27
1 THE PROFIT ORIENTATION OF MICROFINANCE INSTITUTIONS AND EFFECTIVE INTEREST RATES Peter W. Roberts * Goizueta Business School Emory University 1300 Clifton Road, Atlanta, GA, 30322 404‐727‐8585 404‐727‐6313 [email protected] * The author is grateful for the helpful comments provided by David Kyle, Anand Swaminathan and Peter Thompson.

The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

1  

THEPROFITORIENTATIONOFMICROFINANCEINSTITUTIONS

ANDEFFECTIVEINTERESTRATES

PeterW.Roberts*

GoizuetaBusinessSchool

EmoryUniversity

1300CliftonRoad,Atlanta,GA,30322

404‐727‐8585

404‐727‐6313

[email protected]

*TheauthorisgratefulforthehelpfulcommentsprovidedbyDavidKyle,AnandSwaminathanandPeterThompson.

Page 2: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

2  

THEPROFITORIENTATIONOFMICROFINANCEINSTITUTIONS

ANDEFFECTIVEINTERESTRATES

Sincethearrivaloffor‐profitmicrofinanceinstitutions(MFIs),commentatorshavebeenasking

whetherthesectorbenefitsbyMFIsadoptingastrongerprofitorientation.Weaddressthis

questionbyanalyzingtheiradoptionofthefor‐profitlegalform,appointingprivatesector

representationandbankingacumentoMFIboards,andparticipationinmoreextensivefor‐profit

networks.Theresultsconsistentlyindicatethatastrongerfor‐profitorientationcorrespondswith

highereffectiveinterestratesforMFIclients.However,theseeffectsdonotleadtogreater

profitabilityandthereforesustainabilitybecausethesevariablesarealsoassociatedwithincreases

inthemajorelementsofanMFI’scosts.

KeyWords:microfinance,global,interestrates,nonprofit

Page 3: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

3  

“SomeFearProfitMotivetoTrumpPovertyEffortsinMicrofinance”–NewYorkTimesheadline,August28,2009

1.INTRODUCTION

Microfinanceinstitutions(MFIs)arebankingorganizationswhoseprimarypurposeisthatof

providingfinancialservicestopoorandotherwisemarginalizedclients(Mersland&Strøm,2010).

Collectively,themicrofinancesectorislaudedformodifyingstandardbankingpracticesinorderto

effectivelyextendcredittothepoorandindoingsohelpingtoelevatetheirstandardsofliving.

Morespecifically,theinnovationsthatledtothemodernmicrofinancemovementovercametwo

problemspreviouslythoughttoprohibitlendingtothepoor:smallloansizesandlittleorno

collateral(Armendariz&Morduch,2005).

Therecentevolutionofthemicrofinancesectorcanbeviewedintermsoftherapidgrowth

inthenumberofactiveMFIs,increasesinthevolumeofbusinesstheyconduct,abroaderrangeof

financialservicesonoffer,andchangesinthetypesandmotivationsofMFIs.Inthislatterrespect,an

importantmarkerinthesector’sevolutionisthearrivalofprofit‐orientedMFIs.Althoughlaudedby

manyascritically‐importantforthematurationofthesector,theseMFIsalsousheredindebates

aboutwhetheritispossibletoeffectivelyblendnonprofitidealsandfor‐profitorientationsand

practices(Morduch,2000).

Morepractically,thesedebatesarerootedinquestionsaboutwhetherMFIswithstronger

profitorientationsarebetterabletosustainablyaddresstheneedsofpoorborrowers.Some

commentatorsclearlyplaceemphasisontheanti‐povertyorientationofMFIs:“thefirstgoalofMFIs

istoreachmoreclientsinthepoorerstrataofthepopulation,andthesecondgoalisfinancial

sustainability(Mersland&Strøm,2008a,pg.663).”However,itisalsobelievedthatalargenumber

of(especiallynonprofit)MFIsarenotearningsufficientincometocovertheirfullcostsofoperation

andexpansionandmustthereforerelyonsubsidies–intheformofgrantsanddonations–to

sustainthemselves.Concernsaboutthereliabilityofthesefundingsourcesmakesthefinancial

Page 4: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

4  

viabilityofMFIsamajorconcernforsectorparticipants(Mersland&Strøm,2010).

Inthisrespect,profit‐orientedMFIsarepartofthemovementtowardamore‘businesslike’

microfinancesector.Withheightenedbusinessacumenandastrongermarketorientation,profit‐

orientedMFIsaresupposedtosetmoreappropriateloanpricesanddelivergreaterefficiencies,

andthushaveaneasiertimeattractingneededinvestmentintothesector.Thisshould,inturn,

allowthesocialimpactsthattheygeneratetobemoresustainable(Hermes&Lensink,2007).

Thearrivalofprofit‐orientedMFIsalsoraisesconcernsaboutMFIstradingoffsocialfor

financialperformance.Incontrast,agreaterfocusonprofitabilitymightpushconcernsaboutthe

well‐beingofpoorclientstothebackburner.Whiletheseconcernsclearlyapplytofor‐profitMFIs,

theyalsoapplytononprofitMFIswhereattentiontosustainabilityareleadingsometoemphasize

thegenerationoffinancialsurplus,evenifthatsurplusisneverdistributedtooutsideshareholders.

Inbothcases,manyworrythatwewillseeMFIsabandoningthepoorestclientsinsearchofmore

reliableprofitstreams–somethingcommentatorscall“missiondrift”(Copestake,2007).

EvenMFIsthatremainfocusedonthepoorestclientsmightalterthemixofcostsand

benefitsthattheyofferastheystriveforenhancedprofitability(Yunus,2011).Weaddressthis

latterquestionbyexaminingtheimpactofMFIshavingastrongerprofitorientationontheeffective

interestrateschargedtoclients.Whilethisisnottheonlyvariablethatmatterstomicrofinance

clients(Cull,Demirguc‐Kunt,&Morduch,2009),itdoescapturetheeffectivepriceofcreditaccess.

Weexaminedifferencesbetweentheeffectiveinterestrateschargedbynonprofitversus

for‐profitMFIs.However,wealsorecognizethattheprofitorientationofanMFIextendsbeyondits

decisiontooperateasafor‐profitorganization.Itisalsomanifestedinthemoresubtlechoicesand

commitmentsthatanMFImakes.Inparticular,weexaminethecompositionofMFIgoverning

boardstoascertainwhethertheycontainprivate‐sectorrepresentationand/orindividualswith

bankingacumen.Wealsoexaminetheextenttowhichthenetworksupportorganizations(Cook&

Isern,2004,pp.,pg.3)thatanMFIparticipatesinarethemselvespopulatedbynumerousotherfor‐

Page 5: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

5  

profitMFIs.Intheend,ouranalysespaintasomewhatsoberingpictureoftheinfluenceofa

strongerprofitorientationontheeffectiveinterestrateschargedtoMFIclients.Eachofthesethree

variablesisassociatedwithhighereffectiveinterestrates.However,theseincreasesdonot

manifestinhigherMFIprofitabilityandthereforesustainabilitybecausetheMFIsthataremore

profitorientedalsotendtohavehighercosts.

