Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    1/21

    THREE YEARS OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION IN INDONESIA :

    ITS IMPACTS ON REGIONAL ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT AND

    FISCAL SUSTAINABILITY

    Bambang Brodjonegoro (Department of Economics, University of Indonesia)

    INTRODUCTION

    Toward the second general election in the reformasi(reformation) era in 2004, the issueof decentralization and regional autonomy has not been widely considered as critical

    issue in nation building, and hence as one of major platform of political parties. There

    could be many reasons for this circumstance. First, the process might have beenconsidered as quite successful. At least, there was no real chaos occurring as a result of

    the decentralization process. Second, regardless of the effects of the process itself,

    Indonesians have adjusted well to the new condition and therefore, everything related to

    decentralization becomes routine activities. Third, the political parties could be more

    attracted to other issues such as corruption, law enforcement, economic recovery process,than the decentralization issues that might not be visible to many Indonesians. Fourth

    and the most dangerous one, there might be a tendency at central government andpolitical elites to either slow down the decentralization process, or more extreme, go back

    to centralization system in the past. There might be many reasons to explain the lower

    tone of decentralization process but the fact is that only few parties are interested to raisethe decentralization issues as one of their campaign theme.

    After three years of the decentralization process itself, it is still difficult to judge if theprocess is a successful one or not. The international community deemed the process as

    still on the right track citing that the Indonesians was able to manage the massive anddrastic decentralization, and minimize the negative effects. The central government feels

    that they have managed the drastic change quite well but at the same time admits that

    they are still worried about the future and many have to be done in order to direct the

    decentralization on the right path including the revision of law 22/1999 and 25/1999.The local governments, however, are less satisfied than the central one. They are still

    suspicious that the central government is not fully supporting the process, and when the

    process is considered as a failure in the future, there will be a recentralization process.On the other hand, they admit that they have experienced a freedom that did not exist

    during the centralized era, and gradually, the learning process of managing and

    administering the local governments is working. The ordinary Indonesians, especiallythe local residents, might be the only one who keeps questioning the effects of the

    decentralization process. Some claimed that they do not feel any impact of the process,

    while some others felt only the negative impacts. They still believe that the currentprocess is more on the decentralization from central to local governments than the

    decentralization from government to the local people or community.

    Among all types of impacts generated by the decentralization process, the economic (andfiscal) impacts are still considered the most crucial one since Indonesia is still on the

    recovery process after the 1998 financial and economic crisis. Together with political

    1

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    2/21

    reformation, most Indonesians had expectation that the decentralization process will

    contribute to the economic reformation especially reducing disparity between Jawa andoutside Jawa or between the western and eastern part. Giving more economic policy

    decision making power to the local government is also considered as the expected output

    of successful decentralization process. Therefore, this paper is intended to evaluate the

    three years Indonesian decentralization process with the emphasis on the economic andfiscal impacts but the discussion will begin with the evaluation from political and

    administrative point of view since they will affect the economic side eventually. Special

    concern about fiscal sustainability that might relate to decentralization will be on the lastpart of this paper, and this might have further implication to future Indonesia economic

    development pattern.

    DEVOLUTION OF POWER AND POLITICAL APPROACHAfter three years of decentralization, it is not too surprising if there were problems due to

    multi-interpretation or lack of clarity of law 22/1999. In 1999, the law was drafted

    without a blue print or general design of decentralization scheme and without a white

    paper. Sequentially, the decentralization process should begin with the blue printfollowed by a white paper. The white paper should be then the foundation for the legal

    drafting. Due to political condition and limited time availability, the decentralizationprocess in Indonesia jumped directly to the law drafting and as a result, when there is

    confusion about the law itself, no valid reference is available. Various groups, with their

    own argument, are competing to be the true interpreter of the law, especially law22/1999. If one group is in verge of having enough power over the implementation and

    revision of the law, other groups will try very hard to undermine them through frequent

    and sometimes unfair critiques. Ironically, this possible conflict or rivalry sometimestakes place between groups in the ministry of home affairs (MOHA) that is clearly

    responsible for drafting and implementing the decentralization laws, especially frompolitical and administrative point of view.

    Among many confusing and debatable issues in the law 22/1999, there might be threemost crucial issues : devolution of government authorities, formation and amalgamation

    of new local governments, and the local executive-legislative relationship. At the first

    issue, the devolution of government authorities, the central government may claim that

    they have managed the devolution process quite well and after three years, the centralgovernment influence in the local government activities has significantly declined.

    However, the local government might not share the same opinion. They claimed that the

    devolution of authorities was far from clear, and eventhough it was clear, the lineministries at central government were obviously still interested in the authorities. Lack of

    clarity in the devolution process might come from two different extremes in the law. At

    one part, the law states that the central government will only be responsible for fivefunctions plus planning and standardization. At the other part, the law also states that

    each local government has to be responsible for eleven obligatory sectors. The problem

    lies on the gap between the central government obligatory functions and the local

    government ones, and the inconsistency between functions for the central governmentand sectors for local governments. The government regulation (PP) 25/2000 was

    supposed to close the gap by giving more detailed direction to local government, but

    2

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    3/21

    instead the PP used the residual approach that listed only the detailed functions of central

    and provincial government, and left the rest to local government. As a result, the localgovernment can define their functions at their will. It could be a broad range of function

    but at the same time, it could be a small range. There are two predicted outcomes

    generated from this condition, the conflicts of interests between central and local

    governments, and lower quality of basic public services delivery for the local residents.

    The second issue, the formation and amalgamation of new local governments is mostly

    treated exclusively as the political concerns. Whenever there is formation of new localgovernment, the political flavor and interests are much more dominant than other

    consideration. It is no secret that the local elites are jockeying for the local executive

    position through the proposal of new local government formation. The law 22/1999interpretation seems to fully support the formation without real and binding consequences.

