33
FEBRUARY 11th THE RISE AND FALL OF WORLDWIDE INCOME INEQUALITY, 1820-2035 James Gwartney Florida State University [email protected] Hugo Montesinos Florida State University 250 S. Woodward Ave Tallahassee, FL 32306 (850) 408-4465 [email protected] Joseph Connors Florida Southern College [email protected] This draft, 01/30/2019, was prepared for presentation and discussion at the Colloquium on Market Institutions and Economic Processes at NYU, scheduled for 02/11/2019. Abstract The development process and the demographic changes that are a central element of it, explain both the nearly two centuries of increasing income inequality prior to 2000 and the reversal of this trend that followed. There are at least four phases of the development process: (1) pre- development, (2) initial growth, (3) improved productivity, and (4) receding growth. Prior to the Industrial Revolution, the entire world was in phase 1. During 1820-1950, about 20 countries, mostly in Western Europe, North America, and Oceania, moved out of phase 1 and grew more rapidly than the rest of the world, widening income inequality. Between 1960 and 2000, an increasing share of developing countries moved into phase 2 and achieved growth rates similar to the high-income countries, slowing the rise in inequality. By 2000-2015 most developing countries had moved into phases 2 or 3, while the high-income countries slid into phase 4, leading to a sharp reduction in worldwide income inequality. These recent reductions are likely to continue in the near term because of the continuation of favorable demographics, lower cost of transportation and communications, improvements in institutions, increases in human capital, and progress against malaria in developing countries. JEL Classification: O1, J11, D31.

The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

FEBRUARY 11th

THE RISE AND FALL OF WORLDWIDE INCOME INEQUALITY, 1820-2035

James Gwartney

Florida State University

[email protected]

Hugo Montesinos

Florida State University

250 S. Woodward Ave

Tallahassee, FL 32306

(850) 408-4465

[email protected]

Joseph ConnorsFlorida Southern [email protected]

This draft, 01/30/2019, was prepared for presentation and discussion at the Colloquium on

Market Institutions and Economic Processes at NYU, scheduled for 02/11/2019.

Abstract

The development process and the demographic changes that are a central element of it, explain

both the nearly two centuries of increasing income inequality prior to 2000 and the reversal of

this trend that followed. There are at least four phases of the development process: (1) pre-

development, (2) initial growth, (3) improved productivity, and (4) receding growth. Prior to the

Industrial Revolution, the entire world was in phase 1. During 1820-1950, about 20 countries,

mostly in Western Europe, North America, and Oceania, moved out of phase 1 and grew more

rapidly than the rest of the world, widening income inequality. Between 1960 and 2000, an

increasing share of developing countries moved into phase 2 and achieved growth rates similar to

the high-income countries, slowing the rise in inequality. By 2000-2015 most developing

countries had moved into phases 2 or 3, while the high-income countries slid into phase 4,

leading to a sharp reduction in worldwide income inequality. These recent reductions are likely

to continue in the near term because of the continuation of favorable demographics, lower cost of

transportation and communications, improvements in institutions, increases in human capital,

and progress against malaria in developing countries.

JEL Classification: O1, J11, D31.

Page 2: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

2

Introduction

Income inequality continues to be a hot topic among both economists and policymakers. It is

important to recognize that income inequality can be measured (1) across countries, (2) within a

country, and (3) worldwide. Cross-country inequality focuses on the variation in income among

various countries. Within-country income inequality reflects the variation of income among units

(e.g. individuals, households, or families) within a specific country. Finally, worldwide income

inequality is a reflection of how incomes vary among individuals and households throughout the

world.

Considerable recent research has focused on changes in income inequality within countries

[Atkinson, Piketty, and Saez 2011; Alvaredo et al. 2013; Novokmet et al. 2018]. There is

substantial variation in income inequality within countries. Income inequality after taxes and

transfers is relatively low in Canada, Japan and most western European countries and quite high

in Brazil, Egypt, India, Mexico, and South Africa [Solt 2016]. Moreover, within-country income

inequality has increased in recent decades in several large economies, including China, Russia,

and the United States [Assouad, Chancel, and Morgan 2018].

Recent scholarly research has also addressed cross-country and worldwide income

inequality [Bourguignon and Morrisson 2002; Sala-i-Martin 2006; Hellebrandt and Mauro 2015;

Bourguignon 2015; Milanovic 2016]. This article will focus on global income inequality and

make three significant contributions to this literature. First, the development process and

accompanying demographic changes are used to explain the changes in worldwide income

inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970, the relative stability during

1970-2000, and the sharp decline during 2000-2015. Second, Gini coefficient measures are

developed for cross-country income inequality from 1820 to 2015 and for each of the three types

of income inequality for 1960 to 2015. Third, the impact of the development process, the

accompanying demographic trends, and other factors that influence economic growth are used to

project the direction of income inequality in the decades immediately ahead.

Prior to 1970, demographic changes accompanying the development process contributed to

the sizeable increases in cross-country and worldwide income inequality. However, beginning in

the 1970s, changing demographic factors accompanying the development process led to a

leveling off and eventual reversal of the long-term trend. During 2000-2015, most developing

countries were in phases 2 and 3, where growth rates are higher, while the high-income countries

were moving into phase 4, where growth rates are lower. As a result, there was a dramatic

reduction in income inequality during 2000-2015. The recent changes are unprecedented: for the

first time in history, worldwide per capita income is increasing and income inequality is

declining. Further, dramatic reductions in transportation and communication costs have made it

possible for developing countries to achieve historically high growth rates. This transportation-

communication revolution accelerates the catch-up process. Interestingly, while many are

focusing on increases in within-country income inequality, the world is experiencing a dramatic

reduction in cross-country and worldwide income inequality.

This article is structured as follows: Section I examines the four phases of the development

process. Section II describes how a country’s phase of development can be identified and

explains why growth rates will differ across the four phases of development. Section III tracks

the per capita GDP of both modern high-income and developing countries during the past two

centuries and analyzes how changes in their income levels have impacted income inequality.

Page 3: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

3

Section IV derives Gini coefficient measures of income inequality for cross-country, within-

country, and the worldwide distribution of income. The Gini measures document both the nearly

two centuries of increasing income inequality prior to 2000 and the dramatic reversal of that

trend since the turn of the century. Section V explains why the recent reductions in worldwide

income inequality are highly likely to continue in the years immediately ahead and section VI

summarizes.

I. Four Phases of the Development Process

Economic development is a process. At least four different phases of this process are

observable.1

Phase 1 is the pre-development or Malthusian phase. It is characterized by low per capita

income and absence of sustainable economic growth. During this phase, the birth rate is high,

children and youthful teenagers comprise a large share of the population, while the share of

prime working-age adults is relatively small. It is a constant struggle to obtain adequate food,

clothing, and shelter, and few people survive to ages beyond 60 or 65 years. Prior to 1800, this

was the state of the world. According to Maddison [2007], the per capita income of the world

increased by only about 50 percent during the 800 years from 1000 to 1800.

Phase 2 is the initial growth phase. During this phase, sustainable growth occurs, and per

capita income rises. As income levels rise above subsistence, initially this will lead to more rapid

population growth. However, if the country is able to break out of the Malthusian phase and

sustain growth of per capita income, the higher income levels will eventually exert a negative

impact on the quantity of children, but a positive effect on investment in child development

[Becker 1960; Becker and Lewis 1973; Barro and Becker 1989; Doepke 2015; Lucas 2017]. As

per capita income increases, the opportunity cost of having children rises, leading to a reduction

in the birth rate, smaller family sizes, and slower growth of the youthful population. As a result,

through time prime working age adults become a larger share of the population, which also

contributes to the growth of per capita income. The growth of income and smaller family sizes

induce families to invest more time and resources on education, training, and other inputs

designed to improve the quality of children. This investment does not directly increase current

productivity, but it will have a payoff in the future.

Phase 3, it might be called the improved productivity phase, involves a gradual increase in

productivity as the generation with more schooling and training moves to adulthood. As the

higher-skill generation becomes a larger and larger share of the adult population, their higher

productivity will enhance the growth of per capita income. In turn, the higher income levels will

lead to a continuation of the falling birth rate, and decline in the young and increase in prime

working-age adults as a share of total population. These trends will also enhance the growth of

per capita income.

Phase 4 is the receding growth phase. During this phase, the share of population in the prime

age category begins to decline as those in the older age groups become a larger and larger share

of the total population. The productivity of those in the oldest age groupings will fall and many

1 Galor and Weil [2000] divide the development process into three periods instead of four—the Malthusian regime,

the post-Malthusian regime, and the modern growth regime. We use demographic changes and growth of per capita

GDP to identify movement through phases of development, while Galor and Weil focus on population growth and

human capital.

Page 4: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

4

will choose to retire from work activities. Both of these trends—a decline in prime working age

adults and increase in the elderly as a share of the total population—will reduce the long-term

growth of per capita income.

Our analysis of development as a process is closely related to that of Lucas (2004 & 2017).

Like Lucas, we seek to explain the Industrial Revolution and its impact on economic

development in the two centuries that followed. Lucas integrates two models: a Malthusian

model similar to our phase 1 and a human capital model similar to our phases 2 and 3. Lucas

recognizes that the transition from Malthusian stagnation to sustainable growth is complex,

lengthy, and still ongoing in some countries today. Our analysis is supportive of this view.

However, there are also important differences. First, we integrate the role of demographic

changes (increases in the share of population in the prime age category) as countries move out of

the Malthusian phase, while Lucas focuses on the role of migration from agriculture to urban

productive activities. Second, once started, we explain that favorable demographic changes will

interact with growth of per capita income in a manner that accelerates economic growth and

propels its continuation. Finally, our analysis also integrates another transition. As growth leads

to higher income levels and longer life expectancy, eventually the share of population in older

age groupings will increase and the share in the prime age category will decline, leading to a

slowdown in growth (phase 4).

Both economic theory and empirical research indicate that institutions and policies,

investment in human and physical capital, climate, location, and natural resources exert an

impact on development, per capita income, and growth. Development research has focused on

these factors as determinants of growth. But, research in this area has often ignored the

development process and the demographic changes accompanying it. While our focus is on the

development process, we recognize that several factors will influence the rate of growth at

various phases of development and the pattern and speed at which countries move through the

process. Our emphasis on development as a process is supplementary—it is designed to deepen

our understanding of growth and development issues. As will be shown, tracking the

development process enhances our understanding of historic trends and changes in worldwide

income inequality.

II. Identifying the Development Phase of Countries

How can the development phase of a country be identified? The income levels, growth rates,

and share of population in various age groups can help us do so. Data for real per capita GDP

from Maddison [2018], the Penn World Table [Feenstra et al. 2016] back to 1960, and World

Bank [2018] for 1980-2015 will be utilized to determine the income levels and growth rates of

countries. The population figures from the World Bank [2018] for 1960-2015, including the

share in various age groups, will be used for the demographic calculations. Data on economic

and political institutions are also available for a large number of countries since 1980. For

countries for which the institutional data are available back to 1980, the income and

demographic data are also available for 135 countries continuously since 1970 (and 110 since

1960). These 135 countries will constitute our primary data base. In 2015, the population of these

135 countries was 6.7 billion, 93 percent of the population of the world.2

2 Data for Taiwan are unavailable from the World Bank. Therefore, there is one fewer country in the World Bank

dataset.

