45
The New Regionalism and Policy Interdependence Leonardo Baccini Trinity College Dublin [email protected] Andreas Dür University College Dublin [email protected] Abstract Over the last twenty years, the number of bilateral and regional preferential trade agreements in existence has increased very rapidly. Explanations of this development emphasize factors such as the spread of democracy, deadlock in multilateral trade negotiations, and learning. Our argument is that policy diffusion as a result of competition over market access is a major driving force behind what has become known as the “new regionalism”. The causal reasoning is that facing trade diversion, exporters excluded from a preferential trade agreement are likely to mobilize and push their government into signing an agreement with the country in which their exports are threatened. We test our argument against alternative explanations in a quantitative analysis of the proliferation of preferential trade agreements among 168 countries between 1990 and 2007. By showing that competition is indeed a major cause of the new regionalism, the paper contributes to the literatures on regionalism and policy diffusion. Key words: preferential trade agreements, policy diffusion, interest groups, spatial interdependence, Cox model. Current Version: October 2008 First Version: March 2008 Word Count: 12,297

The New Regionalism and Policy Interdependencenk2339/Seminars/Baccini_100108.pdf · The New Regionalism and Policy Interdependence Leonardo Baccini Trinity College Dublin [email protected]

  • Upload
    lemien

  • View
    224

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

The New Regionalism and Policy Interdependence

Leonardo Baccini Trinity College Dublin

[email protected]

Andreas Dür University College Dublin

[email protected] Abstract

Over the last twenty years, the number of bilateral and regional preferential trade agreements

in existence has increased very rapidly. Explanations of this development emphasize factors

such as the spread of democracy, deadlock in multilateral trade negotiations, and learning.

Our argument is that policy diffusion as a result of competition over market access is a

major driving force behind what has become known as the “new regionalism”. The causal

reasoning is that facing trade diversion, exporters excluded from a preferential trade

agreement are likely to mobilize and push their government into signing an agreement with

the country in which their exports are threatened. We test our argument against alternative

explanations in a quantitative analysis of the proliferation of preferential trade agreements

among 168 countries between 1990 and 2007. By showing that competition is indeed a major

cause of the new regionalism, the paper contributes to the literatures on regionalism and

policy diffusion.

Key words: preferential trade agreements, policy diffusion, interest groups, spatial interdependence, Cox model.

Current Version: October 2008 First Version: March 2008 Word Count: 12,297

1

INTRODUCTION

A casual overview of major trade policy developments over the last two hundred years

suggests that preferential trade policies are contagious. The Cobden-Chevalier agreement

between France and the United Kingdom (1860) was the first of a large number of

preferential trade agreements that were concluded in the second half of the nineteenth

century.1 In the interwar years, major European powers moved in parallel to establish

sizeable preferential trading systems with their colonies. The 1960s saw the spread of

regional trade agreements that clearly were a response to the creation of the European

Economic Community (1958). Finally, since the early 1990s many countries in the world

have decided to adopt preferential trade policies, leading to the sharp increase in the number

of preferential agreements in existence that is known as the “new regionalism”.2

Several potential explanations exist for these developments. Different countries

concluding preferential trade agreements at the same time may be the result of a “domino

effect”.3 In this view, the negative externalities from the conclusion of an agreement make

excluded countries scramble for new agreements.4 Alternatively, learning and the spread of

ideas may make countries adopt similar trade policies at the same time. Still another

explanation for parallel trade policy choices can be found in the security externalities that

trade can have.5 If a trade agreement provides security benefits to participating countries, in

an anarchic world in which all countries strive for survival, excluded countries will be pushed

to conclude agreements as well. Moreover, if democracies find it beneficial to conclude

preferential trade agreements, a spread of democracy may create the impression of contagion

1 Lazer 1999; Pahre 2008. 2 Mansfield and Milner 1999. 3 Baldwin 1993. 4 See for example, Oye 1992; Mansfield 1998; Lazer 1999; Gruber 2000; Manger 2005; Dür 2007b. 5 Gowa 1994; Skålnes 1998.

2

among trade policies.6 Finally, developments in the international trading system may create

incentives for all or many countries to pursue similar trade policies.7 For instance, stagnation

of the process of multilateral trade liberalization may stimulate several countries at the same

time to pursue preferential trade policies. In short, a variety of explanations exist that at first

sight provide plausible accounts of the empirical observations outlined above.

In this paper, building on the “domino theory” proposed by Richard Baldwin8, we

argue that the proliferation of preferential trade agreements over the last two decades is an

indication of policy interdependence. Countries excluded from a preferential trade agreement

react by signing their own agreements, thus driving the phenomenon that we know as the

new regionalism. What we add to this explanation is a logic that makes explicit the political

processes at the domestic level that impel the domino effect. The puzzle is that before facing

commercial discrimination, excluded countries are satisfied with the status quo, but once they

feel the negative effects of a preferential trade agreement from which they are excluded, their

trade-policy orientation changes. What are the underlying domestic political processes that

drive this change in trade-policy orientation? Our response is that exporters lobby more

against losses of foreign market access than in favor of opportunities, hence causing a shift

in the balance of domestic interests once a country faces discrimination abroad.

We test this argument against alternative explanations in a quantitative analysis of the

proliferation of preferential trade agreements among 168 countries between 1990 and 2007.

In this empirical analysis, rather than only show that preferential trade agreements are

contagious, our aim is to show why they are so: because of competitive pressures, emulation,

or security externalities? In carrying out the analysis, we introduce several improvements

6 Mansfield et al. 2002. 7 Mansfield and Reinhardt 2003. 8 Baldwin 1993; 1997; 2006.

3

with respect to data and method to the quantitative literature on preferential trade

agreements. Most importantly, we invested substantial effort in establishing an authoritative

list of trade agreements. We also were very cautious in operationalizing our variables in order

to allow for an analysis that comes as close as possible to testing our causal mechanism. The

findings provide strong support for our argument. The choice by different countries to enter

preferential trade agreements is indeed interdependent; and the interdependence increases as

the negative externalities from existing agreements increase.

The paper hence is of relevance to the literature on regionalism in the world

economy. At the same time, we also make a contribution to a growing literature on policy

diffusion and policy interdependence.9 Increasingly, scholars of international political

economy realize that dyads are not independent of each other, and try to model the

interdependence among them.10 Policy interdependence, for example, has been shown to be

a driving force of the diffusion of bilateral investment treaties.11 We add to this literature by

taking seriously a recent call for accepting that “space is more than geography”12 when

establishing the spatial weights matrix that is used to examine policy diffusion. Moreover, we

introduce a new way of measuring the degree of dependence among two observations, which

includes attention to extra-dyadic relationships.

In the following, we first briefly outline the existing literature on the spread of

preferential trade agreements. This discussion shows that a large number of different

explanations for the new regionalism exist. We then establish our argument that focuses on

attempts at regaining market access as driving factor behind the sharp increase in the number

of preferential agreements over the last twenty years. After discussing our data and approach

9 See for example, Gleditsch and Ward 2000; Braun and Gilardi 2006; and Franzese and Hays 2008. 10 Neumayer and Plümper 2008. 11 Elkins et al. 2006. 12 Beck et al. 2006.

4

to testing the argument, we present our empirical findings. In the conclusion, we stress the

implications of our findings for studies on new regionalism and policy interdependence.

EXPLAINING THE NEW REGIONALISM

Over the last fifteen years, the number of dyads forming part of a preferential trade

agreement has increased sharply (see Figure 1). While in 1990, only about 250 pairs of

countries had a preferential trade agreement between them, the number stood at 1829 in

2007.13 With 14,028 dyads in our dataset in 200714, this means that no fewer than 13 percent

of all dyads have a preferential trade link among them. Obviously, the European Union,

owing to its large number of member countries and agreements concluded with third

countries, accounts for a sizeable number of these dyads. The signature of the EU accession

treaties with ten Central and Eastern European countries, for example, explains a large part

of the peak in agreements signed in 2003. This does not mean that the process is limited to

the EU, however. Our data show that across the world, the number of agreements being

signed is increasing. In particular, there is a growing number of South-South agreements and

of agreements involving Asian countries. Moreover, the EU’s increasing membership and

continued attractiveness as partner for preferential trade agreements is itself support for our

argument.

FIGURE 1 APPROXIMATELY HERE

What explains this proliferation of preferential trade agreements across the world? A

sizeable literature has been written that provides a series of different responses to this

13 Below we explain in some detail how we arrive at these numbers. 14 Since some countries, for example states in the area of the former Soviet Union, enter the dataset later than 1990, only 13,800 dyads are included for the whole period.