    The government regulation (PP) that is supposed to back up the clauses about the

    formation already described the process in detail with the criteria. However, lack of

    political willingness at the central government side to manage and control the formation

    of new local governments caused the high influx of new districts and municipalities atmore than 10% annual growth rate. Currently, with more than 410 districts and

    municipalities, it is not clear if the number will keep growing at the same rate after 2004and how this number will contribute to economic efficiency. Many argue that the

    formation of new local governments in Indonesia has nothing to do with the economic

    efficiency and more on entertaining the local political interests. With the slow economicrecovery process and acute corruption, it is quite ironic that Indonesians still give the

    opportunity for wasting the economic resources and for creating more corruption through

    the formation. There are two obvious wasted economic resources as results of new localgovernment formation namely the relatively huge initial investment to set up the local

    administration system, and the higher dependency of local governments to theintergovernmental transfer, especially the general purpose grant (DAU). Brodjonegoro

    and Mahi (2003) noted that many new local governments had relatively insignificant

    local own revenue (PAD) and relied heavily on DAU.

    The third issue, the local executive legislative relationship, becomes one of major

    obstacles in promoting good governance and effective local administration. The law

    22/1999 somehow implied that the local parliament (DPRD) is the most powerful body atthe local level. They basically have the authority to hire, evaluate, and fire the head of

    local executives. Their authority in determining the local budget also seems to be very

    powerful. Therefore, the local executive and legislative relationship is not a productiveand conducive one from local resident point of view. They could either make

    collaboration between them or fight continuously. Each one of them will not be

    beneficial for the local resident and the latter even creates two bupatis (head of district) inKaranganyar District, central Jawa. The collusion between local executive and

    legislative tends to promote the corrupt behavior, and the local legislative tends to be the

    major player. There is relieving trend nowadays when many DPRD members become the

    suspect in the local corruption cases, and some of them have even stayed in the prison.

    3

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    4/21

    Any type of disruption in the local government politics and administrative system

    eventually leads to the disruption of basic public service delivery. Many Indonesians,nowadays, are quite skeptic about the decentralization process simply because they have

    not seen what they expected when the decentralization took place in 2001, a better local

    basic public service delivery. The World Bank report in 2003 might indicate that most

    Indonesians felt that the quality of public services during the decentralization era wasbetter than the previous one, or at least the same. However, the coverage of the survey

    and sampling procedure might not reflect the reality and at the same time, national

    newspapers keep publishing how infrastructures are deteriorating all over Indonesia, andhow the local governments pay little attention to the quality improvement of public

    service delivery. To ensure that every Indonesian will enjoy the minimum basic standard

    of public services, the central government through the ministry of home affairs (MOHA)coordination is trying to promote the implementation of the minimum service standard

    (MSS). While the MSS idea might be good from conceptual point of view, the

    possibility of becoming real success is highly questionable for two reasons. First, due to

    its complexity, even in the developed decentralized country MSS cannot be fully

    implemented. Second, the budget constraint seems to be non-existent when the lineministries are designing the MSS for their respective sectors. Current development

    shows that the MSS design in Indonesia is rather slow due to different perception of theword minimum itself that is interpreted by some ministries as without budget constraint.

    Furthermore, without proper preparation, the MSS implementation could lead to disaster

    when the local government budget cannot fulfill the MSS and eventually they will ask formore transfer from central government.

    To overcome or at least minimize the problems during decentralization era, the centralgovernment is trying to amend the law 22/1999 and law 25/1999. The basic substance of

    the amendment is the introduction of direct election for both local executives andlegislatives. The direct election might bring better accountability at local level and

    somehow, reduce the absolute power of DPRD. Better accountability could lead to more

    responsive local governments in fulfilling the local resident needs. In terms of formationand amalgamation of new local governments, the amendment is trying to impose the

    evaluation of autonomous regions that could lead to status withdrawal by central

    government if local governments cannot fulfill certain criteria after a certain period of

    time. It is still doubtful if this mechanism could work in the current period of uncertaintywhere the central government is still considered weak. The proposed amendment is also

    trying to give significant contribution to better devolution of authorities by listing more

    detailed functions that have to be carried out by local governments. Instead of just sayingthat local government is responsible in education sector, for example, the amendment

    proposes that the local government is responsible in executing the function of providing

    basic education or elementary school for the residents. Although many localgovernments still suspect that the amendment could lead to re-centralization but it has to

    be admitted that the central government is trying seriously to make the decentralization

    process a success story.

    The re-centralization impression among the local governments may appear due to

    redefinition of provincial government role in the decentralization process. In fact, it

    4

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    5/21

    could be attributed as another significant contribution of law 22 amendment process

    where the provincial government has the authority to do monitoring and evaluationprocess over the districts and municipalities in their area. Some argue that with the

    amendment, the provincial government and the governor will become powerful again in

    the near future and that may explain why the governor election is still intense and

    interesting. By giving more power to the provincial government, the central governmentis trying to break the intense relationship between provincial and local governments that

    sometimes leads to the ignorance of local governments on the existence of provincial

    government.

    However, the amendment process of both law 22/1999 and law 25/1999 revealed the old

    and continuous problem at the central level, lack of coordination among the ministriesand especially, rivalry between MOHA and ministry of finance (MOF). Lack of

    leadership at central level contributes significantly to the coordination and rivalry

    problems. Although the central government is trying very hard to create impression that

    decentralization is a nation agenda that has to be obeyed by everybody at central

    government, the perception that law 22/1999 is just a sectoral law belongs to MOHA stillthere. As a result, the conflict with other sectoral law such as mining law, forestry law

    still exists and it is far from easy to make other laws adjusted to the content of law22/1999 (World Bank, 2003). The rivalry between MOHA and MOF seems to be endless

    when it comes to the question of who should be the authority of decentralization process.