Page 5: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

5

When a country is in phase 1, it will have a large share of population under age 15, a small

share in the prime working age 25-59, a low per capita income, and little or no economic growth

over a lengthy time period. If 40 percent or more of a country’s population is under age 15 or if

real per capita GDP (derived by the purchasing power parity method and measured in 2011

dollars) is less than $4 per day, the country will be placed in phase 1.

The share of population under age 15 in 2015 was 40 percent or more in 31 of the 135

countries for which the income data were available. In most of these 31 countries, this was the

case throughout 1960-2015.3 Moreover, in most of these countries, the percent of population in

the prime working-age 25-59 group was 35 percent or less in 2015 and throughout 1960-2015.

Thus, the age composition of these 31 countries indicates that they were in phase 1, the

Malthusian phase, throughout 1960-2015.

Insert Table 1 about here

Table 1 presents the per capita GDP and growth rates for these 31 countries for various

years and time periods during 1960-2015. As expected, the per capita GDP and growth rates of

these economies were exceedingly low. Measured in 2011 PPP dollars, only one (Zimbabwe) of

these countries had a per capita GDP of more than $2,700 in 1960. In 2015, the per capita GDP

of 24 of the 31 Malthusian economies was less than $3,000. Only three (Angola, Republic of

Congo, and Nigeria) of the 31 had a 2015 per capita GDP of more than $4,000. The 2015 per

capita real GDP was lower than in 1960 for ten of the 30 countries for which the data were

available in both years (Note: the GDP data were unavailable for Angola in 1960, and therefore

the growth data for periods including the 1960s are only available for 30 of the 31 countries).

The story was even more dismal for the 1960-2000 period. Twenty of the 30 Malthusian

economies had a lower per capita GDP in 2000 than 1960.4 During 1960-2000, the simple

average annual growth rate for the 30 phase 1 economies was -0.26 percent. The annual growth

rate of the population weighted per capita GDP for this group was even lower, -0.64 percent.

Only five of the 30 achieved a growth rate of 1 percent or more during this 40-year period. The

low per capita GDP and meager growth rates during 1960-2000 are indicative of countries in

phase 1 of the development process.

Why have the Malthusians failed to grow? There are several reasons for the stagnation of

these economies. The Malthusians are the most geographically disadvantaged countries in the

world [Gallup, Sachs, and Mellinger 1999; Sachs 2003]. Almost without exception, their climate

is hot, humid, and disease-prone. They are distant from the major markets of the world. In

addition, their economic institutions are characterized by poorly defined and insecure property

rights, restrictions on trade, and political intervention and corruption. Put simply, entrepreneurs

3 The only exceptions to this rule were Benin and Cameroon in 1960 and Central African Republic, Gambia, and

Sierra Leone in 1960 and 1965. In these cases, their share of population under age 15 was almost 40 percent and it

was increasing. 4 In contrast, only two (Ghana and Haiti) of the 83 non-Malthusian developing countries had a lower per capita

income in 2000 than 1960. One could argue that these two countries should have been included in the Malthusian

group. However, their population share under age 15 implies that Haiti transitioned out of phase 1 between 2000-

2005 and Ghana during 2010-2015.

Page 6: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

6

and investors—both domestic and foreign—will find it more attractive to engage in productive

activity elsewhere.5

How can you tell when a country is moving from phase 1 to phase 2? Both growth of per

capita GDP and changes in the age composition of the population provide the answer. When the

share of population under age 15 falls below 40 percent of the total, this is indicative of

movement from phase 1 to phase 2. As this happens, the prime age group as a share of total

population nearly always rises above 35 percent during the same period or in the near future.

Using the 40 percent under age 15 threshold as the dividing point, 65 developing countries

moved from phase 1 to phase 2 between 1960 and 2015. In 55 of these cases, the prime age

population increased above 35 percent of the total either during the same or following 5-year

period as the under age 15 share receded below 40 percent of the total. In nine of the ten

remaining cases, prime age adults as a share of total population moved above the 35 percent

threshold during the next five years. Thus, while reduction in the under age 15 population below

the 40 percent threshold is the criteria used to identify movement from phase 1 to phase 2, this

change is almost always accompanied by a rise of the prime-age population above 35 percent of

the total, either during the same period or in the near future. Finally, because strong sustained

growth would push per capita income well above subsistence levels, countries are not moved

into phase 2 unless they have a per capita GDP of more than $1,460 (4 dollars a day) in 2011

PPP dollars.

What makes it possible for a country to break out of Malthusian stagnation and begin the

growth process? Historically, several factors including improvements in institutions, price

increases for an important export resource, technological advancements, and population control

measures, have all contributed to the movement of countries from phase 1 to phase 2. Often, the

breakout from phase 1 reflects a combination of these factors.

A country will move from phase 2 to phase 3 as the generation with more schooling and

better training moves to adulthood. With a lag of perhaps two or three decades, the generation

with more schooling and training will begin to enter the labor force, which will increase

productivity as the country moves to phase 3. The movement from phases 2 to 3 is generally an

evolutionary process. The growth of per capita GDP, increases in the schooling of the young, and

length of phase 2 will differ among countries. Thus, the time of movement from phase 2 to phase

3 cannot be identified with a high degree of precision. Therefore, these two phases will be

combined in our empirical analysis.

In contrast with phase 1, countries in phases 2 and 3 will generally experience persistent

economic growth and rising levels of per capita income. Over a period of three, four, or even five

decades, the rising income levels, improvements in nutrition, health, sanitation, and similar

factors will lead to increases in life expectancy. As the elderly population become a larger and

larger share of the total, eventually the prime working-age population will begin to shrink, and

the country will move from phase 3 to phase 4. This will place a drag on the growth of per capita

5 Gallup, Sachs, and Mellinger [1999] provide country data on the share of population at risk of malaria in 1994. In

24 of the 31 Malthusian countries, 100 percent of the population was at risk of malaria. In six others, more than 60

percent of the population was at risk. Mauritania was the only Malthusian country without a high-risk of malaria.

With regard to institutions, none of the 31 Malthusian economies ranked in the top half among countries with an

economic freedom rating in 1995, and only two (Kenya and Uganda) did so in 2000 and 2005 [Gwartney, Lawson,

and Hall 2017].

Page 7: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

7

income. Thus, like phase 1, the growth rate of countries in phase 4 will generally be lower than

for phases 2 and 3.

In the early 1980s, the World Bank classified 21 countries as “high-income industrial”6. The

per capita GDP, growth rates, and demographic characteristics indicate that all 21 of these

countries were in either phases 2 or 3 of the development process during 1960-2000. However,

the situation began to change during the first decade of the 21st century. The share of population

in the prime working-age category began to decline, indicating movement into phase 4. When

the prime age population falls by 1.0 percent or more from its peak during a 5-year period, this is

indicative of a move from phase 3 to phase 4. By 2005, the share of population in the prime age

group of seven countries (Austria, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Japan, Netherlands, and

Sweden) in the high-income group had declined by at least one full percentage point. By 2010,

the prime working-age population of another nine countries (Australia, Belgium, Canada,

France, United Kingdom, Italy, Norway, New Zealand, and the United States) had also fallen by

one percentage point or more. By 2015, the prime working-age population of 19 of the 21 high-

income countries (Switzerland and Luxembourg were the exceptions) had fallen by a similar

amount.

Consider the implications of the development process. Once a country moves from phase 1

to phase 2, it enters a virtuous cycle. Growth of per capita income leads to a reduction in the

birth rate, which leads to a decline in the young and increase in prime working-age adults (25-

59) as a share of the population. In turn, this expansion in population share in the prime working-

age category propels additional growth.7 The declining share of children and higher earnings

both increase the incentive to invest in additional schooling and upgrade human capital, which

eventually leads to higher worker productivity during phase 3. Typically, the transition from

phase 1 through phases 2 and 3 will be a lengthy process, perhaps four or five decades.8 In

contrast with phase 1, countries in phases 2 and 3 of development will generally grow rapidly. Of

course, other factors such as counterproductive institutional change, political instability, or

unfavorable changes in the world price of an important resource could dampen growth, but the

potential for strong growth will be high during phases 2 and 3 of development. But, the virtuous

6 The 21 high income industrial countries were Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Switzerland, Germany,

Denmark, Spain, Finland, France, United Kingdom, Ireland, Iceland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg, Netherlands,

Norway, New Zealand, Sweden, and the United States. In the decades following World War II, these countries were

among the world’s richest. In 1960, the 17 countries with the highest per capita income in the world were all from

this set of 21. The four exceptions (Italy, Ireland, Spain, and Japan) ranked in the top 30.

7 Regression analysis was run with growth of per capita GDP as the dependent variable and lagged prime age adults

as a percent of the total as an independent variable for 1960-2015. Similarly, regressions were run with the prime

age population as a percent of the total as the dependent variable and lagged growth of per capita GDP as an

independent variable. Annual growth rates over both ten and fifteen-year periods were examined and lags of both 5

and 10 years were considered. This analysis was conducted with all 135 countries and with the 21 high-income

countries excluded, with and without per capita GDP at the beginning of the decade, and with level as well as

change in the demographic variable as independent variables. In all regressions the changes in the prime age

population exerted the predicted positive impact on subsequent growth of per capita GDP and the growth of per

capita GDP exerted the predicted positive impact on the subsequent change in prime age adults as a share of the total

population. The variables of interest were significant at the 1 percent level in all regressions. These findings are

highly consistent with our virtuous cycle hypothesis. 8 After countries moved out of phase 1, the increases in the prime age population as a share of the total were

consistent and large. The mean percentage point increases were 4.9 after ten years, 9.7 after twenty years, and 12.7

after thirty years.

Page 8: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

8

cycle will not last forever. Eventually, unfavorable demographic changes—an increase in the

elderly and reduction in prime working-age adults as a share of total population—will lead to a

slowdown in growth.

III. Phases of Development and Their Impact on Relative Incomes Across Countries

The 135 countries of our primary data set can be disaggregated into three separate groups:

(1) the 21 high-income industrial countries, (2) the 31 Malthusian economies that have remained

in phase 1 of development throughout 1960-2015, and (3) the 83 other developing economies.

Further, the 31 Malthusians and the 83 other developing countries might be combined, which

would result in a fourth group: 114 developing economies.

Table 2 presents data on the per capita GDP for each of the four groups and shows the per

capita GDP ratio of the high-income countries divided by the developing economies for various

years. Panel A uses the classic data set of Maddison [2018] to calculate per capita GDP in 2011

dollars back to 1820. The per capita GDP data were available for 16 of the high-income

countries in 1820, 1870, 1913, and 1950.9

The Maddison data prior to 1950 were also incomplete for developing countries. The per

capita GDP figures were available during 1820-1950 for only 36 of the 83 non-Malthusian

developing countries. Fortunately, the most populous developing countries (China, India,

Indonesia, Brazil, Mexico, Philippines, and Turkey) are included. Thus, the 36 developing

countries of the Maddison set comprise the bulk of the population (more than 90 percent) of the

non-Malthusian developing countries. Moreover, the 1950 per capita GDP figures indicate that

the 36 countries are highly representative of the entire group. The 1950 per capita GDP of the

group of 36 was $1,450 compared with $1,426 for the entire set of 83 countries. The data for

virtually all of the Malthusian countries are unavailable from Maddison prior to 1950. Thus, the

per capita GDP for the Malthusian group and all developing countries and the parallel income

ratios for years prior to 1950 are not included in panel A.

