84
The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage Andrew Joliet University of Rochester Page 1

The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

My senior thesis "The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage". Of course it has its rough parts, but the surveys are very nice I think.

Citation preview

Page 1: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

The Myth of ManipulationThe Economics of Minimum Wage

Andrew JolietUniversity of Rochester

Page 1

Page 2: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

ABSTRACT

Myth of ManipulationThe Economics of Minimum Wage

Traditional research on minimum wage has largely focused on its possible employment effects. The negative impact of minimum wages appeared to be empirically and theoretically obvious through most of the 20th century. In 1992 that economist David Card shifted the focus of labor market analysis from competitive to monopsonistic settings. If wages are set monopsonistically it is theoretically possible for mandated wage increases to increase employment. My paper will examine the verity of this possibility as well as provide an exhaustive review of the impact of minimum wages on other outcomes including on-the-job training, school enrollment, prices, and poverty.

I. INTRODUCTIONMinimum wage legislation is a highly controversial topic that is and has been debated in

the public, political, and economics communities throughout the 20th and 21 centuries. The questions of minimum wage and its impact are really questions about labor markets and what we actually know about labor markets and how they operate. The main focus of this paper will be on what theory says labor markets look like, whether or not labor markets actually look like this, and what these labor market theories mean for minimum wage legislation.

I will first discuss the two general theories explaining labor markets. An in-depth overview of competitive labor markets will be given. There will be a focus on the impact of minimum wage in this type of market. Special attention will be paid to employment effects, unemployment effects, on-the-job training, schooling, and prices. The specific effects will be discussed through theory and survey research. We will look at the results of over 150 empirical research papers from 1957 to 2011.

Monopsony theory will also be discussed. There will be a specific focus on the theory and whether or not labor markets look like this. As the reader will discover later in this paper, monopsony theory is used as a justification of minimum wage legislation on the basis that such legislation can increase employment. The relationship between monopsonistic labor markets and minimum wage will be analyzed with a focus on employment. There will be a special focus on labor demand elasticity, size of labor demand, size of labor supply, and the implications of these factors on minimum wage legislation. Once again, these topics will be discussed with an overview of the results of over 150 research papers. In addition, data from the Current Population Survey will be used to take a deeper look at labor markets.

After the differing theories have been discussed, will find that we do not know exactly what labor markets look like. Despite this lack of definitiveness, we will still be able to draw some conclusions about minimum wage legislation. We will come to these conclusions partly by taking a look at what the minimum wage labor force looks like. We will discover that the minimum wage labor force is very small and that even though we don’t have a definitive conclusion on what labor markets look like, minimum wages impact whether positive or negative is likely small and insignificant.

Page 2

Page 3: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Many people believe that markets can simply be manipulated to produce beneficial outcomes, especially if markets are shown to have frictions. I hope that those who read this paper are able to see that even if there are labor market frictions; minimum wage legislation must be structured in a particular fashion to produce optimal outcomes and even then the legislation still has serious implications on the cost structures that firms face. Moreover, I hope readers will see that prices are extremely important in that they send signals to firms and laborers and that a binding minimum wage has serious implications on these signals. History

Minimum wage legislation in the United States dates back to 1912 with Massachusetts organizing a commission to establish wage regulation for women and children. Over the next eight years thirteen other states passed similar legislation, usually with a legal emphasis on women and children. Very quickly these state level minimum wage laws began to be challenged in the courts. The first case dealing with minimum wage ruled on by the Supreme Court was Adkins v. Children's Hospital in 1923. The Court ruled 5-3 that a minimum wage was unconstitutional on the grounds that it violated the Due Process Clause of the Fifth Amendment(PBS).1

In 1933 the Federal Government enacted a $0.40 minimum wage law through the National Industrial Recovery Act(Taylor & Klein 2008). Two years later in May of 1935 the Supreme Court famously ruled that the National Industrial Recovery Act was unconstitutional in Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States. Justice Cardozo’s opinion was “We are of the opinion that the attempt through the provisions of the code to fix the hours and wages of employees of defendants in their intrastate business was not a valid exercise of federal power.”(A.L.A. 1935). It was not long however, until the decision in Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States was reversed with respect to the minimum wage.

