the proportion of an individual

farmer‟s land that utilizes a conservation tillage/no-till technology. This was computed

by taking the total acres of conservation tillage/no-till reported in questions 2a and 2b and

dividing this amount into the total amount of acres farmed as reported in the matricies.

Any missing values were then replaced by mean substitution. Ultimately, this provides a

continuous variable with values that range between 0 and 1.

Independent Variables

Income/Financial Capacity (Ri)

Income data from farmers in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake watershed was

collected and is an important component in both the microeconomic and metaeconomic

derived demand models. The variable, named income2_1, was collected via Question 33

in the administered survey instrument. This question asked respondents to choose a

category that best described their total income from both gross farm sales and other

farm/conservation payments, again, as noted, to indicate the financial or capital capacity

of the farm. Responses were scaled such that the final income variable is reported in

thousand of dollars. Also, missing income values were treated with mean substitution. It

is hypothesized that the income variable will have a positive and significant impact upon

both the no01 and noratio_1 dependent variables.

Soil Slope (Ni)

Page 63: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

56

The physical context of the land in production is thought to be an important

determinant in the adoption of conservation technologies. In the case of tillage strategies,

the most important physical factor appears to be soil slope (i.e. land steepness). For this

reason, soil slopes are estimated in the four county critical area of the Blue River/Tuttle

Creek Lake watershed.

In order to compute soil slope, individual survey respondents were asked to mark

an “X” on a county map in order to indicate the general location of the respondent‟s

principal farm. Then, geographic latitude and longitude coordinates of the principal

farms were determined by using the computer program 3-D Topoquads. Once the

geograpic coordinates were obtained, this information was then utilized in Geographic

Information Systems (GIS) software in order to obtain information regarding soil slope

on a particular respondent‟s principal farm.

Individuals with specialized knowledge in the GIS field were relied upon to

compute the soil slope variable. These individuals used two different data layers when

computing soil slope: a 30 meter digital elevation model (DEM) of the four county area

and a map of 2007 NASS cropland data. Using both the 30 m DEM and the cropland

data, different footprints were created for each crop scenario in the region. These

footprints were used to extract the soil slope information.

With the soil slope information in hand, zonal statistics were then used within the

GIS system in order to compute the minimum, maximum, range, and standard deviation

of the slope information. The final soil slope variable is the mean of the soil information

extracted from the GIS system. Again, all missing values were replaced via mean

substitution.

Page 64: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

57

While physical land characteristics are considered to be important factors in the

individual conservation adoption decision, it is important to note that, for this particular

study, the soil slope variable is hypothesized to not be statistically significant when

attempting to explain a farmer‟s rationale for adopting different tillage strategies. This

hypothesis is due to the fact that the four county target area was specifically chosen

because physical science models predicted that the area exhibited physical characteristics

that lead to a great risk of transporting eroded soil and chemical runoff to the Blue River

system and, ultimately, Tuttle Creek Lake. Since the study area was chosen due to these

characteristics (which included soil steepness), it is expected that there will not be enough

variation in the values of the soil slope variable to yield it as a powerful and statistically

significant predictor of farmer conservation behavior. However, the inclusion of the soil

slope variable does in subsequent statistical models does serve as a statistical test to help

determine that the correct study area has been chosen.

Page 65: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

58

Other-Interest*Self-Interest (IMi*IGi)

The other-interest*self-interest independent variable is the core variable of the

empirical metaeconomic model. As previously indicated, it is theorized that humans rely

upon joint, non-separable shared other-interest tendencies and self-interest tendencies

when making economic decisions. For this reason, other-interest and self-interest

indepenent variables can not be modeled separately. Thus, it has been decided that

proxies for an individual‟s shared other-interest and self-interest tendencies will be

multiplied such that both proxies are taken into account when creating a single

independent variable.

Three proxies were used to measure a survey respondent‟s orientation toward a

shared other-interest: empathy, sympathy, and empathy/others. The need for three

different shared other-interest proxies is due to the fact that other-interest dispositions in

humans evolve. For example, psychologists and neuroscientists like Decety, Michalska,

and Akitsuki (2008) have shown with functional Magnetic Resonance Imaging (fMRI)

that the programming for empathy has been “hard-wired” into the brain circuitry of

normal functioning children. Their results are consistent with previous fMRI studies

involving adults. Thus, it appears that the ability to empathize with other humans is an

innate characteristic possessed by normal humans. Therefore, it is also proposed in this

paper that all humans have the ability to project themselves into the perceived mental

state of others (i.e. “walk in the shoes of others”).

While empathy is defined as the ability to project oneself into the mental state of

others, sympathy is defined in a much different manner. While most relate sympathy to

feelings of compassion, this paper defines sympathy in much the same way as it is

Page 66: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

59

defined by the philosopher Solomon (2007): a human‟s ability to sympathize is

characterized as the ability to buy into a specific group ethic. So, we find that humans

can indeed become “in sympathy with” particular groups and buy into specific group

ethics. This is achieved through the use of empathy. Individuals can project themselves

into the state of mind of specific groups and choose to become in sympathy with the

group in question if the group ethic and goals align with the individual‟s goals. So, we

find that the key to becoming in sympathy with particular groups is the act of empathy.

In other words, empathy can move an individual towards sympathy. However, it should

be noted that the act of empathizing does not automatically lend itself to sympathy.

Becoming in sympathy with a group is still an individual choice that can be accepted or

rejected, but empathizing does provide important information to the individual that aids

in the decision making process. So, in terms of the research at hand, it is proposed that

all inhabitants in the four county target area have the ability to empathize (albeit some

have a greater capacity than others), but it is unlikely that all inhabitants have become in

sympathy with various groups that use the Blue River watershed and Tuttle Creek Lake.

While the acts of empathizing and sympathizing occur strictly within the

individual, it cannot be denied that the opinions and lobbying of other human beings can

in fact influence an individual‟s decision making process. Therefore, the empathy/others

variable was created in order to assess which specific individuals and groups can

influence farmer conservation behavior. This is the final other-interest proxy used in

testing the metaeconomic theory in the study area.

In order to assess a survey respondent‟s capacity to empathize, the perspective

taking and fantasy subscales of the Davis Empathy Scale (a widely used and accepted

Page 67: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

60

psychological scale), were used (Davis, 1980). Respondents were asked to respond to 13

agree/disagree items in order to evaluate their empathetic shared other-interest

tendencies. The line items were all similar to the following form, and formatted as

recommended by the Theory of Planned Behavior (Ajzen, 1991):

In the end, though, factor analysis conducted with the statistical package SPSS (16.0)

showed that 7 of the 13 line items accounted for most of the variation in the empathy

scale presented in question 22. Therefore, the mean of these 7 items (lines 5, 6, 7, 8, 11,

12, and 13) were used to assess a respondent‟s orientation toward the empathetic shared

other-interest.

While the Davis Empathy Scale is a widley used survey instrument that can assess

a person‟s empathizing ability, there is no such instrument available to measure the

degree to which a person is “in sympathy with” various group ethics. For this reason, a

new sympathy scale was created and administered to the farming population of the four

county target area in the watershed. This sympathy scale, which utilized five line items,

was tailored to the problem at hand in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake watershed. The

line items were constructed as seven point agree/disagree Likert scales and all were

similar to the following form:

Page 68: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

61

Ultimately, each respondent was asked if they could be in sympathy with three specific

groups in the region: recreational users of Tuttle Creek Lake, public water suppliers

below Tuttle Creek Dam, and finally, all others that use water from the watershed. Then,

the mean of all line items was calculated in order to determine a respondent‟s final

sympathetic other-interest disposition.

As was the case with the created sympathy scale, there is also not a generally

accepted psychological scale that can asses the degree to which respondents‟ decisions

are influenced by other people. However, the applied theory of planned behavior

(Ajzen, 1991) does provide some guidance in creating questionairres that assess human

behavior. Therefore, the empathy/others variable was constructed specifically for this

study by using information provided by the applied theory of planned behavior.

Question 19 of the survey instrument assesses the influence that others may have

on tillage decisions, with particular attention being paid to other Tuttle Creek Lake water

users, those that can have a direct impact on farming operations (i.e. Farm Service

Agency, landlords, etc.), and family members. Survey participants were asked to respond

to the following statement:

Other people may influence your thinking about farming decisions, and

may affect decisions on your farm. Please mark an “X” at a spot on each

line to indicate how likely you think it is that these people believe you

should use conservation tillage/no-till and chemical BMPs.

Page 69: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

62

Respondents then placed an “X” on 18 different line items, with all items similar to this

form:

Statistical factor analysis of the line item responses confirmed the presence of the three

influential groups cited above. Threfore, there are three independent variables that

represent other water users of Tuttle Creek Lake (mean of line items 10, 11, 12, and 13),

those with direct ties to the farming community (mean of line items 2, 3, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 9,

and 18), and family members (mean of line items 1, 14, 15, 16, and 17).

While three proxies were needed to evaluate the evolution of shared other-

interests of farmers in our sample, only one proxy was needed to assess a farmer‟s

orientation toward self-interest tendencies. The proxy used for this study was the selfism

scale created by Phares and Erskine (1984). This scale has been tested routinely in

psychological disciplines, and it has been deemed as reliable in assessing narcissistic

(selfish) tendencies within individuals.