5

question. We distinguish five broad explanations, stressing the spread of ideas and

emulation, geopolitical balancing, common external shocks, common changes at the

domestic level, and competitive pressures. A first explanation for the new regionalism

stresses the spread of ideas and emulation. If specific trade policy ideas influence the trade

policies of different countries at the same time, such countries may all move in the same

direction, giving the impression of policy interdependence. Charles Kindleberger, for

example, contended that the period of free trade that Europe experienced in the nineteenth

century was a result of the spread of free trade ideas. In his words, “the countries of Europe

in this period should not be considered as independent economies whose reactions to

various phenomena can properly be compared, but rather as a single entity which moved to

free trade for ideological or perhaps better doctrinal reasons.”15

Alternatively, the perceived success of the trade policies of one or several countries

may lead to learning and emulation. Again, this would lead to the observation of parallel

trade policy choices. Suggesting such an influence, the economist Friedrich List, who in 1819

set up a pressure group to lobby for German economic unification, compared the situation

in Germany to that of France: “With envious eyes [traders from Germany] gaze across the

Rhine where a great nation can trade freely from the Rhine to the Pyrenees, from the Dutch

frontier to Italy without meeting with a single customs-house officer.”16 In the debate over

Great Britain’s unilateral adoption of free trade in the first half of the nineteenth century, the

argument that this would induce other countries to follow suit again had a prominent place.17

The principal idea was that other countries would perceive the benefits Great Britain accrued

from its free-trade policy and thus be convinced to follow the same course of action. Finally,

15 Kindleberger 1975, 51. 16 Cited in Birnie 1930, 72. 17 O’Brien 1976, 553.

6

the economic successes of the member countries of the European Economic Community

might have motivated economic integration in Latin America and Africa in the 1960s.18

Second, a spread of preferential trade agreements may result from the need for

balancing the trade-policy choices of other countries. Neorealist International Relations

theory argues that the anarchic structure of the international system makes states

apprehensive of increases in the power of other states, as these states may use their new

capabilities to attack them.19 Since preferential trade agreements that stimulate trade flows

may increase the wealth and hence the power of a country, excluded countries may be

concerned about such agreements.20 An agreement between two countries may thus force

other dyads to follow suit, to retain their current relative position vis-à-vis these countries.

According to this view, what we should witness is the development of rival trade blocs that

mirror security alliances.

Third, parallel trade policy choices can be a result of external shocks that affect all

countries in the system equally. The stagnation of the multilateral process of trade

liberalization, for example, may create incentives for states to pursue preferential trade

liberalization. Realizing that they cannot achieve better access to foreign markets by way of a

multilateral trade agreement, exporters in different countries may decide to lobby their

governments for the pursuit of preferential trade agreements. Alternatively, states may be

pushed to sign preferential trade agreements during multilateral trade talks, as such

agreements may increase their bargaining power at the level of the World Trade

Organization.21 The drawn out negotiations in the Uruguay Round and in the Doha

Development Agenda hence may explain the current proliferation of preferential trade

18 Pomfret 2001, 358. 19 Waltz 1979. 20 Gowa 1994. 21 Mansfield and Reinhardt 2003.

7

agreements. A final external shock that may explain the spread of preferential trade

agreements is the reduction of trade distance as a result of technological progress. Previous

research has shown that the distance between two countries and the remoteness of a dyad

from the rest of the world can explain whether a dyad forms part of the same trade

agreement.22 A decrease in trade distance hence may explain the boost in the number of

trade agreements that we observe over the last two decades.

Fourth, there may be changes at the domestic level that affect different countries at

the same time. Existing research has shown that democratic dyads are more likely to sign a

preferential trade agreement.23 The theoretical rationale given for this finding is that

democratic governments may use trade agreements as a signaling device vis-à-vis domestic

constituents. Following this view, the spread of democracy since the 1980s, which saw

countries in Latin America, Central and Eastern Europe, and Asia move towards democracy,

may thus explain the concurrent proliferation of preferential trade agreements.

Finally, competition for market access may explain the proliferation of trade

agreements. In this view, preferential trade agreements impose costs on excluded countries,

making the latter eager to join or to set up a rival agreement. Following this line of

reasoning, Kenneth Oye argued that discriminatory trade policies in the 1930s and the 1980s

had the unintended consequence of promoting further openness.24 Lloyd Gruber proposed

that the North American Free Trade Agreement (1994) was a consequence of Mexico’s

reaction to the creation of the Canada-United States free trade agreement (1988).25 Marc

Manger demonstrated that Japan concluded a trade agreement with Mexico because it feared

22 Baier and Bergstrand 2004. 23 Mansfield et al. 2002. 24 Oye 1992. 25 Gruber 2000.

8

exclusion from the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA, 1994).26 Finally,

Andreas Dür showed how European discriminatory trade policies in the 1930s and the 1960s

led to an American reaction.27 In the following, we provide an argument that builds on these

studies.

THE PROTECTION-FOR-EXPORTERS ARGUMENT

The protection-for-exporters argument that we set out to explain the spread of trade

agreements over the last two decades builds on the “domino theory of regionalism”.28 At its

most general, this theory postulates that preferential trade policies hurt outsiders by way of

trade diversion.29 Outsiders then feel compelled to react, either by joining a preferential trade

agreement or by setting up an alternative one. Over time, this leads to the spread of

preferential trade agreements.

This idea has been developed in most detail by Richard Baldwin.30 Baldwin starts

from a political economy model according to which governments maximize a function of

interest-group donations, general welfare, and support from groups that oppose membership

for non-economic reasons. To explain why governments react to losses rather than

maximize gains, Baldwin assumes that losers from policies lobby more than do winners

because winners cannot profit from their gains in a competitive setting. He legitimizes this

assumption by arguing that if returns to investments increase in a sector, more firms will be

attracted to that sector, increase competition, and cause gains to be lost again. Consequently,

there is no incentive to lobby for gains; exporters will become active only when facing losses,

such as those stemming from foreign preferential trade policies. This logic, however, is

26 Manger 2005. 27 Dür 2007b. 28 Baldwin 1993. 29 For the concept of trade diversion, see Viner 1950. 30 Baldwin 1993; 1997; 2006.

9

challenged by the fact that many industries are characterized by high barriers to entry.

Among them are not only declining sectors, but also ones that are able to export exactly

because they gain oligopolistic rents in the home market. Such industries, therefore, will

favor voice over exit with or without foreign discrimination. Following this explanation,

whether or not an industry lobbies should be determined by the industry’s barriers to entry

of new capital, but not by its trade orientation (that is, whether it is an exporting or an

import-competing sector).

We formulate a slightly different explanation that resolves this problem. The

resulting “protection-for-exporters” argument assumes the existence of two trade policy

constituencies, exporters and import-competitors. Exporters benefit from better foreign

market access and import-competitors from continued protection of their sector against

foreign competition. While import-competitors tend to be highly mobilized in defense of

their interests, we expect exporters in most circumstances to be hardly politically active. The

reason is that they face substantial uncertainty with respect to the potential benefits from

engaging in lobbying for better foreign market access. Not only do they face the uncertainty

of whether they will be able to convince their own government to pursue their preferences

(an uncertainty that is shared by import-competitors), but they also face uncertainty about

the willingness of a foreign government to reduce its trade barriers. The uncertainty is even

further enhanced by the fact that trade negotiations tend to go on over quite a substantial

time, making it difficult to know the competitive situation of an exporter at the time the

agreement enters into effect. As a result, it is difficult for an exporter to predict whether she

or rather another exporter from the same country (or an exporter from another country that

may also benefit from trade liberalization) will reap the benefits of better foreign market

access.

10

In short, uncertainty strongly inhibits exporters’ lobbying for gains. In this situation,

even if some exporters manage to overcome the uncertainty and become politically active,

the balance of domestic interests will be biased in favor of import-competing interests. It

seems reasonable to expect that a government will take into account this balance of interests

when formulating its trade policy, even if domestic interests do not perfectly translate into

government policies.31 The balance of domestic interests is an important consideration for

decision-makers that want to stay in power because organized interests that are dissatisfied

with government policy will try to mobilize the public. The expectation hence is for

governments to pursue policies that satisfy import-competing interests, even if they do not

close their markets completely as there always are some offsetting pressures from the broad

public that cares about economic efficiency and producers who depend on imports. For the

puzzle at hand, the prediction is for few regional trading arrangements to come into

existence under these circumstances.

Exporters’ incentives to mobilize are substantially different when facing losses,

caused, for example, by the creation of a preferential trading arrangement among foreign

countries. In this situation, rather than having to invest in monitoring foreign markets to

gather information about export opportunities, they can simply react in a fire-brigade

manner to any losses they experience form the trade policy choices of foreign countries.