    Each one of them proposes the amendment of law 22 and law 25 respectively and thebigger problem is that each one of them is working on overlapped issues differently. One

    example is the issue on how the local governments spend their budget. Both laws are

    trying to reach the issue that did not exist in the original version of both laws. However,each one of them approached the issues from different perspective with their own

    standards. MOHA claimed that they should be the authority in this issue since they havedealt with local expenditure issues for a long time, and for them, MOF should concentrate

    on the revenue side of local budget (APBD). On the other hand, MOF claimed that they

    should have authority over the expenditure side of APBD since they are responsible foraccounting and financial reporting standard. The rivalry becomes intense when it comes

    to the idea of having only one law or legal act for decentralization like local government

    act in Philippine (Asanuma et al, 2003). They prefer to maintain the status quo by having

    one law under their responsibility but if there has to be one law, MOHA prefers that it hasto be under their responsibility. That preference could lead to MOHA domination in

    drafting the future of decentralization while the decentralization process should be multi

    facet and takes into account other ministries interests. So far, MOHA is gaining thepower while MOF is weakening, and currently, there is a tendency that MOHA is trying

    to take over some power over the intergovernmental transfer and other local finance

    issues.

    FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT

    In addition to the democratization process, the slow economic recovery process is another

    circumstance that accompanied the decentralization process since 2001. While focus ofthe national budget (APBN) should be to overcome the crisis and maintain economic

    stability, at the same time APBN has to dedicate some amount for new scheme of fiscal

    5

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    6/21

    decentralization as mandated by law 25/1999. Fortunately, there were no significant

    negative effects on the APBN created by that new scheme and most of local governmentscould understand that the relatively low amount of transfer is mostly due to heavy burden

    of APBN rather than the lack of central government commitment in fiscal

    decentralization. On the other hand, the intergovernmental transfer scheme itself is still

    far from optimal due to heavy political interference especially in DAU, natural resourcesrevenue sharing (through the special autonomy of Aceh and Papua), and tax revenue

    sharing.

    The center piece of Indonesian fiscal decentralization is the general purpose grant (DAU)

    that gives the full autonomy to local governments in spending and managing the grant.

    Instead of ad-hoc basis, the DAU utilizes the formula to allocate the grant to allprovincial and local governments in Indonesia. In most local governments, DAU is

    basically their budget since its role is very dominant as demonstrated in table 1 of

    appendix. This heavy dependence to DAU creates disincentive for local governments in

    raising or intensifying the collection local own revenue (PAD). While excessive local tax

    collection and illegal charges might harm the local investment climate, the localgovernments still have to intensify the collection of legal local taxes and charges revenue

    up to the optimal level through better local tax administration system and lawenforcement. Brodjonegoro and Martinez (2002) revealed the significant negative

    correlation between the size of DAU and PAD.

    The allocation of DAU itself is still full of political influence as indicated by the hold-

    harmless provision that guarantees every local government to receive the grant not less

    than the previous allocation. This clearly hurts the fiscal capacity equalization purposethat should be the DAU responsibility. The equalization problem, for now, is resolved

    gradually by keeping the rich regions at the same level as in 2001 and at the same time,giving more to poor regions through the inflation effect of DAU or increasing domestic

    revenue at APBN. Table 2 indicated that the ratio between the lowest and highest DAU

    per capita increased from 15 in 2002 to 20 in 2003. This gradual attempt is still far fromthe ultimate purpose of fiscal capacity equalization since in 2002 the ratio between the

    highest and lowest total local revenue per capita was still 7, a considerably high ratio.

    Another problem of DAU allocation formula is the existence of lump-sum component (a

    certain similar amount to all local government) that eventually triggered the formation ofnew local governments since the small lump-sum amount is still considered a significant

    amount for the proponents of new local governments. MOF is planning to abolish this

    component and incorporate it into a component that ensures the hold-harmless provision.

    Another alternative way to pursue the equalization purpose of DAU is by setting

    independent commission of grant allocation. The existence of independent commissionshould be effective in minimizing the political influence and in promoting the full

    formula approach. However, the central government elites seem to have different

    opinion regarding the mechanism of grant allocation. In the proposed amendment of law

    25/1999, MOF is trying to introduce the idea of independent grant commission thatreports directly to the president. However, MOF has not given enough political power

    yet to the commission since the main responsibility of the commission is just to propose

    6

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    7/21

    the allocation formula to the minister of finance and national parliament (DPR) without

    the guarantee that each one of them will only consider the commission proposal in thediscussion. There is a room for them to select proposals coming from another party.

    MOHA, on the other hand, is trying to keep the role of regional autonomy advisory

    council in the law 22/1999 amendment. Furthermore, MOHA proposed to have only one

    secretariat in DPOD that handles both regional autonomy and fiscal decentralizationmatters. It implies that MOHA will be the authority for intergovernmental transfer issues

    including DAU allocation formula. The national parliament has another idea in their

    version of law 22/1999 amendment that gives the authority to DPR budget committee indetermining the DAU allocation formula. These conflicting ideas simply revealed that

    money and politics are inseparable in Indonesia.

    While DAU becomes the center of attention for most of local governments, another

    serious issue in the local finance, the local own revenue, seems to be neglected. The law

    25/1999 and law 34/2000 obviously do not give significant local taxing power since the

    Indonesian decentralization was designed to be the expenditure-led decentralization

    financed by transfer. However, after three years of decentralization, the aspiration ofhigher local taxing power emerged. One important indicator of regional autonomy

    should be the ability of the local governments to find their own sources of revenue and toreduce the dependence to the transfer. As mentioned briefly, that is not the case in

    Indonesia since most of local governments are spoiled by the existence of DAU and do

    not pay enough attention to optimize the local own revenue. Comparison between annualgrowth rate of local own revenue during 1994-1996 period and 2001-2002 period

    indicated that prior decentralization growth (20%) is much higher than decentralization

    growth (5%). On the other hand, the central government is highly reluctant to give morelocal taxing power by transferring one or more of their taxes to the local government.