2.PROFITORIENTATIONOFMICROFINANCEINSTITUTIONS

Thecollectivepushtoseeamoreprofit‐orientedmicrofinancesectorismostevidentinthe

relativelyhighincidenceoffor‐profitMFIsaroundtheworld.In2009,490ofthe1,169MFIs(42%)

intheMIXMarketdatabasewerefor‐profitMFIs.Theycollectivelycontrolledroughlytwo‐thirdsof

themorethan$65billioninassetsdeployedinthatyear.Clearly,adoptingafor‐profitlegalform

suggestsastrongerprofitorientation.However,thedecisiontooperateasafor‐profitorganization

isnottheonlychoicethatindicatestheprofitorientationofMFIs.Infact,Mersland&Strøm

(2008b)recentlyconcludedthatMFIownership(e.g.,shareholderversusNGO)isnotparticularly

relevantindeterminingitssocialorcommercialorientation.Rather,asCulletal.(2009)suggest,

“earningprofitsdoesnotimplybeinga‘for‐profit’bank.”NonprofitMFIscananddoearnpositive

profitsthataresimplynotdistributedtoshareholdersbutarere‐investedinactivitiesthatfurther

servicetheirclients.Therefore,wealsolookatseveralotherorganizationalchoicesthatplausibly

correspondwithanMFI’sprofitorientation.

Appointingindividualstotheboardofdirectorsrepresentsanimportantstrategicdecision

forMFIs.Advicefromandoversightbytheseboardmembershaveconsequencesfordecisions

takenwithinanMFI.Thoseinterestedinadoptingbestpracticesfromthefor‐profitworldandfrom

thetraditionalbankingsectormightthereforetendtoappointindividualstotheirboardswhobring

experiencefromthesedomains.Morespecifically,appointingindividualsfromtheprivatesector,as

opposedtothegovernmentorNGOsectors,indicatesadesiretobeinfluencedinthisdirection.The

Page 6: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

6  

samecanbesaidaboutappointingindividualswithbankingacumen.Thus,havingprivatesector

representationandbankingacumenontheboardsuggestsastrongerprofitorientation.

AnotherwaythatMFIsdeepentheircommitmenttoaprofitorientationisbyparticipating

innetworkscomprisedofotherfor‐profitsMFIs.Sociologicalandmanagerialresearchonnetworks

indicatesthatthebehaviorandperformanceoforganizationsisinfluencedbythenetworksin

whichtheyparticipate(Brass,Galaskiewicz,Greve,&Tsai,2004).Fromanorganizationallearning

perspective,thetiesthatmakeuporganizationalnetworksareconduitsthroughwhichknowledge

andideasflows.Thiseffectisevidentinastatementtakenfromthewebsiteofoneprominent

microfinancenetwork:“MicroFinanceNetwork(MFN)isaninternationalassociationofleading

microfinanceinstitutions.ThroughtheMFN,31membersfrom27countriesshareideas,

experiences,andinnovativesolutionstothechallengestheyfaceinsearchofcontinuousgrowthand

progress.MFNmembersseektobemodelsofwhatispossibleintheindustry(www.mfnetwork.org).”

Thelatteraspirationpointstoasecondcontrolaspectofnetworks.Thepredominantparticipants

inanorganizationalnetworktendtodefinethenormsandpracticesinthatnetwork(Owen‐Smith

&Powell,2004).IfotherMFIsthatpopulatemicrofinancenetworksarelargelyfor‐profitMFIs,then

theorientationsandideasthattendtoflowthroughthosenetworkswillsupportandreinforcea

strongerprofitorientationamongnetworkparticipants.Thissuggeststhatparticipatingin

networkscomprisedofmorefor‐profitMFIssuggestsastrongerprofitorientation.

AssumingthesevariablesindicatetheprofitorientationofanMFI,thequestionbecomes

howthisorientationinfluencesbehaviorandperformance.Theoptimisticviewisthatsocial

impactswillbeimprovedbyincorporatingmoremarketdisciplineandcommercialacumenintothe

traditionallynon‐profitmicrofinancesector.Inotherwords,“thelureofprofit,economistsassume,

motivatesallentrepreneursandmanagersandfostersefficientdecisionmakingbyprivatefirms

(Weisbrod,1998,p.70).”Thepessimisticviewsuggeststhatthisorientationiseitherdistractingof

detractingfromthepursuitofpovertyreductionasanorganizationalgoal.Afterall,“anonprofit

Page 7: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

7  

organizationhaslittleincentivetoskimponqualityofoutputorotherwisetakeadvantageofpoorly

informedcustomers(Weisbrod,1998,p.70).”Intheformercase,afocusonprofitstendstolead

MFIsawayfromthecommitmentthatimprovestheirabilitytoeffectivelylendtothepoorwhilethe

lattersuggeststhatadesiretoimproveprofitabilitywillleadtodeliberatechoicestocutservicesor

raiseinterestratestomeetthedemandsofhigherprofitability.

Themiddlegroundbetweenthesetwopositions(andthusthenullhypothesisinallthat

follows)suggeststhatdebatesabouttheimplicationsofprofit‐seekingarequiteirrelevant.

MerslandandStrom’s(2008a)analysisfoundthattheimpactofanMFI’sadoptingafor‐profit

orientationonitsperformanceiseffectivelynull.Thiscentristpositionisbasedonthebeliefthat

nonprofitandprofit‐orientedMFIscanbeequallyconcernedwithbothalleviatingpovertyand

financialsustainability:“Apriori,onewouldconsiderthatSHFsaremoreprofit‐orientedthan

NGOs.Similarly,thatNGOsshouldcaremoreaboutreachingthepoorestclientsthanSHFs…

However,analternativehypothesismaybethatSHFsandNGOsdonotperformdifferently,because

theymayusethesamebusinessmodeltocompeteandservecustomersinthemicrofinancemarket

(Mersland&Strøm,2008b).”

Giventheunsettleddebatesandtherelativepaucityofsystematicempiricalanalysis

(Hermes&Lensink,2007,pg.F2),thefollowingsectionsprovideacomprehensiveanalysisofthe

implicationsforeffectiveinterestratesofanMFIhavingastrongerprofitorientation.

3.DATAANDSAMPLE

OuranalysiscombinestwodifferentMIXdatasources(www.mixmarket.org):theirarchiveofMFI

financialinformationandtheirmorerecentSocialPerformanceReports.Theselatterreports

capturedetailedinformationaboutspecificchoicesandconfigurationsthatpertaintoanMFI’s

socialorientation.The358MFIsinoursampleallcompletedSocialPerformanceReportsin2008or

2009andhadcorrespondingfinancialdatafor2009.Toassesstherepresentativenessofthis

Page 8: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

8  

sample,wecompareittothebroadersampleofallMFIsinthe2009MIXfinancialinformationfile

andfindittobebroadlycomparable(seetable1).

Table1abouthere

OuranalysisfocusesononevariablethathasdirectimplicationsfortheclientsofMFIs–the

effectiveinterestratechargedonthefundsthattheyborrow.Followingacceptedpractice

(Gonzalez,2010),oureffectiveinterestratevariableisrealtotalearnedinterestincomeandfees

dividedbytheaveragegrossloanportfolio.AmongthesampledMFIs,theaverageeffectiveinterest

rateis28.06%.

