43
THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) Michael Keen UNU-WIDER conference on ‘Public Economics for Development’ Maputo, July 5 2016 Views are mine alone

THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY)

Michael KeenUNU-WIDER conference on ‘Public Economics for

Development’ Maputo, July 5 2016

Views are mine alone

Page 2: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Public Economics for Development

Work is now marked by:

• Empirical focus, with close attention to – Endogeneity issues – Data, esp. (but not only) large administrative datasets

• Administrative aspects– Likely too an increasing focus, given digitalization

A large, still rich agenda: better integrating theory, evidence, and practicalities—not least for tax

Page 3: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

OUTLINE

• Research on tax administration

• Tax gaps in tax analysis

• Optimal tax administration

• Concluding

Page 4: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

RESEARCH ON TAX ADMINISTRATION

Page 5: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Until recently

Literature on tax administration had focused on:

• Measuring administration and compliance costs

• Embellishing/puzzling over models of tax evasion

No established framework by which to evaluate administrative interventions—unlike policy

Presenter
Presentation Notes
Much of what they do can be rationalized in these terms, but… On embellishing/puzzling: Hashimzade, Myles and Tran-Nam in J Econ Surveys.
Page 6: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Recent explosion of empirical work

Many excellent papers using experiments, natural or other, to address aspects of compliance. E.g.:

• Compliance in VAT chains (Pomeranz, 2015)

• Lotteries (Naritomi, 2013)

• ‘Nudges’ (reviews in Alm (2014), Luttmer and Singhal (2014))

Presenter
Presentation Notes
Mixed results on nudges: Austria vs UK in Luttmer and Singhal
Page 7: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

What has all this taught tax administrators?

• Implications for enforcing VAT chains– Pomeranz results seem to imply “Start at the end”

• Importance of withholding and third party information well-known– British land tax 1697; and Milton Friedman’s regret!

• Are lotteries/nudges first order importance?

Presenter
Presentation Notes
Lottery increase revenue from retailers by 22 percent; but that is just 0.3 percent of state VAT receipts.
Page 8: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Making theory more useful

…by providing practicable frameworks integrating policy and administration

Illustrate this with thinking around ‘tax gaps’

• What significance in wider analysis of tax systems?

• What is the ‘optimal’ tax gap?– Answering that requires thinking about ‘optimal’ tax

administration more widely

Page 9: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

TAX GAPS IN TAX ANALYSIS

Page 10: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Decomposing VAT revenue: ‘C-efficiency’

Can write VAT revenue (in percent GDP) as

where V is VAT revenue, Y is GDP, τS is the standard VAT rate, C is consumption, and

is ‘C-efficiency’C

VEs

C

τ≡

=

YCE

YV c

Page 11: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

C-efficiency drove changes in VAT Revenue, 2003-2010

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Low income Lower middle Upper middle High income

Change in C/YChange in c-efficiencyChange in standard rateChange in V/Y

Page 12: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

So what drives C-efficiency?

With V* the revenue that would be raised if implementation of current system were perfect:

where P is a ‘policy gap’ and Γ a ‘compliance gap’

)1)(1(*

*Γ−−=

== P

VV

CV

CVE

SS

C

ττ

Presenter
Presentation Notes
Note asymmetry: policy gap assumes perfect compliance; compliance gap takes policy to be what it is - Note need only 2 of the 3
Page 13: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

The compliance gap

≡Excess of tax (e.g. VAT) theoretically due over that actually collected, as percent of former

• An increasing focus in many countries. E.g.:– UK has produced ‘VAT gaps’ for several years– Reckon (2009) and CASE (2013) for EU– RA-GAP project at IMF, esp. for developing countries

• Ideally, combine with analysis of ‘policy gaps’– Similar to tax expenditures

Page 14: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

For example (from RA-GAP)

Uganda South Africa

Page 15: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Uses of gap analysis

Can identify:

• Priorities for reform: e.g.:– In Uganda, key issue is compliance gap, halving it

would raise 3% of GDP– For South Africa, policy gap seems the larger concern

• Areas in which to improve compliance– Not just total gap that matters

Presenter
Presentation Notes
Several ways to estimate ‘Top-down’—use national accounts aggregates, largely consumption-data based ‘Bottom-up’—gross up operational information ‘Sectoral’—use sources-uses tables, mimicking VAT: RA-GAP Differing merits, esp. in suggesting responses —choice largely driven by data availability
Page 16: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

VAT gaps by sector

-40

-20

0

20

40

60

80

100

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

Bill

ion

R

Potential vs Actual Revenue by Sector – South Africa

Potential revenue Actual collection

Sectors:

1. Agriculture, forestry and fishery2. Mining and quarrying3. Manufacturing4. Electricity, gas and water5. Construction

6. Wholesale and retail trade, catering and accommodations7. Transport, storage and communications8. Financial intermediation, insurance, real estate and business services9. Community and social services