Insert Table 2 about here

In 1820, people throughout the world were poor. The high-income countries of the

Maddison dataset had a per capita GDP of $1,461 in 1820. By way of comparison, the per capita

GDP of the non-Malthusian developing countries was $821. As column 6 shows, the per capita

income of the high-income group was only 1.8 times that of the developing countries in 1820.

When most everyone is poor, the per capita income differences between the high and low-

income countries are relatively small.

During 1820-1950, the per capita GDP of the high-income countries of Western Europe,

North America, and Oceania grew more rapidly than the rest of the world. The per capita GDP of

the high-income group rose from $1,461 in 1820 to $2,506 in 1870 and $5,413 in 1913. By 1913,

the per capita income of the high-income group was 4.4 times that of the developing economies.

Moreover, the gap continued to widen. By 1950 the per capita GDP of the high-income

9 The five countries for which the data were unavailable are Iceland, Luxembourg, Belgium, New Zealand, and

Switzerland. Because these countries are small, their omission exerts only a minimal impact on the per capita GDP

of the high-income group. The data for 1950 illustrate this point. As Table 2, panel A shows, the per capita GDP for

the 16 high-income countries with data throughout 1820-1950 was $8,469 in 1950, compared to $8,464 for all of the

21 countries of the group.

Page 9: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

9

economies was 5.8 times ($8,469 compared to $1,450) that of the 36 developing countries with

data back to 1820. The 1950 per capita GDP figures for the broader groups of 21 high-income

and 83 developing countries were similar. The 1950 per capita GDP of the 21 high-income

countries was $8,464, 5.9 times the $1,426 figure for the 83 non-Malthusian developing

economies.

Exhibit II, panel A also presents the 1950-2015 Maddison data for the 21 high-income

countries and the developing groups. The per capita GDP of the 31 Malthusian and 83

developing countries were similar during 1950-1970. In 1970, the per capita GDP of the

Malthusians was $2,310 compared to $2,291 for the 83 developing countries. After 1970,

however, the income levels of the two groups followed a dramatically different path. By 1990,

the per capita GDP of the non-Malthusian group had risen to $3,676 while the parallel figure for

the Malthusians had declined to $2023. Further, by 2000 the per capita GDP of the non-

Malthusians had risen to $5,159 while the figure for the Malthusians had fallen to $1,483.

Panel A (columns 5, 6 and 7) use the Maddison data to derive the per capita GDP ratio of

the high-income to the three developing groups for 1950-2015. The per capita GDP ratio of the

high-income group divided by the 31 Malthusian countries (column 5) rose from 7.0 in 1950 to

8.6 in 1980, and then soared to a peak of 25.5 in 2000, before receding to 15.9 in 2015. The path

of the non-Malthusian developing group was similar during 1950-1970, but dramatically

different after 1970. The ratio of the high-income to the non-Malthusian developing group

(column 6) rose from 5.9 in 1950 to 7.7 in 1970 and 7.8 in 1990. However, since 1990, the ratio

has fallen sharply receding to 4.0 by 2015. Interestingly, the per capita GDP ratio of the high-

income to non-Malthusian developing economies was actually lower in 2015 than a century

earlier in 1913.

Exhibit 2 also presents the per capita GDP figures (in 2011 PPP dollars) for the Penn World

Table (panel b) for 1960-2015 and the World Bank (panel c) for 1980-2015. The Pattern is

similar to that for the Maddison data. Like the Maddison data, the Penn World Table and World

Bank figures indicate that the per capita GDP of the high-income countries divided by the

Malthusian group rose sharply during the final decades of the 20th century, but declined

substantially during 2000-2015. This ratio was approximately 16 in 2015. As Panels B and C

show, the ratio of the high-income to the other developing countries rose more slowly and it

peaked in 1990 and has declined sharply since, receding to approximately 4 in 2015.

The increasing ratio of the high-income group compared to the Malthusian economies

during 1960-2000 is not surprising. During these four decades, the 21 high-income countries

were all in phases 2 and 3 of development, while the Malthusians were all stuck in phase 1. As

our analysis of the development process indicates, growth rates are systematically higher in

phases 2 and 3 than phase 1.

All three of the data sets indicate there has been a dramatic change in the ratio of the per

capita GDP of the high-income countries relative to their developing counterparts since 2000.

What accounts for the reversal of the trend toward greater inequality, a trend that had persisted

for at least two centuries? Since 2000, most of the 21 high-income countries have moved from

phase 3 to phase 4, where growth rates are lower. In contrast, all of the 83 non-Malthusian

developing countries had moved out of the Malthusian phase by 2000 into phases 2 and 3, where

growth rates are higher. At the same time, some of the 31 Malthusian economies are showing

signs of breaking out of phase 1 and moving into phase 2 (see Table 1). Thus, their growth rates

Page 10: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

10

have been stronger during 2000-2015. This combination of factors accounts for the declining

ratio of the per capita GDP of the high-income to Malthusian countries during 2000-2015.

When all of the 114 developing countries are included (Table 2, column 7), the ratio of the

high-income to developing economies is slightly higher, but the pattern is the same as for the 83

non-Malthusian developing countries. In both cases (and for all three of the data sets), the per

capita GDP ratio of the high-income countries relative to developing economies declined during

1990-2015. Moreover, the 2015 ratio is lower than in 1960 and about the same as the ratio for the

Maddison data in 1913, illustrating that the degree of inequality between the high and low-

income countries in 2015 is not much different than the situation a century ago.

Most people believe that beginning around 1800, the Industrial Revolution started to

transform the world. This was certainly true for the approximately 15 percent of the world’s

population living in Western Europe, North America, and Oceania. As the Maddison data

(Exhibit 2, panel A) show, the per capita GDP of the high-income countries rose by a whopping

480 percent during the 130 years following 1820. But the change was much less transformative

in the rest of the world. The per capita GDP of the developing countries rose by only 76

percent—less than half a percent annually—during this 130-year period. The $1,450 per capita

GDP of the non-Malthusian developing countries in 1950 was virtually the same as the $1,461

per capita income of the high-income countries in 1820. Further, the stagnation of the 31

Malthusian economies continued for another 50 years. Measured in 2011 dollars, the per capita

GDP of the Malthusian countries was approximately $1500 in 2000 (see panels A, B, and C),

virtually the same as the 1820 figure of the high-income countries nearly two centuries earlier at

the beginning of the Industrial Revolution. In summary, the lives of the 85 percent of the world’s

population living in developing countries were only marginally affected during the century and a

half following the Industrial Revolution. They did a little better during this period than prior to

1800, but not much.

Thus, the transformative growth of the developing economies is a relatively recent

phenomenon. For the non-Malthusian developing economies, it started during the last three

decades of the 20th century, as more and more of these economies moved from phase 1 to phase

2 of development. In 1960 and 1970, three-fourths of the world’s population still lived in

countries that were in the Malthusian phase and only one-fourth in countries that had moved to

phases 2 and 3. By 2000, however, 83 percent of the world’s population resided in countries that

had moved to phases 2 and 3 of development and the figure soared to 88 percent by 2015.

Meanwhile, after the turn of the century, the high-income countries were moving into phase 4,

where growth rates are slower. This combination—most of the developing world in phases 2 and

3 and the high-income countries in phase 4—is closing the income gap between the high and

low-income countries. We now turn to the measurement of how these changes have impacted

worldwide income inequality.

IV. Gini Coefficient Measurement and Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2015

It is important to distinguish between income inequality (1) among countries and (2) within

a country. When most people discuss income inequality, they generally focus on the latter. This

is understandable because political decision-making typically does not extend beyond country

borders. Thus, worldwide income inequality—inequality in the distribution of worldwide

income—is often ignored by the news media, policy-makers, and political commentators.

Page 11: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

11

However, the world is increasingly interrelated and there is more interaction of people

across national boundaries. This elevates the importance of worldwide income inequality.

Further, income differences across countries are substantially greater than those within any

specific country. Thus, worldwide inequality may be an even more important welfare

consideration than inequality within countries. This section will develop three measures of

income inequality. The first is a measure of cross-country inequality, assuming that individual

incomes within each country are equal to the country’s per capita GDP. The second is a measure

of within-country inequality, assuming that all countries have the same per capita GDP as that of

the World. The third is a measure of worldwide inequality that reflects both cross-country

income differences and income differences within each country. All measures will be developed

across time, making it possible to compare inequality over a period of nearly two centuries.

The Gini coefficient is a measure of the degree of income inequality among individuals or

groups. When income is arrayed from low to high, the Gini curve outlines how the cumulative

share of received income changes as the cumulative share of the population increases. The Gini

coefficient ranges from zero to one, where zero represents perfect income equality and one

indicates that a single individual (or entity) receives all the income. Thus, increases in the size of

the Gini coefficient indicate more inequality—a larger share of the total income is received by a

smaller percentile of the population.

IV.A. Methodology

The main ingredient to calculate cross-country income inequality (income inequality among

countries) is their mean income per capita. Comparable measures of cross-country per capita

GDP are available from 1820 to 2015. This allows us to compute the first form of inequality,

among countries, for nearly two centuries. To calculate the second type of inequality, within

countries, the main ingredient is a comparable measure of dispersion for the incomes of

individuals or households living in each country. A comprehensive effort to collect, combine,

and standardize these data has recently been completed by Solt [2016] who constructed the

Standardized World Income Inequality Database (SWIID). The SWIID provides comparable

Gini indices of income inequality for 192 countries, for as many years as possible, from 1960 to

2015. The SWIID “offers coverage double that of the next largest income inequality data set, and

its record of comparability is three to eight times better than those of alternate data sets [Solt

2016, 1].” The SWIID allows us to compute the second form of inequality, within-country, for

nearly six decades.