Moreover, they can be quite certain about the consequences of their lobbying activity. If they

manage to achieve the re-establishment of the market conditions that existed before the

creation of the preferential trade agreement, they should be able to regain their share of that

market. Exporters’ uncertainty of lobbying against losses, consequently, is lower than the

uncertainty of lobbying for gains. The expectation derived from this argument is that a

31 This assumption is common to a large number of studies in the field of International Political Economy. See, for example, Milner 1988; Gilligan 1997; Chase 2005.

11

stronger lobby effort by exporters should be visible in response to losses.32 To the extent

that governments are receptive to changes in the relative balance of different interests in a

country, this shift in the domestic balance of interests should give more prominence to

exporter concerns in the country’s trade policy. In particular, we expect that the country

should enter into negotiations for a trade agreement with the country in which exporters face

a loss of market access.

The strength of the effect just set out depends on the amount of trade diversion that

an agreement causes for an excluded country. The amount of trade diversion, in turn,

depends on the extent to which the exporters of the excluded country directly compete with

a member country of a preferential trade agreement in the market of the other member

country. Simplifying, it can be expected that an agreement between two developed countries

will have a high pull effect for other developed countries, but a low pull effect for

developing countries. An agreement between two developing countries, by contrast, will

have the largest effect on other developing countries. A North-South agreement, finally,

should stimulate other agreements between developed and developing countries. The logic

also suggests that the impact of a preferential agreement should be particularly severe for

countries that see a significant amount of their exports go to one of the member countries.

The reason is that the larger the share of exports concerned, the larger the potential costs,

and the larger also the political power of the exporters concerned. Summarizing, this means

that the likelihood of an agreement between countries A and B increases as the number of

preferential trade agreements A and B form part of increases; the share of exports from A

going to B and B going to A increases; and the degree of competitiveness between the

32 The same expectation of mobilization against losses can be derived from prospect theory (Kahneman and Tversky 1979; Fannis 2004). According to prospect theory, actors are more willing to engage in risky behaviour if they expect losses. While in this paper we cannot empirically test the two approaches against each other, we find the approach based on uncertainty theoretically more appealing.

12

exports of A (B) and the partner countries (C, D,…) of the other side increases. In the form

of a hypothesis:

Hypothesis: The probability of a preferential trade agreement between two

countries increases as the number of preferential agreements in which each of

them participates and the discriminatory trade effects of these agreements

increases.

It is important to stress that our argument leads to the expectation that both

conditions included in this hypothesis are necessary for the diffusion effect to come about.

Preferential trade agreements should not have an effect on the trade policy choices of third

countries unless they generate trade diversion. If we were to see that preferential agreements

spread to countries that do not suffer from trade diversion, this would be an indication that

alternative diffusion mechanism are at play, a question that we take up below.

Any explanation relying on a domino effect begs the question of what the initial

stimulus for the domino effect is, that is, what makes the first domino stone fall. The

endogenous explanation is that in some cases, governments may be able to design an

agreement that imposes costs on third countries rather than domestic import-competing

interests. In such a case, in the absence of lobbying by import-competitors, governments

may have an incentive to conclude an agreement.33 An initial agreement should be

particularly probable between adjacent countries, as in such a case exporters’ uncertainty

about the potential benefits of such a move is likely to be smallest. For some agreements, an

33 Grossman and Helpman 1995, 680.

13

explanation may also require consideration of exogenous factors, such as the geopolitical

interests of countries.

Countries could also be expected to conclude preferential trade agreements because

they expect to benefit from the external effect that we describe here. In fact, there are some

historical examples of countries using preferential trade agreements to put pressure on third

countries. Some evidence, for example, suggests that the Asian and Pacific countries may

have used the threat of preferential liberalization as part of the Asia Pacific Economic

Cooperation (APEC) to force the EU into accepting the conclusion of the Uruguay Round.34

The empirical record, however, suggests that in many cases, decision-makers did not

anticipate the external consequences of a preferential trade agreement. In some cases, they

even were surprised by these effects. Few people, for example, had predicted that the

deepening of European integration in the 1980s would have a major pull effect on third

countries, which led to the creation of the European Economic Area and the negotiation of

a series of Mediterranean agreements.

An aspect of the argument that we have ignored so far is why a member country of a

preferential agreement (country A) should accept the conclusion of a trade agreement with

an excluded country (country B). As country A recently concluded a preferential agreement

with country C, it could be hypothesized that its domestic interests will not lobby in favor of

another agreement. Import-competitors will be particularly sensitive about a further

agreement at a time when they suffer from the consequences of the initial agreement, while

exporting interests will be eager to exploit the new market opportunities. Our argument is

that country A will accept an agreement only if its exporters face losses in country B (the

34 Richardson 1993.

14

inverted logic) or because country B is so eager to reach an agreement with A that it is

willing to make major concessions.

Although we have formulated our argument using the example of bilateral

agreements, the logic also applies to plurilateral preferential agreements. For exporters in third

countries, a multilateral agreement has the same effect as a set of bilateral agreements: it

threatens access to several markets at the same country. A multilateral agreement between

countries A, C, D, and E therefore is likely to have a major pull effect on country B, if it has

major export interests in at least one of these markets and its exports are in competition in

that market with those from at least one of the other member countries. The precise reaction

of country B to this plurilateral agreement will depend on its export interests. If its exports

are concentrated in A, it will conclude a bilateral agreement with that country. If it has export

interests in more than one of these markets, however, it may decide to join the existing

agreement. This is the explanation that we provide for the repeated rounds of enlargement

of the European Union.

What we do no consider in this paper is that a country may react to discrimination in

ways other than signing a trade agreement with one of more of the member countries of a

preferential agreement. For one, it may threaten with retaliation against countries that

impose costs on its exporters. When the European Union moved towards a deepening of

integration in the late 1980s, the U.S. responded with threats to all proposals that had the

potential of imposing costs on its exporters. Such threats can only be used by structurally

powerful countries, however. Weaker countries responded to the Single Market Program

with requests for bilateral agreements, as set out in this paper. A second possible response to

discrimination is a call for multilateral trade liberalization. Again the U.S. reaction to

European integration best illustrates this tactic. The creation of the European Economic

15

Community in the late 1950s caused concern among American exporters. Instead of signing

a preferential agreement with the new trading entity, the U.S. used the Kennedy Round of

world trade negotiations (1964-67) to reduce the discrimination resulting from the European

move.35 Finally, a government may decide to compensate exporters that face costs from

trade diversion by way of a subsidy. World trade rules, however, impose strict limits on the

use of subsidies; governments violating these rules have to fear the imposition of

countervailing duties. Disregarding these alternative tactics leads us to underestimate the

external effect of preferential trade agreements.

DATA AND OPERATIONALIZATION

Only very few studies have tried to quantitatively test the basic idea underlying the argument

about interdependence in the creation of preferential trade agreements.36 What is more, these

existing studies are characterized by a series of shortcomings. Early quantitative studies, for

example, did not explicitly model the spatial correlation at the heart of the theoretical

argument. More recent studies using spatial weights matrixes either restrict the analysis to a

small sample of countries or take a cross-section approach.37 By using time-series rather than

cross-sectional data, establishing an authoritative list of trade agreements, designing a

quantitative test that captures the trade diversion logic that underlies our argument as closely

as possible, and controlling for alternative diffusion mechanism, we improve on the existing

literature with respect to both data and operationalization.

We test our argument on a database of preferential trade agreements among 168

countries between 1990 and 2007. As is evident from Figure 1 above, relatively few

35 Dür 2008. 36 Among the exceptions are Mansfield 1998; Rieder 2006; Egger and Larch 2008. 37 Rieder (2006) restricts the analysis to 25 developed countries and Egger and Larch (2008) adopt a cross-section approach.

16

agreements were signed before 1990, legitimating our choice to start the analysis in that year.

Starting in 1990 also makes sense from a methodological point of view. By extending the

dataset to the years before 1990, we would have to tackle the fact that the Cold War

environment was quite distinct for most countries than the post-Cold War environment. As

Kevin Clarke has forcefully shown, including control variables to deal with omitted variable

bias associated with such a shift may increase rather than reduce this bias.38 We thus follow

his recommendation of substituting research design for control variables by limiting the

dataset to the post-Cold War period. With respect to country coverage, while we have tried

to include as many countries as possible in our analysis, we had to exclude some (mostly very

small) countries owing to data restrictions. This leads to the elimination of a few dyads with

preferential trade agreements, especially in the Caribbean region. We also exclude

Montenegro as it only came into existence in 2006 and hence would have been in the

database for only two years. A few other countries that became independent after 1990 enter

the database in the year of their independence.