TheMIXdataalsoreporttheprofitstatusofeachMFI.Weusethisinformationtocreatea

‘For‐profitMFI’dummyvariablesettooneforMFIsthatoperateasfor‐profitorganizations.

Accordingtotable1,35%ofthesampledMFIsarefor‐profitorganizations.TheMIXSocial

PerformanceReportsaskrespondentsseveralquestionsaboutthecompositionoftheirboards.

Twoquestionsaresalientforthisanalysis.ThefirstaskswhetheranMFI’sboardhasprivatesector

representationandthesecondaskswhetherbankingacumenispresentontheboard.Weusethis

informationtocreatetwoadditionaldummyvariables:‘Privatesectoronboard’and‘Banking

acumenonboard’.

Finally,theMIXwebsitereportsonthecompositionofroughly100networksupport

organizationsthatworkwithMFIsaroundtheworld.Thesenetworks“facilitateandprovide

supporttoorganizationsthatarecommittedtodeliveringfinancialservicestothepoor,”andcanbe

national,regionalorinternationalinorientation(Cook&Isern,2004,pp.,pg.3).Theyrangeinsize

fromfourtomorethan150membersandprovidearangeofservicestotheirmembers,including

financialandtechnicalservices,knowledgemanagement,researchanddevelopmentandpolicy

advocacy.AfterrecordingthenamesofallMFIsparticipatingineachnetwork,wecountthetotal

numberoffor‐profitMFIsthatafocalMFIistiedtobysharednetworkaffiliation.Themaximum

numberoffor‐profittiesis56andsowedividetheobservednumberoftiesforeachsampledMFI

Page 9: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

9  

by56toobtainanormalizedvariablethatrangesfromzero(notiestofor‐profitMFIs)toone(the

maximumnumberofobservedties).

Differingsocialandeconomicconditionsacrosscountriesandregionshaveimplicationsfor

thesupplyofanddemandformicro‐lending(Ahlin,Lin,&Maio,2011).Wecontrolforlocating

acrossthesixregionsisolatedintheMIXdatabases–Africa,EastAsiaandthePacific,Eastern

EuropeandCentralAsia,LatinAmericaandTheCaribbean,MiddleEastandNorthAfricaandSouth

Asia–withaseriesofregionfixedeffects.Atthecountrylevel,weaccountforlocaleconomicand

politicalproblemsbytakingtheaverageofthesixdimensionsoftheWorldBank’sWorldwide

GovernanceIndicator(http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.asp):voiceand

accountability,politicalstabilityandabsenceofviolence,governmenteffectiveness,regulatory

quality,ruleoflawandcontrolofcorruption.Becausetotalpopulationinfluencesthedemandfor

microcredit,wealsocontrolforthenaturallogofeachcountry’stotalpopulationin2009.

Prevailinginterestratesshouldalsobeinfluencedbythedegreeofmicrofinancesector

competition.Followingalargebodyoforganizationalecologyresearch(Hannan&Freeman,1989),

weproxyforthedegreeofcompetitionbycountingthenumberofMFIsactiveineachcountryin

2009(asreportedintheMIXdatabase).Theoverallcountrangesfromalowofone(inTunisia)toa

highof163(inIndia).Giventhedebatesaboutthedifferentialcompetitivenessoffor‐profitand

nonprofitMFIs,wedecomposethisvariableintofor‐profitandnonprofitdensitymeasures.In

doingso,weseethatsomecountries,likeIndia,havelargenumbersofbothfor‐profits(62)and

nonprofits(95).Mexicohasmanyfor‐profits(55)butrelativelyfewnonprofits(ten).Ontheother

hand,Bangladeshhasmanynonprofits(70)butrelativelyfewfor‐profits(3).

Duetoeconomiesofscaleandexperienceeffects,largerandolderMFIsshouldbemore

efficient(Gonzalez,2007).Wethereforeaccountforthesize(naturallogofassets)andage(natural

logoftheyearssinceanMFIstarteditsmicrofinanceoperations)ofeachMFI.Thereisalsointerest

intheroleplayedbyregulationinshapingthebehaviorandperformanceofMFIs(Cull,Demirguc‐

Page 10: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

10  

Kunt,&Morduch,2011).Weincludeadummyvariablesettooneforbanksthatreportedbeing

undertheinfluenceofaregulatoryauthorityin2009.

MFIsalsovaryinthecomplexityandscopeoftheirofferings.Inthisregard,twovariables

thatmightinfluencethecostandperformanceofMFIsaretheextenttowhichtheyalsoengagein

deposit‐takingactivitiesandtheiroutreachlevels.Tocapturetheformereffect,weincludea

variablethatmeasuresthesavingsdeposits‐to‐assetsratioforeachMFI.Weproxyforthedegreeof

outreach(intermsofnumberofindividualstouched)byincludinganotherdummyvariablesetto

oneforMFIsthatarereportedintheMIXdatabaseashavingeithermediumorlargeoutreach

levels.

Commentatorsalsonotethatcostsandthereforeinterestratescanbeinfluencedbyseveral

variablesassociatedwiththedegreeofdifficultyassociatedwithprovidingmicroloansacross

differentclientsegments(Mersland&Strøm,2010,pp.,pg.35).Absentdirectmeasuresofthe

extenttowhichanMFItargetsmarginalizedclients,acceptedproxiesincludeaverageloansize,

targetingwomenborrowersandtargetingindividualsinruralareas(Cull,etal.,2009).Ouraverage

loansizevariableisthemedianloansizeaspercentageofcountrygrossnationalincomepercapita

(Gonzalez,2010).ThefractionofwomenborrowersisreportedinMIXastheshareofoutstanding

loansheldbywomenborrowers.TheSocialPerformanceReportsaskrespondentswhethertheir

MFItargetsruralclients.Weusethisinformationtocreateanotherdummyvariable.Finally,

publishedmissionstatementsprovidesomeindicationoftheextenttowhichpovertyalleviationis

acentralconcernforanMFI.WeexaminethemissionstatementofeachMFIandisolatethosethat

explicitlymentionpoorclientsorpovertyalleviation.

OurfinalcontrolvariablerelatestothelendingmodeladoptedbyeachMFI.Following

HermesandLensink’s(2007)discussionofgroup(orjointliability)lending,weincludeavariable

thatindicateswhetheranMFIemploysindividual,asopposedtogrouporvillagelendingpractices.

Table2reportsdescriptivestatisticsfor,andpair‐wisecorrelationsamongallofthe

Page 11: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

11  

variablesinouranalysis.

Table2abouthere

4.ANALYSISANDRESULTS

Webeginbyenteringthecontrolvariablesintoanordinaryleastsquaresregressionmodel

(seemodel1intable3).Thesignificantcoefficientsrevealaninterestingasymmetrybetweenthe

estimatedeffectsoffor‐profitversusnonprofitcompetition.Thelatternegativeeffectisconsistent

withexpectations.GreatercompetitionfromlargernumbersofnonprofitMFIsdrivesdown

effectiveinterestrates.However,theestimatedeffectisoppositeforthefor‐profitcompetition

variable.Werevisitthesetworesults–whicharerobustacrossthevariousmodelsthatwe

estimate–intheconcludingsectionofthepaper.TheMFIsizevariablehastheexpectednegative

effectoninterestrates.Asexpected,MFIsthatoffermorecost‐effectivelargerloansalsocharge

lowerinterestrates.Ontheotherhand,interestratesaresignificantlyhigheramongtheMFIsthat

havemediumorlargeoutreachlevels,thosethattargetwomenclients,andthosethatemphasize

poverty‐reductionintheirmissionstatements.