    The latest failure to transfer the authority of property tax to the local government wasgood example on how difficult an old paradigm shifts to the new paradigm. It is true that

    the local governments might not have the capability to collect the property tax optimally

    and it is also true that the local governments might be reluctant to impose direct taxes totheir residents. However, the new paradigm of decentralization will move toward the

    more accountable local government and local parliament to the local residents. The

    introduction of property tax as local tax is one of accountability instruments. If the local

    governments are deemed incapable of collecting the property tax revenue, then theycould focus on the tax rate setting and let the more capable central government body

    handling the collection and administration.

    The weak local taxing power has another negative implication regarding the local

    investment climate. Since most of local governments realized that the amount of transfer

    is far from enough to fulfill their needs as a result of slow economic recovery, and at thesame time they do not have alternative from existing local taxes and charges, they are

    trying to find other sources that unfortunately are illegal and disruptive. Imposing new

    charges, levies or fees has become the favourite tools for local governments to generate

    additional revenue and ensure a stable cash-flow management. The easiest targets forthose new additional revenues are unfortunately the local businesses that seem to be

    powerless in that situation.. It is not surprising to find plantation companies in Sumatra

    7

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    8/21

    complaining about the extra fees and levies. Combined with the fact that Indonesia is

    considered not conducive yet for foreign investment, the decentralization processbecomes one of major factors discouraging new investment in Indonesia. The illegal and

    excessive new charges, levies, or fees were some of major factors but more than that, the

    local government in Indonesia is not business friendly yet. The KPPOD survey (KPPOD,

    2003) revealed that the major concern for investors to locate their activities at localitieswas the institutional factors that cover the certainty, law enforcement, licensing process,

    and local regulation. In fact, the local governments create disincentives rather than

    incentives for incoming investment. This lack of incentives comes from a combination ofpolitical structure, economic structure and the relationship between central and local

    governments. In the current relationship between local executives and legislatives, the

    latter has becomes the more powerful party. Local executives have to follow the guidancefrom the legislative. However, due to their weak capabilities, the evaluation of executive

    performance is mostly based on what happens to the APDB budget, especially the total

    amount and its allocation. It is very rare to hear the local legislatives (DPRD) go beyond

    the APBD itself and evaluate the executive performance on how the APBD stimulates the

    local economic development and growth, and subsequently generates jobs and reduceslocal unemployment. In other words, it is APBD that matters for both local legislatives

    and executives, while the GRDP is seen as a factor that will follow automatically thenational economic conditions (Brodjonegoro, 2003). The lack of local elected officials

    accountability to their voters, due to the current election system, is another reason why

    local economic growth and local unemployment are not perceived to be as important asincreasing the revenue in the APBD.

    The lack of local government focus in promoting the output and employment growthleads to lower economic development activities in the regions. It should be noted,

    however, that the impacts of economic crisis might play significant role in slow economicgrowth both at national and local level. At this stage, it is hard to separate the effects of

    economic crisis and decentralization on the regional economic growth. Comparing the

    decentralization period with the crisis period, it is obvious that there has been economicgrowth improvement as indicated by GRDP, investment, and export growth by province

    in table 4,5, 6 and 7. However, the economic growth in decentralization era is still far

    below the economic boom (and centralized) era. The difference for all provinces is quite

    significant and it has to be examined further the reason of the difference apart from thenational macroeconomic condition. Table 4 7 should also alarm the central government

    that the less impressive performance of export and investment at national level might be

    due to problems at regional level that may require more local oriented actions than theuniform macroeconomic policy. Decentralization may play a role in that local oriented

    economic policy. Another alarming finding is de-industrialization all over Indonesia as

    indicated by table 7. The minus growth at some regions plus almost zero growth at otherregions indicated slow or even declining manufacturing growth that has to be anticipated

    as early as possible by both local and national policy makers. KPPOD survey (KPPOD,

    2003) indicated that manufacturing is the main victim of illegal and excessive charges or

    levies. This might effect the manufacturing activities at the local level and eventually atthe national level. An integrated national economic policy that incorporates the local

    8

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    9/21

    specifics has to be the first priority together with the GRDP, rather than APBD,

    orientation from local governments.

    FISCAL SUSTAINABILITY

    One major complain from most of Indonesian local governments is insufficient DAU and

    other types of transfer to support the regional development, especially related to newinfrastructure provision. As table 1 in the appendix indicates that most of local

    governments spent their budget for routine expenditure, especially government

    employees salary and left a little for development expenditure. With that limited amount,it is hard to imagine that the local governments will do some new major projects that

    improve the infrastructure quality in the region. Maintenance of existing infrastructures

    might be the maximum they can do but in reality, infrastructures are deteriorating all overIndonesia. It means that the local budget is simply not enough to cover any effort to

    promote local economic growth and improvement of public service delivery. There

    could be some reasons behind this condition. First, The Indonesian government that still

    works on slow economic process focuses the budget (APBN) on the debt payment and

    their routine expenses with little left for development. Second, most of localgovernments with limited sources of revenue have not been able to manage themselves

    efficiently due to current political situation that makes any efficiency program unpopularand not politically acceptable. Third, most of line ministries at central level still have

    significant power of the projects located on the regions while according to law 22/1999,

    the authority should have been moved to the local level.

    The last reason might reflect what local governments are always suspicious to the central

    government, the reluctance of the part of central governments to devolve their power tothe local level. In other words, the old problem of the tug of war between

    deconcentration and decentralization still exists. Although, the period since 2001 islabeled as decentralization period, it is not that easy to just change the paradigm from

    strong deconcentration in the past. Most of line ministries had the power in their fields

    during the deconcentration period, and the decentralization period basically threatenstheir power. Using many types of arguments such as national priority programs, national

    interest, people interests, and others, they are still trying to justify their authority over the

    execution of programs and projects at the local level. Although they are involving the

    local government units during the activities, the sense that the project belongs to thecenter rather than local creates the impression that the central government does not want

    to devolve the authority. There have been some discussions about this issue but

    whenever it comes to the real action, the question from a line ministry will be who shouldinitiate the policy and if other ministries will follow the policy. Other ministries would

    argue that they do not have trust in local government of delivering the minimum basic

    services that they used to do it in the past. Some also proposed that part of DAU shouldbe earmarked for certain activities related to basic service delivery such as education,

    health, and basic infrastructure.