The next challenge is to combine the cross-country and within-country inequalities to derive

a worldwide income inequality. The main ingredient for this step is to assume a distributional

form to gradually allocate the total income of each country (the per capita GDP multiplied by its

population) among cumulative population shares in a way that is consistent with both the per

capita GDP and the Gini coefficient. The usual assumption is that the income per capita is log-

normally distributed within a country.10 In other words, the natural logarithm of the per capita

10 See for example Pinkovskiy and Sala-i-Martin [2009], Sala-i-Martin and Pinkovskiy [2010], and Hellebrandt and

Mauro [2015]. Some have questioned the appropriateness of the log normal income distribution assumption [Lopez

and Servén 2006; Chen and Ravallion 2010]. These authors have suggested that the assumption of log normality

may be too strong when the income data is generated from surveys based on consumption expenditures. The SWIID

uses survey data of this type. However, our analysis focuses on trends in income inequality and any inaccuracy

introduced by this assumption will not introduce a systematic bias. The same trend of increased global inequality

Page 12: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

12

GDP of individuals within a country follows a normal distribution. Aitchison and Brown [1957]

show that, under this assumption, the Gini coefficient (𝐺𝑖) and the within-country standard

deviation (𝜎𝑖) for the log-income are related by the formula 𝜎𝑖 = √2Φ−1 (1+𝐺𝑖

2), where Φ is the

cumulative standard normal distribution. Furthermore, Young [2011] provides a way to calculate

the Gini coefficient for the mixture of log-normal distributions for countries, even if the mixture,

the worldwide distribution of income, is not log-normal. Young’s formula is not only accurate

(as it replicates almost identically the global inequality estimates of Sala-i-Martin [2006]) but it

is also fast, and it provides an intuitive way to decompose global inequality into its cross-country

and within-country components. The three aggregate measures of inequality are calculated,

mathematically, as follows:

𝐺𝑖𝑛𝑖𝐶𝑟𝑜𝑠𝑠−𝐶𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑦 = ∑∑𝑤𝑖𝑤𝑗𝑌𝑖

𝑌

𝑁

𝑗=1

𝑠𝑖𝑔𝑛(𝑌𝑖 − 𝑌𝑗)

𝑁

𝑖=1

,

(1);

𝐺𝑖𝑛𝑖𝑊𝑖𝑡ℎ𝑖𝑛−𝐶𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡𝑟𝑦 = ∑∑𝑤𝑖𝑤𝑗

𝑁

𝑗=1

(2Φ [1

2√𝜎𝑖

2 + 𝜎𝑗2] − 1) ,

𝑁

𝑖=1

(2);

𝐺𝑖𝑛𝑖𝐺𝑙𝑜𝑏𝑎𝑙 = ∑∑𝑤𝑖𝑤𝑗𝑌𝑖

𝑌

𝑁

𝑗=1(

[ ln(𝑌𝑖) − ln(𝑌𝑗) + 0.5𝜎𝑖

2 + 0.5𝜎𝑗2

√𝜎𝑖2 + 𝜎𝑗

2

]

− 1

)

,

𝑁

𝑖=1

(3);

where 𝑤𝑖 is the share of population of country 𝑖, 𝑌𝑖 is the per capita GDP of country 𝑖, and 𝑌 is

the per capita GDP for the world. Note that one can think of the cross-country inequality as a

case in which all individuals within each country have the same per capita GDP as that of the

country, that is 𝜎𝑖2 = 0. Similarly, the within-country inequality is a special case in which there

are no per capita GDP differences among countries (that is, 𝑌𝑖 = 𝑌 for all i) and therefore all the

inequality stems from differences in individual incomes within the countries.

Table 3 (column 1, panel A) presents the cross-country Gini coefficient for various years

from 1820 to 2015. Note, the Gini coefficient in 1820 was very low, 0.235. This is not

surprising, as people throughout the world were poor in 1820 and the mean income differences

between the high and low-income countries were relatively small. During the 93 years that

followed, the per capita GDP of the high-income countries grew at an annual rate of 1.4 percent,

compared to 0.4 percent for the rest of the world. Even though the growth of per capita income

was slow, and the differential looks small, growth substantially increased cross-country income

differences over the 93 years. Thus, the cross-country Gini coefficient increased to 0.394 in 1870

and 0.495 in 1913. As the high-income countries continued to grow more rapidly than those with

before 2000 and decreasing inequality thereafter is present in other analysis of global income inequality [Milonovic

2016; Bourguignon 2015]. Moreover, Young [2011] compared the inequality estimates using the log normality

assumption with several other measures of inequality and found the estimates to be quite accurate.

Page 13: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

13

lower per capita income, the cross-country Gini coefficient increased to 0.585 in 1950 and 0.586

in 1960.

Insert Table 3 about here

Between 1960 and 1990, the cross-country Gini coefficient fluctuated in a narrow range

between 0.586 and 0.604. After 1990 however, the cross-country Gini coefficient declined

sharply from 0.594 in 1990 to 0.575 in 2000 and 0.466 in 2015. Thus, the Gini coefficient

indicates that cross-country income differences increased substantially over the 140 years from

1820 to 1960, stabilized around 0.600 during 1960-1990 before declining sharply after 1990,

particularly during the first 15 years of this century. The 2015 cross-country Gini coefficient of

0.466 was lower than the parallel figure for 1913, indicating that income inequality among

countries today is lower than it was a century ago.

The SWIID data providing the within-country Gini coefficients are unavailable prior to

1960. Therefore, the within-country and worldwide Gini can only be derived for years since

1960. In addition, the SWIID data provide the within-country Gini coefficient for both market

income (before taxes and transfers) and disposable income (after taxes and transfers). Thus, it is

possible to calculate the within-country and worldwide Gini coefficients for both market and

disposable income. Taxes and transfers generally reduce income inequality. As a result, the Gini

coefficients for disposable income are smaller (indicating less inequality) than the parallel Gini

for market income.

Table 3, panel A, presents the within-country Gini coefficients for both market income

(column 2) and disposable income (column 3) at five-year intervals for 1960-2015. The within-

country Gini coefficient for both market and disposable income rose during 1960-2015. For

market income, the Gini coefficient rose slightly from 0.405 in 1960 to 0.411 in 1980, but more

substantially to 0.468 in 2015. While the Gini for disposable income was smaller, it followed a

similar path, rising from 0.354 in 1960 to 0.361 in 1980 and 0.410 in 2015. Thus, the within-

country Gini coefficient for both market income and disposable income rose by approximately

six hundredths of a point over the 55 years. This increase indicates that, on average, inequality of

both market and disposable income within countries has been rising during the past several

decades.

Panel A of Table 3 also provides the worldwide Gini coefficient of market income (column

4) and disposable income (column 5) at five-year intervals during 1960-2015. The worldwide

Gini coefficient reflects both cross-country and within-country income inequality. Again, the

Gini coefficient is smaller for disposable income than market income, indicating that taxes and

transfers reduce income inequality.

The worldwide Gini coefficient for both market and disposable income rose between 1960

and 1980, was relatively stable between 1980-2000, but declined sharply thereafter. In the case

of market income, the Gini coefficient increased from 0.685 in 1960 to 0.700 in 1980 and 0.690

in 2000. The worldwide Gini for disposable income rose by a similar amount from 0.657 in 1960

to 0.672 in 1980 and 0.661 in 2000. These figures indicate that the 160-year upward trend in

worldwide inequality continued through 1980 before stabilizing during the last two decades of

the 20th century.

Page 14: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

14

Since 2000, however, there has been a dramatic reversal. The worldwide Gini coefficients

for both market and disposable income have declined sharply, indicating a substantial reduction

in worldwide income inequality. The worldwide Gini coefficient for market income declined

from 0.690 in 2000 to 0.672 in 2005, 0.644 in 2010 and 0.627 in 2015. Thus, while the

worldwide Gini coefficient for market income rose by 0.014 during 1960-1990, it fell by an even

larger amount, 0.072 during the quarter of a century that followed. Moreover, the Gini

coefficient of disposable income followed a similar pattern. In 1990, the worldwide disposable

income Gini was 0.671, but it declined to 0.641 in 2005 and 0.586 in 2015.11 Thus, after

increasing by 1.4 hundredths of a point during 1960-1990, the worldwide Gini fell by 8.5

hundredths of a point during 1990-2015.

The Gini data of panel A are for the 135 countries of our primary database. This set of

countries covers approximately 93 percent of the world’s population. Following the collapse of

communism, a number of new countries were formed. Because the GDP data for these countries

were not available continuously back to 1970, they are not included in our primary database.

Both the SWIID and Maddison data are available for 157 countries back to 1990. These

countries constitute 96 percent of the world’s population. In order to verify that the Gini

measures are not biased by the omission of countries, we also calculated the Gini coefficients for

the larger set of 157 countries for years ending in zero or five during 1990-2015.

Table 3, panel B, presents these results. Unsurprisingly, given the large overlap of the two

populations, the results for the 157 countries (panel B) are very similar to the figures for our

primary dataset (panel A). The cross-country Gini coefficient for the larger set of countries were

slightly lower for all years, while the within country Gini coefficients were virtually identical for

the two datasets. As a result, the worldwide Gini coefficient for the larger set of countries were a

little lower. These patterns were present for both the market and disposable income Gini

coefficients. Most importantly, the Gini coefficients of panel B, like those of panel A, indicate

that there was little change in worldwide income inequality during the 1990s, but this was

followed by a sharp reduction in worldwide income inequality during 2000-2015. This was true

for both the market and disposable income Gini coefficients. While the worldwide Gini

coefficients are slightly lower for the larger set of countries, their pattern is identical to the

figures of panel A. Both illustrate that there has been a substantial reduction in worldwide

income inequality during the first 15 years of this century.

Milanovic [2016] and Bourguignon [2015] also described the rise of global income

inequality prior to 2000 and the subsequent decline. They argue that the recent reduction in

worldwide inequality was the result of globalization and express uncertainty about the

11 Some might believe that an increase in within-country inequality and, at the same time, a reduction in worldwide

income inequality is paradoxical. This is not the case because cross-country income differences also exert an impact

on overall income inequality. Consider the example of the United States and China. Within-country income

inequality increased substantially in both countries between 1980 and 2015. Using the disposable income figures,

the Gini coefficient for within-country inequality of the United States increased from 0.316 in 1980 to 0.380 in

2015. Similarly, the within-country Gini coefficient for China rose from 0.290 in 1980 to 0.401 in 2015. During this

period, however, the per capita income of China grew rapidly relative to the United States. The cross-country Gini

coefficient declined sharply from 0.618 in 1980 to 0.296 in 2015. As a result, the overall income differences among

households declined in the unified U.S.-China group. The unified Gini coefficient for the two countries combined

fell from 0.712 in 1980 to 0.512 in 2015. In recent decades, the per capita income of developing countries,

particularly the non-Malthusians, has risen relative to high-income countries. This cross-country reduction in income

inequality has more than offset the increases in within-country inequality in some countries.

Page 15: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

15

continuation of this trend. Our analysis indicates that it is not globalization per se, but rather the

demographic changes accompanying the growth process that underlie the rise and fall of income

inequality. A pattern similar to ours was also found by Hellebrandt and Mauro [2015]. Based on

growth rate projections, they forecast that the recent reductions in income inequality will

continue. Our research indicates that demographic changes underlie the rise and fall of

worldwide income inequality. We now turn to the explanation of why the recent trend is likely to

continue.

V. Five Reasons Why the Recent Reduction in Income Inequality Will Continue

Both the per capita GDP of high-income countries compared to developing economies and

the Gini measure of income inequality indicate that the gap between those with high and low

incomes has narrowed at least since 2000. Will the trend toward less income inequality continue?

There are at least five reasons to believe that it will.

Reason 1: In the years immediately ahead, the overwhelming share of the developing

economies will be in phases 2 and 3 of the development process where growth rates are higher,

while high-income countries will be in phase 4 where growth rates are lower.

Table 4 shows the number of the 114 developing and 21 high-income countries by phase of

development, 1960-2035. The population share for each of the groups is shown in parentheses.

The 1960-2015 figures are based on the actual population estimates from the World Bank

[2018], while the 2015-2035 figures are based on the medium fertility variant population

projections of the United Nations Population Division [2017].