Table3abouthere

WeareprimarilyinterestedintheorganizationalchoicesmadebyMFIsthatindicatea

strongercommitmenttoprofitability:adoptingthefor‐profitstatus,havingprivate‐sector

representationandbankingacumenonboards,andhavingmoreextensivetiestootherfor‐profit

MFIs.Model2introducesthesevariablesintotheeffectiveinterestratemodel.1Thefor‐profitMFI

variableispositivebutnotstatisticallysignificantatconventionallevels(p=.0.11).Moreover,each

ofthethreeboardandnetworkvariablesinflateseffectiveinterestrates.Havingprivatesector

                                                            1Givenconcernsaboutmulticollinearity,wecheckedthevarianceinflationfactors(VIFs)andfoundthehighest(5.02)tobewithintheacceptablerange.Wealsoestimatedfourseparatemodelsthatenteredeachoftheprofit‐orientationsvariablesindividuallyandobtainedthesameresults.Finally,weestimatedan(unreported)modelthatremovedoutlierobservations(i.e.,thoseforwhichtheresidualismorethantwostandarddeviationsawayfromzero)andobtainedthesamepatternofresults.

Page 12: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

12  

representationontheboardcorrespondswithanestimatedincreaseintheeffectiveinterestrateof

3.53percentagepoints.Ensuringthattheboardhasbankingacumencorrespondswithalarger

4.06percentagepointincrease.Finally,increasingtiestootherfor‐profitMFIsfromzerotothe

maximumlevelcorrespondstoa6.97percentagepointincreaseineffectiveinterestrates.2

Giventhesimilarmagnitudesoftheestimatedboardandnetworkeffects,weperformedan

F‐testtoassessthenullhypothesisthattheircoefficientestimatesareequal.Thistestcannotreject

thenullhypothesisofequaleffects(F=0.57;p=0.57).Wethereforesumthethreevariablesintoa

singleindexthatreflectstheoverallprofitorientationofeachMFI.Thisvariablerangesfromalow

ofzero(ineightobservations)toahighof2.96,andaverages1.44.Closerinspectionshowsthatthis

profitorientationvariableissignificantlyhigheramongthefor‐profitMFIs;averaging1.71

comparedto1.29forthenonprofitMFIs(t=5.33;p=0.00).Whentheoverallprofitorientationindex

issubstitutedintomodel2,itseffectispositiveandsignificant;aunitincreasecorrespondingtoa

4.05percentagepointincreaseineffectiveinterestrates(seemodel3).

SomeresearchersexpressconcernsaboutdataqualityinmodelsevaluatingMFI

performance(Mersland&Strøm,2010).Wethereforeestimatedan(unreported)variantofmodel

3basedonthe310MFIsthatreceivedfourorfivestarsfordataqualityfromMIX.Theresultsare

virtuallyidenticaltothosereportedinmodel3.Two‐thirdsofthenonprofitMFIsinthissampleare

NGOs,withcreditunions/cooperativesandnon‐bankfinancialinstitutionscomprisingthe

remainingthird.Roughly80%ofthefor‐profitMFIsarenon‐bankfinancialinstitutions.The

remainingfor‐profitMFIsareeitherbanksorruralbanks.3Toensurethatourresultsarenotan

artifactofthelegalformadoptedbythesampledMFIs,werananother(unreported)modelthat

                                                            2Toassesswhetherthenetworktieseffectsimplyreflectstheoveralldegreeofconnectedness,wecreatedasecondnetworkvariablethatrangesfromzerotooneasanMFImovesfromhavingnotiestoothernon‐profitMFIstoonewhenithasthemaximumnumberofobservedties(131).Inanunreportedmodel,thecoefficientonthisnewvariableisnegativeandinsignificant(=‐1.55;p=0.68)whilethemagnitudeandsignificanceofthefor‐profittievariableremainspositiveandmarginallysignificant(=7.89;p=0.03).3 ThisdistributionoflegalformsinthissampleisqualitativelysimilartothatreportedbyCulletal(2009). 

Page 13: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

13  

includesdummyvariablesforeachlegalform.Again,theresultsreportedinmodel3arereplicated.

Finally,toensurethattheestimatedeffectsoftheprofitorientationvariablesarerobust,we

estimatedavariantofmodel3thatreplacesallregionandcountrycontrolvariableswithasetof

countryfixedeffects(seemodel4).Becauseweonlyincludeobservationsfromcountriesthathave

atleastthreesampledMFIs,thisreducesthesampleto339MFIs.Again,theresultsfrommodel3

arereplicated.Inthismodelaunitincreaseintheprofitorientationvariablecorrespondswitha

3.60percentagepointincreaseineffectiveinterestrateschargedtoMFIclients.

OneofourbasicpremisesisthattheorganizationalchoicesthatMFIsmaketoincorporatea

strongerprofitorientationcanhaveimplicationsaboveandbeyondthatofadoptingthefor‐profit

form.GivenpressuresonnonprofitMFIstoactmoreliketheirmarket‐orientedfor‐profit

counterparts,thesechoicesshouldalsoinfluencetheirbehaviorandperformance.Model5(intable

4)re‐estimatesmodel3usingthesub‐sampleofnonprofitMFIsandshowsasimilarpatternof

effects.Thistime,aunitincreaseintheprofitorientationvariableisassociatedwithamore

substantial5.00percentagepointincreaseineffectiveinterestrates.Inthesub‐sampleof127for‐

profitMFIs,theeffectofastrongerprofitorientationisstillpositive,althoughnolongerstatistically

significant.Itseemsthatthemoredamagingeffectsofastrongerprofitorientation(intermsof

higherinterestrateschargedtoclients)areconfinedtononprofitMFIs,althoughitisinstructiveto

observethatamongthefor‐profitMFIs,thevariablesthatoughttocorrelatewithimproved

businessandbankingacumendonothelptolowertheinterestratevariable.

Table4abouthere

Manyoftheclaimsabouttheimportanceofastrongerprofitorientationrelatestothe

abilityofMFIstoencouragemoreinvestmenttoflowintothesector.Insupportofthisclaim,table

2showsthatfor‐profitMFIstendtobelargerthantheirnonprofitcounterpartsandtendtooperate

inmorepopulouscountries.Extendingthislineofthought,itisplausiblethatthestrongerprofit

orientationismoresuitedtolargerMFIsize.Wemightthereforeexpecttoseetheeffectsofthe

Page 14: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

14  

profitorientationvariablesdisappearorreverseinthesub‐sampleofMFIsthatareabovethe

mediansamplesize.Inmodel7,wedoseeareductionintheestimatedeffectsizeoftheprofit

orientationvariable.Relativetothesub‐sampleofsmallerMFIs,theadverseeffectofastronger

profitorientationisroughlyhalved;producinga2.23percentagepointincreasecomparedtoa5.44

percentagepointincreaseinthesmallerMFIsub‐sample.However,althoughtheadverseeffectof

theprofitorientationvariableoninterestratesislesspronounceditisstillsignificant.