Question 24 of the survey instrument used in the four county target area

administered the selfism scale. Respondents were asked to give their opinions regarding

14 different line items that assessed selfish tendencies. All line items were similar to the

following form:

Page 70: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

63

Although 14 line items were given in question 24, statistical factor analysis indicated that

8 of these items accounted for nearly all of the variance of the scale. So, based on the

information provided in the factor analysis, the mean of those 8 line items (lines 5, 7, 8,

10, 11, 12, 13, 14) were used to compute the final selfism variable.

Once the final shared other-interest and self-interest variables were computed, the

final other-interest*self-interest (IMi*IGi) metaeconomic independent variables could be

created. In order to create these variables, the results from the selfism scale were

reversed such that the two multiplicants would be of the same magnitude and direction.

Then, the results from each other-interest proxy were multiplied by the results of the self-

interest proxy. The result was five independent variables that could be used in three

separate tests of metaeconomic theory (test of empathy, test of sympathy, test of

empathy/others). It is hypothesized that these five variables will have a positive impact

on the probability of a farmer using conservation tillage techniques on his or her farm.

Habit (Ri)

Metaeconomics suggests that most farmers making operating decisions run

largely on emotion or sub-conscious feelings about farming strategies that have worked

in the past. Intriguingly, this assertion is supported by empirical research conducted by

Kahneman (2003). In his work, Kahneman determined that humans in general rely on

“intuition” or emotion in their decision making processes. In fact, he determined that

Page 71: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

64

“effortless thought is the norm” in the everyday lives of humans. So, based on this

empirical contribution to the behavioral economic and psychological economic literature,

it seems prudent to add a measure of habit to the empirical metaeconomic model.

In metaeconomic terms, if someone is on a path 0Z, it is more likely that path will

be maintained through time. In effect, it is proposed that consciously cognitive, rational

calculation and consideration of using more conservation tillage happening at some

earlier time simply leads to underlying, less than cognitive feelings reflected in habitual

tendencies. These internalized past decisions then guide decisions made today (Sautter

et. al, 2008). Thus, we find that once farmers put into practice a new technology, they

become rather reluctant to switch back to practices used in the past.

Habitual tendencies in relation to conservation tillage strategies were measured in

the four county target area by asking the following question: Is the percentage of your

farm under conservation tillage/no-till less, the same, or more than 3 years ago?

Responses were recorded on a seven-point Likert scale. It is expected that this variable

will have a positive and significant impact on the probability of farmers using

conservation tillage on farms in the Tuttle Creek Lake watershed.

Self-Interest*Control (IGi*IVi)

As noted earlier, meateconomic theory proposes that a farmer‟s preference for

control over his or her farming operations can make a large impact upon conservation

technologies used on individual farms. For this reason, farmers in the four county target

area of the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake watershed were asked to respond to several line

items that assess a person‟s views in regard to control over specific farm processes.

Page 72: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

65

Question 15 of the composed survey instrument administers the control scale.

The line items were administered with a seven point Likert scale, and all 18 items took

the following form:

Notice that respondents were essentially marking an “X” on a continuum that measured

whether he or she perceives complete control over conservation practices and their

consequences or if he or she feels that they have no control over conservation practices

and their consequences. This is very similar in nature to the idea of autonomous versus

heteronomous control presented by Angyal (1967), in which autonomous control is

represented as internal self-control and heteronomous control is represented as control

exerted upon the individual by others or the environment in which the individual resides.

It is hypothesized, then, that those who feel that they can use conservation tillage

strategies and still maintain a great amount of autonomous control over farming processes

will be more likely to use conservation tillage on individual farms. In contrast, those that

believe using conservation tillage technologies reduce a farmer‟s autonomous control

over farming processes will be less likely to use conservation tillage strategies.

Statistical factor analysis confirmed that Question 15 assesses three different

types of control: control over specific farm practices (farm control; mean of lines 1, 2, 4,

5, 6, 7, 8, 10, 11, 13, and 15), control exerted upon respondents by others (other control;

mean of lines 9, 12, 16, 17, and 18), and preferences for control over nature (nature

control; mean of lines 3 and 14). With these components determined, the results from the

selfism scale (see above) were then multiplied by the results of the separate control

Page 73: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

66

factors in order to derive the final control variables used in the metaeconomic models.

All missing values were replaced by mean substitution. It is hypothesized that self-

interest tendencies reinforce preferences for control over farm processes, and thus the

final control variables are expected to have a significant and negative impact on the

probability of using conservation tillage on farms located in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek

Lake watershed.

Page 74: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

67

Figure 4.1. Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake Watershed and four county critical area

Nebraska

Kansas

Big BlueRiver

Little BlueRiver

Tuttle CreekLake

Jefferson

Gage

Washington

Marshall

Page 75: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

68

RESULTS AND DISCUSSION

5.1. Summary Descriptive Statistics

The following tables summarize the results of the data collected from the survey

instrument sent to the four county target area in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake

watershed. Each table lists the mean response to each specific line item from the

questionnaire for those that chose to respond the seven-point Likert scales. For the

purpose of providing the results of summary descriptive statistics, all non-responses and

responses of “Do Not Know” and “Does Not Apply” were excluded. Please see

Appendix A for reference to question numbers.

Table 1: Mean Responses to Question 24 (Selfism Scale)

Mean Std. Deviation

slffirst 3.40 1.728

slfnobody 3.61 1.739

slfhoard 3.55 1.581

slfworry 3.24 1.602

slfsell 3.72 1.532

slfworth 2.72 1.356

slfaggr 3.21 1.487

slfahead 2.81 1.634

Page 76: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

69

Table 2: Mean Responses to Question 22 (Davis Empathy Scale)

Mean Std. Deviation

empimag 5.32 1.114

empdisagree 5.47 1.127

empthink 5.32 1.119

empsure 4.73 1.194

empcritic 4.96 1.183

empstory 5.07 1.089

empshoe 4.52 1.261

Table 3: Mean Responses to Question 23 (Sympathy Scale)

Mean Std. Deviation

sympsamecnty 4.74 1.250

sympothrcnty 4.68 1.257

sympoutside 4.41 1.322

sympwatsupl 4.94 1.239

sympbelow 4.90 1.216

Table 4: Mean Responses to Question 19 (Empathy/Others Water Users Scale)

Mean Std. Deviation

infwatsupl 4.38 1.880

infrecr 4.09 1.918

inffrmblw 4.15 1.765

infenv 4.74 1.881

Page 77: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

70

Table 5: Mean Responses to Question 19 (Empathy/Others Farm Entity Scale)

Mean Std. Deviation

infsupl 5.04 1.392

infagron 5.18 1.481

infcommod 3.95 1.650

inflndr 4.36 1.608

inffrnd 4.69 1.466

infext 5.16 1.489

infdealer 3.72 1.449

inffsa 4.90 1.605

Table 6: Mean Responses to Question 19 (Empathy/Others Family Scale)

Mean Std. Deviation

infchild 4.66 2.157

infparent 4.30 2.609

infrelat 4.23 2.085

infspouse 4.88 2.110

Table 7: Mean Responses to Question 15 (Farm Control Scale)

Mean Std.

Deviation

ctrlstable 3.04 1.491

ctrlreg 2.79 1.555

ctrlself 3.45 1.719

ctrlerosion 2.90 1.559

ctrlweeds 3.10 1.592

ctrlinside 3.50 1.277

ctrlperm 3.29 1.822

ctrlme 3.39 1.448

ctrldate 3.91 1.726

ctrlappear 4.11 1.876

Page 78: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

71

Table 8: Mean Responses to Question 15 (Other Control Scale)

Mean Std.

Deviation

ctrllendr 4.36 1.669

ctrlwateruser 4.00 1.541

ctrllndlord 3.75 1.612

ctrlother 4.48 1.486

ctrlsupply 3.87 1.651

Table 9: Mean Responses to Question 15 (Nature Control Scale)

Mean Std.

Deviation

ctrlpownat 4.99 1.849

ctrlnature 5.03 1.935

The tables presented above provide summary descriptive statistics for survey line

items used to compute the selfism, empathy, sympathy, empathy/others, and control

variables that were described in detail in section 4.4. However, these table do not

account for the theorized interactions between selfism and empathy/sympathy (self-

interest*shared other-interest) and selfism and control. Therefore, summary descriptive

statistics for the final variables used in the analysis of tillage behavior among farmers in

the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake watershed are presented below.

Table 10: Mean Results of Final Selfism Variable

N Mean Std.

Deviation Missing

selfism 496 3.29 1.180 0.40%

Page 79: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

72

Table 11: Mean Results of Final Empathy/Sympathy Variables

N Mean Std.

Deviation Missing

empathy 495 5.06 0.807 0.60%

sympathy 496 4.73 1.088 0.40%

infwatuser 490 4.34 1.707 1.61%

inffarm 491 4.63 1.074 1.41%

inffamily 491 4.52 1.816 1.41%

Table 12: Mean Results for Final Control Variables

N Mean Std.