Since 1970, there has been steady movement of the 114 developing economies from phase 1

to phase 2. There were 94 of the developing economies (93.8 percent of their population) in

phase 1 in 1970, and only 20 (6.2 percent of their population) in either phases 2 or 3. By 2000,

however, the number of developing economies in phases 2 or 3 had risen to 65 (79.8 percent of

their population) while the number in phase 1 had fallen to 49 (20.2 percent of their population).

In 2015, 75 developing economies (84.0 percent of their population) were in either phases 2 or 3,

eight others (1.8 percent of their population) had moved to phase 4, and only the 31 Malthusians

(14.2 percent of their population) remained in phase 1.12 As our analysis indicates, when

countries move from phase 1 to phase 2, they begin a virtuous cycle of declining birth rates,

falling share of population under age 15, and increasing share of population in the prime

working-age category, which leads to an acceleration in growth. This was a major contributing

factor to the acceleration in the growth rate of the non-Malthusian developing economies during

1960-2015.

Insert Table 4 about here

Table 4 also shows the share of population of the high-income countries by phase of

development during 1960-2015. All of the high-income countries were in either phases 2 or 3

prior to 2000. But, there was a dramatic change during the first 15 years of this century. By 2015,

12 The eight developing economies that moved into phase 4 by 2015 were Barbados, Hong Kong, Hungary, Malta,

Portugal, Qatar, Singapore, and Thailand. These were among the earliest developing countries to move from phase 1

to phase 2.

Page 16: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

16

19 of the 21 high-income countries (99 percent of their population) had moved to phase 4 and the

other 2 (Switzerland and Luxembourg) are expected to do so by 2020.

As the share of population in phases 2 and 3 of the developing countries increased during

1960-2015, the growth of their per capita income rose. All of the high-income countries were in

phases 2 or 3 throughout 1960-2000 and the growth rates of these economies were also strong.

Since 2000, however, the share of population of the high-income group in phase 4 of

development has soared and, as expected, the growth of their per capita income has declined

substantially. Therefore, the developing countries have grown more rapidly and narrowed the

income gap relative to the high-income countries since 2000. The population projections for

2015-2035 indicate that the population share living in developing countries in phases 2 and 3 of

development will remain large, while all of the population of the high-income countries will be

in phase 4 by 2020. Because growth rates are higher in phases 2 and 3 than phase 4, the pattern

of more rapid growth of the developing countries compared to their high-income counterparts

can be expected to continue. In turn, this will result in the continuation of declining world-wide

income inequality.

Figure 1 illustrates how the movement of countries through the phases of development,

depicted by Table 4, impacts the share of population in the prime working-age 25-59 category

for the 21 high-income, 83 developing, and 31 Malthusian countries. The prime age ratio is

important because an increase in the prime age population as a share of the total will tend to

enhance growth, while a decline will retard it.

Insert Figure 1 about here

For the high-income group, the share of population in the prime age category was relatively

constant during the 1960s, but it rose substantially from 42.4 percent in 1970 to 49.0 in 2000.

However, as more and more of the high-income countries moved to phase 4 during 2000-2015,

the prime age population share has steadily fallen from its peak of 49 percent in 2000 to 46.9

percent in 2015 and it is expected to decline to 44.1 percent in 2035. Thus, it rose by 6.6

percentage points between 1970 and 2000, but it is projected to fall by 4.8 percentage points

between 2000 and 2035.

Turning to the figures for the 83 non-Malthusian developing countries, their prime working-

age population declined from 36.6 percent in 1960 to 33.9 percent in 1975. However, during the

four decades following 1975, the prime age population of the non-Malthusian developing

countries rose steadily to 47.5 percent in 2015, a whopping 13.6 percentage points. By 2015, the

prime-age population as a share of the total of these developing economies was greater than the

parallel figure for the high-income countries. During 2015-2035, the prime age share is projected

to rise briefly, but by 2035 it is expected to recede to the level of 2015.

As Figure 1 shows, the prime age share of the 31 Malthusian economies is substantially

lower than for either of the other two groups. The ratio of prime age to total population of the

Malthusian economies fell from 33.5 percent in 1960 to 30.1 percent in 2000. In contrast, it rose

from 30.1 percent in 2000 to 31.5 percent in 2015 and it is projected to rise another 4.6

percentage points by 2035.

Figure 2 reflects how the demographic changes of Figure 1 impact the growth rates of the

three groups. The fifteen-year moving average growth of per capita GDP is shown for the high-

Page 17: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

17

income, developing, and Malthusian country groups for the period 1965-2015.13 From 1965 to

1975 the high-income countries have a higher growth rate than the other two groups. The

average annual growth rate over the period for the high-income group was just above 4 percent

while the growth rate for the developing countries trended between 2 and 3 percent. As more and

more of the non-Malthusian developing countries moved to phases 2 and 3 of development and

the share of their population in the prime working age increased between 1975 and 2000, the

growth of their per capita GDP began to outpace the high-income countries.

Insert Figure 2 about here

The prime age population as a share of the total increased substantially for both developing

country groups during 2000-2015, while the parallel share of the high-income countries was

declining. These shifts contributed to the stronger growth of developing countries relative to their

high-income counterparts. Moreover, the prime age population of both groups of developing

economies will continue to rise relative to the high-income countries for at least two more

decades.14 This pattern of demographic changes will lead to a continuation of the more rapid

growth of the developing economies relative to high-income countries in the years immediately

ahead.

Reason 2: Because low-income countries can emulate advanced technologies and successful

business practices of high-income countries, they are able to grow more rapidly than their higher

income counterparts. The lower transportation and communication costs of recent decades have

enhanced the gains from this source.

Discovery of new, improved technologies and better ways of doing things are an important

source of growth and development. Advanced economies invest billions in research and

technological development designed to improve products and reduce production cost. The

advanced technologies and successful business practices of high-income countries provide an

important secondary benefit for developing countries. Businesses and entrepreneurs in

developing countries can merely copy (or adopt at a low cost) the successful technologies and

practices of the more advanced economies. Moreover, the reductions in transportation and

communication costs of recent decades accelerates the transmission and enlarges the gains from

this source.

As the result of lower transportation costs and improved communications, there is now more

exchange of both goods and ideas between people living in high and low-income countries than

at any time in history. Consider how just one change, albeit an important one, the development

of the standardized steel shipping container, has impacted international trade and the well-being

of people living in countries distant from major markets. Because these containers are

standardized in size and design, thousands of them can be stacked on large ships, and transported

at a low cost to ports throughout the world. Upon arrival, machines can lift them on to rail cars

and trucks for transport to inland distribution centers and manufacturing facilities. As a result,

13 The data cover the period 1950-2015, but the graph begins in 1965 due to the fifteen-year moving average. 14 The working-age population as a share of the total presented in Figure 1 is based on the population weighted

means. Because the population weighted means might be driven by a few large countries such as China and India,

we also derived parallel graphics using the simple means. The pattern based on the simple mean values was similar

to the pattern for the population weighted means, indicating that the demographic changes were widespread among

the countries in the three groups.

Page 18: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

18

international transport costs have been reduced by an estimated 75 percent during the past four

decades.15

Of course, the reductions in transport and communication costs increase the gains from trade

and specialization for people throughout the world. But, they are particularly advantageous to

developing countries because they facilitate their integration into world markets. This integration

makes it possible for previously isolated regions to attract investment, obtain productive inputs,

adopt advanced technologies, emulate successful business practices, and use their unique

resources to produce goods and services for consumers throughout the world.

During the past 50 years, the world has experienced something like the Industrial

Revolution: the transportation-communication revolution. Like the Industrial Revolution, the

more recent revolution has expanded opportunities and enhanced economic growth. But the two

revolutions differ in their impact on inequality. As we previously discussed, the Industrial

Revolution resulted in substantial income gains for about 15 percent of the World’s population,

but the affect was minimal in the rest of the world. In contrast, the impact of the transportation-

communication revolution is exerting a broader impact—it is changing the developing world

even more than the developed economies.16 Today, more than at any time in history, people

living in developing countries have an opportunity to trade with and benefit from interaction with

those living in the high-income developed world. As a result, developing countries are able to

both grow more rapidly than their high-income counterparts and achieve highly impressive

growth rates. Thus, the transportation-communication revolution is reducing rather than

increasing worldwide income inequality.

In recent decades, almost all of the high-growth economies have been developing countries.

Consider the number of countries that have achieved per capita GDP growth greater than 5

percent in recent decades. Using the Maddison [2018] data, 5 countries achieved this threshold

during the 1980s, and all were developing countries. In the 1990s, the per capita GDP of 7

countries grew at an annual rate greater than 5 percent, and all but one were developing

countries. During 2000-2010, a whopping 18 countries achieved annual growth of per capita

GDP greater than 5 percent and all were developing countries. Finally, thirteen countries had

average annual growth rates of 4 percent of more during the quarter of a century, 1990-2015. All

13 were developing countries.

Moreover, developing countries today are able to achieve growth rates beyond what was

thought to be possible only a few decades ago. Growth rates above 2 percent for lengthy time

periods were largely absent prior to 1950. The annual real growth rates of per capita GDP of the

United Kingdom and United States, the most prosperous of the high-income economies during

the 1800s, were 1.0 percent and 1.4 percent, respectively. During the 12 decades from 1820 to

1940, the growth of per capita GDP during a decade never exceeded 3 percent in either the

United Kingdom or United States.

15 Glaeser and Kohlhase [2004] analyze the impact of reductions in transportation costs on the allocation of

populations within regions. They estimate transportation costs have declined by more than 90 percent during the 20th

century. 16 The breadth of the transportation-communication revolution is illustrated by the experience of the 83 non-

Malthusian developing countries. These countries which comprise approximately three-fourths of the world’s

population, generated 27.8 percent of world GDP in 1960, 34.9 percent in 1980, 40.4 percent in 2000, and 56.6

percent in 2015. This increase in the relative contribution of these economies to world GDP has been remarkable.

Page 19: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

19

It is informative to compare the high growth rates achieved by many developing countries

since 1960 with the modest growth rates of the earlier era. The per capita GDP of Hong Kong

grew at an annual rate of 4.9 percent during the 40 years from 1960 to 2000. The growth rate of

Singapore was even more impressive, 5.7 percent during the same 40-year period. During the 50

years of 1965-2015, the per capita GDP of South Korea and Botswana grew at annual rates of

5.8 percent and 5.4 percent, respectively. Still more recently, the per capita GDP of China rose at

an annual rate of 5.9 percent during 1980-2015 and India at a 4.8 percent annual rate during

1990-2015.

The high-growth rates of a substantial number of developing economies during recent

decades stand in stark contrast with both those of today’s high-income countries and the growth

rates of the past. These high-growth rates are transforming the world. They are being driven by

low-cost transport of goods and transmission of information and technology. Further, these gains

will continue for the foreseeable future.

Reason 3: The developing economies are adopting institutions and policies more consistent

with growth and prosperity

In the past, counterproductive policies and institutions have undermined the potential of

many developing economies. However, there has been substantial improvement in the

institutional quality of developing countries in recent decades.