(a)CostsandSustainability

EffectiveinterestratesarethesumofprofitsearnedplusthreemajorcomponentsofanMFI’scosts:

operatingexpenses,financialexpensesandlossesduetoloanimpairment.Wecontinueour

analysisbylookingathowthevariablesinmodel3alsoinfluencethesethreecostcomponents.

Operatingexpensesarelargelyafunctionofsalariesandstaffproductivity(Gonzalez,2010).Thus,

theoperatingexpensevariablethatweanalyzeisthesumofthesenon‐financialexpenses(plus

depreciationandamortizationandotheradministrativeexpenses)dividedbytheaveragegross

loanportfolio(Mersland&Strøm,2008a).Thevariablethatcapturesfinancialexpensesis

calculatedasthetotalfinancialexpensesrelativetotheaveragegrossloanportfolio.Finally,the

loanlossesvariableisthesimilarratioofthevalueofloanswritten‐offdividedbytheaveragegross

loanportfolio.

Giventheobviousinterdependenceamongthesethreecostvariables,weestimatethe

effectsofourcovariatesinaseemingly‐unrelatedregressionframework(Zellner,1962).The

resultsfromthissystemofequations–presentedasmodel8intable5–suggestthatmostofthe

systematicvarianceinMFIcostspertainstooperatingexpenses.Havingmorenonprofit

competitioninacountrycorrespondswithloweroperatingexpenseratios.Thefor‐profitMFI

competitionvariablehasnodiscernibleeffect.TheMFIsizevariablehasanegativeandsignificant

effectonoperatingexpenses,corroboratingexpectationsabouteconomiesofscaleintheMFI

Page 15: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

15  

sector.Thereisalsoevidenceofthedocumentedtrade‐offbetweenfocusingonpovertyalleviation

andcostefficiency(Hermes,Lensink,&Meesters,2011).Theestimatedeffectsoftargetingwomen

borrowersandemphasizingpovertyreductioninthemissionstatementarepositiveandsignificant

intheoperatingexpensesequation.Ontheotherhand,thedecisiontotargetruralclientshasa

marginallynegativeeffect,perhapsduetolowerlandandlaborcostsinless‐developedareas.

Finally,takinginmoredeposits,andtherebyincreasingorganizationalcomplexity,corresponds

withhigheraverageoperatingexpenses.

Table5abouthere

Turningtothevariablesofinterest,theprofitorientationvariableisassociatedwith

significantlyhigheroperatingexpenses(=5.77)andhigherloanimpairmentexpenses(=0.67).Its

effectonfinancialexpensesisalsopositivebutnotsignificant.Theestimatedeffectofthefor‐profit

MFIvariableisalsopositiveinallthreeequations,albeitonlymarginallysignificantinthefinancial

expensesequation.Thus,thereisnoevidenceoftheexpectedefficiencybenefitsofadoptinga

strongerprofitorientation.ThesefindingsareconsistentwithHudonandTraça(2011),whofind

thatMFIsthatreceivehigherlevelsofsubsidies–whichareprobablythelessprofit‐orientedMFIs

inthissample–areactuallymoreefficient.Moregenerally,thepatternreinforcesacorefindingof

MerslandandStrom(2008b),whofindnoevidencethatshareholder‐ownedMFIsare

systematicallymorecost‐effectivethantheirNGOcounterparts.

OnejustificationforthehigherinterestrateschargedbyMFIswhodemonstrateastronger

commitmenttoprofitabilityrelatestotheneedforMFIstobefinanciallysustainable.Intheory,by

providingmorebusinessacumenandmarketdiscipline,astrongerprofitorientationreducesthe

needforMFIstorelyonsubsidies.Instead,higherinterestratesand/orlowercostsallowthemto

earnthesurplusesthatallowthemtosustainoperationsontheirownterms.

AnMFI’sfinancialself‐sufficiencyratioequalsitsnetincomedividedbyitstotalcosts.

ValuesgreaterthanoneindicatethatanMFIisabletocoveritscostsandthereforesustainitself

Page 16: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

16  

overtime.WecreateadummyvariablesettooneforMFIswithfinancialself‐sufficiencyratios

greaterthanoneandanalyzeitscovariatesinalogisticregressionmodel.Arguably,thesearethe

MFIsthatgeneratedenoughprofitin2009tosustainthemselvesovertime.Thesignificant

coefficientsinmodel10(intable6)suggestthatgreatercompetitionfromotherfor‐profitMFIs

increasestheprobabilitythananMFIisfinanciallyself‐sustaining.Whetherornotavariableleads

tosignificantfinancialsustainabilitydifferencesdependsontheextenttowhichtheestimated

interestrateandcosteffectsoffsetoneanother.Inthisrespect,thefactthatcompetitionfromother

for‐profitMFIsincreasesthelikelihoodthatanMFIwillbefinanciallyself‐sustainingisexplainedby

thefactthatitsestimatedimpactoninterestrates(=0.27inmodel3)isgreaterthatthe

correspondingeffectsoncosts(consistentlynullacrossthethreeequationsinmodel9).Onthe

otherhand,emphasizingwomeninlendingportfoliosandpoverty‐alleviationinmission

statementsbothreducethelikelihoodthatanMFIisfinanciallyself‐sustaining.MFIsthatplace

greateremphasisonwomentendtohavehigheroperatingcosts(=18.90intheoperating

expensesequationinmodel9)thatarenotfullyaccountedforbytherelativelyhigherinterestrates

thattheychargetheirclients(=9.11inmodel3).Thisleadstotheoverallnegativeeffectonthe

probabilityofbeingfinanciallyself‐sustaining.AsimilarsetofobservationsappliestoMFIsthat

emphasizepovertyintheirmissionstatements.

Table6abouthere

Theprofitorientationvariableexertsnosignificanteffectonsustainability.Thisoverallnull

effectisexplainedbythefactthatthepositiveeffectoninterestratescharged(=4.05inmodel3)

ismorethanfullyoffsetbyitsadverseeffectsonoperatingexpensesandloanimpairmentexpenses

(=5.77and=0.23respectivelyinmodel9).Similarly(althoughestimatedwithlessprovision)for‐

profitMFIstendtochargehigherinterestratesbutalsooperatewithhigherexpenses,especially

financialexpenses.

Page 17: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

17  

5.DISCUSSIONANDCONCLUSION

“AreviewofmicrofinancepolicyreportsrevealsthatmostofthemhighlightthestrengthsofSHFsandtheweaknessesofNGOs.Inparticular,theyemphasisthatNGOsarelesscommercialandprofessionalbecausetheylackownerswiththepecuniaryincentivetomonitormanagement(Mersland&Strøm,2008b).”