Deviation Missing

farmctrl 488 3.37 1.008 2.01%

ctrlothers 487 4.08 1.008 2.21%

natctrl 487 5.01 1.701 2.21%

Table 13: Mean Results for Final Selfism*Empathy/Sympathy Variables

N Mean Std.

Deviation Missing

selfemp 488 24.07 8.080 2.01%

self2symp 488 22.65 8.463 2.01%

slfuserinf 482 20.75 10.403 3.21%

slffarminf 483 21.92 7.923 3.01%

slffamilyinf 483 21.42 10.519 3.01%

Table 14: Mean Results for Final Selfism*Control Variables

N Mean Std.

Deviation Missing

slffarm 479 15.64 5.627 3.82%

slfothers 478 19.34 6.776 4.02%

slfnat 478 23.60 10.007 4.02%

Table 15: Mean Results for Final Income Variable

Page 80: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

73

N Mean Std.

Deviation Missing

income2 475 158.91 211.413 4.62%

Table 16: Mean Results for Final Soil Slope Variable

N Mean Std.

Deviation Missing

slope 498 3.11 0.648 0.00%

Table 17: Mean Results for Final Habit Variable

N Mean Std.

Deviation Missing

notilchng 497 3.85 2.132 0.20%

Inspection of the tables presented above provides some interesting insights into

the psychological makeup of the respondents in the four county target area. First, notice

that the final selfism scale (Table 10) indicates that self-interest tendencies are in fact

present within farmers in the watershed. However, the mean score of the scale (3.29) is

much less than might be predicted using the standard framing of the problem of adoption

using traditional microeconomics. In fact, a microeconomics frame would suggest that

the mean score of the selfism scale would be much closer to six or seven, and, being

exactly true to the theory, everyone would need to answer seven Instead, what we find is

that the final selfism score shows that respondents are actually much closer to selfless,

rather than selfish.

In addition to selfish tendencies being present within respondents in the

watershed, survey results also indicate that shared other-interest tendencies in the form of

empathy and sympathy also exist within the region (Table 11). Intriguingly, a

Page 81: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

74

comparison of the mean results of self-interest tendencies and shared other-interest

tendencies in the watershed actually show that shared other-interest tendencies occur at a

greater magnitude than self-interest tendencies. This finding places traditional,

microeconomic based renditions of farmer behavior in question.

Closer inspection of Table 11 also provides some critical information regarding

metaeconomic theory. Previously, it was noted that metaeconomics theorizes that all

individuals are born with an innate ability to empathize with other individuals. The

ability to empathize, then, can ultimately lead an individual to become “in sympathy

with” the ethic and goals of a particular group of people. It was carefully noted, though,

that the ability to empathize does not necessarily lead to sympathy.

Information given in Table 11 shows that this idea may in fact be plausible.

Notice that the mean score of the final empathy scale is 5.06 units. Given that empathy

was measured with a seven-point Likert scale, it is obvious that respondents clearly have

the ability to empathize with other individuals. Comparing the empathy scale with the

scale that measures sympathy, though, indicates that there is a great amount of variability

in the respondents‟ ability to sympathize with groups that use Tuttle Creek Lake. First,

the mean score of the sympathy scale was 4.73 units, a result that is lower than the mean

score of the final empathy scale. Second, and more importantly, the standard deviation of

the sympathy scale was 1.088 units. This result is higher than the standard deviation of

the empathy scale, which produced a result of 0.807 units. Based upon these numbers,

then, we can reasonably speculate that all respondents in the four county target area have

the ability to empathize (albeit at different capacities), whereas not all respondents have

become in sympathy with the ideals and goals of other users downstream that rely upon

Page 82: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

75

Tuttle Creek Lake. This result can also be concluded by inspecting the distribution of

responses to the empathy and sympathy scales. These distributions are provided in

Figure 5.1 and 5.2. Taking all of this information together shows that the end result is in

line with ideas put forward by metaeconomic theory.

Finally, the tables presented above also show that missing values in the final

dataset used to draw conclusions regarding farmer behavior in the watershed is not a

pervasive problem. As expected, the variable with the greatest amount of missing data

was the variable that measured a farmer‟s financial capacity to implement the technology

as represented by gross income. However, the amount of missing data for this variable

only measured 4.62 percent. Given that this and all other variables have missing data at a

rate less that 5 percent, the use of mean substitution to replace the missing values in final

behavioral models appears appropriate.

5.2. Correlations

While the summary descriptive statistics for the region provided above provide

interesting insights into the psychological makeup of farmers in the region, it also seems

that an examination of correlations between each of the scale variables used may also

yield some useful information in moving forward with an empirical test of metaeconomic

theory. Keeping this in mind, a correlation table that includes all behavioral variable

proxies used in the survey of the four county target area of the Blue River/Tuttle Creek

Lake watershed is presented below in Table 18.

Page 83: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

76

Table 18: Correlations Between Various Behavioral Proxies

income slope selfism empathy sympathy infwatuser inffarm inffamily notilchng farmctrl ctrlothers natctrl

income 1.000 -0.149a -0.074 -0.016 -0.022 0.065 0.020 0.036 0.206

a -0.131

a 0.096

b -0.003

slope -0.149a 1.000 0.085 -0.034 0.007 -0.078 -0.011 0.067 -0.021 0.042 0.035 -0.041

selfism -0.074 0.085 1.000 -0.234a -0.225

a -0.166

a -0.101

b -0.057 -0.075 0.199

a -0.048 -0.003

empathy -0.016 -0.034 -0.234a 1.000 0.421

a 0.186

a 0.185

a 0.128

a 0.075 -0.200

a -0.118

a -0.018

sympathy -0.022 0.007 -0.225a 0.421

a 1.000 0.356

a 0.231

a 0.063 -0.064 -0.189

a -0.084 -0.153

a

infwatuser 0.065 -0.078 -0.166a 0.186

a 0.356

a 1.000 0.566

a 0.303

a 0.036 -0.151

a -0.099

b -0.072

inffarm 0.020 -0.011 -0.101b 0.185

a 0.231

a 0.566

a 1.000 0.340

a 0.042 -0.154 -0.160

a -0.077

inffamily 0.036 0.067 -0.057 0.128a 0.063 0.303

a 0.340

a 1.000 -0.067 -0.001 0.016 0.077

notilchng 0.206a -0.021 -0.075 0.075 -0.064 0.036 0.042 0.042 1.000 -0.063 0.016 0.023

farmctrl -0.231a 0.042 0.199

a -0.200

a -0.189

a -0.151

a -0.154

a -0.154

a -0.063 1.000 0.104

b 0.112

b

ctrlothers 0.096a 0.035 -0.048 -0.118

a -0.084 -0.099

b -0.160

a -0.160

a 0.016 0.104

b 1.000 0.079

natctrl -0.003 -0.041 -0.003 -0.018 -0.153a -0.072 -0.077 0.077 0.023 0.112

b 0.079 1.000

a = p<0.01, b = p<0.05

Page 84: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

77

78

At first glance of Table 18, one should notice that there is a fair amount of

correlation exhibited between the items used in the survey of farmers situated above

Tuttle Creek Lake. While this would pose a problem in traditional microeconomic

frames, the correlation in the context of metaeconomic theory actually helps to explain

psychological tendencies and overall behavior exhibited by farmers in the watershed.

It has been noted several times that metaeconomic theory proffers that self-

interest and shared other-interest tendencies within humans are joint and non-separable.

So, one would expect that there would be a negative and significant correlation between

self-interest and shared other-interest proxies, as self-interest would pull an individual

toward maximum profit on path 0G and shared other-interest would pull the individual

toward maximizing shared other-interest(s) on path 0M. Table 18 provides just this type

of information. Notice that the selfism proxy is negatively correlated with both the

empathy and sympathy proxies. In addition, the water user and farm entity portions of

the empathy/others scale are also negatively correlated with the selfism scale.

Importantly, all of these correlations are significant at either the p<0.01 or p<0.05 level.

Therefore, these results lend credence to the idea that self-interest and shared other-

interest tendencies within the human brain are perhaps biologically intertwined and non-

separable.

In addition to the negative correlation exhibited by the self-interest and other-

interest proxies, we also find significant positive correlation between self-interest

tendencies and proxies intended to measure a farmer‟s desire for autonomous control

over his or her farming operations (farmctrl variable). Again, this result was predicted by

Page 85: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

78

78

using metaeconomic theory. As specified earlier, it is thought that preferences for

autonomous control are reinforced by selfish tendencies. In other words, a person that

wants complete control over outcomes in his or her life is not likely to let preferences and

desires from others influence their decisions. Thus, we would expect this type of person

to be on the self-interest maximizing path 0G and let self-interest tendencies dominate

their decision making processes. Thus, we would indeed expect a positive and significant

correlation between the selfism scale and the scale used as a proxy to measure desire for

control over farm processes. We would also expect significant negative correlations

between the farm control scale and all proxies used to measure shared other-interest

tendencies within respondents, which Table 18 also shows to be true.

Finally, it should also be noted that significant and positive correlations exist

between all proxies used to measure an individual respondent‟s orientation toward a

shared other-interest. This helps to validate that each scale is in fact measuring the

intended psychological phenomenon and provides an even greater basis for using three

separate tests of the metaeconomic model, with each using a different other-interest

proxy.