Table 5 presents data on several measures of institutional quality for our 114 developing

countries at five-year intervals for 1980-2015. The mean summary economic freedom of the

world rating is presented in column 1 [Gwartney, Lawson, and Hall 2017]. This comprehensive

measure of economic institutions is based on ratings ranging from zero to ten for 42 different

components. Higher ratings indicate institutions and policies more consistent with economic

freedom. The mean summary rating of developing countries rose steadily from 4.84 in 1980 to

6.30 in 2000, and 6.62 in 2015.

Insert Table 5 about here

In addition to the country summary ratings, the Economic Freedom of the World data

provide ratings for five major areas, including legal structure and protection of property rights,

access to sound money, and international exchange. Both economic theory and prior research

indicate that a legal system that provides for the protection of property rights and unbiased

enforcement of contracts is a highly important ingredient for economic growth and development.

The Economic Freedom of the World legal structure data provide a measure of this factor. As

Table 5, column 2 shows, the mean legal structure rating of the developing countries rose from

3.72 in 1980 to 4.58 in 2000, and 4.82 in 2015. Table 5 also shows the mean ratings for access to

sound money (column 3) and international exchange (column 4). The monetary rating rose

sharply from 5.59 in 1980 to 8.04 in 2015. The mean rating for international exchange followed

a similar path, increasing from 4.09 in 1980 to 6.77 in 2015. Like the summary ratings, the

ratings for these institutional categories of the developing countries show substantial

improvement throughout 1980-2015, particularly in the monetary and international trade areas.

The Freedom House [2017] political rights (column 5) and Polity IV [Marshall, Gurr, and

Jaggers 2016] democracy ratings (column 6) are also presented in Table 5. Like the economic

freedom measures, these political measures also improved substantially. The mean political

Page 20: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

20

rights measure, in a scale ranging from 1 (least free) to 7 (most free), rose from 3.1 in 1980 to

4.23 in 2015. The polity IV mean rating, in a scale ranging from -10 (strongly autocratic) to +10

(strongly democratic) rose from -3.43 in 1980 to +3.69 in 2015. Thus, the mean rating for this

variable indicates a substantial shift from authoritarian regimes toward democracy during 1980-

2015.

Clearly, the developing countries now have both freer economies and more democratic

political institutions than was the case in 1980. These institutional improvements have

accelerated the growth of developing economies in recent decades.17 Moreover, incentives

impact the development of institutions. The classic article of Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson

[2001] highlights this point. As the authors stressed, institutions protecting private property

rights and restraining the powers of the executive were more likely to emerge when colonizing

settlers planned for permanent settlement. Similar forces are currently at work. The

transportation-communication revolution enhances the incentive for developing countries to

adopt sound economic institutions. When lower transport and communication costs increase the

potential gains derived from trade openness, a sound legal system, monetary stability, and

integration into the world market network, businesses, investors, and political decision-makers

will have a stronger incentive to support such policies. The recent institutional improvements of

developing countries shown in Table 5 may already be reflective of this point. The payoff for

developing countries, particularly those distant from major markets, derived from sound

institutions is currently greater than was the case three or four decades ago. This positive change

in incentives increases the probability developing countries will maintain and improve the

quality of their institutions in the future.

Reason 4: The secondary school enrollment and completion rates of young people in

developing economics have increased sharply in recent decades. As these young people move

into the prime working age category, the productivity of the labor force in developing countries

will improve, and thereby contribute to more rapid growth.

Table 6 presents data on the Barro and Lee [2013] secondary schooling enrollment rates for

those age 15 to 19 years and the secondary schooling completion rates for persons age 20 to 24

for the developing economies and the Malthusians for 1960-2010. The secondary schooling

enrollment rate of 15 to 19-year-olds rose from 17.0 percent in 1960 to 37.0 percent in 1980, and

59.5 percent in 2010. The completion rates followed a similar path, rising from 5.9 percent in

1960 to 16.4 percent in 1980, and 34.2 percent in 2010. Of course, the parallel figures for the

Malthusian countries were lower, but they have also increased steadily and substantially over the

50-year period. As these young people move into the work force in the decades immediately

ahead, their increases in schooling will enhance productivity and contribute to the future

economic growth of developing countries.

Insert Table 6 about here

Hanushek and Woessmann [2008; 2010; 2012] emphasize the role of educational quality, as

opposed to quantity, for economic growth. The transportation-communication revolution

provides low-cost access to the highest quality education available in the world. Initiatives such

as MIT OpenCourseWare, Coursera, Edx, Codecademy, Moz, and Youtube illustrate this point.

17 For evidence that institutions exert a positive impact on economic growth see: Barro [1991], Barro [1997],

Gwartney, Holcombe, and Lawson [2006], Shleifer [2009], and Acemoglu et al. [forthcoming].

Page 21: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

21

The availability of these technologies is a recent phenomenon bringing a broad, worldwide,

access to high-quality education, a faster diffusion of ideas, and a reduction of disparities in the

level and quality of human capital that is attainable. These opportunities will likely accelerate the

catch-up growth for developing countries entering in phases 2 and 3 of the development process

in the years immediately ahead.

Furthermore, the Malthusian escape process can also be thought of as a transition from

physical capital to human capital [Tamura 1996; Galor and Weil 2000; Galor 2011]. First, the

human capital accumulation is both a cause and a consequence of the transition, enhancing

technological progress. This will push the country into a virtuous cycle of phases 2 and 3 of the

development process. As both the quantity and quality of educational opportunities increase, the

Malthusian escape will accelerate. Second, as technological progress continues to rise and the

costs of high-quality educational opportunities continue to decline, a larger set of countries and a

broader share of their population will have greater access and opportunity to develop their human

capital. While the Industrial Revolution increased inequality by concentrating physical capital in

the hands of a few in a selected group of countries, the transportation-communication revolution

is reducing inequality by providing broader, and more disperse, access to high-quality education

across the globe.

Reason 5: Improvements in health, protective measures, and prevention have reduced the

adverse impact of malaria in recent years.

Malaria has substantially reduced the productivity and climate for investment of many poor

countries, particularly those in Africa. But, progress has been made. Table 7 presents data on

reported cases of malaria as a percentage of the total population for the 31 Malthusian, the non-

Malthusian African, the 83 other developing countries, and for Asia and Latin America. These

data indicate that the incidence of malaria is most severe in Africa, and particularly for the

Malthusian African countries. The incidence of malaria in the 83 developing economies has been

around 1 percent throughout 1990-2015, and it has been in a declining pattern since 2000.

Further, the figures indicate that malaria is no longer a major problem in either Asia or Latin

America. In contrast, the incidence of malaria is substantially higher in Africa. The malaria cases

as a share of the population for the 31 Malthusian economies rose from 10.7 percent in 1990 to

13.5 percent in 2005, before receding to 9.4 percent in 2015. Data are available for eight non-

Malthusian African economies (Botswana, Cabo Verde, Gabon, Ghana, Mauritius, Namibia,

Swaziland, and South Africa). While the problem of these countries is less severe than for the

Malthusian countries, it is nonetheless substantial, particularly in Gabon, Ghana, and Namibia.

Insert Table 7 about here

The recent decline in malaria cases, along with continuing improvements in prevention,

health care, and treatment, provide reason for future optimism.18 As previously indicated, a

substantial share of the 31 Malthusian economies have grown more rapidly and shown signs of

moving from phase 1 to phase 2 during the last 15 years. With continuing progress against

18 Since 2000, substantial progress has been made against malaria. The prevalence of infection in children ages 2-10

has been cut in half in Africa during 2000-2015 [Bhatt et al. 2015]. Based on Gapminder data [Rosling 2008] and

our own calculations, malaria fatalities per 10,000 reported cases have fallen from 41.9 in 1990 to 23.0 in 2010.

Otten et al. [2009], in an examination of malaria in Rwanda and Ethiopia, document substantial reductions in the

number of malaria cases and deaths resulting from malaria since 2001.

Page 22: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

22

malaria, many of these countries are likely to break out of phase 1 and begin the virtuous cycle in

the years immediately ahead.

VI. Summary and Conclusion

Prior to the Industrial Revolution, the world was Malthusian. Growth of per capita income

was absent and most everyone was poor—phase 1 of development. The Industrial Revolution

brought change, but mostly for people living in a small set of countries in Western Europe, North

America, and Oceania, representing about 15 percent of the world’s population. Even though

growth of per capita income in these locations was slow by today’s standards, it was more rapid

than the rest of the world. Therefore, income inequality continually expanded during the 150

years following the Industrial Revolution.

This slow-motion world began to speed up in the last half of the 20th century. Developing

countries began to escape Malthusian stagnation and move to phases 2 and 3 of development. As

they did so, they benefitted from the virtuous cycle of development—growth of per capita

income, reductions in the birth rate, and increases in the prime age population as a share of the

total, which propelled additional growth. Further, huge reductions in transportation and

communication costs driven by innovation and technology facilitated production far from the

world’s major markets, integrating many developing countries into the world market network.

This second economic revolution, the transportation-communication revolution, both increased

the gains from trade and the transmission speed of successful business ideas and practices

throughout the developing world. This combination of factors made it possible for more and

more developing countries to move out of the Malthusian phase of development, benefit from the

accompanying virtuous demographic changes, and achieve historically high growth rates that

were unattainable only a few decades earlier. Further, the growth of the high-income countries

decelerated as they moved into phase 4 of development. Thus, the two-century trend toward

increasing income inequality slowed during the latter part of the 20th century and eventually

reversed.

The Gini coefficients confirm the substantial increase in income inequality from 1820 to late

in the 20th century, slowdown in the trend during the latter part of the 20th century, and sharp

reversal of trend during 2000-2015. For the first time in history, the world experienced both

substantial increases in per capita income and reductions in income inequality. Further, it is

highly likely that this situation will continue for another decade or so because most of the

developing countries are in phases 2 and 3 of the development process while the high-income

countries are in phase 4. In addition, the low transport and communication costs, improvements

in economic and political institutions, increases in human capital of the working-age population,

and declining incidence of malaria will elevate the growth of developing countries in the decades

immediately ahead.

The development process and accompanying demographic changes as countries move

through different phases of development enhance our understanding of the factors underlying the

historic pattern of worldwide income inequality. Others have noted the pattern of inequality

described here. However, because the development process was not incorporated into their

analysis, they were unable to explain why the two-century trend of increasing income inequality

reversed and use the forces underlying the reversal to make a persuasive case about the future

direction of global inequality.

Page 23: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

23

References

Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson, “The Colonial Origins of

Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation,” American Economic Review, 91

(2001), 1369–401.

Acemoglu, Daron, Suresh Naidu, Pascual Restrepo, and James A. Robinson, “Democracy Does

Cause Growth,” forthcoming, Journal of Political Economy.

Aitchison, John, and James AC Brown., “The Lognormal Distribution with Special Reference to

Its Uses in Economics,” Indian Economic Review, 3 (1957), 114–16.

Alvaredo, Facundo, Anthony B. Atkinson, Thomas Piketty, and Emmanuel Saez, “The Top 1

Percent in International and Historical Perspective,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 27

(2013), 3–20.