The dyads included in the analysis are non-directional, that is, we do not distinguish

between the country pair Albania-Argentina and the reverse country pair Argentina-Albania.

The reason for using non-directed dyads is that we do not know which country started the

negotiations for a preferential trade agreement. While in single case studies it may be possible

to find out exactly which country made the first step in calling for a trade agreement, doing

so for the large number of agreements included in our analysis is not practical. What is more,

using non-directed dyads makes sense from a theoretical point of view: we expect an

agreement to come about only if both countries feel some pressure to engage in

negotiations. In most cases, therefore, we would expect the future member countries to

38 Clarke 2005.

17

informally agree on the need for an agreement before they formally launch the negotiations.

In total, we consider up to 14,028 dyads per year for a total number of 225,833 observations.

The dependent variable in our analysis is whether two countries sign a preferential

trade agreement in a specific year. We opted for the year of signature rather than the year of

entry into force of an agreement, as signing an agreement is an important indication that

governments respond to exporter lobbying. The year of signature is also important for the

effect that agreements have, since it is in this moment that exporters in third countries

should become worried about the potential negative consequences for them. We invested

substantial effort in establishing an authoritative list of trade agreements signed between

1990 and 2007. Using three different databases, namely the list of regional trade agreements

notified with the World Trade Organization, the Tuck Trade Agreements Database, and the

McGill Faculty of Law Preferential Trade Agreements Database, but excluding partial-scope

agreements and agreements that include no preferential treatment, we find that 1600 dyads

formed a preferential trade agreement between 1990 and 2007.39

For our analysis, we also needed to know which dyads already formed part of a

preferential trade agreement in 1990, since dyads with an agreement drop out from our

analysis. Our database hence includes all agreements effectively implemented between 1945

and 1989 that were still in existence in 1990, and all new agreements signed between 1990

and 2007. We exclude a few agreements from our database that formally were in existence in

1990 but had not been effectively implemented. Examples are the Latin American

Integration Association, which did not lead to any significant preferential tariff reductions,

and the Economic Community of Central African States (until 1993, when member

countries signed a revised agreement). Such agreements, which only exist on paper, do not

39 These databases are available at http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/region_e/summary_e.xls; http://www.dartmouth.edu/~tradedb/; and http://ptas.mcgill.ca/ [all last accessed August 18, 2008].

18

have an external effect, and thus should not contribute to the domino effect we are

interested in. The agreements that we consider to be effectively implemented with

discriminatory consequences as of 1 January 1990 are: the EU; the European Free Trade

Association (EFTA); the agreements between the EU and EFTA countries; the agreements

between the EU and Cyprus, Israel, and Malta; the agreements between the U.S. and Canada

and Israel; the Caribbean Community; and the South African Customs Union.

We do not consider second or third agreements signed between two countries. This

is an important restriction especially for European dyads, where we see a stepwise deepening

of integration. We also see a transformation of bilateral agreements between the European

Union and third countries across Europe into accession treaties. All Central and Eastern

European countries, for example, signed bilateral free trade agreements with the EU in the

early 1990s. Since dyads are ignored once they concluded an agreement, events such as the

accession to the EU of ten of these countries in 2004 do not figure in our analysis. While the

deepening of integration can have effects similar to those captured by our theoretical

argument (and can be a reaction to preferential trade agreements among third countries), we

decided to exclude these cases from our analysis to secure unit homogeneity (as the political

economy of deepening an agreement may be slightly different from the political economy of

an initial agreement). More generally, by opting for a dichotomous dependent variable, we

abstract from the fact that some preferential agreements are more far-reaching, and hence

potentially more trade-diverting, than others.

Policy Diffusion: Competition and Emulation

The model that we estimate includes a spatial weights matrix and control variables for both

the dyad under consideration and potential external shocks. We thus estimate the following

equation:

19

yit = βxit + δwiyt-1+ εi (1)

where β and δ are the coefficients and wi is the ith row of the spatial weights matrix. We use

three different approaches to estimate this model. First, in line with earlier research, we

estimate a Cox proportional hazards model, adjusted for clustering on dyads.40 The

advantage of using the Cox model is that it does not require any assumption about the shape

of the underlying survival distribution. As is common practice in recent research on the

statistical analysis of panel data with a binary dependent variable, we base significance test on

Huber (robust) standard errors.41 These standard errors can take account of possible

heteroskedasticity (serial correlation) or intra-group correlation of the data. Second, we use a

frailty model (Gamma distributed) to control for the heterogeneity between groups, which turns

out to be statistically significant in our case. As Janet Box-Steffensmeier and Bradford Jones

argue, heterogeneity can result from the omission of relevant variables.42 Not dealing with

heterogeneity can lead to an underestimation of the effect of covariates that increase the

hazard rate and an overestimation of the effect of covariates that reduce the hazard rate.

Finally, since our dataset is heavily zero-inflated, we also estimate the models using a rare

events logistic regression.43 The use of this approach is recommended since common logistic

regression underestimates the impact of the explanatory variables on the probability of the

rare event. In addition, there is the risk that the standard errors are biased with a large

number of zeros in the dependent variable.

The main independent variable is an N*N*t spatial weights (also called connectivity)

matrix. A spatial weight matrix measures the impact of a policy change in a dyad on all other

40 The study by Elkins et al. on the diffusion of bilateral investment agreements is also based on the Cox model. Darmofal (forthcoming) provides an extensive analysis of the use of survival models with spatial effects. 41 Beck 2008, 486. 42 Box-Steffensmeier and Jones 2004, 141. 43 In our dataset, only about 0.7 percent of the dyads have a score of 1.

20

dyads. It weighs the policy change by specific factors, such as spatial proximity or degree of

economic interdependence. In our case, the policy change is whether a dyad signed an

agreement in the last five years. We opt for a five year period as we think that while it may

take some time for exporters in third countries to react to the creation of a preferential trade

agreement, and for this reaction to have an impact on the trade policies of a country, after

some time the external effect of a preferential trade agreement should disappear. After five

years, exporters will either have been successful in convincing their government to reach an

agreement with the members of a preferential trade agreement or will have adapted to the

new situation.

We weigh the influence of the policy change in other dyads in a way that

approximates the trade diversion logic as directly as possible. The hypothesis set out above

leads us to the expectation that the pressure on country B to respond to a preferential trade

agreement between countries A and C by signing an agreement with A should depend on the

importance of market A for B and the degree of competition between the exports to A by B

and C. In form of a formula, the spatial weight for dyad AB is as follows:44

∑∑

+

=

,...,d,...a_c,

d...b_c,

ba

,...,d,...b_c,

d...a_c,

ab n*c

en*

c

e

lkdcabk (2)

where kab is greater than 0 if countries A and B are connected. In this formula, e is the share

of a country’s exports going to the other country, c is the degree of competition between two

countries and n a variable that takes on the value 1 if country A (B) signed an agreement with

countries C, D, and so on between one and five years ago. The variable is lagged by one year

44 The spatial matrices have been calculated using the software MATLAB 7.0 employing a program designed by the authors for this purpose. Although frequently done in the literature (see Freanzese and Hays 2008, 580), we do not row-standardize our connectivity matrix since we do not have any theoretical reason to do so and since row-standardization may influence the results and may impact inference (see Plümper and Neumayer 2008, 26).

21

to avoid simultaneity bias. This may lead to an underestimation of the spatial effect, if

countries already react to other countries’ negotiations of preferential trade agreements. An

example of this would be African countries that initially are reluctant to sign an Economic

Partnership Agreement with the EU, and then still jump on the bandwagon as they fear

exclusion from agreements signed by the EU and other African countries. The subscripts a,

b, and so on denote the countries.

The formula has two parts: the first part assesses the pressure on A resulting from

B’s trade agreements and the second part the pressure on B resulting from A’s trade

agreements. The additive term captures the idea that the probability that A and B sign an

agreement depends on both sides’ incentive to conclude one. As set out above, an agreement

will only come about if either both countries face exclusion in the other’s market or one

country faces very large costs and thus will be willing to make major concessions to achieve

an agreement.

With respect to the importance of the other country’s market, we use dyadic exports

as a share of a country’s total exports. A potential problem with this is that export shares are

partly endogenous to our argument. The share of exports of country A going to country B

should decrease as country B signs a preferential trade agreement with country C, at least as

long as countries A and C export the same goods. We deal with this endogeneity problem by

lagging the matrix by one year. The term used to denote this matrix below is “trade and

competition”.