Asthemicrofinancesectormatures,morequestionswillbeaskedaboutwhetheritisevolvingina

waythatadvantagesthepoorestpeopleontheplanet.Inparticular,weexpectthat“theroleof

fully‐commercial,profit‐seekinginstitutionsinprovidingsuchmicrofinanceloans[willcontinueto

be]controversial(Cull,etal.,2009).”Profit‐orientedMFIsareexpectedtobemoreefficientbut

thendistributemoreoftheirearnedsurplustooutsideshareholders.Nonprofitsareexpectedtobe

lessconcernedaboutgeneratingsurplusforownersbutalsolessoperationallyefficient.

Thebaselineexpectationsabouttheeffectsofastrongerprofitorientation–whichhave

beenchallengedelsewhere–arenotatallsupportedinthisanalysis.Thevariablesthatsuggesta

strongerprofitorientationdonotloweranyofthemajorcomponentsofanMFI’scost.Nordothey

significantlyimproveMFIsustainability.Theonlythingthatwecanconcludeisthattheeffective

interestrateschargedbyMFIswithstrongerprofitorientationsaresignificantlyhigheronaverage.

Inlightofthepersistentcommentaryregardingtheneedforamoremarket‐basedorientationin

thesector,thisoffersasomewhatsoberingaccountoftheimplicationsofMFIshavingstrongerfor‐

profitorientations.

Theeffectsrevealedinthisanalysissuggeststhatadvisoryinputsfromindividualswith

private‐sectorbackgrounds,withtraditionalbankingacumenorexperiencerunningfor‐profitMFIs

donothelpMFIsnavigatethetrade‐offsbetweenefficientservicedeliveryontheonehandand

organizationalsustainabilityontheother.TheyalsoreinforceanobservationmadebyArmendariz

andMorduch(2005),whonotehow“pioneeringmodelsgrewoutofexperimentationinlow‐

incomecountries…ratherthanfromadaptationsofstandardbankingmodelsinrichercountries.”

Page 18: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

18  

Itseemsthattheinsightsthatarerequiredtoachievepovertyalleviationalongwithfinancial

sustainabilitywillsimilarlynotcomefromtheimportationofadvicefromthosefamiliarwith

standardbankingmodels.

Thevariablesthatindicateastrongerprofitorientationneverseemtoproducetheexpected

benefitsforMFIclients.So,weconcludethepaperbyjoiningothersinstressingthat“ratherthan

concentratingonanMFIs‘commercialization,’attentionshouldbefocusedonhowtoreducecosts

perclient(Mersland&Strøm,2010,pg.35).”Giventhestrongcorrespondencebetweenvariables

thatsystematicallyinfluencebothMFIcostsandeffectiveinterestrates,itseemsthatdiscussionsof

howtostimulatestrongerprofitorientationsshouldbereplacedwiththosewhichmoredirectly

addressMFIefficiency.Forinstance,considerationmightbegiventohowonemightinducemore

nonprofitcompetition,ortoeffectivelyscalingefficientandeffectiveMFIs–bothnonprofitandfor‐

profit–asbothofthesevariablesseemtoreduceoperatingcostsandlowereffectiveinterestrates

(thelatterwithincreasedprofitability).

Otherfindingsfromtables3and4warrantfurtherscrutiny.Consider,forexample,the

asymmetriceffectsofthelevelsoffor‐profitandnonprofitcompetition.Theresultsthatpertainto

nonprofitcompetitionareconsistentwithourunderstandingofhowmarketsaresupposedto

operate.GreaternumbersofsuppliersforceMFIstobecomemorecostefficientinordertoattract

clients.Thecombinationofcompetitionandinducedefficienciesdrivesdowneffectiveinterest

rates.Thisisthespecificdynamicthatcommentatorswanttoseewithinthesector.However,the

correspondingeffectsofincreasednumbersoffor‐profitMFIsarecounter‐intuitive.Here,larger

numberstendtocorrespondwithsignificantlyhighereffectiveinterestrates(forallMFIsandfor

thesub‐sampleofnonprofitMFIs)andhigherMFIprofitability.Thisresultissorobustinthesedata

thatitseemsoddtoequatetheincreasednumbersoffor‐profitMFIswithincreasedMFI

competition.Theseasymmetriccompetitiveeffectsareclearlyworthyoffurtheranalysis.Inthe

meantime,wemustquestionthenetbenefitofinducinggreaterparticipationofMFIswithstronger

Page 19: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

19  

profitorientations.Inadditiontotheiradversedirecteffectsoninterestrates,theirproliferationin

acountryleadstoevenfurtherinterestrateincreases.

Inclosing,weproposethatthiskindofresearchallowspractitionersandcommentatorsto

lookbeneathbroadgeneralizationsaboutthedirectionofthemicrofinancesectorandappreciate

thediversityinobservedoutcomesthatareattributabletothemorespecificchoicesthatbothfor‐

profitandnonprofitMFIsmake.Inthisrespect,itmaynotbethatimportanttodeterminewhether,

onaverage,theMFIsectorisexperiencewhatsomearecallingmissiondrift.Itmaynotevenbe

importanttoascertainwhether,onaverage,for‐profitandnonprofitMFIsaremakingdifferent

choicesandtrade‐offs.Whatisimportantistheknowledgeofhowthespecificdecisionstakenby

MFIsareabletomoreorlesseffectivelymeetthetwinchallengesofaddressingpovertywhile

sustainingandscalingtheseimpacts.

Thatsaid,wemustalsostresstheneedforanappropriateinterpretationofthesecross‐

sectionalresults.Allwecansayforsureisthatin2009,MFIsthatdisplayedstrongerprofit

orientationstendedtochargehighereffectiverateswhileoperatingathighercost.Thesefindings

aregermanetothosethatseektoofferadviceonwhatkindsofMFIstendtoproducewhatkindsof

performanceoutcomesandsocialimpacts.Theyarealsoimportanttothoseresponsiblefor

directingfundstowardmoreimpactfulandsustainableMFIs.Here,onemightstresstheneedfor

thosewithavailablefunds–evenfundsthatseekmarketreturns–lookpastthefor‐profitversus

nonprofitdistinctionandlooktolendtoMFIsthatareoperatingefficientlyandpricing

competitively.However,ourresultsaresilentonthecausaleffectsofanindividualMFImoving

toward(orawayfrom)astrongerfor‐profitorientation.Addressingthiskindofquestion,whichis

clearlypartofthepolicyquestionsthatpertaintohowexistingMFIsmightbetterservetheir

clients,requiresalongitudinalanalysisofMFI’sthatswitchtobecomefor‐profitorganizations,that

changethecompositionoftheirboards,orthatchangetheextenttowhichtheirnetworksare

dominatedbyfor‐profitMFIs.Giventhebenefitsassociatedwithisolatingsuchexogenousimpacts

Page 20: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

20  

onMFIbehaviorandperformance,thiskindofdataandanalysiswillbemostuseful,andwillsurely

addrigortothedebatesaddressedinthispaper.

