22
ORIGINAL PAPER The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework Jens Glowienka Ó Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2014 Abstract According to the case law of the European Court of Justice, personal circumstances of nonresident taxpayers from other member states of the European Union do not need to be taken into account by the state of source when determining the taxable income of such nonresidents. Thus, the refusal of a subsistence level to nonresidents is in general in line with the European law. However, according to the relevant rulings of the court no additional tax burdens may caused by using higher tax rates for nonresidents. In this paper it is therefore examined in what ways the subsistence level may be refused to nonresidents. In order to do so, it is crucial to examine how the subsistence level is granted to resident taxpayers. Especially if the subsistence level is entirely integrated into the tax scale, this might lead to incorrect results. In order to avoid such incorrect results, each limit of the tax scale has to be analyzed more precisely. As this paper shows, there is even a contradiction in the rulings of the European Court of Justice. Additionally, this paper shows that an incorrect refusal of the subsistence level leads to a modification of the applicable tax rates for nonresidents. As a result, nonresidents are faced with an additional tax burden on top of the additional tax burden caused by the refusal of the subsistence level itself. These implications are shown for the case of Germany. They might be in breach with former rulings of the court. Keywords Income tax Nonresident Legal framework Germany Subsistence level JEL Classification C59 H24 K34 J. Glowienka (&) Lehrstuhl fu ¨r Allgemeine Betriebswirtschaftslehre, insbesondere Betriebswirtschaftliche Steuerlehre und Wirtschaftspru ¨fung, Europa-Universita ¨t Viadrina, Frankfurt (Oder), Große Scharrnstraße 59, 15230 Frankfurt (Oder), Germany e-mail: [email protected] URL: http://www.wiwi.europa-uni.de/de/lehrstuhl/fact/steuern/index.html 123 J Bus Econ DOI 10.1007/s11573-013-0704-2

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

  • Upload
    jens

  • View
    213

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

ORI GIN AL PA PER

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresidenttaxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legalframework

Jens Glowienka

� Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2014

Abstract According to the case law of the European Court of Justice, personal

circumstances of nonresident taxpayers from other member states of the European

Union do not need to be taken into account by the state of source when determining

the taxable income of such nonresidents. Thus, the refusal of a subsistence level to

nonresidents is in general in line with the European law. However, according to the

relevant rulings of the court no additional tax burdens may caused by using higher

tax rates for nonresidents. In this paper it is therefore examined in what ways the

subsistence level may be refused to nonresidents. In order to do so, it is crucial to

examine how the subsistence level is granted to resident taxpayers. Especially if the

subsistence level is entirely integrated into the tax scale, this might lead to incorrect

results. In order to avoid such incorrect results, each limit of the tax scale has to be

analyzed more precisely. As this paper shows, there is even a contradiction in the

rulings of the European Court of Justice. Additionally, this paper shows that an

incorrect refusal of the subsistence level leads to a modification of the applicable tax

rates for nonresidents. As a result, nonresidents are faced with an additional tax

burden on top of the additional tax burden caused by the refusal of the subsistence

level itself. These implications are shown for the case of Germany. They might be in

breach with former rulings of the court.

Keywords Income tax � Nonresident � Legal framework � Germany �Subsistence level

JEL Classification C59 � H24 � K34

J. Glowienka (&)

Lehrstuhl fur Allgemeine Betriebswirtschaftslehre, insbesondere Betriebswirtschaftliche Steuerlehre

und Wirtschaftsprufung, Europa-Universitat Viadrina, Frankfurt (Oder), Große Scharrnstraße 59,

15230 Frankfurt (Oder), Germany

e-mail: [email protected]

URL: http://www.wiwi.europa-uni.de/de/lehrstuhl/fact/steuern/index.html

123

J Bus Econ

DOI 10.1007/s11573-013-0704-2

Page 2: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

1 Introduction

According to the rulings of the European Court of Justice (ECJ), it is in general not

harmful if the subsistence level is refused to nonresidents in the state of source

within the European Union (EU). It is solely the responsibility of the resident state

to grant this relief in order to consider personal circumstances. The way of refusing

the subsistence level is limited by the legal framework of the EU. Especially with

regard to the taxation of nonresidents in the state of source, the ECJ has ruled three

important judgments that influenced the taxation in the several member states of the

EU. Therefore, this paper examines in a first step whether there are any

contradictions in the method of refusing the subsistence level as proposed by the

ECJ.

Furthermore, the granting of a subsistence level is a technical topic of tax

collection. Especially if it is integrated into the applicable tax scale, it is not always

obvious whether it is granted as a tax credit or a basic allowance. This may lead to

an incorrect refusal of the subsistence level to nonresidents and accordingly to an

additional tax burden for them, on top of the additional tax burden caused by the

refusal of the subsistence level itself. While this refusal may in general be in line

with earlier decisions of the ECJ, the technical implementation of refusing the

subsistence level in some jurisdictions might still violate the guidelines of other ECJ

decisions. After the analysis of the refusal of the subsistence level in an abstract

manner, the results of this analysis are applied to the concrete case of Germany.

After a short literature overview about the topic as a whole, the analysis is

divided into two parts: The first part analyzes the consequences of the rulings set by

the ECJ. Therefore, a short introduction is given into the relevant rulings and the

possibilities of granting the subsistence level. Based on these rulings, the different

methods of granting the subsistence level shall be identified if the subsistence level

is integrated into the applicable tax scale. A simple numerical example demonstrates

the possible impact the tax revenues of the state. The second part analyzes the

current situation of nonresidents in Germany as an example and shows the impact

on an individual nonresident taxpayer.

2 Literature overview

How tax benefits can be granted is one topic of many textbooks in public finance

(e.g. Pollak 1980; Homburg 2010). In Germany discussions about how a subsistence

level should be implemented often occur at times a tax reform is initiated. An

example for a former discussion is given by Peffekoven (1972) with regard to the

tax reform in the 1970s. Twenty years later, the German Federal Constitutional

Court (BVerfG 1992) ruled that the former subsistence level in the German tax scale

was not in line with the German constitution because it was too low. As a reaction to

this decision, a new discussion in literature started in Germany about how the

subsistence level should in general be granted to the taxpayer. Siegel and Schneider

(1994, p. 597–599) introduce a graphical view on this topic. Homburg (1995) shows

formally that the subsistence level as a deduction from the taxable income may be

J. Glowienka

123

Page 3: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

integrated into the applicable tax scale. Seidl (1997) points out that a deduction from

the taxable income is not equal to granting the subsistence level as a tax credit. An

extensive historical background with regard to this topic is given by Treisch (1999,

2005) who points out that granting the subsistence level mainly depends on the legal

system in each country.

A brief summary of the discussion as a whole is given by Wosnitza and Treisch

(1999a) which includes an analysis of the discussed alternatives. Their article

revived the discussion of how the subsistence level should be granted. Please refer

to Bareis (1999a), Siegel (1999), Schneider (1999), Jachmann (1999) and Wosnitza

and Treisch (1999b) for further explanations.