Presenter
Presentation Notes
One unique and important aspect of the methodology used by RA-GAP in estimating the VAT gap is that it can break down potential and actual VAT by sectors of activity. Sectoral VAT collection data in South Africa shows revenues are highly concentrated in 8. Financial intermediation, insurance, real estate and business services, 6. Wholesale and retail trade, catering and accommodations, and 3. Manufacturing. A tax administration can then investigate the reasons for discrepancies between potential and actual VAT collection in each sector. The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classification problems. Aside: Actual revenue may be greater than potential revenue because of differences between the national accounts attribution of activities to industrial sectors and VAT reporting of transactions according to sectors by taxpayers. There is a recurrent issue in the sectoral decomposition of the compliance gap, which is one reason why we always say it is indicative only and needs to be interpreted with care. Where the data permits, we adjust out the anomalous results. It is worth noting that this sort of misallocation does not affect the overall level of the estimated compliance gap.
Page 17: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

And UK compliance gap

Fraud Crisis

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

Presenter
Presentation Notes
Combine this with estimates of C-efficiency, infer policy gap as residual
Page 18: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

But—Is compliance gap too big or too small?

• A tendency to think that whatever compliance gap is, it’s too big– But closing it is costly, including through

possible impact on activity

• So what is the optimal compliance gap?– How, more generally, to characterize optimal

administrative interventions?

Page 19: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

OPTIMAL TAX ADMINISTRATION

Page 20: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Three Questions

Page 21: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Q1: How should we assess administrative Interventions?

• There is an established framework for assessing optimal tax rates—focused on the “elasticity of taxable income”

• Is there are an administration-side analogue?– i.e. a sufficient statistic summarizing what’s

needed to make normative judgments?

Presenter
Presentation Notes
A long tradition of measuring administration and compliance costs, often relative to revenue—but what is its relevance for decision-making?
Page 22: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Q2: What is the optimal compliance gap?

• The compliance gap is not a welfare measure– As noted earlier: may not be worth expend resources

to reduce the gap; and reducing it may worsen the tax distortion

• So, how do we know if a compliance gap is too big or too small?

Page 23: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Q3: Administration or policy to raise revenue?

A very basic question for policy-makers:

If additional revenue is needed, is it better to secure this by

(a) Strengthening administration, or(b) Increasing statutory rates?

Page 24: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

A framework to address them

Page 25: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Integrating the analysis of tax policy and administration (Keen-Slemrod, 2016)

Pure efficiency: Extending a standard model to allow (non-) compliance and administration costs

where 𝑟𝑟 = 𝑇𝑇 𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤 − 𝑒𝑒 − 𝐴𝐴(𝛼𝛼)

Taxpayer chooses 𝑤𝑤 and 𝑒𝑒; government chooses 𝑇𝑇and 𝛼𝛼

)(),()( rVeCewlTwlU +−−−= α

Presenter
Presentation Notes
Many considerations: Horizontal equity, cycle…. ‘Enforcement’ here includes taxpayer services et Sounds theoretical but implicitly assuming…
Page 26: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Optimal choice of tax rate, T

• Well-known: A sufficient statistic for behavioral responses to tax rate changes is “elasticity of taxable income” = elasticity of reported tax base to (one minus) tax rate– Higher this is, the lower is the optimal tax rate

• Large empirical literature seeks to estimate this– Almost all for advanced countries

Page 27: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Answers

Page 28: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Choice of administrative intervention

The optimal choice of 𝛼𝛼 satisfies

𝜙𝜙 = 𝐸𝐸(𝑧𝑧,𝛼𝛼)where: • 𝜙𝜙 is an adjusted ratio of (marginal)

administration and compliance costs to revenue• 𝐸𝐸(𝑧𝑧,𝛼𝛼) is the enforcement elasticity of tax

revenue

Page 29: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

So answer to Q1 is: The enforcement elasticity

Like the taxable income elasticity, 𝐸𝐸 𝑧𝑧,𝛼𝛼 is a sufficient statistic for behavioral impact

E.g. If 𝑣𝑣′ = 1.2, 𝑎𝑎/𝑧𝑧=0.006 and 𝑐𝑐/𝑧𝑧=0.011, more enforcement is desirable iff 𝐸𝐸(𝑧𝑧,𝛼𝛼) exceeds 0.1

Presenter
Presentation Notes
NB: With non-proportional tax, it is elasticity of revenue that matters—hence the terminology
Page 30: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

What we know about the enforcement elasticit(ies) of taxable income?

• Evidence from panel of EU compliance gaps suggests 𝐸𝐸𝑍𝑍 = 0.17

• Experimental evidence– For audit, 𝐸𝐸𝑍𝑍 = 0.1-0.2

• Empirically, some IRS work (Plumley)…– Mainly concerned with choice between

administrative instruments…suggests 𝐸𝐸𝑍𝑍 for audit of 0.6-0.85 (?)