Page 21: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

21  

TABLE1.CURRENTSAMPLE

Sample

AllMIXMarket(2009)

N 358 1,169Shareoffor‐profitMFIs 35% 42%Averageassets(log) 16.34 15.84Averageeffectiveinterestrate 28.06 25.38

Page 22: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

22  

TABLE2.DESCRIPTIVESANDCORRELATIONS

Mean (0) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16) (17)(0)Effectiveinterestrate 28.06 (1)Countryproblems 65.38 ‐0.15 (2)Countrypopulation(log) 3.27 ‐0.03 ‐0.12 (3)For‐ProfitMFIsincountry 15.93 0.17 ‐0.19 0.67 (4)NonprofitMFIsincountry 25.37 ‐0.27 0.00 0.59 0.51 (8)Assets(log) 16.34 ‐0.30 ‐0.02 0.09 0.10 0.18 (9)Age(log) 2.43 ‐0.06 ‐0.05 ‐0.10 ‐0.15 0.02 0.22 (5)Regulated 0.54 ‐0.17 0.06 0.06 0.15 ‐0.05 0.35 ‐0.18 (6)DepositstoAssets 0.15 ‐0.20 0.19 0.05 0.06 0.06 0.31 0.18 0.20 (7)Medium/LargeOutreach 0.60 0.00 0.03 0.16 0.22 0.15 0.66 0.09 0.21 0.10 (10)Averageloansize(log) 0.33 ‐0.35 0.20 ‐0.30 ‐0.23 ‐0.20 0.29 0.01 0.25 0.27 ‐0.05 (11)Fractionwomenborrowers 0.62 0.29 ‐0.11 0.32 0.32 0.33 ‐0.07 0.02 ‐0.23 ‐0.23 0.21 ‐0.50 (12)Poor/povertyinmission 0.44 0.16 ‐0.02 0.25 0.17 0.18 0.00 ‐0.08 ‐0.08 ‐0.12 0.22 ‐0.24 0.33 (13)Targetruralclients 0.77 ‐0.06 0.09 ‐0.18 ‐0.08 0.00 0.12 0.14 0.00 ‐0.04 0.12 0.00 0.04 0.08 (14)Lendtoindividuals 0.88 ‐0.12 0.15 ‐0.28 ‐0.24 ‐0.20 0.10 0.08 0.11 0.14 ‐0.13 0.25 ‐0.36 ‐0.24 0.06 (15)For‐profitMFI 0.35 ‐0.01 ‐0.01 0.18 0.31 0.03 0.25 ‐0.30 0.50 0.11 0.12 0.20 ‐0.15 ‐0.09 ‐0.17 0.08 (16)Privatesectoronboard 0.36 0.11 0.02 0.12 0.19 0.08 0.09 ‐0.20 0.14 ‐0.11 0.24 ‐0.03 0.17 0.10 ‐0.07 ‐0.08 0.18 (17)Bankingacumenonboard 0.82 0.17 ‐0.03 0.17 0.20 0.02 0.18 ‐0.12 0.18 ‐0.06 0.25 ‐0.09 0.13 0.08 ‐0.08 ‐0.04 0.22 0.28 (18)Tiestofor‐profitMFIs(norm) 0.26 0.18 ‐0.13 ‐0.02 0.25 0.02 0.32 0.08 0.20 ‐0.08 0.28 ‐0.05 0.14 0.00 0.06 ‐0.02 0.14 0.11 0.13

Page 23: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

23  

TABLE3.EFFECTIVEINTERESTRATESCHARGEDBYMICROFINANCEINSTITUTIONS

Model1(Controls)

Model2(Profit

Orientation)

Model3(SingleIndex)

Model4(Country

FixedEffects)Countryproblems 0.01

(0.05)0.01(0.05)

0.01(0.05)

Countrypopulation(log) 0.76(0.70)

1.08(0.69)

1.02(0.68)

For‐ProfitMFIsincountry 0.33**(0.05)

0.25**(0.05)

0.27**(0.05)

NonprofitMFIsincountry ‐0.26**(0.04)

‐0.23**(0.04)

‐0.24**(0.04)

Assets(log) ‐1.96**(0.59)

‐2.52**(0.59)

‐2.40**(0.58)

‐1.21*(0.55)

Age(log) 0.21(1.01)

0.46(1.03)

0.61(1.02)

0.98(0.97)

Regulated ‐0.74(1.48)

‐2.26(1.53)

‐2.13(1.52)

‐2.92¥(1.57)

DepositstoAssets ‐3.39(3.10)

‐1.20(3.04)

‐1.31(3.03)

‐2.67(3.10)

Medium/LargeOutreach 5.02**(1.92)

3.97*(1.89)

3.92*(1.88)

‐0.44(1.73)

Averageloansize(log) ‐8.61**(2.50)

‐8.47**(2.45)

‐8.76**(2.43)

‐8.65**(2.60)

Fractionwomenborrowers 11.26**(3.01)

8.85*(2.93)

9.11*(2.96)

9.91**(2.97)

Poor/povertyinmission 3.86**(1.31)

4.14**(1.27)

4.14**(1.27)

2.72*(1.21)

Targetruralclients ‐1.86(1.43)

‐0.65(1.41)

‐0.67(1.41)

‐1.18(1.34)

Lendtoindividuals ‐0.13(2.02)

‐0.86(1.97)

‐0.83(1.96)

0.52(1.80)

For‐profitMFI ‐ 2.49

(1.55)2.46(1.55)

2.42(1.55)

Profitorientation

‐ ‐ 4.05**(0.88)

3.60**(0.86)

‐Privatesectoronboard ‐ 3.53**(1.31)

‐ ‐

‐Bankingacumenonboard ‐ 4.06*(1.62)

‐ ‐

‐Tiestofor‐profitMFIs(norm) ‐ 6.97*(2.93)

‐ ‐

Fixedregioneffects (yes) (yes) (yes) (no)Fixedcountryeffects (no) (no) (no) (yes) N 358 358 358 339AdjustedR2 0.48 0.51 0.51 0.65**p<0.01;*p<0.05;¥p<0.10

Page 24: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

24  

TABLE4.MODERATINGFACTORS:FOR‐PROFITSTATUSANDSIZE

Model5(NonprofitMFIs)

Model6(For‐ProfitMFIs)

Model7(LargerMFIs)

Model8(SmallerMFIs)

Countryproblems ‐0.04(0.06)

0.11(0.09)

0.01(0.06)

0.04(0.07)

Countrypopulation(log) 1.16(0.82)

0.92(1.33)

0.37(0.85)

2.14*(1.05)

For‐ProfitMFIsincountry 0.12¥(0.07)

0.40**(0.09)

0.37**(0.06)

0.10(0.09)

NonprofitMFIsincountry ‐0.17**(0.06)

‐0.26**(0.06)

‐0.27**(0.04)

‐0.19**(0.07)

Assets(log) ‐2.39**(0.82)

‐2.50**(0.85)

‐1.59¥(0.81)

‐2.44*(1.18)

Age(log) 0.62(1.36)

1.46(1.69)

1.76(1.25)

‐1.02(1.60)

Regulated ‐0.55(1.93)

‐5.19(3.25)

‐2.88(1.93)

‐3.13(2.46)

DepositstoAssets ‐2.76(4.31)

‐1.54(4.69)

2.52(3.48)

‐11.53*(5.60)

Medium/LargeOutreach 3.89(2.45)

2.99(3.43)

1.58(2.73)

5.84*(2.94)