5.3. Results of Logit Test of Microeconomic and Metaeconomic Theory

As noted, Logit models were used to empirically estimate the equivalent of

equations (21) through (24). The following three tables summarize the results.

Page 86: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

79

Table 19: Logistic Estimation of No-Till Adoption Decision (Empathy Other-Interest Proxy)

Variable

Role of

Capital

Adding

Tempered Self

Adding

Habitual Tendency

Adding Selfism

Reinforced Control

Constant 1.005 -0.730 -1.823c -1.078

Income 0.006a 0.005

a 0.004

a 0.004

a

Slope -0.033 0.016 0.038 0.008

Empathy*Selfism

0.070

a 0.066

a 0.090

a

Habit

0.383

a 0.371

a

Selfism*Farm Control

-0.089

a

Selfism*Other Control

0.013

Selfism*Nature Control

0.002

-2 Log Likelihood 442.134 422.482 384.954 374.016

χ2 (Block) 31.474a 19.651

a 37.529

a 10.938

b

χ2 (Model) 31.474a 51.125

a 88.653

a 99.592

a

Nagelkerke R2 .100 .159 .266 .295

Percentage Correct:

0 0 2.2 23.1 28.6

1 100 99.8 96.8 95.8

Overall 81.7 81.9 83.3 83.5

Df 2 3 4 7

Note: a p<.01,

b p<.02,

c p<.05,

d p<.10

Page 87: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

80

Table 20: Logistic Estimation of No-Till Adoption Decision (Sympathy Other-Interest Proxy)

Variable

Role of

Capital

Adding

Tempered Self

Adding

Habitual Tendency

Adding Selfism

Reinforced Control

Constant 1.005 0.122 -1.157 -0.787

Income 0.006a 0.006

a 0.004

a 0.004

a

Slope -0.033 -0.012 0.004 -0.022

Sympathy*Selfism

0.037

b 0.041

b 0.043

c

Habit

0.401

a 0.391

a

Selfism*Farm Control

-0.082

a

Selfism*Other Control

0.035

Selfism*Nature Control

0.017

-2 Log Likelihood 442.134 435.479 393.881 384.343

χ2 (Block) 31.474a 6.655

b 41.598

a 9.538

c

χ2 (Model) 31.474a 38.129

a 79.727

a 89.624

a

Nagelkerke R2 .100 .120 .241 .267

Percentage Correct:

0 0 0 16.5 22.0

1 100 100 96.1 96.8

Overall 81.7 81.7 81.5 83.1

Df 2 3 4 7

Note: a p<.01,

b p<.02,

c p<.05,

d p<.10

Page 88: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

81

Table 21: Logistic Estimation of No-Till Adoption Decision (Empathy/Others Other-Interest Proxy)

Variable

Role of

Capital

Adding

Tempered Self

Adding

Habitual Tendency

Adding Selfism

Reinforced Control

Constant 1.005 -0.734 -1.894c -1.176

Income 0.006a 0.005

a 0.004

a 0.004

a

Slope -0.033 0.006 0.020 -0.022

Water User Empathy*Selfism

0.013 0.014 0.016

Farm Entity Empathy*Selfism

0.090

a 0.084

a 0.093

a

Family Empathy*Selfism

-0.021 -0.016 -0.010

Habit

0.381

a 0.374

a

Selfism*Farm Control

-0.094

a

Selfism*Other Control

0.022

Selfism*Nature Control

0.009

-2 Log Likelihood 442.134 413.540 376.536 365.692

χ2 (Block) 31.474a 28.593

a 37.005

a 10.844

b

χ2 (Model) 31.474a 60.067

a 97.072

a 107.916

a

Nagelkerke R2 .100 .185 .289 .317

Percentage Correct:

0 0 6.6 22.0 27.5

1 100 99.3 96.3 96.3

Overall 81.7 82.3 82.7 83.7

Df 2 5 6 9

Note: a p<.01,

b p<.02,

c p<.05,

d <.10

Page 89: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

82

81

In all three models presented above, the column labeled “Role of Capital”

is representative of equation (21) and represents the standard empirical derived

demand function; the column labeled “Adding Tempered Self” is representative

of equation (22) and represents the most basic metaeconomic empirical derived

demand function; the column labeled “Adding Habitual Tendency” is

representative of equation (23) and adds the aforementioned habit variable to the

metaeconomic derived demand function; and finally, the column labeled “Adding

Selfism Reinforced Control” is representative of equation (24) and adds the three

previously mentioned control variables to the metaeconomic derived demand

function.

Examination of the results from all three models provides some very

intriguing insights into what motivates the conservation tillage adoption decision

among farmers in the four county target area above Tuttle Creek Lake. First, take

note of the results presented in the column labeled “Role of Capital” in all three

logit models. This is the empirical derived demand model described in

microeconomic-based production economics. As microeconomics would suggest,

we find that income (i.e. financial capacity) is a significant variable that helps to

explain a farmer‟s decision to adopt no-till and conservation tillage technologies.

The chi-square statistic for this model also shows the overall model to be

significant in explaining tillage behavior. While the model is significant, though,

it should be noted that the coefficient on the income variable indicates that an

increase in income actually has a very small impact on a farmer‟s tillage decision.

Page 90: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

83

81

In fact, a one thousand dollar increase in gross income only increases the odds of

a farmer adopting no-till and conservation tillage strategies by 0.06 percent (i.e.

less than one percent). Also note that the microeconomic model does a poor job

of predicting which respondents do not use no-till and conservation tillage

technologies.

While the microeconomic model predicts conservation tillage behavior

reasonably well, it does not compare favorably to the empirical derived demand

model proffered by metaeconomic theory. In fact, we find that regardless of the

shared other-interest proxy used (empathy, sympathy, or empathy/others), the

metaeconomic derived demand model predicts conservation tillage behavior much

better than the microeconomic-based derived demand model.

The basic metaeconomic derived demand model is presented in Tables 19,

20, and 21 under the column labeled “Adding Tempered Self.” Notice that in all

three tables, the income variable remains significant, just as in the

microeconomics model. Yet, we also find that the metaeconomic variables (self-

interest*shared other-interest) contribute significantly to understanding farmer

tillage behavior. In Table 21, we find that the empathy*selfism variable is a

significant predictor when attempting to understand tillage behavior in the

watershed. The chi-square (block) statistic also shows that adding the tempered

self-interest variable improves the overall model fit. Also, we find that the R-

square statistic increased from 0.10 to 0.159.

Page 91: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

84

81

Table 21, which presents the results of the metaeconomic derived demand

model that uses sympathy as a proxy for an individual‟s shared other-interest

tendency, tells much the same story as the results provided in Table 20. Again,

income is a significant variable in the individual tillage decision. However, like

the model that uses empathy as a proxy, the sympathy*selfism variable is also a

significant factor in predicting the tillage decision. Also, the magnitude of the

coefficient associated with the sympathy*selfism variable is larger than the

coefficient associated with an individual‟s income level. Finally, we again see

that the chi-square (block) statistic indicates that the addition of the

sympathy*selfism variable improves overall model fit, and the Nagelkerke R-

Square statistic increases from 0.10 to 0.12.

Finally, Table 22 presents the metaeconomic derived demand model when

the empathy/others variables are used as proxies for an individual‟s shared other-

interest tendency. Yet again, we find that this model tells much the same story as

the models presented in Tables 20 and 21. Again, income is a significant variable

in the tillage decision, but the farm entity*selfism coefficient is also significant

and greater in magnitude than the income coefficient. Somewhat surprisingly,

though, this model shows that both other lake users and family members do not

appear to impact the conservation tillage decision in farmers residing above Tuttle

Creek Lake. Despite these surprising results, the metaeconomic model presented

in Table 22 still yields a better fitting model than the standard production

economics derived demand model. This is evidenced by the significant chi-

Page 92: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

85

81

square (block) statistic and an increase in the Nagelkerke R-square statistic from

0.10 to 0.185.

The results presented in Tables 20, 21, and 22 show that the

metaeconomic derived demand model yields a better description of what

motivates tillage behavior in the watershed than the microeconomics model.

However, it is theorized that the basic metaeconomic model can be further refined

and improved by adding variables that account for individual habitual tendencies

and preferences for control. The columns labeled “Adding Habitual Tendency”

and “Adding Selfism Reinforced Control” provide the results when proxies for

these two phenomena are added to the metaeconomic model.

Inspection of Tables 20, 21, and 22 show that adding individual habitual

tendencies does in fact improve the basic metaeconomic derived demand model,

regardless of which shared other-interest proxy is used. In all three cases, the

habit variable coefficients are significant, large in magnitude, and in the

hypothesized positive direction. In addition to this, the income and shared other-

interest variables all remain significant in all three models. The addition of a

habit variable also substantially improves the model fit of the metaeconomic

derived demand model. All three chi-square (block) statistics are significant, and

in all three instances we find considerable increases in the Nagelkerke R-square

statistics. This suggests that subconscious feelings about tillage decisions made in

the past play a great part in tillage decisions that are made today or in the future.