In 1937, the 1935 ruling was reversed in West Coast Hotel Co. v. Parrish when a chambermaid sued her employer for paying her less than the minimum wage that the state of Washington had established. The case ultimately went to the Supreme Court which ruled in favor of the defendant, resulting in the overruling of the Court’s decision in 1935. The Court felt that minimum wages can be established to protect the health and well-being of workers. Justice Charles Hughes delivered the opinion of the Court which stated “The legislature was entitled to adopt measures to reduce the evils of the "sweating system," the exploiting of workers at wages so low as to be insufficient to meet the bare cost of living, thus making their very helplessness the occasion of a most injurious competition.”(West 1936).

The overruling of Schechter Poultry Corp. v. United States opened way for the Fair Labor Standards Act(FLSA) to be passed in June of 1938. The FLSA established a Federal minimum wage of $.25 per hour, $3.86 in 2010 dollars(Grossman). FLSA allowed states to set minimums above Federal levels. FLSA has been amended ten times2, since its inception, in order to increase the Federal minimum wage.3 Between the enactment of FLSA in 1938 and

1 Violated the Due Process Clause on the grounds that people have the right to "to obtain from each other the best

terms they can as the result of private bargaining."2 The bill has been ten times to increase the minimum wage; other amendments to FLSA have been passed that do

not deal with wages.3 The Fair Labor Standards Act, 29 U.S.C. § 201

Page 3

Page 4: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

2011 the Federal minimum wage has risen from $3.86 in 2010 dollars to $7.25 in 2010. The real minimum wage peaked in 1968 at $10.03, 2010 dollars. The history of the nominal and real increases in the Federal minimum wage is shown in Graph 1.

Graph 1 illustrates the effect of inflation on the value of the minimum wage. This effect results in the famous saw-tooth chart. The real minimum wage level increases with minimum wage increases and decreases as inflation erodes the value of the minimum wage.

GRAPH 1.

How Many Minimum Wage Workers are There?In 2006 Ted Kennedy said this in reference to minimum wage workers, “...there are

millions of mothers and fathers for whom that’s the reality”(Ted, 2006). The fact of the matter is minimum wage workers make up a very small portion of the total labor force. Moreover, since the 1970’s the number of minimum wage workers as a part of the total labor force has been cut by over 50%, see Graph 2.

The amount of minimum wage workers in 1979 was 6,912,000. This made up 6.6% of the total labor force. By 2010 there were only 4,361,000 workers making at or below the Federal minimum wage. These workers made up only 2.8% of the total work force. These numbers are significantly smaller than the proponents and even the opponents of minimum wage lead people to believe. These figures are important for both opponents and proponents of minimum wage legislation to keep in mind because whether the policy produces positive or negative effects the scale of the total impact will be small because of so few people being affected.

Page 4

Page 5: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

GRAPH 2.

AgeThe Bureau of Labor Statistics publishes figures on the age of minimum wage workers

from the annual Current Population Survey. According to CPS, a large portion of minimum wage workers, as of 2010, are under 25 years old, 49% of the minimum wage labor force. 16-19 year olds made up 22.8% of the minimum wage labor force and 20-24 year olds made up 26.2% of the minimum wage labor force. Once one reaches the age of 25, ones likelyhood of being a minimum wage worker drops precipitously. The 25-29 year olds made up only 19.4% of the minimum wage labor force. Graph 3 shows how the older the demographic, the lower the amount of minimum wage workers. So, if minimum wage has negative or positive effects it is likely going to primarily effect 16 to 24 year olds. This is important to keep in mind when considering who a minimum wage is aimed at helping, which will be discussed throughout this paper.