The literature discussing the taxation of nonresidents on a European level is

usually very specific to each individual ruling of the ECJ. The decision C-234/01—

Gerritse (ECJ 2003) was criticized by Grams and Schon (2008, p. 660) who

developed another principle to tax the income of nonresidents using an average tax

rate. Their concept has been ignored by literature in the past. Some more general

questions were asked by Wattel (2000), focusing on the progressive taxation of

nonresidents in the EU. An other interesting work is Mattson (2003). He asked, if

the ECJ really understands the policy behind tax benefits. In his opinion tax benefits

based on personal circumstances—such as the granting of a subsistence level—are

relevant parts of the tax rate. Finally, the ECJ is not allowed to rule against the tax

rates of member states (Mattson 2003, p. 194).

An introduction to the German income tax is given by Hey and Seer (2013) with

considerable references to current legal publications. Detailed information regarding

the procedure on tax collection is delivered by Liebing (2004) and the legal

commentaries. Loschelder (2013) and Wied (2013) discuss the taxation of

nonresidents in Germany. They state that the current procedure of taxing

nonresidents is in line with the European legal framework. Additionally they are

of the opinion that adding the subsistence level to the domestic income of

nonresidents is only a technical aspect to tax nonresidents and conclude that this

method is suitable to avoid an additional tax burden.

As can be seen from the above, the literature in Germany mainly discusses the

issue of how the subsistence level should be granted in general for resident

taxpayers. However, there is no literature so far that analyzes the effects of refusing

the subsistence level to nonresidents from an economic perspective and whether the

results differ depending on the method used for granting the subsistence level. The

reasons for this missing piece in literature may be speculative. On the one side, this

topic needs fundamental legal knowledge, especially in national tax law and

European law. On the other side claimed Bareis (1991, 1999a, b, 2010) that for

analyzing such a topic the use of precise mathematical models is needed. A

combination that may only can be found in German Business Research on taxation.

In a first step, this paper shall therefore identify the impacts of denying the

subsistence level to nonresidents and hence show in a second step whether there is a

contradiction with the EU law. With regard to the taxation of nonresidents in

Germany, the thesis of Loschelder and Wied that by simply adding the subsistence

level to the taxable income of a nonresident leads to a reasonable result without

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers

123

Page 4: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

violating EU law, has not been proven so far. Therefore this article shall show

whether this thesis is correct.

3 General analysis

3.1 European framework

The implementation and arrangement of the national tax law lies solely in the hands

of each member state (Kokott and Ost 2011, p. 497; Greggi 2009, p. 119; Englisch

2003, p. 91). However, the aforementioned arrangement must not limit the

fundamental freedoms of the EU (Kokott and Ost 2011, p. 496). This also applies to

nonresident taxpayers. As there is no primary legal framework on the European

level, it is the duty of the ECJ to decide whether the fundamental freedoms of a

nonresident are violated by a national tax law or not.

The ECJ has introduced the principles with regard to the taxation of nonresidents

in three major decisions: In the first decision of the ECJ in 1995 (C-279/93—

Schumacker, ECJ 1995) it was ruled that resident and nonresident taxpayers may in

general be treated differently for tax purposes as they are not in comparable

situations. Subject to certain exceptions, personal circumstances of nonresidents

need not be considered in the state of source as they are in general taken into

account in the state of residence. This concept was named the so-called Schumaker-

Doctrine in literature. The general rule may only be disregarded if the nonresident

has a very low income in the country of residence.

Another question of whether nonresidents may be subject to a higher tax rate in

comparable situations was addressed by the ECJ in 1996 (C-107/94—Asscher, ECJ

1996). As a result, the ECJ rejected the application of higher tax rates for

nonresidents in the case of the Dutch tax law.

In the third decision in 2003 (C-234/01—Gerritse, ECJ 2003), the ECJ pointed

out three central statements with respect to the treatment of nonresidents (Seer et al.

2005, p. 290). Firstly, the ECJ ruled that the taxable income of resident and

nonresident taxpayers must be determined on the same basis including expenditures

connected to generating the taxable income.1 However the ECJ confirmed that—

based on the ruling in 1995 (ECJ 1995)—it is not harmful if personal circumstances

are refused to nonresidents. This was in 2004 picked up in the ruling (C-169/03—

Wallentin, ECJ 2004) in which it was decided that the subsistence level may be

disregarded for nonresidents even if is integrated in the tax scale.

Secondarily, the ECJ ruled in Gerritse (ECJ 2003) that a fixed tax rate applicable

to nonresidents is not in line with the European law if this tax rate leads to a higher

tax burden of the nonresident compared to a progressive tax rate—disregarding the

subsistence level—applicable to a resident taxpayer. Thirdly and most importantly,

it was decided in the second head note that the subsistence level may be added to the

taxable income of a nonresident.

1 In this ruling the German legislature failed to supply a justification for the unequal treatment. For

further details refer to ECJ (2003, recital 29, p. I-5955).

J. Glowienka

123

Page 5: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

3.2 Possibilities of granting a subsistence level

3.2.1 The general structure of tax scales

A tax (Tax) is levied by applying a tax scale T(�) to an assessment basis TI, the

taxable income.2 Thus, the mathematical function of the tax has in general the

following structure:

Tax ¼ T TIð Þ: ð1ÞIt shall furthermore be assumed that the tax scale function is divided into three

different zones (n = {1, 2, 3}) which are described by the Term Tn. Within these

zones, individual tax scales are applied. The limits of these zones are described by

TLn. Thus, the general function of the tax burden (1) can be expressed as follows

Tax ¼T1 TIð Þ TI� TL1

T2 TIð Þ TL1\TI� TL2

T3 TIð Þ TI [ TL2

8<

:ð2Þ

in which T1(TI) is the so-called ‘‘Zero-Zone’’. This means that no tax is being

charged. Consequently, the value for the function is zero. For now, the Zero-Zone

shall avoid a negative income tax. Hence, the zone is only applicable for a taxable

income below or equal to zero (TL1 = 0).

T2 and T3 are assumed to be linear zones of the tax scale. Thus, the taxable

income is taxed at a constant tax rate tn. t2 is the tax rate of the second zone (n = 2),

accordingly t3 is the tax rate of the third zone (n = 3). Let us now assume that t2 is

lower than t3 to simulate a progressive structure of the whole tax scale (Homburg

2010, p. 65; Siegel and Bareis 2004, p. 114; Pollak 1980, p. 243). By including the

adjustment factor in the form of c3 = TL2 � (t2 – t3) \ 0 in order to avoid

discontinuities in the tax scale, (2) transfers to the following tax scale:

Tax ¼0

t2 � TI

t3 � TI þ TL2 � t2 � t3ð Þ

TI� 0

0\TI� TL2�TI [ TL2

8<

:ð3Þ

3.2.2 The subsistence level as a deduction from the taxable income

It shall now be assumed that the taxable income TI consists of the income

I determined by national tax law. Additionally, a subsistence level (g) shall be

included in calculating the tax burden. The first alternative to grant this subsistence

level is a deduction from the taxable income. This means that the legislator accepts

that these private expenses are deductible like income related expenses. This also

implies that the applicable tax rules must include this form of deduction in the

section defining the taxable income.

If this method applies, the impact on the function of the tax burden can easily be

shown by computing TI = I - g. This term inserted into (3) leads to:

2 A similar method was used by (Bareis 1991, p. 407) in the discussion of the elder tax scale.

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers

123

Page 6: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

Tax ¼0 I � g� 0

t2 � I � gð Þ 0\I � g� TL2

t3 � I � gð Þ þ TL2 � t2 � t3ð Þ I � g[ TL2

8<

:ð4Þ

In the second alternative, the subsistence level is inserted as a basic allowance into

the tax scale. Thus, the whole tax scale only depends on the income I. A definition in

the article determining the taxable income is accordingly avoided. In this alternative

an additional adjustment factor c2 is needed and has to be inserted into the second

zone of tax scale. Additionally, the factor in the third zone (c3) has to be modified.