One way of measuring the degree to which two countries compete on the same

market is to disaggregate trade flows to the sector or even product level and then correlating

the direction of trade flows. However, weak trade data for many of the countries that we

22

include in our analysis made us opt for a proxy measure instead.45 We use the (natural log of

the) difference between the per capita Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of countries B and C

as a proxy for the extent that these two countries compete in the market of country A.46 The

assumption underlying this operationalization is that countries with a similar GDP per capita

have a similar factor endowment and thus should export the same goods. A North-North

agreement should have an impact on other Northern countries47; a South-South agreement

on other Southern countries; and a North-South agreement should make Northern countries

conclude an agreement with the Southern and Southern countries with the Northern

member of the agreement. For example, the EU should have reacted to the North American

Free Trade Agreement by signing an agreement with Mexico, as it exports similar goods to

that country as does the US.48 That it did not sign an agreement with the US also supports

our logic, as the EU’s exports to the US do not compete with those from Mexico.

Figures 2a and 2b illustrate how this variable changes for two cases. In Figure 2a, we

show the spatial weight for the dyad Bolivia and Chile. On November 29, 1990, the Andean

Pact (now Andean Community), of which Bolivia is a member but Chile is not, decided to

establish a free trade area by January 1993. This decision increased the pressure on Chile to

conclude a trade agreement with Bolivia. The pressure on Chile grew even stronger as a

result of the September 10, 1994, free trade agreement between Bolivia and Mexico. It is no

wonder then that Bolivia and Chile signed an agreement one year later. In Figure 2b, the

agreement between the Czech Republic and the EU has only little impact on the dyad Czech

45 In fact, even at the aggregate level, dyadic trade data is quite problematic, as it includes many missing values and exhibits major jumps in the time series for less developed countries. See also Gleditsch 2002. 46 We use natural logarithms of many of the variables, since they are characterized by frequent (economic and geographical variables) or occasional (spatial variables) large observations. 47 Intra-industry trade, which is important between developed countries at a similar stage of development, lowers the potential for trade diversion. The operationalization used here thus makes us overestimate the pressure that preferential agreements among developed countries exert on other developed countries. The results are consequently biased against our argument. 48 In fact, this is what happened. See Dür 2007a.

23

Republic – Bulgaria, as Bulgaria is expected to export different goods to the Czech Republic

than the then member states of the EU. The pressure on Bulgaria increased as a result of the

agreements between the Czech Republic and Latvia (1993) and the accession of Romania to

the Central European Free Trade Agreement (CEFTA) in 1997. The logical result was the

conclusion of a trade agreement between the Czech Republic and Bulgaria in 1998, as part of

the latter country’s accession to CEFTA.

FIGURES 2a and b APPROXIMATELY HERE

As indicated above, several alternative causal mechanisms could drive the diffusion

of trade agreements. In the empirical analysis below, we control for the possibility that

diffusion is a result of emulation or security externalities. Emulation is defined as

ritualistically “following or doing oppositely of others”.49 It is most likely among countries

that are culturally close. The expectation thus is that the probability of a preferential trade

agreement between countries A and B increases, as the number of preferential agreements

that A and B participate in increases and the cultural distance between A and B decreases.

Building on work by Zachary Elkins, Andrew Guzman and Beth Simmons, we construct

three different spatial weights matrices measuring cultural proximity to capture this effect.50

Each of the matrices uses a different proxy for cultural distance: whether two countries share

the same predominant language, predominant religion, and a common colonial past. We also

control for the possibility of diffusion resulting from security externality. To capture this

effect, we calculate a spatial weight matrix that increases the probability of countries A and B

49 Franzese and Hays 2008, 572. 50 Elkins et al. 2006, 831.

24

signing an agreement if country C, with which B has had a military conflict since World War

II, signed a preferential trade agreement with another country in the last five years.

Control Variables

In our models, we also take into account a series of variables that characterize the dyad

under analysis and the context in which a dyad considers concluding an agreement. Doing so

is vital to avoid overestimating the effect of the spatial lag, as parallel policy choices may be a

result of correlated unit-level factors or exogenous shocks that are common to various

dyads.51 Thus, in accordance with previous studies in the field, we include several economic,

geographical, and political variables as control variables in our base model. Most of these

variables are lagged by one year to avoid endogeneity problems. In the robustness checks

below, we add further control variables.

Concerning the economic variables, we control for the amount of trade between the

two countries, as previous research has shown that as trade between countries increases, the

probability of forming a preferential trade agreement increases as well (TRADE). It can also

be hypothesized that signing an agreement between two economies of relatively equal size

should be easier that signing one between a large and a small economy. Among the reasons

to expect such an effect is that the small country may fear becoming overly dependent on

the large country and that for the large country the economic benefits of an agreement with

a small country are likely to be small. The welfare gains from an agreement may also increase

as the parties to an agreement become more similar in economic size.52 The measure that we

use for this variable is the absolute difference in GDP between the two countries (SIM).

We also include a measure of the size of the economy of the two countries to

capture the idea that the larger the countries participating in a preferential trade agreement,

51 Franzese and Hays, 2008. 52 Baier and Bergstrand 2004.

25

the larger the economic gains. As Scott Baier and Jeffrey Bergstrand argue, a preferential

agreement between two large economies increases the volume of trade in more varieties than

one between two small economies.53 In addition, the larger increase in trade among two large

countries causes a larger net expansion of demand and hence a larger rise in real income. We

capture this idea by including the GDP of the smaller of the two countries in a dyad (GDP).

A further factor that potentially influences the likelihood of an agreement between a pair of

countries is the level of development. The more developed the two countries, the easier they

should find it to conclude an agreement. This is so for two reasons. First, a country with a

highly developed economy is less dependent on tariff revenues. Second, a developed country

is in a better position to compensate societal groups that face adjustment costs due to trade

liberalization.54 The variable that captures this argument is the absolute difference in GDP

per capita (GDP PER CAPITA). As with other variables that are measured at the level of the

state, we convert this one into a dyadic variable by opting for the lower of the two values as

the one characterizing the dyad.

Two control variables capture domestic and international political factors. At the

international level, it is quite straightforward to assume that military allies should be more

likely to sign an agreement than other pairs of countries (ALLIANCE). At the domestic level,

previous research has shown that democratic pairs of countries tend to sign more

preferential trade agreements than non-democratic or mixed pairs.55 We use the seven point

Freedom House scale of democracy to measure this variable, with 1 being the value for a

completely free and 7 the value for a completely oppressive regime (DEMOCRACY).56 The

53 Ibid., 45. 54 Ruggie 1982. 55 Mansfield et al. 2002. 56 Freedom House 2007.

26

advantage of the Freedom House index over others is that it covers all of the countries in

our dataset and provides values for up to 2007.

Finally, we include two variables that measure the geographic distance between

countries, as previous research has shown an effect of distance on the likelihood of signing a

preferential agreement.57 On the one hand, neighboring countries can be expected to have a

higher probability of signing an agreement. Not only are there on average closer economic

links between neighboring countries, but also the political links tend to be stronger. We thus

expect countries that share a common border to be more likely to sign an agreement

(CONTIGUITY). On the other hand, since trade costs increase with distance, geographically

closer countries are more likely to form a preferential trade agreement. We thus include the

(natural logarithm) distance in kilometers between the two capitals of the pair of countries in

our base model (DISTANCE).

FINDINGS

In a first step, we estimate four different models (see Table 1). First, we report the findings

of a Cox proportional hazards model, adjusted for clusters on dyads, with the restricted set

of control variables. The findings are strongly supportive of our argument. The coefficient

for the domino effect has the right sign and is statistically significant at the 0.01 level. Some

of the variables capturing the alternative diffusion mechanisms are also statistically

significant. Countries seem to be influenced in their decision to conclude agreements by the

agreements concluded by other countries with the same language and colonial heritage.

Religion is the only of these three variables capturing the emulation argument that is not

statistically significant. Neither is the rivalry argument supported by the empirical

57 Krugman 1992; Baier and Bergstrand 2004.

27

examination. Countries do not seem to be reacting to the agreements concluded by countries

that may pose a military threat.

TABLE 1 APPROXIMATELY HERE

Many of the control variables that have been shown to be important in previous

research also turn out to be significant in this model, giving added plausibility to our

findings. For one, a pair of countries with a strong trade link is more likely to form a trade

agreement. Furthermore, pairs of countries with relatively large economies are more likely to

sign an agreement. Security concerns seem to play a role as well, as countries that form part

of the same alliance are more likely to form an agreement. Moreover, democratic pairs of

countries are less prone to conclude an agreement, thus confirming previous research.58 Also

intuitive is the finding that distance reduces the likelihood of an agreement. Interestingly,

however, contiguous countries are less likely to form an agreement than countries that do not

share a common border.