    While the debate of deconcentration v decentralization might be endless, there is onestrategic policy to gradually shift the central government paradigm and minimize the

    deconcentration activities. The specific purpose grant (DAK) that theoretically should be

    9

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    10/21

    devoted to handle the jurisdictional spill-over effects, ensure minimum service standard,

    and to pursue the national interest, is the best instrument to gradually devolve the lineministries power. With the scheme of DAK that still involves the central government

    ministries and agencies, the local government will own the projects or programs but they

    will be under the monitoring and evaluation from respective central ministries and central

    ministries will still have the decision on the types of programs or projects to be financed.The shift from DIP (central government programs and projects) to DAK could be

    designed in medium term perspective to make smooth adjustment both at central and

    local level. With greater DAK, the local governments will have higher opportunity todevelop the regions based on their plans and assessment. As many agree, the local

    governments know better the local needs than the central ministries.

    From fiscal sustainability point of view, this kind of shift will not affect the APBN much

    since the transaction is basically transfer from development expenditure account to

    intergovernmental transfer account, in this case DAK. Such a move will also ensure the

    fiscal sustainability at national level. Currently, there are requests from local

    governments to central government in allocating more than 25% net domestic revenue forthe DAU. For first three years, the government always imposed the minimum amount of

    25% net domestic revenue and because of that request, the central government willallocate 25.5% for 2004 DAU. This slight increase might not affect the national fiscal

    sustainability but the idea from one of influential ministry to increase the DAU to be 30%

    of net domestic revenue might threaten the sustainability. That threat becomes moresignificant if there is no shift from DIP to DAK since the central government is forced to

    find additional revenue or to cut other types of expenditure. The move to increase the

    DAU up to 30% of net domestic revenue will not affect the sustainability if accompaniedby the shift from DIP to DAK and by defining the better the devolution of authorities.

    Without proper management of this matter, there could be a condition where the centralgovernment runs out of money while they are still responsible for many government

    authorities.

    Another potential disruption of fiscal sustainability that relates to fiscal decentralization

    process is the disbursement of natural resources revenue sharing. The central

    government has committed to avoid the late disbursement program in the past that caused

    the large surplus at natural resources rich regions due to inability of absorbing the budgetclosed to the end of budget year. This late disbursement also caused the uncertainty in

    the local government cash flow management with few regions have to borrow from

    external sources to anticipate the incoming revenue. Beginning in 2004, thegovernment will allocate the budgeted amount rather than the actual amount that caused

    the delay. With the budgeted amount that was based on the last year actual transfer, the

    central government has a risk of transferring money to the regions more than they aresupposed to be. The fluctuation of both natural resources commodity production and

    price could increase the risk that may eventually affect the fiscal sustainability at central

    level. The sustainability becomes a more significant issue since the APBN has the

    obligation to pay the debt that was about 17.5% of the total budget in 2003 (table 8 ofappendix). This proportion was lower than in 2001 and 2002. Quite interestingly, the

    debt payment proportion in 2003 was lower than the DAU proportion and

    10

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    11/21

    intergovernmental transfer proportion. In 2001-2002, the debt proportion was higher

    than DAU but lower than intergovernmental transfer. Any proportion increase of debtpayment together with DAU proportion pattern (and other transfer instrument) will

    certainly put the national budget in danger.

    To finance the development in decentralized era, there are possibilities that both central

    and local governments have to look for external sources. The internal sources shouldcome from tax revenue intensification and higher economic growth that leads to higher

    tax revenue. Due to current difficulties in expanding the tax base and promoting

    economic growth because of lack of investment, the external sources should beprioritized but with cautions. The central government already issues government bonds

    for sources of funding and it will imply in debt payment burden of the budget in the near

    future. The foreign loan is still there but its importance might decline a little bit due tounpopularity among Indonesians. Local government, on the other hand, is still prohibited

    to borrow from external sources, especially from foreign sources. There have been

    discussions that the prohibition might be lifted in the near future, and the central

    government has already amended the law 25/1999 by introducing the on-lending concept

    for local governments. With this on-lending concept, the international agencies will haveto negotiate and make an agreement with central government on behalf of local

    governments that need foreign borrowing. The central government will then lend themoney to the local governments and supported by an agreement, the central government

    can charge the local governments through the intergovernmental transfer if the local

    governments are in default position. This might minimize the bigger risk of threateningthe fiscal sustainability. Another possibility is the issuance of local government bonds. It

    might take some years before the local governments can really issue the bonds and get

    the financial sources they need. The risk to fiscal sustainability is there if the localgovernments are allowed to issue the bond, especially if the central government might

    have to bail out. To minimize the risk, the local government bankruptcy law has to beready together with the secondary bond market. But first of all, there has to be trust

    toward the local government management from the market and it has to be developed by

    local governments themselves through good governance practices and ability to managethe local economic development process.

    CONCLUDING REMARKSThe three years period of decentralization process could be labeled as a mild success.The success could be demonstrated by how the Indonesians quickly adjusted to massive

    and drastic changes from a very strong centralized government, given only one year of

    preparation. The relatively smooth transfer of 2 millions civil servants might be thesymbol of smooth devolution process that did not create significant social or political

    unrest. The central government, especially some line ministries, is still trying to be

    involved more in the local activities, and it is understandable given their almost absolutepower in the past. The local governments might be still in the learning process on how to

    rely on their own but they are learning quickly and given the limited budget, they can still

    manage the government administration relatively well. The amendment of both law

    22/1999 and law 25/1999 should be treated as a significant improvement ofdecentralization process with the emphasis on better monitoring from central government

    and accountability at local level. On the fiscal side, there might be a problem of less than

    11

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    12/21

    equal DAU but it is improving albeit gradually. Some efforts to separate the political

    influence from DAU allocation should give a hope of more equal allocation based onindependent judgement. The central government also improves the natural resources

    revenue sharing disbursement that could neutralize the restless local governments. On

    the fiscal sustainability perspective, the central government has relatively managed the

    debt well so that the proportion for the intergovernmental transfer is higher in APBN. Aprudent and cautious national budget management is the key to success but the latest

    request to increase the DAU portion might have to be observed carefully.