With c2 = – t2 �g and c3 = TG2 � (t2 – t3) – t3 �g formula (4) transforms into:3

Tax ¼0 I� gt2 � I � t2 � g g\I� TL2 þ gt3 � I þ TL2 � t2 � t3ð Þ � t3 � g I [ TL2 þ g

8<

:: ð5Þ

It can be concluded that if the legislator chooses this method, the provision

defining the tax scale must clarify that the applicability of the zones in the tax scale

depends on g. This fact is implicitly shown by Homburg (1995) and Seidl (1997),

however it is not mentioned explicitly.

The whole concept of granting a subsistence level as a deduction from the taxable

income is illustrated in Fig. 1. The taxable income (I) is shown on the abscissa and

the resulting tax (Tax) is shown on the ordinate. The starting point is the original tax

scale without the consideration of a subsistence level (solid line). It consists of three

scale zones T1, T2 and T3. T1 appears in the interval from negative infinity to point

A, which is equal to the point of origin in the coordinate system. The second zone

T2 is described by the line segment from point A to point B. The point B marks the

transition to the third zone T3 starting at a taxable income of TL2. If no subsistence

level is granted, only c3 is the adjustment factor. It can be graphically described as

the vertical line segment from point A to point C.

The transformation of the original tax scale by including the subsistence level as

a deduction from the taxable income is marked with a dashed line. T10, T2

0 and T30

mark the different zones after the transformation. As can be seen in Fig. 1, the

original tax scale is horizontally shifted to the right. The amount of the shift is the

granted deduction from the taxable income g. Hence the points A and B shift to the

position A0 and B0. That means that the second zone of the tax scale starts at a

taxable income greater than g. Nevertheless, the range of the second zone is not

modified. In contrast to the original tax scale, the third zone does not start at TL2, but

at TL2 ? g. Additionally two new points are inserted. These are the points C10 and

C20. The vertical line segment from A to C1

0 shows the amount of the additional

adjustment factor c2, which is described in Fig. 1 by c20. The vertical line segment

3 We get the value of c2 in order to equalize T2 (g) and T1 (g). T2 is generally defined as T2

(TI) = t2 � TI ? c2. T1 is defined to be the Zero-Zone: T1 = 0. The following result is 0 = t2 � g ? c2.

Transposed to c2, we get c2 = -t2 � g. The value of c3 is the result of the equalization of T2 (TL2 ? g)

and T3 (TL2 ? g), transposed for c3. Therefore, c2 has to be inserted into T2. Thus, we get

t2 � (TL2 ? g) – t2 � g = t3 � (TL2 ? g) ? c3. Transposed to c3, we get after some simplifications

c3 = TL2 � (t2 - t3) – t3 � g.

J. Glowienka

123

Page 7: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

from A to C20 describes the modified adjustment factor c3 in case of a granted

subsistence level. For a better visibility in Fig. 1, it is denoted with c30.

By calculating the difference between the original tax scale and the tax scale with

the subsistence level, it can be demonstrated how each individual taxpayer gains

from the subsistence level granted as a deduction. The difference is named

DTdeduction. It is calculated by subtracting (5) from (4) with TI = I:

DTdeduction ¼

0

� t2 � I� t2 � gI � TL2ð Þ � t2 � t3ð Þ � t2 � g� t3 � g

I� 0

0\I� g

g\I� TL2

TL2\I� TL2 þ g

TL2 þ g\I

8>>>>>><

>>>>>>:

ð6Þ

It can be concluded from (6) that if a taxpayer has an income below zero, there is

no gain from the introduction of a subsistence level. In case of an income between gand TL2 or greater than TL2 ? g, the benefit is constant. If the income of the

taxpayer is within the interval, which is subject to a shift of the tariff section, the

benefit depends on the generated income. Less precisely, the more income is

generated in progressive tax scales, the higher the granted benefit. This result can

also be found in the paper of Peffekoven (1972, p. 408).

All findings for this case can be summarized as follows: Firstly, granting the

subsistence level as a deduction from the taxable income leads to a horizontal shift

of the applicable tax scale. That means that each zone of the tax scale starts at a zone

limit increased by the amount of the subsistence level. Each zone has the same range

as in the original tax scale when no subsistence level was taken into account.

Secondly, if this method may be implemented into the tax scale the same result

occurs. For that case, it is crucial to determine the limits of each zone depending on

the subsistence level.

I TL2

c3

TL2 + ηc2'

c3'

ηA A'

B B'

C

C2'

T2

T3

T1

C1'

T1'

T2'

T3'

Tax scale without the subsistence level

Tax scale with the subsistence level

Direction of the horizontal movement

Tax

Fig. 1 Graphical description of granting the subsistence level as a deduction from the taxable income

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers

123

Page 8: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

3.2.3 The subsistence level as a tax credit

Another possibility of considering the subsistence level is to grant a tax credit. In

contrast to the deduction from the taxable income, this concept provides the same

absolute tax benefit with less modifications for each individual. Peffekoven (1972,

p. 408) points out that a constant tax credit is equal to a decreasing basic allowance

in progressive tax scales. The effects of the subsistence level is shown in Fig. 2

using the same notation as Fig. 1.

If a subsistence level is granted as a tax credit (dashed line in Fig. 2), the tax

scale shifts vertically towards the abscissa. The amount of the shift depends on the

granted tax credit. Nevertheless, the starting point of the second zone (point A) is

horizontally shifted to the right (point A0) if a negative income tax is excluded. This

means that the second zone (T20) begins at a higher taxable income. Contrary to

point A, point B shifts vertically to B0. This means that the starting point of the third

zone (T30) does not move horizontally. However, the application of the third zone

leads to a lower tax. This implies that the range of the second zone is reduced. By

implementing this method into the tax scale, the points C10 and C2

0 mark the amount

of the adjustment factors. The additional adjustment factor c2 is described by the

vertical line segment from A to C10 (marked as c2

0). The modified adjustment factor

c30 consists of the sum of the additional adjustment factor c2

0 and the vertical shifted

adjustment factor c3. The result of this modification of the tax scale is that each

individual who earns an income exceeding g benefits from a constant tax reduction.

In case of implementing this method into the tax scale, expression (7) shows the

impact to the whole tax scale in a formal way. Therefore the tax scale in the second

zone (T2) is not applied to the amount of g and accordingly only the amount of

income that exceeds g is taxed. The additionally inserted adjustment factor (c2) has

again only the task to avoid discontinuities in the tax scale. It shall be pointed out

that the limits of each zone have to be independent from g in the provision of the tax

rules defining the tax scale. This above-mentioned condition integrated into

expression (3) with TI = I leads to the modified tax scale. With c2 = –t2 � g and

c3 = TL2 � (t2 – t3) – t2 � g, one gets:

Tax ¼0 I� gt2 � I � t2 � g g\I� TL2

t3 � I þ TL2 � t2 � t3ð Þ � t2 � g I [ TL2

8<

:: ð7Þ

Additionally, the impact on each individual taxpayer is the difference between

the original tax scale and the tax scale considering the subsistence level. The

difference is described as DTtax credit. It is calculated by subtracting (7) from (3)

under the condition TI = I:

DTtax credit ¼0

� t2 � I� t2 � g

I� 0

0\I� g

g\I

8><

>:ð8Þ

As a result of (8), the benefit for each individual from the subsistence level in the

form of a tax credit depends on the generated income I only if the income is between

J. Glowienka

123

Page 9: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

0 and g. Merely for this range the rule—the higher the generated income, the higher

the benefit for the individual taxpayer—applies. If the income exceeds the amount

of g, the benefit is constant at an amount of c2.