Assouad, Lydia, Lucas Chancel, and Marc Morgan, “Extreme Inequality: Evidence from Brazil,

India, the Middle East, and South Africa,” AEA Papers and Proceedings, 108 (2018), 119–

23.

Atkinson, Anthony B., Thomas Piketty, and Emmanuel Saez, “Top Incomes in the Long Run of

History,” Journal of Economic Literature, 49 (2011), 3–71.

Barro, Robert. J., “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries” Quarterly Journal of

Economics, 106 (1991), 407–43.

——, Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study (Cambridge, MA:

MIT Press, 1997).

Barro, Robert J., and Jong Wha Lee, “A New Data Set of Educational Attainment in the World,

1950–2010,” Journal of Development Economics, 104 (2013), 184–98.

Barro, Robert J., and Gary S. Becker, “Fertility Choice in a Model of Economic Growth,”

Econometrica, 57 (1989), 481–501.

Becker, Gary S., “An Economic Analysis of Fertility,” in Richard Easterlin, ed., Demographic

and Economic Change in Developed Countries (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,

1960).

Becker, Gary S., and H. Gregg Lewis., “On the Interaction between the Quantity and Quality of

Children,” Journal of Political Economy, 81 (1973), S279–88.

Bhatt, Samir, D. J. Weiss, E. Cameron, D. Bisanzio, B. Mappin, U. Dalrymple, K. E. Battle et

al., “The Effect of Malaria Control on Plasmodium Falciparum in Africa between 2000 and

2015.” Nature, 526 (2015): 207–11.

Bourguignon, Francois, The Globalization of Inequality (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University

Press, 2015). Kindle.

Bourguignon, François, and Christian Morrisson, “Inequality Among World Citizens: 1820-

1992,” American Economic Review, 92 (2002), 727–744.

Page 24: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

24

Chen, Shaohua and Martin Ravallion, “The Developing World is Poorer Than We Thought, but

no Less Successful in the Fight Against Poverty,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125

(2010), 1577–1625.

Doepke, Matthias, “Gary Becker on the Quantity and Quality of Children,” Journal of

Demographic Economics, 81 (2015), 59–66.

Feenstra, Robert C., Robert Inklaar, and Marcel P. Timmer, “The Next Generation of the Penn

World Table, American Economic Review, 105 (2015), 3150–82. http://www.ggdc.net/pwt/.

Freedom House. Freedom in the World 2017 (New York, NY: Freedom House, 2017).

Gallup, John Luke, Jeffrey D. Sachs, and Andrew D. Mellinger, “Geography and Economic

Development,” International Regional Science Review, 22 (1999), 179–232.

Galor, Oded, Unified Growth Theory (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2011).

Galor, Oded, and David N. Weil, “Population, Technology, and Growth: From Malthusian

Stagnation to the Demographic Transition and Beyond,” American Economic Review, 90

(2000), 806–28.

Glaeser Edward L., and Janet E. Kohlhase, “Cities, Regions and the Decline of Transport Costs,”

in Florax, Raymond J.G.M., and David A. Plane., eds., Fifty Years of Regional Science

(Berlin: Springer-Verlag, 2004).

Gwartney, James D., Randall Holcombe, and Robert Lawson, “Institutions and the Impact of

Investment on Growth,” Kyklos, 59 (2006), 255–73.

Gwartney, James, Robet Lawson, and Joshua C. Hall, Economic Freedom of the World: 2017

Annual Report (Vancouver, B.C.: Fraser Institute, 2017).

Hanushek, Eric A., and Ludger Woessmann, “The Role of Cognitive Skills in Economic

Development,” Journal of Economic Literature, 46 (2008), 607–68.

——, Education and Economic Growth (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 2010).

——, “Do Better Schools Lead to More Growth? Cognitive Skills, Economic Outcomes, and

Causation,” Journal of Economic Growth, 17 (2012), 267–321.

Hellebrandt, Tomas, and Paolo Mauro, “The Future of Worldwide Income Distribution,”

Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper 15-7, 2015.

Lopez, Humberto, and Luis Servén, “A Normal Relationship? Poverty, Growth and Inequality,”

World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3814, 2006.

Lucas Robert, “The Industrial Revolution: Past and Future,” Federal Reserve Bank of

Minneapolis, 2004.

Lucas, Robert, “What was the Industrial Revolution?,” NBER Working Paper 23547, 2017.

Maddison, Angus, Contours of the World Economy, 1–2030 AD: Essays in Macro-Economic History

(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007).

Page 25: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

25

Maddison Project Database, version 2018. Bolt, Jutta, Robert Inklaar, Herman de Jong and Jan

Luiten van Zanden (2018), “Rebasing ‘Maddison’: new income comparisons and the shape

of long-run economic development” Maddison Project Working Paper, nr. 10, available for

download at www.ggdc.net/maddison.

Marshall, Monty G., Ted R. Gurr, and Keith Jaggers, “Political Regime Characteristics and

Transitions, 1800–2016,” Polity IV Project, 2016. http://www.systemicpeace.org/.

Milanovic, Branko, Global Inequality: A New Approach for the Age of Globalization

(Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2016).

Novokmet, Filip, Thomas Piketty, Li Yang, and Gabriel Zucman, “From Communism to

Capitalism: Private versus Public Property and Inequality in China and Russia,” AEA Papers

and Proceedings, 108 (2018), 109-13.

Otten, Mac, Maru Aregawi, Wilson Were, Corine Karema, Ambachew Medin, Worku Bekele,

Daddi Jima et al., “Initial Evidence of Reduction of Malaria Cases and Deaths in Rwanda

and Ethiopia Due to Rapid Scale-Up of Malaria Prevention and Treatment,” Malaria Journal

8 (2009).

Pinkovskiy, Maxim, and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, “Parametric Estimations of the World

Distribution of Income,” NBER Working Paper 15433, 2009.

Rosling, Hans, “Gapminder,” Accessed June 15, 2018. http://www.gapminder.org/data.

Sachs, Jeffrey D, “Institutions Don’t Rule: Direct Effects of Geography on Per Capita Income,”

NBER Working Paper 9490, 2003.

Sala-i-Martin, Xavier, “The World Distribution of Income: Falling Poverty and… Convergence,

Period,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121 (2006), 351–97.

Sala-i-Martin, Xavier, and Maxim Pinkovskiy, “African Poverty is Falling... Much Faster Than

You Think!,” NBER Working Paper 15775, 2010.

Shleifer, Andrei, “The Age of Milton Friedman,” Journal of Economic Literature, 47 (2009),

123–35.

Solt, Frederick, “The Standardized World Income Inequality Database,” Social Science

Quarterly, 97 (2016), 1267–81.

Tamura, Robert, “From Decay to Growth: A Demographic Transition to Economic Growth,”

Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 20 (1996), 1237–61.

United Nations Population Division. “World Population Prospects 2017,” Accessed May 27,

2018. https://www.un.org/development/desa/publications/world-population-prospects-the-

2017-revision.html

World Bank, “World Development Indicators,” Accessed May 1, 2018.

http://databank.worldbank.org/wdi

World Health Organization, World malaria report 2015. (Geneva: World Health Organization,

2015).

Page 26: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

26

Young, Alwyn, “The Gini Coefficient for a Mixture of Ln-Normal Populations,” London School

of Economics and Political Science Working Paper, 2011.

Page 27: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

27

Tables and Figures

Table 1: Per Capita GDP and Annual Growth Rates for 31 Malthusian Economies, 1960-2015.

Country 1960 1980 2000 2015 1960-2015 1960-2000 2000-2015

Angolaa

3,120 1,647 8,631 11.04

Benin 1,281 1,842 1,489 2,141 0.93 0.38 2.42

Burkina Faso 1,557 1,608 1,355 1,527 -0.04 -0.35 0.80

Burundi 973 1,157 962 723 -0.54 -0.03 -1.90

Cameroon 1,067 1,694 2,252 2,754 1.72 1.87 1.34

Central African Rep. 1,395 1,044 911 605 -1.52 -1.07 -2.73

Chad 1,482 888 989 2,387 0.87 -1.01 5.87

Congo, Rep. 1,396 2,888 2,727 4,526 2.14 1.67 3.38

Congo, Dem. Rep. 2,119 1,782 443 836 -1.69 -3.91 4.23

Côte d'Ivoire 2,070 3,136 2,127 3,473 0.94 0.07 3.27

Ethiopia 750 1,105 608 1,576 1.35 -0.52 6.35

Gambia 1,994 2,241 1,812 1,948 -0.04 -0.24 0.48

Guinea 1,419 1,427 1,059 1,606 0.23 -0.73 2.78

Guinea-Bissau 841 1,267 1,357 1,313 0.81 1.20 -0.22

Kenya 1,396 2,033 2,086 3,090 1.44 1.00 2.62

Liberia 887 1,118 524 798 -0.19 -1.32 2.80

Madagascar 1,121 1,092 975 1,288 0.25 -0.35 1.86

Malawi 1,092 945 873 960 -0.23 -0.56 0.63

Mali 1,164 638 885 1,563 0.54 -0.69 3.79

Mauritania 1,037 1,961 1,945 3,323 2.12 1.57 3.57

Mozambique 546 459 606 1,277 1.54 0.26 4.97

Niger 1,361 1,497 669 895 -0.76 -1.78 1.94

Nigeria 2,179 6,414 2,657 5,540 1.70 0.50 4.90

Rwanda 728 1,058 705 1,676 1.52 -0.08 5.77

Senegal 2,337 1,515 1,850 2,446 0.08 -0.58 1.86

Sierra Leone 1,962 1,754 998 1,033 -1.17 -1.69 0.23

Tanzania 1,360 2,159 1,137 2,429 1.05 -0.45 5.06

Togo 1,102 1,847 1,160 1,482 0.54 0.13 1.63

Uganda 1,210 940 1,129 1,883 0.80 -0.17 3.41

Zambia 1,706 1,462 1,153 3,537 1.33 -0.98 7.47

Zimbabwe 2,710 4,003 2,696 1,759 -0.79 -0.01 -2.85

Simple Average 1,408 1,809 1,348 2,227 0.50 -0.26 2.80

Population Weighted Average 1,913 2,743 1,483 2,791 0.69 -0.64 4.22

Minimum 546 459 443 605 -1.69 -3.91 -2.85

Maximum 2,710 6,414 2,727 8,631 2.14 1.87 11.04

Source: Maddison [2018] and own calculations. Maddison [2018] presents alternative per capita GDP

figures that are recommended for calculation of growth rates. This series was also used to calculate the

growth rates for columns 5, 6, and 7. The pattern of the results was similar to those shown above.

Note: a The 1960 per capita GDP for Angola was unavailable.