It is constructive to keep in mind what these numbers mean in absolute terms. Graph 4 shows what part of the total labor force the different aged minimum wage workers makeup. The 16 to 24 year olds made up a mere 1.4% of the total labor force4. The 16-19 year olds made up 0.6% of the total labor force, the 20-24 year olds made up 0.7% of the total labor force, and the 25-29 year olds made up a low 0.3% of the total labor force. Once again, minimum wage workers make up a very small proportion of the total labor force, i.e. there are few minimum wage workers.

4 These are total minimum wage workers in the 16-24 year old demographic divided by total labor force.

Page 5

Page 6: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

GRAPH 3.

GRAPH 4.

EducationAnother useful statistic when studying the minimum wage is the educational attainment

of minimum wage workers. We see that in 2010 58% of minimum wage workers had a high school diploma, but no college degree, 29% had an associate degree or higher and 13% had less than a high school diploma. These statistics will be useful when we look at the training and schooling effects of minimum wage. Additionally, these are important figures when considering the demographics that minimum wage effects. They show that minimum wage primarily affects people with high school diplomas and college degrees. Popular opinion appears lean towards the idea that most minimum wage workers are high school dropouts.

Page 6

Page 7: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

GRAPH 5.

OccupationIn addition to age, CPS also contains data on the industries that minimum wages effect.

These statistics will be important for when we look at labor demand and supply elasticities later on. CPS statistics show us that a very large percent of minimum wage workers work in “Food preparation and serving related occupations”. These workers make up 38.8% of the total minimum wage labor force. The second largest industry with minimum wage workers is “Sales and related occupations”. This industry has about 16.8% of minimum wage workers. “Personal care and service occupations”, “Office and administrative support occupations”, “Transportation and material moving occupations”, and “Building and grounds cleaning and maintenance occupations” have between 6-7 percent of minimum wage workers respectively. These results can be seen in Appendix 1, Graph 1A.

These statistics show us that most minimum wage workers are in service industries. Despite most minimum wage workers being concentrated in service industries, there are also non-service, production, industries which pay minimum wage and are effected by minimum wage legislation. Again this will be discussed in more detail when we discuss labor demand and supply elasticities.Location

The last statistic that we will look at is location of minimum wage workers. Location is another statistic that will come into our analysis when we discuss the conditions that minimum wage legislation must meet in a monopsonistic market. CPS finds that there are large differences in state level minimum wage participation. When comparing the state with the highest portion of minimum wage worker's as a part of its labor force, Mississippi with 9.5%, with the state with the smallest portion, Washington with 1.1%, there is an 8.4% difference between minimum wage work forces. These differences are illustrated in Graph 2A in Appendix 1. The idea here is that minimum wages affect different areas more or less. This statistic will be shown to be important when crafting minimum wage legislation in a later section.

Page 7

Page 8: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

II. COMPETITIVE MARKET THEORY AND THE MINIMUM WAGE

What is a labor market? A labor market is a market in which there are buyers and sellers of labor. In this market we observe the buying and selling behaviors of firms and laborers. Just like in a goods market where there are infinite types of goods that can be demanded and supplied at different prices and quantities, in a labor market there are infinite types of labor that can be demanded and supplied at different wages and employment levels. The demand and supply of labor are represented by the labor demand and labor supply curves.Aggregate Labor Demand

Aggregate labor demand is how much firms as a whole, the market, are willing to pay for particular quantities of labor. In a competitive labor market, firms determine how much labor to hire by finding the points of profit maximization when they face different costs. This is illustrated in Charts 1A and 1B.

In Chart 1A we see three curves. We see a total cost curve with low wages, a total cost curve with high wages, and a total product curve. The total product curve is based off of how much output firms can produce with particular quantities of inputs. The total product curve tends to be increasing at a decreasing rate. The reason for this is that the total product curve is based how productive capital and labor are and capital and labor tend to have diminishing returns.