Summarizing the findings of this method, it can be stated that granting a tax

credit leads to a vertical shift of the applicable tax scale. Secondly, this method can

also be implemented into the tax scale. Therefore it is necessary to point out that the

relevant provision of the national tax law has to define the limits of each zone

independently from the granted subsistence level. Thirdly, each person with an

income exceeding the amount of the subsistence level is granted a constant tax

benefit.

3.3 Critical reflection of the European legal framework

Taking the decisions of the ECJ into account, it can be stated that the subsistence

level for nonresidents may in general be refused in the state of source (Schumacker-

Doctrine). As already mentioned, the ECJ (2003) stated in the second principle of its

decision in that the refusal of the subsistence level by adding the applicable amount

to the taxable income should in general be in line with the European legal

framework.

This headnote is intuitively comprehensible if the subsistence level is granted as

a deduction from the taxable income. Starting at expression (5) and substituting the

income I with I ? g, which describes the addition of the subsistence level to the

income, one gets the expression (3) with TI = I. This is the tax scale if no

subsistence level is taken into account. That means that if the subsistence level is

granted by deduction from the taxable income, the modification described by the

ECJ (2003) leads to the ‘‘correct’’ result as this modification does not lead to a tax

burden additional to the tax burden caused by the refusal of the subsistence level.

The results change if the subsistence level is granted as a tax credit (7). If the

amount of g is added to the domestic income of a nonresident, this leads to the

following expression (9). With TI = I ? g, one gets for (7):

Tax

I TL2

c3

c2'

c3'

ηA

B

B'

C

C2'

T2

T3

T1

C1'

T1'

T3'

T2'

A'

c3 Tax scale without the subsistence level

Tax scale with the subsistence level

Direction of the horizontal movement

Fig. 2 Graphical description of granting the subsistence level as a tax credit

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers

123

Page 10: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

Tax ¼0 I� 0

t2 � I I� TL2 � gt3 � I þ TL2 � t2 � t3ð Þ þ g � t3 � t2ð Þ I [ TL2 � g

8<

:ð9Þ

which is not equal to (3) with TI = I in the third zone of the tax scale. As a result, an

additional tax is levied on the domestic income of nonresidents if the principle of

the decision in the case Gerritse (ECJ 2003) is applied by way of a tax credit and

this income in the state of source exceeds TL2 - g. In other words, the refusal in

accordance with the principles of the Gerritse decision (ECJ 2003) results in dif-

ferent tax scales for residents and nonresidents. This is inconsistent with the earlier

court decision in case Asscher (ECJ 1996) in which the ECJ ruled against the

application of a further additional tax on the domestic income of nonresidents.

Assuming that the principles of both rulings shall not be violated, the subsistence

level must be refused in a different way than proposed in Gerritse (ECJ 2003).

Instead of adding g, this term must be set equal to zero (g = 0) in order to calculate

the tax burden for nonresidents for the correct refusal. Using formula (7), one

obtains with c2 = -t2 � g = 0 and c3 = TL2 � (t2 - t3) - t2 � g = TL2 � (t2 -

t3) \ 0 the following expression, which is identical to (3) with TI = I:

Tax ¼0

t2 � It3 � I þ TL2 � t2 � t3ð Þ

I� 0

0\I� TL2

I [ TL2

8<

:: ð10Þ

In order to calculate the additional tax burden for nonresidents caused by the

method described by formula (9) for the incorrect refusal, expression (10) has to be

subtracted from (9). For this purpose, expression (10) gets the notation Tg=0 and

expression (9) the notation TI?g. The additional tax burden shall be named

DTincorrect refusal. With DTincorrect refusal = TI?g - Tg=0 one gets:

DTincorrect refusal ¼0 I� TL2 � gI þ gð Þ � t3 � t2ð Þ þ TL2 � t2 � t3ð Þ TL2 � g\I� TL2

g � t3 � t2ð Þ I [ TL2

8<

:: ð11Þ

This additional tax burden is zero up to an income of TL2 - g. After that it

increases until the taxable income reaches TL2. If the taxable income exceeds this

limit, the additional burden remains constant.

The following Fig. 3 illustrates the problem graphically. The starting point now

is the tax scale with a tax credit (short dashed line). The tax scale is divided into the

three zones T10, T2

0 and T30. Point A0 characterizes the zone limit, which is g for the

end of the Zero-Zone (T10) and the beginning of the second zone of the tax scale

(T20). Point B0 marks the end of the second zone in TL2 and the beginning of the

third zone. C10 and C2

0 mark the amount of the adjustment factors essential to avoid

discontinuities in the applicable tax scale.

If the subsistence level is correctly refused (g = 0), the original tax scale without

an integration of a subsistence level similar to Eq. (3) is received. This is shown in

Fig. 3 with a solid line. It consists of the three zones of the tax scale T1, T2 and T3.

The point A denotes the end of the first zone T1 and the beginning of zone T2. B

denotes the end of the second zone T2 and the beginning of the third zone T3. The

J. Glowienka

123

Page 11: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

vertical line segment from point A to point C describes the adjustment factor c3 of

the third zone T3. As a result, the tax scale with subsistence level is moved vertically

up (black arrow). The maximum of the additional tax burden for taxpayers who are

faced with the refusal of the subsistence level is denoted by the vertical line segment

a.

In case of an incorrect refusal, the tax scale moves horizontally to the left (dashed

arrow) and accordingly points A0 and B0 move to the left. A00 describes the end of the

first zone of the tax scale (T100). In this zone, the correct and the incorrect refusal

lead to the same result.

Point B00 describes the end of the second zone T200. Following the above-

mentioned example, it horizontally moves to the position TL2 - g. Again in this

zone, the correct and incorrect refusal lead to the same result until the income equals

TL2 - g. The maximum of the additional tax burden is the vertical line segment a.

If however the income of the taxpayer exceeds this amount, the zone T300 applies

and thus the taxpayer is faced with an additional tax. This additional tax increases

until the taxable income reaches TL2 (point B200). If the income exceeds TL2, the

additional tax remains constant. The bold formatted vertical line segment

(DTincorrect refusal) in Fig. 3 denotes this additional tax. The additional tax burden

as a whole describes the vertical line segment b in Fig. 3. It consists of the

additional tax burden caused by the refusal of the subsistence level (line segment a)

and the additional tax caused by the horizontal shift of the tax scale

(DTincorrect refusal).