    Aside from relatively success stories, the decentralization process could still lead to a

    failure if the local governments and central government are not practicing their proper

    behavior in new paradigm of decentralization. At the local government side, thetendency to prioritize local budget rather than local GRDP will still discourage the

    potential investors that want to stay away from illegal and excessive charges or levies.

    Local budget (APBD) should be treated as a local economic stimulator than the final

    purpose itself. Local parliament (DPRD) should share the same spirit and in order to

    support that, accountability of both local legislative and executive to the local votersshould be promoted, and everyone has to support the first direct election in 2004 for local

    legislative. It it fails, then the accountability mechanism might have to wait another fiveyears. Accountability of local governments to voters should ensure a better basic public

    service delivery and local government should begin to formulate how to build an

    effective local government that will not spend too much on routine activities. On theborrowing issue, the local governments have to convince the central government and

    potential lenders that they are capable in managing the borrowing without jeopardizing

    the current fiscal sustainability. As many agree, the local borrowing is a best localrevenue collection instrument since it will create a win-win condition for both borrower

    and lender.

    At the end, the success of decentralization process will lie on the central government that

    designs the process and commits to the implementation. Although it is not visible, thereis a tendency that decentralization is not one of priorities of central government. The

    decentralization activities are already considered as routine activities. It might be a good

    one if all the process is perfect and smooth, but it is dangerous if everything is not in

    place yet. That could lead to the impression that the central government is not so seriousanymore in promoting decentralization and prefers to go back to old paradigm. Lack of

    coordination and intense rivalry among central ministries do not help the situation with

    the impression that the decentralization process is no longer a national interest but aministry interest. The strong national leadership should handle this matter, and it could

    start from the amendment process of law 22/1999 and law 25/1999 that seems to go

    separate ways and it ends up in tug of war rather than a vision for decentralizationprocess itself. At the fiscal side, the central government still has to manage the fiscal

    sustainability that has effects on decentralization process and most importantly,

    Indonesians should avoid a large scale of economic crisis due to local government

    behavior in borrowing and managing their budgets as in the case of Brazil.

    12

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    13/21

    REFERENCES

    Asanuma, Shinji, and Bambang Brodjonegoro (2003),Indonesias Decentralization

    Policy : Origins, Issues, and Prospects, presented at the International Symposium onIndonesias Decentralization Policy : Problems and Policy Directions, Hitotsubashi

    University, Tokyo.

    Brodjonegoro, Bambang (2002), Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia, in Hadi Susastro,

    Anthony L Smith, and Han Mui Ling (eds), Governance in Indonesia: Challenges

    Facing the Megawati Presidency.Singapore: The Institute of Southeast Asian Sudies.

    Brodjonegoro, Bambang (2003),Decentralization and Business, presented at the

    Indonesian Update, Research School of Asian Pacific Studies, Australian National

    University, Canberra.

    Brodjonegoro, Bambang (2003),Decentralization and Urbanization in Indonesia : The

    Concept of Metropolitan Area, presented at the Asian Development Conference,

    Kitakyushu, Japan.

    Brodjonegoro, Bambang and Jorge Martinez (2002),An Analysis of IndonesiasTransfer System : Recent Performance and Future Prospects, presented at The

    Andrew Young School of Policy Studies sponsored conference on Can

    Decentralization Help Rebuild Indonesia ?,Georgia State University, Atlanta.

    Brodjonegoro, Bambang and Shinji Asanuma (2000), The Regional Autonomy and

    Fiscal Decentralization in Democratic Indonesia, Hitotsubashi Journal of

    Economics, Vol. 41 No.2, pp.111-122.

    Ford, J. Fitz G, and Bambang Brodjonegoro (2004), Inter-Governmental Fiscal Relations

    and State Building: The Case of Indonesia, in R.M. Bird (ed.), Asymmetric Fiscal

    Decentralization: Glue or Solvent?World Bank, Washington DC, forthcoming

    KPPOD(2003), Regional Investment Attractiveness: Business Perception,Jakarta:

    Komite Pemantauan Pelaksanaan Otonomi Daerah (KPPOD) and Asia Foundation.

    Mahi, Raksaka, and Bambang Brodjonegoro (2003),The Indonesian Political Economyof Decentralization, presented at the International Symposium on Indonesias

    Decentralization Policy : Problems and Policy Directions, Hitotsubashi University,

    Tokyo.

    Matsui, Kazuhisa, and Mudrajad Kuncoro (2003),The Role of Local Governments inIndonesia : A Survey of Recent Development, presented at the International

    Symposium on Indonesias Decentralization Policy : Problems and Policy Directions,Hitotsubashi University, Tokyo.

    Sato, Motohiro, Bambang Brodjonegoro, and Hamid Paddu (2003),IntergovernmentalTransfer and Tax Sharing in Indonesia : Theories, Practices, and Political

    Recommendation, presented at the International Symposium on Indonesias

    Decentralization Policy : Problems and Policy Directions, Hitotsubashi University,

    Tokyo.

    13

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    14/21

    Suwandi, Made (2002),The Implementation of Regional Autonomy : The Indonesian

    Experience, presented at The Andrew Young School of Policy Studies sponsoredconference on Can Decentralization Help Rebuild Indonesia ?, Georgia State

    University, Atlanta.

    Usui, Norio, and Armida Alisjahbana (2003),Local Development Planning and

    Budgetting in Decentralized Indonesia, presented at the International Symposium onIndonesias Decentralization Policy : Problems and Policy Directions, Hitotsubashi

    University, Tokyo.