Page 93: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

86

81

Finally, we also find that the preference for control variables presented in

the columns labeled “Adding Selfism Reinforced Control” also help to refine and

improve the basic metaeconomic derived demand model. Regardless of the

shared other-interest proxy used, the selfism*farm control variable becomes a

significant predictor when attempting to understand tillage behavior. The variable

is also in the hypothesized negative direction. Again, as when adding the habit

variable, the addition of the selfism reinforced control variables contributes

significantly to the overall model fit, as evidenced by the significant chi-square

(block) statistic in all three cases. The Nagelkerke R-square statistics also

increase with the addition of the control variables to the metaeconomic model. It

should be noted, though, that only the selfism*farm control variable is significant

in the model. This indicates that an individual‟s preferences for control over

nature and attitudes toward control exerted on their farms by others are not

important in the tillage adoption decision.

In sum, the results presented in Tables 20, 21, and 22 indicate that the

refined metaeconomic model that includes habitual tendencies and preferences for

control is vastly superior at predicting tillage behavior in the Blue River/Tuttle

Creek Lake watershed than the standard microeconomics model. This

metaeconomic model gives the largest Nagelkerke R-square statistics, best overall

model fit, and yields the greatest percentage of correct 0,1 dependent variable

predictions. Thus, it appears that new economic models that account for the

Page 94: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

87

81

psychological dispositions described here should be created in order to truly

understand the conservation adoption decision made by farmers.

5.4. Results of Heckman Test of Conservation Tillage Intensity

While the results above give a fairly clear depiction of the several different

factors that can motivate farmers in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek watershed to

adopt conservation tillage strategies, it is also important to attempt to understand

what factors influence the conservation tillage intensity decision made by farmers

in the watershed. Given that the refined metaeconomic derived demand model

did the best job in predicting the adoption decision made by farmers, these same

variables were used in constructing Heckman models from the data obtained from

the region. The results of the three models, which were constructed with the

software program Shazam, are presented below.

Page 95: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

88

Table 22: Probit Estimation of Individual No-Till Adoption Decision (Empathy Other-Interest Proxy)

Variable Coefficient Standard Error T-Stat

Constant -0.461 0.494 -0.933

Income 0.00163 0.000550 2.96a

Slope -0.0150 0.121 -0.125

Empathy*Selfism 0.0501 0.0133 3.76a

Habit 0.217 0.365 5.95a

Selfism*Farm Control -0.0471 0.0152 -3.10a

Selfism*Other Control 0.00361 0.0161 0.225

Selfism*Nature Control 0.00130 0.00931 0.140

Log Likelihood -236.80 - -

Cragg-Uhler R2 .29 - -

% Right Predictions 0.84

a p<.01,

b p<.02,

c p<.05,

d p<.10

N = 498

Page 96: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

89

Table 23: Semi-Log Estimation of Individual No-Till Intensity (Empathy Other-Interest Proxy)

Variable Coefficient Standard Error T-Stat

Constant -0.234 0.177 -1.32

Income 0.000225 0.000127 1.77d

Slope -0.0409 0.0404 -1.01

Empathy*Selfism 0.00182 0.00421 0.431

Habit -0.00616 0.0134 -0.462

Selfism*Farm Control -0.0156 0.00534 -2.92a

Selfism*Other Control 0.0100 0.00496 2.02c

Selfism*Nature Control 0.00400 0.00308 1.30

Adjusted R2 .03 - -

a p<.01,

b p<.02,

c p<.05,

d p<.10

N = 407

IMR = 0.070

Page 97: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

90

Table 24: Probit Estimation of Individual No-Till Adoption Decision (Sympathy Other-Interest Proxy)

Variable Coefficient Standard Error T-Stat

Constant -0.308 0.488 -0.630

Income 0.00160 0.000543 2.95a

Slope -0.0338 0.119 -0.283

Sympathy*Selfism 0.0259 0.0111 2.34b

Habit 0.225 0.0364 6.16a

Selfism*Farm Control -0.0438 0.0150 -2.92a

Selfism*Other Control 0.0159 0.0155 1.03

Selfism*Nature Control 0.00929 0.00870 1.07

Log Likelihood -236.80 - -

Cragg-Uhler R2 .26 - -

% Right Predictions 0.83

a p<.01,

b p<.02,

c p<.05,

d p<.10

N = 498

Page 98: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

91

Table 25: Semi-Log Estimation of Individual No-Till Intensity (Sympathy Other-Interest Proxy)

Variable Coefficient Standard Error T-Stat

Constant -0.201 0.175 -1.15

Income 0.000218 0.000127 1.72d

Slope -0.0437 0.0403 -1.08

Sympathy*Selfism -0.00119 0.00366 -0.326

Habit -0.00561 0.0133 -0.421

Selfism*Farm Control -0.0151 0.00531 -2.85a

Selfism*Other Control 0.0116 0.00493 2.34a

Selfism*Nature Control 0.00440 0.00302 1.46

Adjusted R2 .03

a p<.01,

b p<.02,

c p<.05,

d p<.10

N = 407

IMR = 0.382

Page 99: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

92

Table 26: Probit Estimation of Individual No-Till Adoption Decision (Empathy/Others Other-Interest Proxy)

Variable Coefficient Standard Error T-Stat

Constant -0.609 0.505 -1.21

Income 0.00175 0.000574 3.05a

Slope -0.0199 0.123 -0.162

Water User*Selfism 0.00678 0.0118 0.573

Farm Entities*Selfism 0.0542 0.0169 3.21a

Family*Selfism -0.00610 0.00993 -0.615

Habit 0.211 0.0367 5.76a

Selfism*Farm Control -0.0468 0.0152 -3.09a

Selfism*Other Control 0.00840 0.0155 0.543

Selfism*Nature Control 0.00603 0.00910 0.661

Log Likelihood -236.80 - -

Cragg-Uhler R2 .31 - -

% Right Predictions 0.83

a p<.01,

b p<.02,

c p<.05,

d p<.10

N = 498

Page 100: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

93

Table 27: Semi-Log Estimation of Individual No-Till Intensity (Empathy/Others Other-Interest Proxy)

Variable Coefficient Standard Error T-Stat

Constant -0.251 0.178 -1.41

Income 0.000229 0.000127 1.80d

Slope -0.0353 0.0406 -0.869

Water User*Selfism 0.00325 0.00384 0.847

Farm Entities*Selfism 0.00136 0.00559 0.243

Family*Selfism -0.00352 0.00340 -1.04

Habit -0.00752 0.0134 -0.560

Selfism*Farm Control -0.0158 0.00534 -2.96a

Selfism*Other Control 0.0107 0.00473 2.27c

Selfism*Nature Control 0.00458 0.00307 1.49

Adjusted R2 .03 - -

a p<.01,

b p<.02,

c p<.05,

d p<.10

N = 407

IMR = 0.211

Page 101: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

94

93

Notice that the Heckman model is a two stage process. First, a probit estimation

of the (0,1) adoption decision must be constructed. Then, using the information obtained

in the probit analysis, a statistic called the Inverse Mills Ratio is computed and used as a

variable in the second step standard OLS estimation. In the OLS estimation, all

observations with a “0” on the dependent variable are removed, such that the estimate is

applied only to those that use conservation tillage in varying intensities. The inverse

mills ratio, then, is meant to correct for the resulting bias in the estimation due to the

elimination of all data associated with those respondents that do not use conservation

tillage technologies.

The probit estimation is similar in nature to the logit model. In fact, the only real

difference is that the probit estimation assumes a normally distributed error term, whereas

a logit model assumes that the error term is distributed in a logistical manner. Given the

similarities in the modeling techniques, it would be expected that the results from the

probit estimations used in the Heckman technique above should be quite similar to the

results produced by the logit model estimation described earlier. Inspection of Tables 23,

25, and 27 show this to be exactly the case. In fact, the probit estimation conducted as a

part of the overall Heckman technique tells the exact same story as the logit models

presented earlier. This is to say, the probit estimation, regardless of which shared other-

interest proxy is used, indicates that the shared other-interest*selfism variable, the habit

variable, the selfism*farm control variable, and the income variable are all significant

predictors in the conservation tillage adoption decision. So, given the similarities in the

results between the probit and logit estimations, we assert with relative confidence that

Page 102: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

95

93

metaeconomic theory provides a robust and consistent derived demand model that helps

to explain the tillage adoption decision exhibited by farmers in the four county target area

above Tuttle Creek Lake.

While the metaeconomic variables described above tell a consistent story

regarding the conservation tillage adoption decision, the conservation tillage intensity

decision appears to be influenced by different factors. Inspection of Tables 24, 26, and

28 shows that the only variables that are consistently significant in predicting the tillage

intensity decision are selfism*farm control and selfism*other control. Notice that the

income variable, too, is significant in all models. However, it is only significant at the

p<0.10 level, a cutoff value that is determined to be too high for determining significance

levels in behavioral economics research.

One should take note that the coefficient associated with the selfism*farm control

is negative, while the coefficient associated with the selfism*other control variable is

positive. This result, though, is not entirely unexpected. Farm control is measured as the

degree to which the respondent perceives having autonomous control over his or her

farming processes while using conservation tillage strategies. This variable was coded

for statistical analysis in such a way that larger numbers indicated less perceived

autonomous control over farming processes while using conservation tillage strategies.