Averageloansize(log) ‐11.43**(4.15)

‐8.04**(3.16)

‐9.12**(2.61)

‐14.86**(4.78)

Fractionwomenborrowers 7.44*(3.76)

4.46(5.99)

8.40*(3.84)

9.92*(4.79)

Poor/povertyinmission 2.26(1.60)

6.23**(2.23)

3.28*(1.50)

4.55*(2.06)

Targetruralclients ‐2.02(1.88)

2.09(2.20)

1.93(1.71)

‐2.67(2.30)

Lendtoindividuals ‐2.31(2.27)

4.15(4.07)

‐2.88(2.61)

0.83(2.97)

For‐profitMFI ‐ ‐ 2.75

(1.85)3.29(2.65)

Profitorientation

5.00**(1.14)

1.51(1.48)

2.23*(1.09)

5.44**(1.40)

Fixedregioneffects (yes) (yes) (yes) (yes) N 231 127 179 179AdjustedR2 0.50 0.57 0.53 0.50

**p<0.01;*p<0.05;¥p<0.10

Page 25: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

25  

TABLE5.THREEELEMENTSOFMFICOSTS

Model9aOperatingExpenses

FinancialExpenses

Loan

ImpairmentCountryproblems ‐0.24*

(0.11)‐0.06¥(0.03)

0.03(0.02)

Countrypopulation(log) 3.04*(1.52)

0.32(0.42)

0.06(0.26)

For‐ProfitMFIsincountry ‐0.03(0.12)

0.01(0.03)

‐0.02(0.02)

NonprofitMFIsincountry ‐0.35**(0.08)

‐0.03(0.02)

‐0.01(0.01)

Assets(log) ‐6.38**(1.30)

0.12(0.36)

0.01(0.22)

Age(log) ‐2.75(2.27)

‐0.02(0.63)

0.33(0.39)

Regulated ‐2.38(3.41)

‐0.48(0.95)

‐0.00(0.58)

DepositstoAssets 16.67**(6.78)

1.49(1.88)

‐2.32*(1.15)

Medium/LargeOutreach 3.02(4.21)

‐1.12(1.17)

0.12(0.71)

Averageloansize(log) ‐4.05(5.42)

0.70(1.50)

0.59(0.92)

Fractionwomenborrowers 18.90**(6.62)

1.60(1.84)

0.90(1.12)

Poor/povertyinmission 11.83**(2.84)

‐0.07(0.79)

0.09(0.48)

Targetruralclients ‐5.22¥(3.16)

1.29(0.87)

‐0.61(0.54)

Lendtoindividuals ‐5.05(4.38)

‐0.85(1.22)

1.20(0.74)

For‐profitMFI 3.47

(3.46)1.86¥(0.96)

0.23(0.59)

Profitorientation

5.77**(1.97)

0.55(0.55)

0.67*(0.33)

Fixedregioneffects (yes) (yes) (yes) N 358 “R2” 0.37 0.09 0.12

**p<0.01;*p<0.05;¥p<0.10 aSeeminglyunrelatedregressionmodel

Page 26: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

26  

TABLE6.SELF‐SUFFICIENCY(SUSTAINABILITY)

Model10aSustainabilityPr(F.S.S.>1)

Countryproblems 0.01(0.01)

Countrypopulation(log) 0.01(0.16)

For‐ProfitMFIsincountry 0.04**(0.01)

NonprofitMFIsincountry 0.00(0.01)

Assets(log) 0.21(0.15)

Age(log) 0.50*(0.25)

Regulated 0.01(0.37)

DepositstoAssets 1.85*(0.95)

Medium/LargeOutreach 0.20(0.46)

Averageloansize(log) ‐0.49(0.59)

Fractionwomenborrowers ‐1.46*(0.74)

Poor/povertyinmission ‐0.66*(0.31)

Targetruralclients 0.34(0.34)

Lendtoindividuals ‐0.64(0.48)

For‐profitMFI 0.06

(0.37)Profitorientation

‐0.14(0.21)

Fixedregioneffects (yes)N 358Log‐Likelihood ‐168.78

**p<0.01;*p<0.05;¥p<0.10aLogisticregressionmodel

Page 27: The Profit Orientation of Microfinance Institutions and Effective

27  

REFERENCES

Ahlin, C., Lin, J., & Maio, M. (2011). Where does microfinance flourish? Microfinance institution performance in macroeconomic context. Journal of Developmental Economics, 95, 105‐120. 

Armendariz, B., & Morduch, J. (2005). The Economics of MicroFinance (Second ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. 

Brass, D. J., Galaskiewicz, J., Greve, H. R., & Tsai, W. (2004). Taking stock of networks and organizations: A multilevel perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 47, 795‐817. 

Cook, T., & Isern, J. (2004). What Is a Network? The Diversity of Networks in Microfinance Today. Copestake, J. (2007). Mainstreaming microfinance: Social performance management or mission drift? 

World Development, 35, 1721‐1738. Cull, R., Demirguc‐Kunt, A., & Morduch, J. (2009). Microfinance meets the market. Journal of Economic 

Perspectives, 23, 167‐192. Cull, R., Demirguc‐Kunt, A., & Morduch, J. (2011). Does Regulatory Supervision Curtail Microfinance 

Profitability and Outreach? . World Development, 39, 949‐965. Gonzalez, A. (2007). Efficiency drivers of microfinance institutions (MFIs): The case of operating 

costs.Unpublished manuscript. Gonzalez, A. (2010). Analyzing microcredit interest rates: A review of the methodology proposed by 

Mohammed Yunus.Unpublished manuscript. Hannan, M. T., & Freeman, J. (1989). Organizational Ecology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Hermes, N., & Lensink, R. (2007). The empirics of microfinance: what do we know? The Economic 

Journal, 117, F1‐F10. Hermes, N., Lensink, R., & Meesters, A. (2011). Outreach and efficiency of microfinance institutions. 

World Development, 39, 938‐948. Hudon, M., & Traça, D. (2011). On the efficiency effects of subsidies in microfinance: An empirical 

inquiry. World Development, 39, 966‐973. Mersland, R., & Strøm, R. Ø. (2008a). Performance and governance in microfinance institutions. Journal 

of Banking and Finance, 33, 662‐669. Mersland, R., & Strøm, R. Ø. (2008b). Performance and trade‐offs in microfinance organisations—Does 

ownership matter? Journal of International Development, 20, 598‐612. Mersland, R., & Strøm, R. Ø. (2010). Microfinance mission drift? World Development, 38, 28‐36. Morduch, J. (2000). The microfinance schism. World Development, 28, 617‐629. Owen‐Smith, J., & Powell, W. W. (2004). Knowledge networks as channels and conduits: The effects of 

spillovers in the Boston biotechnology community. Organization Science, 15, 5‐21. Weisbrod, B. A. (1998). Institutional form and organizational behavior. In W. W. Powell & E. S. Clemen 

(Eds.), Private Action and the Public Good (pp. 69‐84). New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Yunus, M. (2011, January 14, 2011). Sacrificing Microcredit for Megaprofits. New York Times,  Zellner, A. (1962). An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests for 

aggregation bias. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 57, 348‐368.