Model 1 thus provides strong support for the argument that the signing of a

preferential agreement among two countries has an effect on the probability of other

countries signing a preferential trade agreement with them. We include figures to illustrate

the magnitude of this effect (see Figures 3a, 3b, 4a, and 4b). Figure 3a shows the effect of a

change in the importance of a market on the diffusion effect. As set out in the hypothesis

above, the spatial effect of a trade agreement between two countries on a third country is

much stronger if the excluded country has substantial export interests in at least one of these

two countries. Figure 3b shows the same effect for the second variable that forms part of the

58 Mansfield et al. 2002.

28

trade and competition matrix. The more similar the exports of country B to those of country

C, the greater the threat of trade diversion in country A, and thus the greater the incentive

for country B to sign an agreement with country A. Figures 4a and 4b compare the

substantive effects of the trade and competition matrix and the common colonial heritage

matrix. As the graphs show, the effect is stronger for the competition variable.

FIGURES 3a, b and 4a, b APPROXIMATELY HERE

Models 2, 3, and 4 provide further support for our argument. In Model 2, we include

additional control variables to check the robustness of our base model. The first of these is

economic growth, as an economic downturn may increase the probability of a PTA being

formed.59 We use the average value for the two countries (GDP GROWTH). We also control

for the export orientation of countries, that is, the importance that exports have as a

percentage of the overall economy.60 The more export oriented a country is, the larger the

political influence of export interests should be. With exporters expected to benefit from a

preferential trade agreement, an increase in exporters’ power should increase the probability

that this country signs a preferential agreement. Since members of the World Trade

Organization (WTO) tend to have more similar trade policies than countries that do not

form part of this international organization, dyads in which both countries are WTO

members should be more likely to conclude an agreement (WTO).

Furthermore, we consider the possibility that during multilateral trade negotiations in

the WTO countries’ propensity to conclude preferential trade agreements increases (WTO

59 See for example Mattli 1999. 60 As is common in the literature, we measure export orientation by the natural logarithm exports to GDP ratio in year t-1. See also Rodrik 1995.

29

ROUND). We also control for the argument reported above that involvement in trade disputes

may influence a pair’s propensity to conclude a trade agreement. Having a trade dispute with

the other side should decrease the likelihood of an agreement (TRADE DISPUTE), while

having a dispute with a third party should increase it (TRADE DISPUTE THIRD PARTY). As

culturally similar countries may find it easier to negotiate an international agreement, we also

include three proxies for cultural similarity, namely common language, same religion, and

common colonial heritage (LANGUAGE, RELIGION, and COLONY). Finally, since being an

island may influence a country’s willingness to sign an agreement – namely increasing the

willingness to overpass its geographical disadvantages – we also control for this variable in

our extended models (ISLAND).

The results of the model including these control variables are very similar to those

reported in Model 1. Among the new variables, most have the expected effect. For example,

a strong export orientation makes countries eager to form preferential agreements. This

finding provides support for our causal mechanism, which draws attention to the role of

exporters in lobbying for preferential trade agreements. Two member countries of the WTO

are more likely to conclude an agreement than if at least one country of a dyad is not a

member of the WTO. A trade dispute between the two countries, however, makes them less

likely to conclude an agreement. Interestingly, the previous finding by Walter Mattli that a

lack of economic growth makes countries sign an agreement is not supported.61

In Models 3 and 4 we change the econometric approach, but without that changing

the substantive findings. Noteworthy is the fact that in the model in which we use a rare

events logistic regression (Model 4), the substantive effect of our key variable is even larger

61 Mattli 1999.

30

than in the other models. Overall, across all four models the support for our argument is

thus very strong.

ROBUSTNESS CHECKS

To check the robustness of our results, we made a series of changes to our base model. For

all of the changes discussed below, the results are roughly comparable to the ones presented

and are available upon request. First, we estimated models in which we assume that

preferential trade agreements have an impact on third countries for three and seven years

after their signature. These changes control for the robustness of our initial hunch of a five-

year effect. Second, with respect to the importance of the export market, we use the inverse

of the geographical distance between A and B as a proxy for the amount of trade between

the two countries. The advantage of using distance is that the quality of this data is very good

(while data on dyadic trade flows is problematic). Moreover, distance has been shown to be a

very important determinant of trade flows. This is a result of the fact that trade costs

increase with geographic distance. By using distance we also avoid potential endogeneity

problems arising with trade flows as discussed below.

Third, we disaggregate the spatial weights matrix set out above into its component

parts. On the one hand, we estimate a model in which the spatial weight is purely determined

by the difference in per capita GDP between the excluded country and the potential

competitor. On the other hand, we assess a model with a spatial weights matrix calculated by

solely considering the excluded country’s exports to the discriminating country. The

expectation for these two models is for the spatial effects to be statistically significant but of

smaller magnitude than the ones reported above. This expectation is borne out by the

analysis.

31

Finally, we estimated a series of models in which we dropped all dyads with (1) an

EU country, (2) an EU or EFTA country, and (3) two Northern countries. The reason for

excluding EU and EFTA countries is that both trading entities may be considered unitary

actors in the international trading system. Our expectation was that relying on member states

(as done above) rather than the aggregate trading entities should make us underestimate the

competition effect in which we are interested. The following example illustrates this

expectation: the agreement between the EU and Mexico (2000) is best seen as a response to

the North American Free Trade Agreement.62 The countries within the EU that pushed for

this agreement were Spain, France and Germany. By coding this agreement for 15 EU

member countries, including countries such as Ireland and Finland that had no interest in

the agreement with Mexico, the competition effect is diluted. The EU creates further

difficulties for our analysis: joining the EU means that the new member country has to sign

up to all trade agreements that the EU forms part of at the time of accession. While a

country such as Hungary may have joined the EU because of the logic set out in our

argument, it was probably hardly interested in signing an agreement with Mexico.

Nevertheless, in our analysis, there is no difference between accession and accepting

agreements with third countries.

TABLE 2 APPROXIMATELY HERE

Table 2 shows the results of the models excluding EU and EFTA countries. In fact,

as expected, the competition effect is stronger than in the base model. The fact that the

values for all other variables are very similar to those reported above provides a strong

62 Dür 2007a.

32

indication that our results are very robust. The one variable that becomes statistically

significant in Models 5 and 6 is rivalry. This is very intuitive, as military conflict has not

played a role in Europe since World War II, but it does play a role in other continents. The

most interesting finding, however, is that democracy no longer plays a role once the

European countries are excluded from the dataset. This suggests that earlier findings of pairs

of democracies being more likely to sign an agreement were driven by the European

countries alone.63 In Model 7, we dropped all the dyads between two developed economies

to show the impact of policy diffusion on North-South and South-South preferential

agreements that are a special feature of the current wave of regionalism. Again the results

concur with the previous models.

CONCLUSION

This analysis has shown that the formation of preferential trade agreements is indeed an

interdependent process. A country forms an agreement with another country if it competes

on that market with third countries that already have preferential access. In making this

point, we have contributed a quantitative test of an argument that is quite prominent in the

literature on regionalism. Existing research offers several qualitative case studies of how

excluded countries react to the creation of a preferential trade agreement. Nevertheless,

quantitative research on this issue has so far been limited to a very small number of studies,

which moreover are hampered by several shortcomings. We have been careful in designing a

direct test of the argument and gathering more reliable data on the existence of preferential

trade agreements than had been done before.

Our paper also contributes to the literature on spatial effects (policy diffusion), by

calculating a trade-weighted matrix rather than one based solely on geographical distance,

63 Mansfield et al. 2002.

33

and by taking into account extra-dyadic relations. The time-varying nature of trade flows

created major problems for earlier studies, which we overcome in this problem. To our

knowledge, so far there has not been any attempt made at including extra-dyadic

relationships in the definition of spatial lags, although doing so may be consistent with

theory in many instances. For example, in the diffusion of bilateral investment treaties, the

effect of one agreement on other countries’ willingness to conclude an agreement may also

depend on the relationship between the third country and the developing country that signed

the initial agreement.