The findings can be summarized as follows: Firstly, refusing the subsistence level

to a nonresident by adding this amount to the domestic income should be in line

with the European legal framework following the ECJ decision in case Gerritse

(ECJ 2003). Secondly, this leads to the correct refusal if the subsistence level is

granted to residents as a deduction from the taxable income. Thirdly, the refusal of

the subsistence level leads to an additional tax burden for nonresidents if it is

A'

Tax

I

c3

ηA, A''

B

B'

T3

T1 , T

1'' T

1'

T3'

T2'' T

2'

ΔTincorrect refusal

B''

T3''

C''

TL2

TL2–η

C

C2'

a

a

b

C1' c3'

T2

Tax scale without subsistence level

Tax scale with subsistence level

Tax scale with incorrect refusal

Direction of the horizontal movement in case of a incorrect refusal

Direction of the vertical movement in case of a correct refusal

Fig. 3 Graphical description of the incorrect and the correct refusal of a tax credit

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers

123

Page 12: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

granted as a tax credit. In the latter case, a conflict between the more recent decision

in the year 2003 (ECJ 2003) and the earlier decision in the year 1996 (ECJ 1996)

can be identified. This is a finding, which should be discussed more intensively by

legal research on taxation.

3.4 Numerical example

In the following numerical example the effects of the above-mentioned methods and

the implications from the rulings of the ECJ shall be demonstrated for an individual

taxpayer and a fictional state.

A nation with five taxpayers shall be assumed where each taxpayer earns a

different annual income I (EUR 5,000; EUR 15,000; EUR 25,000; EUR 35,000 and

EUR 50,000). Furthermore, a simple tax scale as demonstrated in (3) with TI = I,

t2 = 10 % and t3 = 50 % shall be assumed. The limit of the zone (TL2) is set at an

amount of EUR 30,000.

As a start, the government of the state plans to introduce a subsistence level g of

EUR 10,000 that is integrated into the tax scale and granted as a deduction from the

taxable income similar to expression (5). Following (5), the government has to

define the limits of each zone depending on the subsistence level. In the following

Table 1, the columns show the individuals, their annual income, their income tax if

no subsistence level is granted, their income tax if a subsistence level is granted and

in the last column the benefit for each individual from introducing the subsistence

level. Each row of the table describes the impact on each individual. The last row

shows the impact on all taxpayers as a sum. This may be interpreted as the fiscal

effect on the state as a whole.

As can be seen in Table 1, the introduction of a subsistence level as a deduction

from the taxable income leads to a reduced tax burden for each individual. Thus, the

government earns a reduced amount of taxes. The benefit for each individual

depends in general on the generated income. It is constant if before and after

considering a subsistence level the same zone applies. It varies if the applicable

zone changes.

Alternatively, the government plans to introduce a subsistence level by

implementing a tax credit into the tax scale. Therefore, expression (7) is used in

Table 1 A numerical example for the impact on introducing the subsistence level as a deduction from

the taxable income

Individual Annual

income in

EUR

Income tax according to

(3) in EUR (applied

zone, average tax rate)

Income tax according to

(5) in EUR (applied

zone, average tax rate)

Benefit from introducing

the subsistence level

according to (6) in EUR

1 5,000 500 (T2, 10 %) 0 (T1, 0 %) -500

2 15,000 1,500 (T2, 10 %) 500 (T2, 3 %) -1,000

3 25,000 2,500 (T2, 10 %) 1,500 (T2, 6 %) -1,000

4 35,000 5,500 (T3, 16 %) 2,500 (T2, 7 %) -3,000

5 50,000 13,000 (T3, 26 %) 8,000 (T3, 16 %) -5,000

Sum 130,000 23,000 (18 %) 12,500 (10 %) -10,500

J. Glowienka

123

Page 13: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

order to modify the tariff function. Again, an amount of EUR 10,000 shall be

exempted from taxation. Table 2 shows the impact of granting a subsistence level as

a tax credit.

Similar to the method of deduction, every taxpayer with an income greater than

zero gains from the tax credit. Furthermore, the amount of the benefit differs. In the

above-mentioned example, taxpayers with an income exceeding the subsistence

level g gain a constant tax benefit of EUR 1,000 if the tax credit is granted. Only if

the income is greater than zero but less than g, the taxpayers’ benefit is less than for

any other income. The reason is quite simply identified: a person with a low income

has accordingly a lower tax burden levied on this income than a person with a

higher income.

In order to compare the possible impact on the state, the last rows of Tables 1 and

2 are relevant. Following these two examples, it is less expensive for the

government to grant a tax credit than applying the method of deduction when

introducing a subsistence level. As shown in Table 1, the introduction of a

subsistence level of EUR 10,000 costs the government EUR 10,500 of unearned

taxes compared to the situation where no subsistence level is granted. In case of the

subsistence level granted as tax credit, the state earns less taxes of EUR 4,500. From

a tax revenues’ perspective, it is more attractive to grant a tax credit. Additionally,

this result may be politically relevant as every taxable person is faced with the same

tax benefit.4

The following Table 3 analyzes the impact of the refusal of the subsistence level

according to the court decision in case Gerritse (ECJ 2003). For this, it is assumed

that the subsistence level is implemented into the tax scale as a tax credit (7).

Additionally, all five taxpayers are now assumed to be nonresidents.

If the subsistence level is refused the way it is granted, this would lead to the

results in the third column. In contrast to that, the fourth column shows the results of

the tax burden on non-residents if the subsistence level is refused as proposed in the

ruling ECJ (2003). The last column shows the additional tax burden caused by the

incorrect refusal. From the tax revenues perspective, it is more attractive to reject

Table 2 A numerical example for the impact on introducing a subsistence level as a tax credit

Individual Annual

income in

EUR

Income tax according to

(3) in EUR (applied

zone, average tax rate)

Income tax according to

(7) in EUR (applied

zone, average tax rate)

Benefit from introducing

the subsistence level

according to (8) in EUR

1 5,000 500 (T2, 10 %) 0 (T1, 0 %) -500

2 15,000 1,500 (T2, 10 %) 500 (T2, 3 %) -1,000

3 25,000 2,500 (T2, 10 %) 1,500 (T2, 6 %) -1,000

4 35,000 5,500 (T3, 16 %) 4,500 (T3, 7 %) -1,000

5 50,000 13,000 (T3, 26 %) 12,000 (T3, 16 %) -1,000

Sum 130,000 23,000 (18 %) 18,500 (14 %) -4,500

4 This might be interesting regarding to the discussion in German literature (summarized by Wosnitza

and Treisch 1999a, b). In focus was often the question, what is the most equitable way to grant this tax

benefit.

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers

123

Page 14: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

the subsistence level as proposed in the Gerritse decision (ECJ 2003) if it is

integrated as tax credit. Rejecting the subsistence level regarding this method, leads

to additional tax revenues of EUR 10,000.

4 The subsistence level in Germany

4.1 National legal framework

In the last sections, the problems with respect to granting the subsistence level were

discussed in an abstract manner. However, using the example of Germany, it can be

shown that these problems may have a much greater effect than suspected at first glance.

Pursuant to sec. 1 (1) of the German Income Tax Act (ITA), a person is

considered to be a resident taxpayer if his habitual abode or dwelling is in Germany.

Accordingly, a nonresident person is subject to a limited taxation if domestic

German income as codified in sec. 49 ITA is generated.

Following the ECJ rulings, income related expenses may be deducted from the

domestic income of a nonresident, however nonresidents are excluded from deducting

expenses deriving from their individual situation in accordance with sec. 50 (1) ITA.