The other curves in Chart 1A are the total cost curves. These curves consist of fixed and variable costs, variable costs being rent and wages. What we see is that total cost curves are increasing at an increasing rate. We can understand this by looking at a bakery. Let’s say that a bakery wants to expand its operations. In order to do so they must buy more ovens, more shop space, more insurance, etc. So what we see is that the more our bakery produces the more costs it is going to have to pay in order to increase production. This results in an upward sloping total cost curve as seen in Chart 1A.

The total cost curve changes when variable or fixed costs change, this includes changes in wages. This can be seen when comparing the total cost curve with low wages versus the total cost curve with high wages. As you can see when wages increase there is an upward shift in the total cost curve.We can use the total cost and product curves to determine the marginal cost and marginal product curves. The marginal cost and marginal product curves look at what it costs to produce an additional unit or how much more products will be produced with additional labor input.

The importance of the total cost and product curves and marginal cost and product curves is that these curves give firms points of profit maximization in reference to specific cost structures. The easiest way to find the point of profit maximization is by using the marginal product and marginal cost curves. This is illustrated through Chart 2B. We see that when wages increase QL-QH less labor is wanted.

We can use these curves to find the aggregate labor demand curve. We can do this by showing how these curves respond to increases and decreases in wages. We saw earlier that increases in wages resulted in an upward shift in total costs. When the total cost curve shifts upwards, as seen in Chart 1A, the marginal cost curve also shifts upwards, as seen in Chart 1B. This results in different points of profit maximization. Specifically, when total costs and marginal

Page 8

Page 9: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

costs increase, firms hire less, as seen by the shift from QL to QH. Firms hire less labor when its relative cost increases. What this means is that when wages increase, increasing total costsand marginal costs, firms demand less labor, i.e. a downward sloping labor demand curve.

CHART 1.

Aggregate Labor SupplyAggregate labor supply is how much labor, laborers are willing to provide at different

wages. The labor supply curve is really determined by an evaluation of opportunity cost. Laborers deciding whether or not to work have two basic choices: consumption or leisure. If a laborer decides to work, he will have more money, i.e. a greater ability to consume, but he will also have less leisure time. This trade off can be seen in Chart 2A.

We can determine the aggregate labor supply curve by looking at how labors respond to increases and decreases in wages. In Chart 2A laborer can either spend 24 hours a day in leisure or work 24 hours a day at $10 an hour. He cannot spend more than 24 hours in leisure or working because a day is only 24 hours long. Additionally, he cannot make more than $240 hours a day because of the time constraint and wage constraint. In this situation, our laborer will choose x* hours of leisure and y* consumption. Now if we increase the wage to $20 an hour our curve pivots. Our laborer can now either work 24 hours for $480 or spend 24 hours in leisure. It is most likely that our laborer will work more, y’ compared to y*, and spend less time

Page 9

Page 10: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

in leisure, x’ compared to x*, because the opportunity cost of not working is significantly higher. His choice is seen by the differences in his indifference curves in these two situations.

CHART 2.

We can use the above discussion to formulate a labor supply curve. The more and more the curve pivots upwards, a wage increase, the more work the laborer will provide. This trend is seen in our aggregate labor supply curve by it being upward sloping.Market Equilibrium

Once we have calculated the aggregate labor demand and aggregate labor supply curves, we can find the market equilibrium. This is the point at which the two curves intersect, where marginal cost equals marginal product. It tells us how much labor is demanded for an entire labor market, i.e. total amount of labor that is demanded by an aggregate of firms. This is illustrated in Chart 3A(Market). In a competitive labor market, market equilibrium is important because it tells at what wage all individual firms will pay their workers. Firm Equilibrium

According to competitive markets theory, market equilibrium establishes a flat marginal cost curve for all firms. This means that an individual firm can hire as much labor as it wants at the market equilibrium wage. This can be seen graphically in Chart 3A, where the aggregate quantity of labor supplied is Q* and the market equilibrium wage is P*. The firm level chart tells us what the individual firm’s labor demand curve is. An individual firm will purchase the amount of labor at which their labor demand curve5 intersect the market equilibrium wage. This is point Q’. According to competitive markets theory, an individual firm can hire as much labor as it wants at the market equilibrium wage. This idea of a flat marginal cost curve is very important in our discussion of minimum wage legislation. It is the main difference between a competitive labor market model and a monopsonistic labor market model. We will discuss this difference in more depth in the following section.Assumptions for a Competitive Labor Market