In future research, the present analysis could be extended in several respects. For

one, it would be interesting to take into account excluded countries’ possibility of forming a

rival agreement, rather than signing an agreement with a member country of a preferential

trade agreement. The classic case for such a rival agreement is the formation of the

European Free Trade Agreement in response to the creation of the European Economic

Community. Moreover, it would make sense to consider the fact that some dyads may

deepen their agreements in response to other dyads concluding agreements, and that the

deepening of agreements may lead other countries to seek an agreement as well. For

example, the Single European Act (1987) arguably increased the interest among

Mediterranean countries in signing a trade agreement with the EU. Finally, a good argument

can be made that current preferential trade agreements not only threaten trade but also

foreign direct investments. The North American Free Trade Agreement, for example, not

only created problems for European companies exporting to Mexico, but also to European

companies interested in investing in Mexico. A future study may take into account the

contents of agreements and foreign investment flows in providing an even more

comprehensive examination of the diffusion story.

34

REFERENCES

Baldwin, Richard E. (1993) ‘A Domino Theory of Regionalism’, NBER Working Paper No.

4465.

Baldwin, Richard E. (1997) ‘The Causes of Regionalism’, The World Economy 20 (7): 865-88.

Baldwin, Richard E. (2006) ‘Multilateralising Regionalism: Spaghetti Bowls as Building Blocs

on the Path to Global Free Trade’, World Economy 29 (11): 1451-518.

Beck, Nathaniel (2008) ‘Time-Series—Cross-Section Methods’, in Janet M. Box-

Steffensmeier, Henry E. Brady and David Collier (eds.) Oxford Handbook of Political

Methodology (Oxford: Oxford University Press), 475-93.

Beck, Nathaniel, Kristian Skrede Gleditsch, and Kyle Beardsley (2006) ‘Space Is More than

Geography: Using Spatial Econometrics in the Study of Political Economy’,

International Studies Quarterly 50 (1): 27-44.

Birnie, Arthur (1930) An Economic History of Europe, 1760-1930 (London: Methuen & Co.).

Box-Steffensmeier, Janet M. and Bradford Jones (2004) Event History Modeling: A Guide for

Social Scientists (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

Braun, Dietmar and Fabrizio Gilardi (2006) ‘Taking ‘Galton’s Problem’ Seriously: Towards a

Theory of Policy Diffusion’, Journal of Theoretical Politics 18 (3): 298-322.

Chase, Kerry A. (2005) Trading Blocs: States, Firms, and Regions in the World Economy (Ann

Arbor: University of Michigan Press).

CEPII (2005) Dataset, available at http://www.cepii.fr/anglaisgraph/bdd/bdd.htm.

Clarke, Kevin A. (2005) ‘The Phantom Menace: Omitted Variable Bias in Econometric

Research’, Conflict Management and Peace Science 22 (4): 341-52.

Darmofal, David (forthcoming) ‘Bayesian Spatial Survival Models for Political Event

Processes’, unpublished paper.

35

De Groot, Henri L.F., Linders, Gemt-Jan, Rietveld, Piet, and Subramanian, Umu (2004)

‘The Institutional Determinants of Bilateral Trade Patterns’, Kyklos, Vol. 57 (1): 103-

123.

Dür, Andreas (2007a) ‘EU Trade Policy as Protection for Exporters: The Agreements with

Mexico and Chile’, Journal of Common Market Studies 45 (4): 833-55.

Dür, Andreas (2007b) ‘Foreign Discrimination, Protection for Exporters and U.S. Trade

Liberalization’, International Studies Quarterly 51 (2): 457-80.

Dür, Andreas (2008) ‘Bargaining Power and Trade Liberalization: European External Trade

Policies in the 1960s’, European Journal of International Relations 14 (4): 645-69.

Egger, Peter and Mario Larch (2008) ‘Interdependent Preferential Trade Agreement

Memberships: An Empirical Analysis’, Journal of International Economics.

Elkins, Zachary, Andrew T. Guzman, and Beth A. Simmons (2006) ‘Competing for Capital:

The Diffusion of Bilateral Investment Treaties, 1960-2000’, International Organization

60 (4): 811-46.

Encyclopedia Britannica (2001) Encyclopedia Britannica Book of the Year (Chicago:

Encyclopaedia Britannica).

Fanis, Maria (2004) ‘Collective Action Theory Meets Prospect Theory: An Application to

Coalition Building in Chile, 1973-75’, Political Psychology 25 (3): 363-88.

Franzese, Robert J. and Jude C. Hays (2008) ‘Spatial Analysis’, in Janet M. Box-

Steffensmeier, Henry E. Brady and David Collier (eds.) Oxford Handbook of Political

Methodology (Oxford: Oxford University Press), 570-604.

Gilligan, Michael J. (1997) Empowering Exporters: Reciprocity, Delegation, and Collective Action in

American Trade Policy (Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press).

36

Gleditsch, Kristian S. and Ward, Michael D. (2000) “War and Peace in Space and Time: The

Role Of Democratization” International Studies Quarterly, Vol. 44(1): 1-29.

Gleditsch, Kristian S. (2002) ‘Expanded Trade and GDP Data, 1946-99’, Journal of Conflict

Resolution 46: 712-24.

Gowa, Joanne (1994) Allies, Adversaries, International Trade (Princeton: Princeton University

Press).

Gruber, Lloyd (2000) Ruling the World: Power Politics and the Rise of Supranational Institutions

(Princeton: Princeton University Press).

Henisz, Witold. J. (2000) ‘The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth’, Economics

and Politics 12 (1): 1-31.

Heniz, Witold J. (2006) ‘Political Constraint Index’, available at http://www-

management.wharton.upenn.edu/henisz/.

Holmes, Tammy (2005) ‘What Drives Regional Trade Agreements that Work?’, HEI Working

Paper No. 07.

Horn, Henrik and Petros C. Mavroidis (2006) ‘WTO Dispute Settlement Database’, available

at http://go.worldbank.org/X5EZPHXJY0.

Kahneman, Daniel and Amos Tversky (1979) ‘Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision

Under Risk’, Econometrica 47 (2): 263-91.

Kindleberger, Charles P. (1975) ‘The Rise of Free Trade in Western Europe’, Journal of

Economic History 35 (1): 20-55.

Lazer, David (1999) ‘The Free Trade Epidemic of the 1860s and Other Outbreaks of

Economic Discrimination’, World Politics 51 (4): 447-83.

Manger, Mark (2005) ‘Competition and Bilateralism in Trade Policy: The Case of Japan’s

Free Trade Agreements’, Review of International Political Economy 12 (5): 804-28.

37

Mansfield, Edward D. (1998) ‘The Proliferation of Preferential Trading Arrangements’,

Journal of Conflict Resolution 42 (5): 523-43.

Mansfield, Edward D. and Helen V. Milner (1999) ‘The New Wave of Regionalism’,

International Organization 53 (3): 589-627.

Mansfield, Edward D. and Eric Reinhardt (2003) ‘Multilateral Determinants of Regionalism:

The Effects of GATT/WTO on the Formation of Preferential Trading

Arrangements’, International Organization 57 (4): 829-62.

Mansfield, Edward D., Helen V. Milner, and B. Peter Rosendorff (2002) ‘Why Democracies

Cooperate More: Electoral Control and International Trade Agreements’, International

Organization 56 (3): 477-513.

Mattli, Walter (1999) The Logic of Regional Integration: Europe and Beyond (Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press).

Milner, Helen V. (1988) Resisting Protectionism: Global Industries and the Politics of International

Trade (Princeton: Princeton University Press).

Neumayer, Eric and Thomas Plümper (2008) ‘Spatial Effects in Dyadic Data’, unpublished

paper.

O’Brien, Denis (1976) ‘Customs Unions: Trade Creation and Trade Diversion in Historical

Perspective’, History of Political Economy 8 (4): 540-63.

Pahre, Robert (2008) Politics and Trade Cooperation in the Nineteenth Century: The “Agreeable

Customs” of 1815-1914 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

Polity IV (2007) ‘Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800-2007’, available at

http://www.systemicpeace.org/polity/polity4.htm.

Pomfret, Richard (2001) The Economics of Regional Trading Arrangements (Oxford: Oxford

University Press).

38

Richardson, Michael (1993) ‘Pacific Leaders Are Urged Push EC in GATT Talks’, The

International Herald Tribune, 2 November.

Rieder, Roland (2006) ‘Playing Dominoes in Europe: An Empirical Analysis of the Domino

Theory for the EU, 1962-2004’, HEI Working Paper No. 11/2006.

Ruggie, John Gerard (1982) ‘International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded

Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order’, International Organization 36 (2): 379-415.

Shackman, Liu, and Wang (2005) “Measuring Quality of Life Using Free or Public Domain

Data. Social Research Update.” Available at http://sru.soc.surrey.ac.uk/.

Skålnes, Lars (1998) ‘Grand Strategy and Foreign Economic Policy: British Grand Strategy in

the 1930s’, World Politics 50 (4): 582-616.

Viner, Jacob (1950) The Customs Union Issue (New York: Carnegie Endowment for

International Peace).