In general, the taxable income of residents is inserted into the tax scale in

accordance with sec. 32a ITA in order to calculate the tax burden. As a result, the

tax exemption of the subsistence level is automatically granted. In contrast to

residents, a subsistence level is in general not granted to nonresidents.5 Due to the

changes in the German tax law in 2009,6 the taxable income of nonresidents is

increased by the amount of the subsistence level (sec 50 (1) sentence 2, 1st clause

ITA). Subsequently, this increased income has to be inserted into the tax scale

Table 3 A numerical example for the refusal of the subsistence level according to the rulings of the ECJ

2003—Gerritse if the subsistence level is granted as a tax credit

Individual Annual

income

in EUR

Income tax according

to (3) in EUR (applied

zone, average tax rate)

Income tax according

to (9) in EUR (applied

zone, average tax rate)

Additional annual tax burden

caused by the incorrect

refusal according to (10) in

EUR

1 5,000 500 (T2, 10 %) 500 (T2, 10 %) 0

2 15,000 1,500 (T2, 10 %) 1,500 (T2, 10 %) 0

3 25,000 2,500 (T2, 10 %) 4,500 (T3, 18 %) ?2,000

4 35,000 5,500 (T3, 16 %) 9,500 (T3, 27 %) ?4,000

5 50,000 13,000 (T3, 26 %) 17,000 (T3, 34 %) ?4,000

Sum 130,000 23,000 (18 %) 33,000 (25 %) ?10,000

5 For example employees are excluded from this general principle according to sec. 50 (1) ITA. Another

exception applies to nonresidents who earn most of their income in Germany and who can opt for a

fictitious unlimited tax liability in accordance with sec. 1 (3) ITA.6 In 2009 the taxation of income of nonresidents has been changed within the framework of the annual

tax act in Germany (JStG 2009). Substantial change was the abolishment of the minimum taxation. This

enactment was based on the decision of the ECJ (2003).

J. Glowienka

123

Page 15: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

pursuant to sec. 32a ITA in order to calculate the tax burden. In legal based

literature, this procedure is interpreted as only a technical implementation

(Loschelder 2013, p. 2262). This is an assumption that is further analyzed in the

following sections.

4.2 The German tax scale and its parameters

The German income tax scale T(I) is divided into five zones. Within these zones,

discrete functions Tn(I) within the limits of each tax scale TLn are applied. The first

zone is the so-called ‘‘Zero Zone’’. This is followed by two progressive zones

having a rising curve of marginal tax rates. Therefore, the tax scales in the second

and third zone are described as quadratic functions (‘‘linear-progressive areas’’,

Homburg 2010, p. 79).

The parameters an and bn describe the path of the marginal tax rate function and

shall be considered as exogenously given by the legislator.7 The absolute term cn is

however endogenously determined by the defined tax scale in order to avoid

discontinuities in the curve characteristics (Homburg 2010, p. 79). In the political

discussion, a starting marginal tax rate is often mentioned (i. e. Bundesrat 2012). It

is necessary to point out that such starting tax rate is not defined in the relevant

article sec. 32a ITA. There are only functions depending on the taxable income

given. The last two zones of the German income tax scale are linear functions.

Summarizing the above statements, the tax scale in accordance with sec. 32a (1)

ITA can in general be described by:

TðIÞ ¼

0 I� TL1

I � ða2 � I þ b2Þ þ c2 TL1\I� TL2

I � ða3 � I þ b3Þ þ c3 TL2\I� TL3

t4 � I þ c4 TL3\I� TL4

t5 � I þ c5 I [ TL4

8>>>><

>>>>:

: ð12Þ

The defined zone limits of the tax scale pursuant to sec. 32a (1) ITA exclusively

depend on the taxable income (I). Therefore, the subsistence level is not taken into

account, which again means that at no point an emphasis is placed on the

relationship between the limits of the zones (TLn) and the granting of the subsistence

level. This indicates that the German legislator applies a tax credit to grant the

subsistence level (see chapter 3.2.3; Bareis 1999a, p. 93). The following Table 4

shows the amount and the origin of each zone limit of the tax scale in sec 32a ITA.

For the general analysis, the section limits and the relevant adjustment factors of each

zone in the German tax scale were calculated. The section limits of the second and the

fifth zone (g and h) are given exogenously by the legislator. The others can be calculated

by equalizing the first derivatives of the second and the third zone as well as equalizing

the first derivatives of the third and the fourth zone. The individual adjustment factors are

calculated by equalizing the adjacent tax functions of each zone. The results for all

absolute terms in each section of the tax scale are displayed in Table 4.

7 A quite similar notification can be found at (Siegel 1999, p. 559).

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers

123

Page 16: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

In Table 4 it is shown that the subsistence level is taken into account in the form

of a constant adjustment of g � (a2 � g ? b2) which is subtracted from the remaining

income tax. This means, that Germany grants the subsistence level as a tax credit.

4.3 The additional tax burden of nonresidents

4.3.1 The consequence of sec. 50 (1) ITA

Following the interpretation of the ECJ judgment in case Gerritse (ECJ 2003), the

taxable income of a nonresident is increased by the amount of the subsistence level

[sec. 50 (1) sentence 2, first clause ITA]. After this modification, the tax scale

pursuant to sec. 32a (1) ITA has to be used. In contrast to the opinion in literature

(Loschelder 2013, p. 2262), the taxable income still has a virtual component equal

to the amount of the subsistence level. Loschelder justifies his opinion by the fact

that this component would be eliminated by the adjustment factor of each zone in

the tax scale. Additionally, he shows two examples (Loschelder 2013, p. 2262).

However, another consequence caused by adding the subsistence level—and this

is missing in his argumentation—is that each particular zone applies for a lower

income, which means that the income is taxed at a higher rate. As generally shown

in chapter 3.3, the shift of the different limits of the tax scale is a horizontal shift

towards the point of origin. The amount of the horizontal switch is equal to the

amount of the subsistence level.

Table 4 Limits of the tax scale and adjustment factors of the German income tax scale in accordance

with sec 32a ITA

Zone (n) Zone limit (TLn-1) Adjustment factor (cn)

1 – –

2 g c2 = -g � (a2 � g ? b2)

3 12� b3�b2

a3�a2 c3 ¼ � 14� b2�b3ð Þ2

a2�a3þ c2

4 12� t4�b3

a3 c4 ¼ � 14� b3�t4ð Þ2

a3þ c3

5 h c5 = -h � (t5 - t4) ? c4

Table 5 Limits of the tax scale and adjustment factors of a nonresident taxpayer taxed pursuant to sec.

50 (1) ITA

Zone (n) Zone limit (TLn–1) Adjustment factor (cn)

1 – –

2 0 c2 = 0

3 12� b3�b2

a3�a2� g c3 ¼ 1

4� b2�b3þ2�g� a2�a3ð Þ½ �� b3�b2þ2�g� a2�a3ð Þ½ �

a2�a3

4 12� t4�b3

a3� g c4 ¼ 1

4� b3�t4þ2�g�a3½ �� t4�b3þ2�g�a3½ �

a3þ c3

5 h - g c5 = (h - g) � (t4 - t5) ? c4

J. Glowienka

123

Page 17: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

The results for the German tax scale are described in Table 5. Not surprisingly,

the zone limits and the adjustment factors differ from those in Table 4.