Presenter
Presentation Notes
Also need to break into G-H effects and effects on non-compliance The 1.1. calculated from Plumley (2002) as: Increasing audit rate from 0.65 to 1.65 (proportionate increase of 1.5) raises $56 bn of revenue (p.8); Revenue raised at the lower audit rate (from p.2) is 275/0.15-275=1560; so proportional increase in revenue is 56/1560=0.04. Then elasticity is 0.04/1.5=0.03. (Assuming here that base is proportional to revenue)
Page 31: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

More on the cost term

This is

𝜙𝜙 =𝛼𝛼 𝑐𝑐𝛼𝛼

𝑣𝑣′ + 𝛼𝛼𝑎𝑎′

𝑡𝑡𝑧𝑧which differs from standard cost/ revenue ratio in:

(a) Discounting compliance costs by 𝑣𝑣′: because they are not financed from distorting tax revenue

(b) It is marginal costs that matter

Page 32: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Putting this framework to work

A discrete administration reform is desirable iff

Δ𝑈𝑈 ≡ 𝑣𝑣′ − 1 𝑡𝑡∆𝑧𝑧 − 𝑣𝑣′∆𝑎𝑎 − ∆𝑐𝑐

Meiselman (2017) applies this to effect of letters sent to suspected non-Detroit city tax nonfilers

Finds welfare gain negative– mainly because of large compliance costs

Page 33: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

A2: Optimal compliance gap

The gap is 𝑔𝑔 ≡ 𝑒𝑒/𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤, and the optimal gap is characterized by an inverse elasticity rule

𝑔𝑔1−𝑔𝑔

= −𝜙𝜙𝐸𝐸(𝑒𝑒,𝛼𝛼)

So for this we need to know the evasion elasticity.

E.g., with the cost figures above, a compliance gap of 14.5% is optimal iff a 10 percent increase in spending on enforcement would reduce evasion about 5%.

Page 34: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

A3: Administration vs. rate increase

Answer is more likely to be enforcement:

• Higher is the elasticity of taxable income– Because that means high inefficiency

• Higher is the tax rate

• Higher is enforcement elasticity

• Lower are administration and compliance costs– Former especially damaging to case for

implementation

Page 35: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

And more

Page 36: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Are enforcement and tax rates strategic complements or subs.?

Matters because e.g.:

• If technology makes detecting evasion easier…

• Optimal tax rate goes down if strategic substitutes (on left)…

• …but goes up if they are complements

T(𝛼𝛼)

𝛼𝛼(𝑇𝑇)

T

𝛼𝛼

Answer to Q3 prompts another question

Page 37: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Some extensions

• Many are straightforward…– Multiple administrative instruments

• Results on allocation of a fixed administration budget

– Discrete reforms– When part of c is a transfer– Multiple households

• Generalizing concealment costs to 𝑐𝑐(𝑒𝑒, 𝑎𝑎𝑣𝑣𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑎𝑐𝑐𝑒𝑒, 𝑤𝑤)—but only a small redefinition of 𝜙𝜙 is needed

Page 38: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

CONCLUDING

Page 39: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Two views

“…it is time to put to rest the claim that [evasion, avoidance, and administration] is…understudied”

Slemrod and Yitzhaki, 2002

“…there is still only a relatively small scholarly literature [on] tax administration”

Hasseldine, 2011

First view has become more persuasive—but much remains

Presenter
Presentation Notes
They’re both right – different views of the question
Page 40: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

Integrity of the Registered

Taxpayer Base

Assessment and Mitigation of Risk

Supporting Voluntary

Compliance

Filing of Tax Returns

Payment of Obligations

Ensuring Accuracy of Reporting

Tax DisputeResolution

Operational Efficiency and Effectiveness

Accountability and

Transparency

Performance Outcome

Areas

ISORA/RA-FIT: Collects RA data and establish baselines/benchmarks

TADAT: Assessment tool

And two new data sources

Page 41: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

ISORA: Collecting information on tax administrations

• Understand historical performance

• Establish baselines by income group and other groupings

• Identify trends0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

AFR (16) APD (4) EUR (6) MCD (4) WHD (18)

As p

erce

ntag

e of

exp

ecte

d re

turn

s

Source: RA-FIT Database, 2010

On Time Filing Rates By Region

Page 42: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

TADATResults from 27 countries

A20%

B+15%

B20%

C+0%

C40%

D+0%

D5%

Scores Breakdown: Zambia

www.tadat.org

Page 43: THINKING ABOUT TAX ADMINISTRATION (AND POLICY) · The gap may indicate compliance issues in the sector, or may highlight sector classifica\൴ion problems. \爀屲Aside: Actual revenue

ReferencesKeen, Michael and Joel Slemrod, 2016, “Optimal tax administration,” forthcoming in the Journal of Public Economics.

Luttmer, Erzo and Monica Singhal, 2014, “Tax Morale,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 28, pp. 159–68.

Meiselman, Ben, 2017, “Ghostbusting in Detroit: Evidence on Nonfilers from a Controlled Field Experiment.” Mimeo, University of Michigan.

Naritomi, Joana, 2013, “Consumers as Tax Auditors,” Unpublished paper, Harvard University

Pomeranz, Dina, 2015, “No Taxation without Information: Deterrence and Self-Enforcement in the Value Added Tax,” American Economic Review, Vol. 105, pp. 2539-2569.

Plumley, Alan, 1996, “The Determinants of Individual Income Tax Compliance,” Internal Revenue Service, U.S. Department of the Treasury, Publication 1916 (Rev. 11-96).