    World Bank (2003),Decentralizing Indonesia : A Regional Public Expenditure Review

    Overview Report, East Asia Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Unit,Jakarta.

    APPENDIX

    TABLE 1: Percentage of Prefectures /Municipalities Distribution Based on Elements of

    Budget Shares to Total Local Budget (APBD), Year 2002

    Source:APBD 2002

    14

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    15/21

    TABLE 2: DAU per capita 2002 - 2003

    DAU/population (million Rp)Province (including

    districts and

    municipalities) 2002 2003

    Sumatra

    Sumatra: Dista Aceh 484.05 489.74Sumatra: North Sumatra 315.03 344.16

    Sumatra: West Sumatra 460.24 520.29

    Sumatra: Riau 468.96 382.45

    Sumatra: Jambi 508.31 564.91

    Sumatra: South Sumatra 295.03 316.88

    Sumatra: Bengkulu 485.02 569.81

    Sumatra: Lampung 284.38 318.25

    Java

    Java: DKI Jakarta 77.68 73.00

    Java: West 191.58 563.05

    Java: Central 266.82 339.63

    Java: DI Yogyakarta 418.84 458.65

    Java: East 251.64 273.19

    Bali 490.67 525.01

    Nusa Tenggara

    Nusa Tenggara: West 355.16 389.23

    Nusa Tenggara: East 527.84 640.07

    Kalimantan

    Kalimantan: West 437.97 512.48

    Kalimantan: Central 650.19 807.68

    Kalimantan: South 443.59 545.31

    Kalimantan: East 449.21 457.65

    Sulawesi

    Sulawesi: North 571.87 585.33

    Sulawesi: Central 600.38 655.29

    Sulawesi: South 426.35 483.77

    Sulawesi: South East 593.67 755.03

    Maluku 584.84 806.62

    Irian Jaya 1,192.27 1,490.65

    2002 :

    Highest : Irian Jaya : Rp 1,192.27Lowest : DKI Jakarta : Rp 77.68Ratio : Highest/Lowest : 15.3

    Tahun 2003 :Highest : Irian Jaya : Rp 1,490.65Lowest : DKI Jakarta : Rp 73Ratio : Highest/Lowest : 20.4

    15

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    16/21

    TABLE 3: Local Revenue per Capita 2002

    Province (including

    districts andmunicipalities)

    APBD revenue/population(in million Rp)

    Sumatra

    Sumatra: Dista Aceh 1,219.62

    Sumatra: North Sumatra 474.85

    Sumatra: West Sumatra 640.08

    Sumatra: Riau 2,027.54

    Sumatra: Jambi 685.82

    Sumatra: South Sumatra 461.95

    Sumatra: Bengkulu 575.56

    Sumatra: Lampung 383.41

    Java

    Java: DKI Jakarta 939.45

    Java: West 320.48

    Java: Central 356.13

    Java: DI Yogyakarta 582.50

    Java: East 378.99

    Bali 952.42

    Nusa Tenggara

    Nusa Tenggara: West 476.61

    Nusa Tenggara: East 622.16

    Kalimantan

    Kalimantan: West 574.02

    Kalimantan: Central 1,065.17

    Kalimantan: South 663.27

    Kalimantan: East 1,746.75

    Sulawesi

    Sulawesi: North 674.91

    Sulawesi: Central 714.20

    Sulawesi: South 569.51

    Sulawesi: South East 705.99

    Maluku 734.41

    Irian Jaya 2,260.10

    Highest : Irian Jaya : Rp 2,260.10Lowest : DKI Jakarta : Rp 320.48Ratio : highest/lowest : 7.05