4.3.2 The consequence of setting the subsistence level equal to zero

As already mentioned in the general analysis, g must set equal to zero if the

subsistence level is granted as tax credit. Thus, in this case TL1 shifts to the point of

origin while the other sections remain unchanged. That means that the marginal tax

rates for income greater than the subsistence level are identical for resident and

nonresident taxpayers. This is in contrast to the current procedure ruled in sec.

50 (1) ITA.

In contrast to the limits of the tax scale, the absolute term changes. This occurs

first in the second zone where the adjustment factor c2 now equals zero. This leads

to further changes in all subsequent zones as the adjustment factors of each section

are decreased by the constant amount of g � (a2 � g ? b2). Table 6 summarizes the

different results for each zone.

Finally, if the subsistence level is denied, the tax scale pursuant to sec. 32a (1)

ITA is used for nonresidents in such a way that second zone is applied to an income

higher than zero up to the limit TL2. The other limits remain unchanged. With

Table 6 Limits of the tax scale and adjustment terms of the German income tax scale in the case of the

denial of the subsistence level

Zone (n) Zone limit (TLn–1) Adjustment factor (cn)

1 – –

2 g c2 = 0

3 12� b3�b2

a3�a2 c3 ¼ � 14� b2�b3ð Þ2

a2�a3

4 12� t4�b3

a3 c4 ¼ � 14� b3�t4ð Þ2

a3þ b2�b3ð Þ2

a2�a3

h i

5 h c5 ¼ �h � t5 � t4ð Þ � 14� b3�t4ð Þ2

a3þ b2�b3ð Þ2

a2�a3

h i

Table 7 Exogenous and endogenous parameters for the tax year 2014

Exogenous parameter Value Endogenous parameter Value in EUR

a2 974.58 9 10-8 TL2 13,469

b2 -2,283,282.64 9 10-8 TL3 52,881

a3 228.74 9 10-8 c2 -489

b3 17,808,201.88 9 10-8 c3 -1,842

t4 0.42 c4 -8,239

t5 0.45 c5 -15,761

g EUR 8,354

h EUR 250,730

Source: Sec. 32a ITA, press release of the German Bundesrat (2012) and own calculations

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers

123

Page 18: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

respect to a nonresident taxpayer, the adjustment factor of each zone is decreased by

the amount of the adjustment factor of the second zone.

4.4 The comparison of both methods

In order to show the impact on nonresident taxpayers, the different tax burdens of

each method are calculated. In the first column of Table 7, the calculated exogenous

parameters are described for the tax year 2014 which influence the endogenous

parameters displayed in the third column of Table 7.

The annual additional tax burden DT(I) of nonresidents compared to the one of

residents are displayed in Fig. 4. The calculations neglect the solidarity surcharge in

Germany. If the parameter of the subsistence level is set equal to zero, the additional

tax burden of a nonresident increases up to the amount where the income is equal to

the subsistence level. If the domestic income exceeds the subsistence level, the

additional tax burden remains constant at EUR 489.

This is in contrast to the current method where the taxable income is increased by

the subsistence level. In this case, the absolute tax burden of a nonresident increases

until an annual income of EUR 52,881 is reached. The additional tax burden

increases to approximately EUR 3,509. The maximum of the additional tax burden

is reached at an income exceeding EUR 250,730 leading to an additional tax of

approximately EUR 3,759.

The treatment of residents and nonresidents in relation to their marginal and

average tax rates is shown in Fig. 5. If the subsistence level is refused, the marginal

tax rate on the German income of nonresident taxpayers increases from zero to the

‘‘starting tax rate’’ of 14 %. This applies when the income is less than the

subsistence level. If the income exceeds the subsistence level, the marginal tax rate

Fig. 4 The annual additional tax burden of a nonresident

J. Glowienka

123

Page 19: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

of a nonresident taxpayer is exactly the same as the one of a resident taxpayer.

Nevertheless, the average tax rates of nonresidents are higher for all income.

Under the current provision, the marginal tax rates for nonresidents are—up to a

domestic income of EUR 52,881—higher compared to the marginal tax rates of

resident taxpayers. The same applies within the interval of a taxable income from

EUR 242,376 to EUR 250,730. Between EUR 52,881 and EUR 242,376 and for an

income of more than EUR 250,731, the marginal tax rates are equal for both,

residents and nonresidents. The average tax rate for nonresidents starts at 14 %.

Moreover, this average tax rate is higher than for residents and also exceeds the case

in which the subsistence level is correctly refused.

5 Conclusion

The topic of this article was the impact of the refusal of the subsistence level for

nonresidents. This topic is influenced on the one side by the decisions of the ECJ

and on the other side by the national tax law. After a short literature overview, the

analysis started with the general legal framework set by the ECJ.

The theoretical analysis pointed out that granting the subsistence level as a

deduction from the taxable income leads to a horizontal shift of the applicable tax

scale. This method can be implemented into the tariff function, which leads to an

equivalent result. For those purposes it is crucial to determine the limits of each

zone depending on the subsistence level.

Fig. 5 Marginal and average tax rates of residents and nonresidents

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers

123

Page 20: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

Secondly, granting the subsistence level as a tax credit leads to a vertical shift of

the applicable tax scale. This method can also be implemented into the tax scale. For

that purpose, the relevant article of the national tax law has to define the limits of

each zone independently from the granted subsistence level.

Following ECJ (2003), it should be in line with the European legal framework

that the subsistence level is refused for nonresidents by adding the applicable

amount to the generated income in the state of source. However if the subsistence

level is granted as a tax credit, this refusal leads to an additional tax burden for

nonresidents on top of the additional tax caused by the denial of the subsistence

level. Thus, in these situations a conflict between the more recent decision in case

Gerritse (ECJ 2003) and the earlier decision in case Asscher (ECJ 1996) can be

identified. This finding should be more intensively discussed by legal research on

taxation.

A numerical example was used to in general describe the fiscal impact of a state

in general. It can be concluded that it is firstly financially less attractive for a state to

grant the subsistence level as a deduction from the taxable income than as a tax

credit. Secondly, refusing the subsistence level the same way it is granted is

financially less attractive than using the second principle the ECJ set in case Gerritse

in 2003 (ECJ 2003).

The findings were applied to the case of Germany to give a less general example.

It was established that the subsistence level even in Germany is granted as a tax

credit. This was identified by analyzing the definitions of the tariff limits in sec. 32a

ITA which do not depend on the subsistence level. Following the taxation of

nonresidents in accordance with the decision of the ECJ, nonresidents who are

denied the subsistence level are faced with an additional tax burden. At its

maximum, this additional tax burden amounts to EUR 3,759. This might be in

breach with the rulings of the ECJ (1995) and should be relevant for further legal

research of this topic.

Acknowledgments This paper has benefit from contributions of various people, especially Stephan

Kudert, Adrian Cloer and the participants of the 6th EUV/EBS Doctoral Seminar in Warsaw. Language

support was delivered by Daniela Blaudow and Michaela Schreier. Finally, the department editor Jochen

Hundsdoerfer and two anonymous reviewers provided very helpful support on this and a former version

of this manuscript.

References

Bareis P (1991) Existenzminimum, Bemessungsgrundlage und Tarifstruktur bei der Einkommensteuer.