So, a one unit increase in this proxy should impact conservation tillage intensity in a

negative manner. Thus, the negative coefficient on the final selfism*farm control

variable makes sense in this context.

Page 103: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

96

93

The positive coefficient on the selfism*other control also makes a great deal of

sense. This result is due to how the other control variable was coded for statistical

analysis purposes. The variable was coded in such a way that larger numbers indicate

that others have no heteronomous control over the conservation tillage intensity decision.

If the respondent perceives that others cannot exert heteronomous control over the

conservation tillage intensity decision, it can be reasonably inferred that the respondent

must feel that he or she maintains autonomous control over the situation. Thus, we

would expect that a one unit increase in this variable would yield a positive result upon

the intensity of conservation tillage used on an individual farm.

While the direction of the selfism*farm control and selfism*other control can be

reasonably explained, one must also take the results in Tables 24, 26, and 28 with a grain

of salt. First, the selfism*other control variable is not a significant variable when

sympathy is used as a shared other-interest proxy. Also, the model fits for the standard

OLS portions of the Heckman models presented above are poor, with R-squared values of

no greater than 0.03 units. Therefore, it appears that follow-up work should be conducted

in the watershed in order to better determine what motivates the conservation tillage

intensity decision.

Page 104: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

97

93

Figure 5.1. Distribution of mean empathy scale responses

Figure 5.2. Distribution of mean sympathy scale responses

1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 7.00

empathy

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

Co

un

t

1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 7.00

sympathy

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

Co

un

t

Page 105: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

98

93

CONCLUSIONS, IMPLICATIONS, AND RECOMMENDATIONS

The overall goal of this research was to more fully understand farmer

conservation behavior, and in the process, perhaps discover some information that could

prove to be useful in solving the pollution problems in the Blue River and Tuttle Creek

Lake. It was also thought that results from this research could be used to help improve

conservation policies administered throughout the United States.

This study was very unique in nature. This research could be classified as an

economic study, and includes all the elements one would expect to find in an empirical

study using derived demand theory as presented in microeconomic-based production

economics. However, the research conducted also sought to go beyond and transcend

(the notion of “meta”) the traditional economic framework, and thus metaeconomic

theory (which includes elements from psychology, sociology, and other social sciences)

was also used to test the motivations for farmer conservation behavior.

Given the exceptional set of circumstances used in this study, the results produced

from the research are also very unique in nature. For instance, the results indicate that a

farmer‟s income/financial capacity is an important factor in the conservation tillage

adoption decision faced by farmers in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake watershed. This

result makes intuitive sense, as most conservation practices are not inherently profitable

and there is some level of cost associated with purchasing new tractors, planters, and

other equipment that must be used in order to farm using conservation tillage strategies.

What makes the result truly remarkable, though, is that increases in income/financial

Page 106: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

99

93

capacity, in an absolute sense, actually have a very small (albeit significant) impact upon

the conservation tillage decision. In fact, our results showed that a one thousand dollar

increase in a farmer‟s income increases the odds of conservation tillage adoption by less

than one percent. This result is completely counter to the idea that substantial increases

in income are needed in order to induce farmers to engage in conservation tillage

activities.

In addition to our findings concerning the role of income in farmer tillage

behavior, other psychological variables included in this research make the results

distinctive and somewhat ground breaking. Most prominent in our research is the fact

that both self-interest tendencies and shared other-interest tendencies play a role in the

conservation tillage adoption decision made by farmers in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek

Lake watershed. This research first showed that proxies used to measure self-interest and

shared other-interest tendencies are significantly and negatively correlated. This lends

credence to the idea that ego and empathy are joint, non-separable, and in constant

conflict as proposed by metaeconomic theory. Thus, it also appears likely that individual

decisions cannot be made without considering both self-interest and shared-other interest

tendencies together. In metaeconomic terms, then, it appears as though a decision maker

must consider both conflicting tendencies and integrate them into one decision or

behavior on path 0Z.

Logit models created with survey data collected in the region also show the

importance of the self-interest and shared other-interest interaction. In all models, the

shared other-interest*self-interest variable proved to be significant when attempting to

Page 107: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

100

93

predict conservation adoption in the watershed. Since the selfism scale was ultimately

reversed when creating this interaction variable, the result is really a measure of how a

person is oriented towards the shared other-interest in farming. The results ultimately

show, then, that those farmers who are less selfish in nature are likely currently using

conservation tillage practices and are much more likely to continue using the technology

in the future.

In addition to the results concerning the shared other-interest*self-interest

interaction, the survey data compiled and models created also indicated that a farmer‟s

preferences regarding autonomous and heteronomous control are also very important

factors in the conservation tillage adoption decision. The logit and Heckman models

created considered three different exploratory control variables: control over farm

processes, control exerted by others, and preferences for control over nature. The results

of the logit models consistently show that farm control is a significant variable. This

result shows that if a person believes that they can use conservation tillage techniques and

still keep complete autonomous control over their farm, they will be more likely to use

conservation techniques. However, if a farmer perceives a loss of control over their farm

by using conservation tillage, the odds of conservation tillage adoption significantly

deteriorate. In addition to the results from the logit models, the Heckman models

produced show that both farm control and other control impact the conservation tillage

intensity decision. So, contrary to predictions and theory offered in microeconomics, it

appears that these psychological context variables really do play an important role in

individual decision making. It should be noted, though, that preferences for control over

Page 108: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

101

93

nature was not deemed to be major factor in the conservation tillage adoption or intensity

decision.

Finally, this research also concluded that a farmer‟s habitual tendencies play a

major role in the tillage adoption decision. In fact, in terms of coefficient magnitude, the

habit variable proved to have the greatest impact upon the conservation adoption

decision. This is to say, a one unit increase in the habit proxy yields nearly a forty

percent increase in the odds of conservation tillage adoption. So, it appears that those

that have used conservation tillage strategies in the past are much more likely to continue

using it in the future. However, it must be cautioned that the opposite situation may also

apply. This is to say, if a farmer has not been convinced of the benefits of using

conservation tillage techniques and continues to use intensive tillage technologies, he or

she is more likely to rely on subconscious feelings and intuition and continue to use

intensive tillage practices. In terms of policy, then, it seems imperative to use a mix of

education and financial incentives in order to help convince intensive tillage farmers of

the benefits of conservation tillage technologies. Once these intensive tillage users have

converted to conservation tillage techniques, they will then be much more likely to

continue using the technology.

The results from this study indicate that a single over-arching conservation policy

administered on a volunteer basis is not likely to be successful in reducing agricultural

non-point pollution. This conclusion can be drawn because our survey results show that

farmers are very heterogeneous in their psychological and economic motivations. This is

Page 109: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

102

93

starkly different than the homogenous Homo economicus assumed in standard economic

theory.

The results show that farmers vary in the degree to which they are influenced by

both self-interest and other-interest tendencies. Those that are more self-interested in

nature are most likely influenced by profit considerations. Therefore, financial incentive

programs may help encourage these farmers to engage in conservation practices.

However, by only targeting these self-interested individuals through the use of financial

instruments, a large subset of the farming population that is largely influenced by a

psychological orientation toward the shared other-interest are most likely not going to

participate in the incentive programs. These other-interested individuals are most likely

to participate in programs that emphasize the communal side of farming in a way that can

help them identify with others. In other words, they enjoy a connection with others that

comes from being identified as a “conservation farmer,” and being in unity with other

such producers.

While there are some in the farming community that are motivated to engage in

conservation activities by the extremes of either self-interest or shared other-interest, our

results show that most individual farmers will be motivated by a complex mix of self-

interest and other-interest on the metaeconomic satisficing path 0Z. So, it appears that

the best conservation policies are those that can emphasize both self- and other-interest.

While financial incentives may help those who are beginning to use conservation

tillage measures, it is unlikely that increases in income alone are enough to sustain usage

of the technology over long periods of time. Therefore, education programs will continue

Page 110: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

103

93

to play a role in helping farmers move toward using conservation technologies.

Education programs can especially stimulate a farmer‟s self-interest tendencies.

Extension educators can show that conservation tillage may result in using less fuel,

helping soil retain moisture, and in producing higher yields. So, while a focus on the

financial side remains important, the results of this study also point to the need to help

farmers see the possibility of using conservation measures for their own sake and lead to

more sustainable use of the techniques. In this case, we also find that educational

programs can stimulate a farmer‟s shared other-interest tendencies, showing that

conservation tillage technologies help conserve soil quantity and quality, protect

farmland for future generations, and prevent soil and chemical runoff to nearby rivers and

streams. So, educational programs can help to show farmers that conservation

technologies are good for both self-interest and other-interest tendencies. Extension

educators could design programs specifically focused on building and enhancing a

community ethic within the farming population to become a “conservation farmer” and

help establish a unity with the cause (sympathy) of using tillage strategies that improve

water quality. As more small groups of farmers…even including the morning coffee

event at the local diner…become engaged in the process, we can reasonably expect that

this sympathy can also be built through word of mouth, and through the networks of

farmers connecting with other small groups throughout the community. In fact, this

shared ethic needs to spread to others beyond the farmers themselves, to include

equipment, fertilizer, herbicide and see dealers; the landlords, and others considered

earlier herein in the list of those who may influence and be influenced by farmers. As the

Page 111: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

104

93

unity with the cause of a less polluted lake evolves and spreads, can reasonably expect

that a synergistic path 0Z will emerge and the use of conservation tillage technologies

will be much more consistently applied.