Page 28: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

28

Table 2: Per capita GDP of the 31 Malthusian, 114 Developing, and 83 non-Malthusian

Developing Economies relative to the 21 High-Income Industrial Countries

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

Year

High Income

21

Malthusian

31

83 non-

Malthusian

Developing

114

Developing

Ratio

(1) / (2)

Ratio

(1) / (3)

Ratio

(1) / (4)

1820 1,461 821 1.8

1870 2,506 845 3.0

1913 5,413 1,219 4.4

1950 8,469 1,450 5.8

1950 8,464 1,216 1,426 1,408 7.0 5.9 6.0

1960 11,782 1,525 1,698 1,683 7.7 6.9 7.0

1970 17,633 2,310 2,291 2,293 7.6 7.7 7.7

1980 23,590 2,743 3,186 3,144 8.6 7.4 7.5

1990 28,832 2,023 3,676 3,505 14.3 7.8 8.2

2000 37,876 1,483 5,159 4,734 25.5 7.3 8.0

2010 41,839 2,417 9,173 8,279 17.3 4.6 5.1

2015 44,514 2,791 11,015 9,845 15.9 4.0 4.5

1960 11,712 1,913 1,629 1,654 6.1 7.2 7.1

1970 17,493 2,297 2,279 2,281 7.6 7.7 7.7

1980 23,075 2,498 3,152 3,090 9.2 7.3 7.5

1990 29,171 1,291 3,490 3,265 22.6 8.4 8.9

2000 38,396 1,087 5,037 4,585 35.3 7.6 8.4

2010 41,990 2,408 9,003 8,133 17.4 4.7 5.2

2015 45,230 2,804 11,143 9,963 16.1 4.1 4.5

1980 20,226 2 ,635 3 ,608 3 ,536 7.7 5.6 5.7

1990 32,272 1,877 4,378 4,120 17.2 7.4 7.8

2000 39,082 1,700 6,073 5,571 23.0 6.4 7.0

2010 42,100 2,500 9,506 8,578 16.8 4.4 4.9

2015 44,538 2,813 11,406 10,165 15.8 3.9 4.4

Panel A: Maddison (2018)

Panel B: Penn World Table

Panel C: World Bank

Notes: 1. The mean per capita GDP figures for each group were derived by first calculating the total

GDP for each group and then dividing by the total population of the group. The figures in panel A are

from Maddison [2018] and are expressed in 2011 PPP dollars.

2. The high-income group of panel A from 1820-1950 includes 16 of the 21 high-income countries.

The five countries for which the per capita GDP figures were unavailable are: Belgium, Iceland,

Luxembourg, New Zealand, and Switzerland. Three high-income countries (Germany, Spain, and

Japan) had data in 1800 and 1850, but not 1820. The value for 1820 was interpolated by adding 2/5 of

the change over the period to the 1800 real per capita GDP. Over the period 1820-1950, only 36 of the

83 developing countries (column 3) had continuous data. These 36 countries constituted over 90

percent of the developing world population in 1950. During 1820-1950, the per capita income data

were unavailable for all of the Malthusian countries. Finally, the second 1950 row begins the data that

includes the 21 high-income countries, the 31 Malthusian countries, and 77 of the 83 non-Malthusian

developing countries. The six developing countries omitted from the Maddison data were: The

Bahamas, Belize, Bhutan, Brunei Darussalam, Fiji, and Suriname.

Page 29: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

29

Table 3: Gini Coefficients Across-Country, Within-Country, and Worldwide. Pre and Post Taxes and Transfers.

Panel A: 135 countries of primary dataset

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Cross-Country

Year

Market Income

(Pre-Tax, Pre-Transfer)

Disposable Income

(Post-Tax, Post-Transfer)

Market Income

(Pre-Tax, Pre-Transfer)

Disposable Income

(Post-Tax, Post-Transfer)

1820 0.235

1870 0.394

1913 0.495

1950 0.585

1960 0.586 0.405 0.354 0.685 0.657

1965 0.594 0.406 0.356 0.692 0.665

1970 0.598 0.406 0.357 0.697 0.670

1975 0.602 0.407 0.358 0.699 0.672

1980 0.604 0.411 0.361 0.700 0.672

1985 0.595 0.417 0.366 0.696 0.667

1990 0.594 0.428 0.379 0.699 0.671

1995 0.578 0.442 0.392 0.690 0.659

2000 0.575 0.450 0.402 0.690 0.661

2005 0.544 0.462 0.413 0.672 0.641

2010 0.493 0.469 0.413 0.644 0.606

2015 0.466 0.468 0.410 0.627 0.586

Panel B: Extended set of 157 countries

1990 0.585 0.425 0.375 0.689 0.660

1995 0.572 0.439 0.388 0.685 0.655

2000 0.570 0.447 0.398 0.686 0.657

2005 0.539 0.458 0.409 0.667 0.636

2010 0.488 0.464 0.409 0.639 0.601

2015 0.461 0.464 0.405 0.624 0.584

Source: Maddison [2018], World Bank [2018], Solt [2016], Young [2011], and own calculations

Notes: The 135 countries of panel comprise 92 percent of the world's population while the 157 countries of panel B comprise 96 percent of

the World's population.

Within-Country Worldwide

Page 30: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

30

Table 4: Number of developing and high-income countries by phase of development, 1960-2035

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Year phase 1 phases 2 or 3 phase 4 phase 1 phases 2 or 3 phase 4

1960 96 (95.0%) 18 (5.0%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 21 (100%) 0 (0%)

1970 94 (93.8%) 20 (6.2%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 21 (100%) 0 (0%)

1980 75 (55.8%) 39 (44.2%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 21 (100%) 0 (0%)

1990 64 (47.3%) 50 (52.7%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 21 (100%) 0 (0%)

2000 49 (20.2%) 65 (79.8%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 20 (90.2%) 1 (9.8%)

2010 32 (13.3%) 82 (86.7%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 5 (6.8%) 16 (93.2%)

2015 31 (14.2%) 75 (84.0%) 8 (1.8%) 0 (0%) 2 (1.0%) 19 (99.0%)

2020 27 (12.5%) 74 (84.6%) 13 (2.9%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 21 (100%)

2025 21 (12.4%) 68 (59.5%) 25 (28.1%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 21 (100%)

2030 14 (11.7%) 68 (58.7%) 32 (29.6%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 21 (100%)

2035 9 (7.0%) 71 (65.8%) 34 (27.2%) 0 (0%) 0 (0%) 21 (100%)

Sources: World Bank [2018], Penn World Table [Feenstra et al. 2015], United Nations [2017], and own calculations

Note: Figures for 2020-2035 are based on the United Nations Demographic Projections. A country is classified as Malthusian if it was in

phase 1 of development continuously since 196-2015. A country is in phase 1 of development in any given year, if its share of population

under age 15 is larger than 40 percent or if its per capita GDP is lower than $1,460 (4 dollars a day). A country is considered in phase 4 if

its prime working age 25-59 share of total population has declined by 1 percent or more from its peak.

Number in each phase (and population share)

for 114 developing economies

Number in each phase (and population share)

for 21 High-income economies

Page 31: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

31

Table 5: Economic and Political Institutions for the 114 Developing Economies, 1980-2015

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Year

Economic

Freedom

(Summary Legal System Sound Money

International

Exchange

Freedom House

(Political Rights)

Polity IV

(Democracy)

1980 4.84 (81) 3.72 (66) 5.59 (88) 4.09 (73) 3.10 (104) -3.43 (104)

1985 4.91 (87) 3.80 (84) 5.90 (91) 4.19 (77) 3.29 (104) -2.91 (104)

1990 5.20 (91) 3.97 (85) 5.80 (91) 4.96 (83) 3.51 (105) -0.49 (104)

1995 5.79 (91) 4.66 (87) 6.06 (91) 6.29 (84) 3.95 (106) 1.99 (106)

2000 6.30 (91) 4.58 (91) 7.23 (91) 6.83 (91) 4.16 (106) 2.49 (106)

2005 6.45 (100) 4.69 (100) 7.49 (100) 6.73 (100) 4.28 (106) 3.07 (107)

2010 6.59 (109) 4.80 (109) 7.74 (109) 6.87 (109) 4.16 (106) 3.26 (107)

2015 6.62 (114) 4.82 (114) 8.04 (114) 6.77 (114) 4.23 (106) 3.69 (107)

Source: Gwartney et al. [2017], Freedom House [2017], and Marshall et al. [2016].

Note: The number of countries for which data were available is indicated in parentheses. The Economic Freedom of the World index

(columns 1-4) ranges theoretically from 0 (least economically free) to 10 (most economically free). The Freedom House Political

Rights index (column 5) has been inverted so that the scale ranges from 1 (least free) to 7 (mostly free). The Polity IV democracy

index (column 6) ranges from -10 (least democratic) to +10 (most democratic).

Page 32: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

32

Table 6: Secondary Enrollment Rates (ages 15-19) and Secondary Completion Rates (ages 20-

24) for Developing and Malthusian Economies, 1960-2010

Table 7: Malaria Reported Cases as a Percentage of the Total Population

Year

Enrollment rate

(age 15-19)

Completion rate

(age 20-24)

Enrollment rate

(age 15-19)

Completion rate

(age 20-24)

1960 17.0 5.9 4.8 1.0

1965 20.3 7.4 5.9 1.4

1970 25.4 10.7 7.8 1.8

1975 31.3 12.9 11.8 3.6

1980 37.0 16.4 15.8 5.5

1985 40.4 19.1 17.9 7.3

1990 42.3 23.6 18.3 9.3

1995 44.5 24.3 17.8 8.5

2000 48.3 26.4 19.5 8.3

2005 53.9 30.0 23.8 9.9

2010 59.5 34.2 31.5 11.6

Source: Barro and Lee [2013]

Note: Columns 1 and 2 are for the 98 (of 114) developing economies for which the

data were available. Columns 3 and 4 are for 23 (of 31) Malthusian Economies for

which data were availalable.

Developing Economies Malthusian Economies

Year 31 Malthusian

Non

Malthusian

Africa

Other

Developing

83 Asia Latin America

1990 10.7 2.7 0.7 0.6 0.4

1995 9.0 4.7 1.2 1.0 0.6

2000 11.6 7.6 1.4 0.4 0.4

2005 13.5 5.9 1.0 0.2 0.4

2010 11.1 3.7 0.7 0.1 0.1

2015 9.4 4.0 0.7 0.0 0.1

Source: World Health Organization [2015], Gapminder [Rosling 2008], and World Bank [2017]

Note: The original source for these data is the World Health Organization. Reported Malaria cases

per 100,000 people from 1990 to 2006 comes from Rosling [2008]. The World Bank [2017]

provides the number of cases per 1,000 people at risk from 2005 to 2015. These sources were

combined to derive a comparable series of malaria cases as a share of total population for the

period 1990-2015.

Page 33: The Rise and Fall of Worldwide Income Inequality, 1820-2035as.nyu.edu/content/dam/nyu-as/econ/misc/Worldwide... · inequality during the past two centuries: the rise from 1820-1970,

33

Figure 1: Share of Total Population in the Prime Working Age 25-59 Group for the 21 High-

Income, 31 Malthusians, and 83 Other Developing Economies, 1960-2015 (Actual); 2020-2035

(Projected)

Source: World Bank [2018] and United Nations Population Division [2017]

Figure 2: Annual Growth Rates for the High-Income, Developing, and Malthusian Countries

1965-2015 (15-Year Moving Average)

Source: Maddison [2018]

25

30

35

40

45

50

1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2035

Per

cen

t

21 High-Income 83 Non-Malthusian Developing 31 Malthusian

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

Gro

wth

rat

e

21 High-Income Non-Malthusian Developing Malthusian