Finanz-Rundschau fur Einkommensteuer mit Korperschaftsteuer und Gewerbesteuer 73(14):

405–412

Bareis P (1999a) Leistungsfahigkeit, Existenzminimum, progression und Staatshaushalt. Diskussion des

Beitrags von Michael Wosnitza und Corinna Treisch DBW 59. Jg. (1999), S. 351–368. Die

Betriebswirtschaft 59(4):555–558

Bareis P (1999b) Systematisierung der Einkommensteuer. In: Henke K (ed) Zur Zukunft der

Staatsfinanzierung, 1st edn. Nomos, Baden–Baden, pp 87–101

Bareis P (2010) Zur Problematik steuerjuristischer Vorgaben fur die Einkommensteuer. Tarifstruktur und

Familiensplitting als Musterbeispiele. Deutsches Steuerrecht 48(11):565–574

Bundesrat (2012) Press release 192/2012. Grundfreibetrag steigt. http://www.bundesrat.de/DE/presse/pm/

2012/192-2012.html

J. Glowienka

123

Page 21: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

BVerfG (1992) 2. Senat (1992). BVerfGE 87:153–181

ECJ (1995) C-279/93, Schumacker. Slg. 1995:I-249–I-268

ECJ (1996) C-107/94, Asscher. Slg. 1996:I-3113–I-3132

ECJ (2003) C-234/01, Gerritse. Slg. 2003:I-5945–I-5963

ECJ (2004) C-169/03, Wallentin. Slg. 2004:I-6458–I-6468

Englisch J (2003) Zur Dogmatik der Grundfreiheiten des EGV und ihren ertragsteuerlichen Implika-

tionen. Steuer und Wirtschaft 80:88–97

Grams H, Schon I (2008) Die Kunstlerbesteuerung nach dem Referentenentwurf des BMF und dem

Regierungsentwurf zum Jahressteuergesetz 2009. Internationales Steuerrecht 17(18):656–661

Greggi M (2009) European taxation of dividends, interests and royalities: the impact on third countries

investors. Issues Bus Law 1:115–128

Hey J, Seer R (2013) Einkommensteuer. In: Lang J, Tipke K (eds) Steuerrecht, 21st edn. Schmidt, Koln,

pp 263–457

Homburg S (1995) Zur Steuerfreiheit des Existenzminimums: Grundfreibetrag oder Abzug von der

Bemessungsgrundlage? FinanzArchiv 52(2):182–195

Homburg S (2010) Allgemeine Steuerlehre, 6th edn. Vahlen, Munchen

Jachmann M (1999) Gleichmaßige Besteuerung nach der wirtschaftlichen Leistungsfahigkeit und

Umverteilung. Stellungnahme zu Michael Wosnitza/Corinna Treisch: ‘‘Leistungsfahigkeitskonzep-

tionen und steuerliche Behandlung des Existenzminimums’’, DBW 59. Jg. (1999), S. 351–368. Die

Betriebswirtschaft: DBW 59(4):553–555

JStG (2009) Jahressteuergesetz 2009. JStG 2009, BGBl. I 2008 63:2794–2845

Kokott J, Ost H (2011) Europaische Grundfreiheiten und nationales Steuerrecht. Europaische Zeitschrift

fur Wirtschaftsrecht 22(13):496–503

Liebing P (2004) Beschrankte Einkommensteuerpflicht in der Europaischen Union. Wege fur eine

Neukonzeption. Dissertation. Universitat Universitat Duisburg-Essen

Loschelder F (2013) § 50 EStG Sondervorschriften fur beschrankt Steuerpflichtige. In: Weber-Grellet H

(ed) Einkommensteuergesetz, 32nd edn. Beck, C H, Munchen, pp 2257–2270

Mattson N (2003) Does the European Court of Justice understand the policy behind tax benefits based on

personal and family circumstances? Eur Tax 43(6):186–194

Peffekoven R (1972) Freibetrag oder Steuerkredit? Zu einem Problem der Einkommensteuerreform.

FinanzArchiv 30(3):392–417

Pollak H (1980) Steuertarife. Handbuch der Finanzwissenschaft 2(1980):239–266

Schneider D (1999) Das einkommensteuerliche Existenzminimum: kein problem alternativer Lei-

stungsfahigkeitskonzeptionen, sondern ein Tarif- und Transferproblem. Stellungnahme zu Michael

Wosnitza/Corinna Treisch: Leistungsfahigkeitskonzeptionen und steuerliche Behandlung des

Existenzminimums DBW 59 (1999), S. 351-368. Die Betriebswirtschaft: DBW 59(4):560–563

Seer R, Kahler B, Ruping H, Thulfaut K (2005) Die Rechtsprechung des EuGH auf dem Gebiet der

direkten Besteuerung in den Jahren 2003 und 2004. Europaisches Wirtschafts- und Steuerrecht

2005(7):289–309

Seidl C (1997) Die steuerliche Berucksichtigung des Existenzminimums—tarifliche Nullzone, Freibetrag

oder Steuerabsetzbetrag? Steuer und Wirtschaft 74:142–146

Siegel T (1999) Existenzminum und Leistungsfahigkeit. Diskussion des Beitrags von Michael Wosnitza

und Corinna Treisch DBW 59. Jg. (1999), S. 351-368. Die Betriebswirtschaft. Stuttgart: Schaffer-

Poeschel 59(4):558–560 (ISSN 0342-7064, ZDB-ID 2130531)

Siegel T, Bareis P (2004) Strukturen der Besteuerung. Betriebswirtschaftliches Arbeitsbuch Steuerrecht;

Grundzuge des Steuersystems in Strukturubersichten, Beispielen und Aufgaben, 4th edn.

Oldenbourg, Munchen, Wien

Siegel T, Schneider D (1994) Existenzminimum und Familienlastenausgleich: Ein Problem der Reform

des Einkommensteuerrechts. Deutsches Steuerrecht 32(17):597–604

Treisch C (1999a) Existenzminimum und Einkommensbesteuerung. Dogmengeschichte, Analyse der

Besteuerungsprinzipien und Regelungsvorschlag. Dissertation, Technische Universitat Chemnitz

Treisch C (2005) Taxable treatment of the subsistence level of income in German Natural Law. Acc Bus

Financ Hist 15(3):255–278

Wattel P (2000) Progressive Taxation of non-residents and intra-EC allocation of personal tax

allowances: why Schumacker, Asscher, Gilly and Gschwind do not suffice. Eur Tax 40(6):210–223

Wied E (2013) § 50 EStG. In: Heuermann B (ed) Einkommensteuergesetz, Korperschaftsteuergesetz,

Gewerbesteuergesetz. EStG, KStG, GewStG; Kommentar, Stand: Juni 2013 (119. Erg.-Lfg.).

Vahlen, Munchen

The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers

123

Page 22: The refusal of the subsistence level for nonresident taxpayers: an analytical survey of the relevant legal framework

Wosnitza M, Treisch C (1999a) Leistungsfahigkeitskonzeptionen und steuerliche Behandlung des

Existenzminimums. Die Betriebswirtschaft: DBW 59(3):351–368

Wosnitza M, Treisch C (1999b) Existenzminimum und Maßgroßen der steuerlichen Leistungsfahigkeit.

Replik zu den Stellungnahmen von Bareis, Jachmann, Schneider und Siegel. Die Betriebswirtschaft:

DBW 59(4):563–564

J. Glowienka

123