While this research has implications for farm level conservation policy and local

implementation of programs and practices, it also has implications for the water quality

conflict that is beginning to emerge between upstream farmers and downstream water

users in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek watershed. The disagreement in the watershed, while

not highly publicized at this point in time, is a real phenomenon that can not be ignored,

especially when one considers that any type of resolution regarding water quality in the Blue

River and Tuttle Creek Lake will have an impact on both upstream and downstream

stakeholders. However, if we begin to work toward a solution to the dispute now, it is

possible that the conflict can be resolved without mandates and regulation from State and/or

Federal governments. The key to this type of agreement would be through an expression of

empathy-sympathy on the part of the both upstream producers (and other upstream residents)

and downstream water users/residents.

We look especially to the notion of sufficient reason for a new vision and change as

framed in Bromley (2006) for guidance in this situation. In turn, in order to understand the

notion of sufficient reason in the context of the metaeconomic behavior found in the

farming population, we must first step back and think about the underlying philosophical

basis for institutional and behavioral change, and policy change more generally, and for

economic theorizing about said change. Bromley (2006) argues real change is rooted in

pragmatism, and a kind of volitional pragmatism in particular, not in utilitarianism.

Pragmatism is also in the foundation of metaeconomics. This means that life is really

Page 112: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

105

93

about “incessant doing” and that policy change is an inherent part of this “doing,” and we

do the best we can (Bromley, 2006, p. 137). It also means that as members of a

democratic society and market economy, we are able to be freely practical in our choices,

going beyond mere calculations of optimums. Thinking back to the metaecconomic

figure presented in Chapter 3, we can see that this situation is easily depicted: individuals

do not generally respond only to the price ratio and self-interest maximization at point A,

but rather temper their interests in satisficing, as represented in the kinds of real choices

illustrated at point B; point B cannot be “calculated” as can point A. Indeed, we do not

even seek the maximums at point A or C, but rather do our best at point B.

Bromley (2006, pp. 51-62) clarifies that institutions are composed of three

entities: norms and traditions, working rules, and private property relations, with private

property relations being especially important in policy construction and change. All

condition and temper behavior, in that individuals are embedded in, through internalizing,

these institutions, which are represented in the various metaeconomic paths 0M. As

policy evolves, private property regimes are modified, as some individuals receive new

duties (restraints), while others receive new rights (liberation) and expansion of

individual action (Bromley, 2006, p. 23). In effect, some are given the opportunity to act

on their newly awarded path OG; others are required to move away from it. Ultimately,

then, it is changes to these institutions that bring about overall change in policy, and

behavioral change on a new path 0Z.

In thinking about how the metaeconomics and sufficient reason frames merge, we

find that modifications to institutions occur through expressions of empathy and

Page 113: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

106

93

sympathy. This is to say, those engaged in conflict can be freely practical in decision

making by empathizing and negotiating with each other. If all affected parties are willing

to walk in the shoes of the others, we will generally see the emergence of ever more

sympathy with the common cause, in this case a less polluted lake, with changes in

institutions and policy that bring about peaceful conflict resolution. More specifically, in

the case of stakeholders in the Blue River/Tuttle Creek Lake watershed, then, if we find

ample amounts of empathy/sympathy in the region, we would expect that a peaceful

resolution to the water quality conflict is possible.

As shown previously, survey results from farmers in the region above Tuttle

Creek Lake showed that empathy and sympathy are both present in the region. The

relatively high mean scores of both the empathy and sympathy measures show that

farmers upstream of Tuttle Creek Lake have the capacity to walk in the shoes of

downstream Lake users and engage in the policy process such that the irritation caused by

the water quality and quantity conflict may subside. Therefore, a memorandum of

agreement concerning water quality in the region indeed seems possible between the two

impacted parties.

In order for the water quality conflict to truly subside, though, downstream water

users must also be willing to engage in the act of empathizing with upstream farmers in

order to understand the difficulties faced by those farmers in preventing erosion and

chemical runoff. Also, this expression of empathy would, as in the case of the farmers,

also have to result in sympathy for the shared cause of a less polluted lake.Unfortunately,

we do not at this time have data concerning public water suppliers and residents

Page 114: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

107

93

downstream of Tuttle Creek Lake. Therefore, more research needs to be conducted

concerning the role that empathetic and sympathetic tendencies of both downstream and

upstream water users might have on shaping future policy decisions in the watershed.

Ultimately, though, such knowledge and this approach could have a substantive impact

on the policy process and the potential resolution of the water quality conflict in the Blue

River/Tuttle Creek Lake watershed.

While substative conclusions can be drawn from this research, there are certain

limitations. The first issue that may need to be addressed concerns model form. Proxies

for self-interest, other-interest, and preferences for control were all used to create specific

interaction terms in both the logit and Heckman models. However, no linear effects for

the interactions were created in the model. This approach can be defended based upon

the theorectical representation of the brain. However, this form should continue to be

evaluated. It seems that the use of Structural Equation Modeling (SEM) could prove to

be useful to confirm the relationships between self- and other-interest, and self-interest

and preferences for control. This work, though, has been left for another study.

Importantly, this study is another in a series of tests of metaeconomic theory, with

similar results. Metaeconmic tests began in the late 1980‟s, and continue to this day.

Intriguingly, these studies continue to find evidence of a substantive role for both the

shared other-interest and control in an individual‟s decision making process. However,

this testing needs to be expanded further in order to validate the generalizability of the

model.

Page 115: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

108

93

While there are indeed drawbacks to the metaeconomic research conducted in the

Blue River/Tuttle Creek watershed, the fact remains that the results produced have

provided some intriguing insights into potential motivators for farmers to utilize

conservation tillage strategies in the region. It is our hope, then, that these results and

future research can help to improve conservation policy in the United States. Hopefully,

too, the improved policies can lead to the restoration of rivers, streams, and lakes to a

more natural and clean state, and conflicts regarding water quality can be resolved.

Page 116: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

109

93

References

Ajzen, I. “The Theory of Planned Behavior.” Organizational Behavior and Human

Decision Processes 50 (1991): 179-211.

Angyal, A. Foundations for a Science of Personality. Cambridge, MA: The

Commonwealth Fund by Harvard University Press, 1967.

Artikov, I., S.J. Hoffman, G.D. Lynne, L.M. Pytlik-Zillig, Qi Hu, A.J. Tomkins, K.G.

Hubbard, M.J. Hayes, and W. Waltman. “Understanding the Influence of

Climate Forecasts on Farmer Decisions as Planned Behavior.” Journal of

Applied Meteorology and Climatology 45 (2006): 1202-1214.

Barnes, P. Kansas State University, interview by Robert Sheeder (2006).

Bromley, D.W. Sufficient Reason: Volitional Pragmatism and the Meaning of Economic

Institutions. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2006.

Cain, Z., and S. Lovejoy. “History and Outlook for Farm Bill Conservation Programs.”

Choices (2004): 37-42.

Cary, J.W., and R.L. Wilkinson. “Perceived Profitability and Farmers‟ Conservation

Behaviour.” Journal of Agricultural Economics 48, 1 (1997): 13-21.

Casey, F. and G. D. Lynne. “Adoption of Water Conserving Technologies in Agriculture:

The Role of Expected Profits and the Public Interest.” In F. Casey, A. Schmitz,

S. Swinton and D. Zilberman (Editors). Flexible Incentives for the Adoption of

Environmental Technologies in Agriculture. Norwell, MA: Kluwer Academic

Publishers, 1999, 229-247.

Page 117: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

110

93

Chouinard, H.H., T. Paterson, P.R. Wandschneider, and A.M. Ohler. “Will Farmers

Trade Profits for Stewardship? Heterogeneous Motivations for Farm Practice

Selection.” Land Economics, 84,1 (2008): 66-82.

Cooper, J.C. “Combining Actual and Contingent Behavior Data to Model Farmer

Adoption of Water Quality Protection Practices.” Journal of Agricultural and

Resource Economics 78 (1997): 30-43.

-------- and Keim, R.W. “Incentive Payments to Encourage Farmer Adoption of Water

Quality Protection Practices.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78

(1996): 54-64.

Cory Jr., G.A. “A Behavioral Model of the Dual Motive Approach to Behavioral

Economics and Social Exchange.” Journal of Socio-Economics, 35 (2006a): 592-

612.

--------. “Physiology and Behavioral Economics.” Chp 2 In Handbook of Contemporary

Behavioral Economics: Foundations and Developments, edited by M. Altman, pp.

24-49. Armonk, New York: M.E. Sharpe, 2006b.

--------. The Consilient Brain: The Bioneurological Basis of Economics, Society, and

Politics. New York: Kluwer Academic/Plenum Publishers, 2004.