Waltz, Kenneth N. (1979) Theory of International Politics (New York: Random House).

World Trade Organization (2008) ‘Members and Observers’, available at

http://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/whatis_e/tif_e/org6_e.htm.

39

Table 1: Testing the Domino Argument Covariates Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 464

Estimation Cox Model (clusters on

dyads)

Cox Model (clusters on

dyads)

Cox Model (Gamma Frailty)

ReLogit (clusters on

dyads) Domino theory

TRADE & COMPETITION 0.24 ** (0.09)

0.24 ** (0.09)

0.23 ** (0.10)

0.36 ** (0.12)

Alternative diffusion SPATIAL LANGUAGE 0.12 **

(0.03) 0.10 ** (0.03)

0.25 ** (0.03)

0.18 ** (0.03)

SPATIAL COLONY 0.16 ** (0.04)

0.14 ** (0.03)

0.11 ** (0.03)

0.12 ** (0.04)

SPATIAL RELIGION -0.01 (0.03)

-0.05 (0.03)

-0.03 (0.03)

-0.06 * (0.02)

RIVALRY 0.07 (0.07)

0.12 (0.07)

0.13 (0.08)

0.19 (0.11)

Control variables TRADE 0.08 **

(0.03) 0.07 ** (0.03)

0.08 ** (0.03)

0.12 ** (0.04)

SIM 0.003 (0.13)

0.04 (0.02)

0.03 (0.03)

-0.03 (0.03)

GDP 0.31 ** (0.03)

0.34 ** (0.03)

0.48 ** (0.03)

0.58 ** (0.04)

GDP PER CAPITA 0.003 (0.01)

0.004 (0.01)

0.004 (0.01)

0.02 (0.01)

ALLIANCE 0.58 ** (0.06)

0.56 ** (0.07)

0.61 ** (0.08)

0.54 ** (0.09)

DEMOCRACY -0.12 ** (0.02)

-0.09 ** (0.02)

-0.12 ** (0.02)

-0.13 ** (0.02)

CONTIGUITY -0.73 ** (0.17)

-0.77 ** (0.16)

-0.23 (0.18)

-0.22 (0.23)

DISTANCE -1.16 ** (0.07)

-1.15 ** (0.07)

-2.24 ** (0.05)

-2.242 ** (0.06)

GDP GROWTH -0.01 (0.004)

-0.01 ** (0.004)

-0.01 (0.01)

EXPORT ORIENTATION 0.10 ** (0.03)

0.10 ** (0.04)

0.03 (0.04)

WTO 0.25 ** (0.07)

0.38 ** (0.08)

0.24 ** (0.09)

WTO ROUND

0.68 ** (0.10)

0.78 ** (0.10)

0.82 ** (0.09)

TRADE DISPUTE -1.63 ** (0.55)

-1.60 ** (0.58)

-1.72 ** (0.61)

TRADE DISPUTE THIRD

PARTY 0.05

(0.07) 0.01

(0.08) 0.11 (0.1)

LANGUAGE

-0.03 (0.15)

0.17 (0.13)

0.27 * (0.13)

RELIGION

0.27 ** (0.08)

0.33 ** (0.09)

0.58 ** (0.10)

COLONY

0.28 * (0.16)

0.20 * (0.11)

0.25 * (0.12)

ISLAND 0.23 ** (0.07)

0.32 ** (0.07)

0.57 ** (0.09)

Observations 225,833 225,833 225,833 225,833 Number of dyads signing a PTA 1,600 1,600 1,600 1,600

Log likelihood -13,510.19 -13,460.39 -13,119.20

Notes: standard errors are in parentheses. ** Significant at 1%, * significant at 5%.

64 The cubic natural spline functions are not reported. All spline functions are statistically significant at the 1 per cent level.

40

Table 2: Robustness Checks

Covariates Model 5 (excluding the EU)

Model 6 (excluding the EU and

EFTA)

Model 7 (excluding North-North

dyads)

Estimation Cox Model (clusters on dyads)

Cox Model (clusters on dyads)

Cox Model (clusters on dyads)

Domino effect TRADE & COMPETITION 0.31 **

(0.08) 0.28 ** (0.08)

0.24 ** (0.09)

Alternative diffusion LANGUAGE 0.20 **

(0.03) 0.20 ** (0.03)

0.13 ** (0.03)

COLONY 0.17 ** (0.05)

0.21 ** (0.05)

0.17 ** (0.04)

RELIGION -0.02 (0.03)

-0.003 (0.03)

-0.004 (0.03)

RIVALRY 0.18 * (0.08)

0.22 ** (0.08)

0.09 (0.07)

Dyadic controls TRADE 0.08 **

(0.03) 0.07 * (0.03)

0.08 ** (0.02)

SIM 0.01 (0.02)

0.03 (0.02)

0.01 (0.02)

GDP 0.30 ** (0.03)

0.28 ** (0.03)

0.34 ** (0.02)

GDP PER CAPITA 0.03 ** (0.01)

0.03 (0.01)

0.03 ** (0.01)

ALLIANCE 0.74 ** (0.08)

0.80 ** (0.09)

0.61 ** (0.07)

DEMOCRACY -0.02 (0.02)

-0.04 (0.02)

-0.11 ** (0.02)

CONTIGUITY -0.40 * (0.16)

-0.29 (0.17)

-0.72 ** (0.17)

DISTANCE -0.97 ** (0.08)

-1.02 ** (0.09)

-1.15 ** (0.07)

Observations 185,234 176,492 221,561 Number of dyads signing a PTA 1,159 1,053 1,535

Log likelihood -9,509.64 -8,539.71 -13,460.39

Notes: standard errors are in parentheses. **Significant at 1%, *significant at 5%.

41

Figure 1: The proliferation of preferential trade agreements, 1990-2007

42

Figures 2a and b: The spatial weights

43

Figures 3a, b. Cox model clusters on dyads: survival estimates for Trade and competition, comparing important versus irrelevant trade partner and close versus not close competitors.

0.60

0.70

0.80

0.90

1.00

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18Time Period

Export share = 0 Export share >= 20%

Kaplan-Meier survival estimates

0.60

0.70

0.80

0.90

1.00

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18Time Period

Not close competitor Close competitor

Kaplan-Meier survival estimates

Figures 4a, b. Cox model clusters on dyads: survival estimates for trade & competition and common colonial past.

.6.7

.8.9

1S

urv

iva

l

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18Time Period

Trade and competition = min Trade and competition = max

Survival Estimates

.6.7

.8.9

1S

urv

ival

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18Time Period

Common colonial past = min Common colonial past = max

Survival Estimates

Data Appendix

Variables Mean Std. deviation Minimum Maximum Data sources

Dependent variable Average survival rate 0.01 0.08 0 1 Domino effect DISTANCE AND COMPETITION

TRADE AND COMPETITION 0.63 0.03

0.90 0.20

0 0

7.99 6.74

(1) (1)

Competing Arguments SPATIAL LANGUAGE SPATIAL RELIGION SPATIAL COLONY

RIVALRY

0.91 1.58 1.68 0.16

1.32 1.51 1.57 0.41

0 0 0 0

9.36 9.91 9.36

4

(2) (3) (2) (4)

Controls SIM GDP RLF

GDP PER CAPITA GDP GROWTH

TRADE TRADE DEPENDENCE EXPORT ORIENTATION

ALLIANCE DEMOCRACY DISTANCE CONTIGUITY

WTO TRADE DISPUTE

DISPUTE WITH THIRD PARTY WTO ROUND LANGUAGE RELIGION COLONY ISLAND

3.70 1.77 9.14 1.71 0.33 8.84

0.0003 5.99 0.13 4.73 8.69 0.02 0.51 0.005 0.28 0.65 0.08 0.15 0.15 0.28

2.07 1.25 11.46 3.46 6.63 1.32 0.04 1.50 0.34 2.01 0.75 0.14 0.50 0.07 0.45 0.48 0.27 0.37 0.36 0.45

0 0.10

0 0

-52.6 3.37

0 1.55

0 1

2.35 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0

9.49 8.57 89.82 62.91 35.2 13.68 0.59 12.93

1 7

9.90 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1

(1) (1) (1) (1) (1) (1) (1) (1) (4) (5) (2) (2) (6) (7) (6) (8) (3) (2) (2) (2)

Sources: (1) IMF; (2) CEPII (2005) (3) Encyclopedia Britannica Book of the Year 2001; (4) Correlates of War dataset; (5) Freedom House (2007); (6) World Trade Organization (2008); (7) Horn and Mavroidis (2006); (8) Compiled by the authors.