    16

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    17/21

    TABLE 4 : Average Annual GRDP Growth by Province

    Source : LPEM FEUI

    Average Annual Growth (%)PROVINCE

    1994-1996 1999-2000 2001-2002

    NANGGROE ACEH DARUSSALAM 0.02 -0.04 0.00SUMATERA UTARA 0.09 0.02 0.02

    SUMATERA BARAT 0.08 0.02 0.02

    R I A U 0.05 0.03 0.02

    J A M B I 0.09 0.03 0.02

    SUMATERA SELATAN 0.08 0.02 0.02

    KEP. BANGKA BELITUNG - - 0.02

    B E N G K U L U 0.07 0.02 0.02

    L A M P U N G 0.09 0.02 0.03

    D K I J AKARTA 0.09 0.02 0.02

    J AWA BARAT 0.09 -0.04 0.02

    BANTEN - - 0.03J AWA TENGAH 0.07 0.02 0.02

    D I YOGYAKARTA 0.08 0.02 0.02

    J AWA TIMUR 0.08 0.02 0.02

    B A L I 0.08 0.02 0.02

    NUSA TENGGARA BARAT 0.08 0.14 0.02

    NUSA TENGGARA TIMUR 0.09 0.02 0.03

    KALIMANTAN BARAT 0.10 0.01 0.01

    KALIMANTAN TENGAH 0.10 0.01 0.02

    KALIMANTAN SELATAN 0.10 0.02 0.02

    KALIMANTAN TIMUR 0.07 0.02 0.02

    SULAWESI UTARA 0.09 0.03 0.02

    GORONTALO - - 0.03

    SULAWESI TENGAH 0.08 0.02 0.03

    SULAWESI SELATAN 0.08 0.02 0.02

    SULAWESI TENGGARA 0.07 0.03 0.03

    M A L U K U 0.07 -0.01 0.01

    MALUKU UTARA - - 0.01

    P A P U A 0.17 0.01 0.04

    17

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    18/21

    TABLE 5 :Average Annual Inv stment Growth by Province

    Source

    e

    Average Annual Growth (%)PROVINCE

    1994-1996 1994-1996NANGGROE ACEH DARUSSALAM 0.02 -0.04 0.03

    SUMATERA UTARA 0.13 0.02 0.01

    SUMATERA BARAT 0.10 0.01 0.01

    R I A U 0.08 0.01 0.01

    J A M B I 0.07 0.04 0.01

    SUMATERA SELATAN 0.13 0.02 0.02

    KEP. BANGKA BELITUNG - - 0.03

    B E N G K U L U 0.02 0.02 0.02

    L A M P U N G 0.21 0.05 0.01

    D K I J AKARTA 0.11 0.01 0.01

    J AWA BARAT 0.21 0.00 0.03BANTEN - - 0.03

    J AWA TENGAH 0.08 0.03 -0.08

    D I YOGYAKARTA 0.08 0.03 0.08

    J AWA TIMUR 0.11 -0.03 0.00

    B A L I 0.09 0.01 0.01

    NUSA TENGGARA BARAT 0.12 -0.02 0.01

    NUSA TENGGARA TIMUR 0.08 0.04 0.02

    KALIMANTAN BARAT 0.20 0.02 -0.02

    KALIMANTAN TENGAH 0.07 -0.02 0.13

    KALIMANTAN SELATAN 0.10 0.08 -0.03

    KALIMANTAN TIMUR 0.02 0.00 0.07SULAWESI UTARA 0.17 0.27 0.20

    GORONTALO - - 0.01

    SULAWESI TENGAH 0.06 0.02 0.02

    SULAWESI SELATAN 0.18 -0.03 0.02

    SULAWESI TENGGARA 0.05 0.03 0.04

    M A L U K U 0.16 0.00 0.14

    MALUKU UTARA - - 0.03

    P A P U A 0.15 0.07 0.05

    : LPEM FEUI

    18

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    19/21

    TABLE 6 :Average Annual Export Growth by Province

    Average Annual Growth (%)PROVINCE

    1994-1996 1994-1996

    NANGGROE ACEH DARUSSALAM 0.00 0.00 -0.10

    SUMATERA UTARA 0.11 0.02 0.07

    SUMATERA BARAT 0.07 -0.05 0.00

    R I A U 0.07 0.10 0.04

    J A M B I 0.10 0.01 0.00

    SUMATERA SELATAN 0.16 0.08 0.00

    KEP. BANGKA BELITUNG - - -0.01

    B E N G K U L U 0.17 0.02 0.02

    L A M P U N G 0.07 0.06 -0.27

    D K I J AKARTA 0.12 0.02 0.09

    J AWA BARAT 0.12 -0.06 0.00

    BANTEN - - 0.02

    J AWA TENGAH 0.08 0.07 -0.09

    D I YOGYAKARTA 0.07 0.01 0.03

    J AWA TIMUR 0.09 0.06 -0.05

    B A L I 0.09 0.01 0.01

    NUSA TENGGARA BARAT 0.12 1.02 0.04

    NUSA TENGGARA TIMUR 0.11 -0.13 0.10

    KALIMANTAN BARAT 0.04 0.01 -0.12

    KALIMANTAN TENGAH 0.10 0.00 -0.10

    KALIMANTAN SELATAN 0.01 0.01 -0.05

    KALIMANTAN TIMUR 0.11 0.05 0.01

    SULAWESI UTARA 0.12 0.01 0.05

    GORONTALO - - 0.07

    SULAWESI TENGAH 0.03 0.02 0.02

    SULAWESI SELATAN 0.01 0.01 0.04

    SULAWESI TENGGARA 0.19 0.35 0.01

    M A L U K U 0.01 -0.16 0.02

    MALUKU UTARA - - 0.05

    P A P U A 0.25 0.00 -0.11

    Source : LPEM FEUI

    19

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    20/21

    TABLE 7 :Average Annual Manufacturing Growth by Province

    Source : LPEM-FEUI

    Average Annual Growth (%)PROVINCE

    1994-1996 1994-1996

    NANGGROE ACEH DARUSSALAM 0.01 -0.15 -0.01

    SUMATERA UTARA 0.09 0.02 0.04

    SUMATERA BARAT 0.12 0.03 0.01

    R I A U 0.12 0.05 0.02

    J A M B I 0.15 0.01 0.02

    SUMATERA SELATAN 0.10 0.02 0.01

    KEP. BANGKA BELITUNG - - 0.02

    B E N G K U L U 0.12 0.03 0.03

    L A M P U N G 0.09 0.01 0.01

    D K I J AKARTA 0.09 0.02 0.01

    J AWA BARAT 0.15 0.02 0.02

    BANTEN - - 0.02

    J AWA TENGAH 0.08 0.02 0.02

    D I YOGYAKARTA 0.07 -0.01 0.02

    J AWA TIMUR 0.12 0.01 -0.01

    B A L I 0.11 -0.01 0.03

    NUSA TENGGARA BARAT 0.09 0.03 0.03

    NUSA TENGGARA TIMUR 0.05 0.02 0.02

    KALIMANTAN BARAT 0.08 0.02 0.01

    KALIMANTAN TENGAH 0.03 -0.06 0.01

    KALIMANTAN SELATAN 0.11 -0.03 -0.01

    KALIMANTAN TIMUR 0.03 0.03 -0.01

    SULAWESI UTARA 0.10 0.03 0.03

    GORONTALO - - 0.01

    SULAWESI TENGAH 0.08 0.01 0.02

    SULAWESI SELATAN 0.08 0.04 0.01

    SULAWESI TENGGARA 0.21 0.03 -0.01

    M A L U K U 0.06 -0.16 0.00

    MALUKU UTARA - - 0.00

    P A P U A 0.14 -0.04 0.04

    20

  • 8/12/2019 Three Years of Fiscal Decentralization in Indonesia - Brodjonegoro (2004)

    21/21

    TABLE 8 :Intergovernmental Transfer, Debt Payment, and National Budget

    Year

    DAU/TotalExpenditure (%)

    Transfer/TotalExpenditure (%)

    Interest + Principal DebtPayment/TotalExpenditure (%)

    2001 17.67 23.73 20.862002 20.00 27.21 22.71

    2003 20.77 29.01 17.46

    Sumber : Departemen Keuangan RI