Cutforth, L.B., C.A. Francis, G.D. Lynne, D.A. Mortensen, and K.M. Eskridge. “Factors

Affecting Farmers' Diversity Approach.” Amer. J. Altern. Agri. 16, 4 (2001):

168-176.

Davis, M.H. “A Multidimensional Approach to Individual Differences in Empathy.”

JSAS Catalog of Selected Documents in Psychology 10, 4 (1980): 85-102.

Page 118: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

111

93

Decety, J., K.J. Michalska, and Y. Akitsuki. “Who Caused the Pain? An fMRI

Investigation of Empathy and Intentionality in Children.” Neuropsychologia 46,

11 (2008): 2607-2614.

Economic Research Service. “ERS/USDA Briefing Room-Conservation Policy:

Background.”

http://www.ers.usda.gov/Briefing/ConservationPolicy/background.htm

(accessed January 30, 2008).

Ervin, C.A. and D.E. Ervin. “Factors Affecting the Use of Soil Conservation Practices:

Hypotheses, Evidence, and Policy Implications.” Land Economics 58, 3 (1982):

277-292.

Etzioni, A. “The Case for a Multiple-Utility Conception.” Economics and Philosophy, 2,

2 (1986): 159-183.

Frisch, R. Theory of Production. Chicago: Rand McNally and Company, 1965.

Gould, B.W., W.E. Saupe, and R.M. Klemme. “Conservation Tillage: The Role of Farm

and Operator Characteristics and the Perception of Soil Erosion.” Land

Economics, 65, 2, (1989): 167-182.

Heckman, J.J. “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error.” Econometrica 47, 1

(1979): 153-161.

Kruse, C.E. “Explaining Farmer Behavior in Relation to Sequestering Carbon on

Nebraska Farms.” Master‟s thesis, University of Nebraska-Lincoln, 2003.

Kahneman, D., P.P. Waker, and R. Sarin. “Back to Bentham? Explorations of

Experienced Utility.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, May (1997): 375-405.

Page 119: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

112

93

--------. “Maps of Bounded Rationality: Psychology for Behavioral Economics.”

American Economic Review, 93 (2003): 1449-1475.

Kalinowski, C.M., G.D. Lynne, and B. Johnson. “Recycling as a Reflection of Balanced

Self-Interest: A Test of the Metaeconomics Approach.” Environment and

Behavior, 38, 3 (2006): 333-355.

Lakoff, G. Moral Politics: What Conservatives Know that Liberals Don’t. Chicago: The

University of Chicago Press, 1996.

Lichtenberg, E. “Cost-Responsiveness of Conservation Practice Adoption: A Revealed

Preference Approach.” Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 29, 3

(2004): 420-435.

Lohr, L. and T.A. Park. “Utility-Consistent Discrete-Continuous Choices in Soil

Conservation.” Land Economics 71, 4 (1995): 474-490.

Link, M. 2005 Nebraska Surface Water Quality Monitoring Report. Lincoln, NE:

Nebraska Department of Environmental Quality, 2005.

Lynne, G.D. “Allocatable Fixed Inputs and Jointness in Agricultural Production:

Implications for Economic Modeling: Comment.” American Journal of

Agricultural Economics, 70, 4 (1988): 948-949.

Lynne, G.D. “Modifying the Neo-Classical Approach to Technology Adoption With

Behavioral Science Models.” J. Agr. Applied Econ. 27,1 (July, 1995): 67-80.

--------. “Divided Self Models of the Socioeconomic Person: The Metaeconomics

Approach.” Journal of Socio-Economics, 28 (1999): 267-288.

Page 120: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

113

93

--------.“On the Economics of Subselves: Toward a Metaeconomics.” Chp. 6 In

Handbook of Contemporary Behavioral Economics: Foundations and

Developments, edited by M. Altman, pp. 99-122. Armonk, New York: M.E.

Sharpe, 2006a.

--------. “Toward a Dual Motive Metaeconomic Theory.” Journal of Socioeconomics 35

(2006b): 634-651.

-------- and C. F. Casey. “Regulation of Technology Adoption When Individuals Pursue

Multiple Utility.” Journal of Socioeconomics 27, 6 (1998): 701-719.

MacLean, P. The Triune Brain in Evolution: Role in Paleocerebral Functions. New

York: Plenum, 1990.

Mayberry, D., L. Crase, and C. Gullifer. “Categorising Farming Values as Economic,

Conservation, and Lifestyle.” Journal of Economic Psychology 26 (2005): 59-72.

McCown, R. “New Thinking About Farmer Decision Makers.” In The Farmer’s

Decision: Balancing Economic Agriculture Production with Environmental

Quality, ed. J.L. Hatfield, 11-44. Ankeny, IA: Soil and Water Conservation

Society.

National Agricultural Statistics Service. 2002 Census of Agriculture, Volume 1, Chapter

2: Kansas County Level Data.

http://www.nass.usda.gov/census/census02/volume1/ks/st20_2_008_008.pdf

(accessed October 13, 2008).

Page 121: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

114

93

National Agricultural Statistics Service. 2002 Census of Agriculture, Volume 1, Chapter

2: Nebraska County Level Data.

http://www.nass.usda.gov/census/census02/volume1/ne/st31_2_008_008.pdf

(accessed October 13, 2008).

Nowack, P. and P. Korsching. “The Human Dimension of Soil and Water Conservation:

A Historical and Methodological Perspective.” In Advances in Soil and Water

Conservation, eds. F. Peirce and W. Frye. Chelsea, MI: Ann Arbor Press.

O‟Brien, P. “Water Quality of the Big Blue River Basin: A Brief Comparison of Local

and State Surface Water Quality.” Nebraska Department of Environmental

Quality, 2008. http://www.deq.state.ne.us/ (accessed May 21, 2008).

Phares, E.J. and N. Erskine. “The Measurement of Selfism.” Educational and

Psychological Measurement, 44 (1984): 597-608.

Sautter, J.A., N. Ovchinnikova, C. Kruse, and G.D. Lynne. “Farmers‟ Decisions

Regarding Carbon Sequestration: A Metaeconomic View.” University of

Nebraska-Lincoln Working Paper (in review with Society and Natural

Resources), 2008.

Schutz, A., and T. Luckman. The Structures of the Life-World, Vol.1. Trans. R.M. Zaner

and H. Engelhardt. Evanston, Il: Northwestern University Press, 1973.

Sen, A.K. On Ethics and Economics. New York: Basil Blackwell, 1987.

--------. “Rational Fools: A Critique of the Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory.”

Philosophy and Public Affairs, 6 (1977): 317-344.

Page 122: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

115

93

Shea, P.J., M. Burbach, G.D. Lynne, A. Martin, and M. Milner. “USDA National

Integrated Water Quality Project Grant Proposal.” 2006.

Sheeder, R. and G.D. Lynne. “Offsetting the Oil Addiction: Farmers Motivated to

Sequester Carbon.” Cornhusker Economics, August 22, 2007.

Smith, A. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Ed. E.

Cannan. New York: Modern Library, 1937.

--------. The Theory of Moral Sentiments (6 ed.). Eds. D.D. Raphael and A.L. Macife.

Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Classics, 1982. Originally Published in 1759.

Solomon, R.C. True to Our Feelings: What Emotions are Really Telling Us. Oxford, New

York: Oxford University Press, 2007.

Stafford, M. “Water Plentiful in Northeast Kansas, But Delivery at Times is Difficult to

Manage.” The Topeka Capital-Journal, Online Edition. November 2, 2003.

http://www.cjonline.com/stories/110203/kan_waternek.shtml (accessed May 21,

2008).

Supalla, R.J. “Institutional Arrangements to Improve Water Quality in Irrigated

Agriculture.” Water Resources Development 19, 1 (2003): 89-99.

Wallace, B. and F. Clearfield. Stewardship, Spirituality, and Natural Resources

Conservation: A Short History. USDA-NRCS, Social Sciences Institute, ID#

T015, 1997.

Wilson, D.R. “The Evolutionary Neuroscience of Human Reciprocal Sociality: A Basic

Outline for Economists.” Journal of Socio-Economics, 35, 4 (2006): 626-633.

Page 123: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

116

93

Wu, J., R.M. Adams, C.L. Kling, and Tanaka, K. “From Microlevel Decisions to

Landscape Changes: An Assessment of Agricultural Conservation Policies.”

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 86, 1 (2004): 26-41.

Page 124: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

117

93

Appendix A

Soil and Chemical Management Survey of Kansas and Nebraska Farmers

Page 125: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

118

93

Page 126: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

119

93

Page 127: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

120

93

Page 128: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

121

93

Page 129: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

122

93

Page 130: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

123

93

Page 131: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

124

93

Page 132: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

125

93

Page 133: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

126

93

Page 134: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

127

93

Page 135: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

128

93

Page 136: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

129

93

Page 137: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

130

93

Page 138: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

131

93

Page 139: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

132

93

Page 140: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

133

93

Page 141: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

134

93

Page 142: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

135

93

Page 143: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

136

93

Page 144: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

137

93

Page 145: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

138

93

Page 146: Understanding Farmer Conservation Behavior: A Behavioral

139

93