In order for the above discussion to hold together labor markets must be competitive. In order for a labor market to be competitive five assumptions must be upheld. The assumptions

5 The labor demand curve is different from firm to firm.

Page 10

Page 11: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

say all agents have perfect information, all agents are identical, all units of output are identical, there are a large number of firms, and all firms are price takers.

CHART 3.

Now, none of these assumption hold perfectly in labor markets, i.e. labor markets are not perfectly competitive. Though these assumptions are not perfectly upheld, they can still be used to judge how competitive labor markets are. For example, we do not see perfect information in labor markets. Information may be costly and difficult to attain. If one is interested in determining whether or not a labor market is competitive or not one must test how close markets are to perfect information. All that is required for markets to be competitive is for markets to be close to these assumptions. So, just because markets are not perfectly competitive, the five assumptions are not perfectly upheld, does not mean markets are not competitive.Minimum Wage in a Competitive Labor Market

Minimum wage is by definition a price floor, meaning that the objective of minimum wage legislation is to prevent wages from being under a particular level. A minimum wage set at $5 prevents the price of labor from going under $5. In order for a price floor to have an impact it must be set above market equilibrium wage. A minimum wage set above market equilibrium wage is called a “binding minimum wage”. If the minimum wage is not binding firms and laborers will continue providing and purchasing the same amount of labor at the same wage. This point is illustrated in Chart 4A. M” is the minimum wage; firms cannot pay laborers less than M”. Since M” below the market equilibrium wage, therefore not a binding minimum wage, the situation in Chart 4A will not result in any changes. The main reason for this is that firms are profit maximizing and a minimum wage of M” does not change their cost structure; therefore it does not change their points of profit maximization.

An “effective” minimum wage, a binding minimum wage, would be set above the market equilibrium wage. In essence, the proponents of minimum wage legislation do not think that market equilibrium wages are high enough, so they would set the minimum wage above the

Page 11

Page 12: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

market equilibrium wage. Under a competitive market model, this would result in decreases in employment and increase in unemployment6.

Chart 4B illustrates the effect of a binding minimum wage. In Chart 4B, firms want to pay market equilibrium wages because this is the point at which profits are maximized, but the minimum wage, M+, prevents this. Firms can no longer pay wages less than M+. Since the cost structure facing the firm has now changed, firms now have a different point of profit maximization. As discussed earlier when the cost structure becomes more expensive, total costs increase, and firms hire less. As a result, total employment decreases by at least Q*-Q+78.

CHART 4.

6 Why say employment decreases and unemployment increases. A minimum wage will cause firms to hire less labor in a competitive market decreasing employment and increasing unemployment, but a minimum wage also sends a price signal to workers who were not considered part of the labor force to join the labor force(laborers who had stopped looking for work). These new laborers enter the labor force and do not have jobs to take because the price signal they responded to was artificial. This results in an increase in unemployment while not decreasing employment.7 The firm we are looking at would hire Q++-Q’ less labor.8 This might not be entirely true, if firms are able to decrease on-the-job training, increase product prices, or change another part of their cost or revenue structure. This idea will be discussed in later sections on prices and training.

Page 12

Page 13: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

It is possible that unemployment increases by more than Q*-Q+. Prices send signals to market participants. Higher prices tell producers to produce more. When the minimum wage is increased it sends a signal to people to supply more labor. The labor force is calculated by adding together the total number of employed persons and the total number of unemployed persons, but there is an additional group that is in this calculation. This group is made up of people who are unemployed and who have stopped looking for employment. It is possible that a minimum wage will send a signal to these workers to start looking for employment again, but since the minimum wage is not a natural market signal there will not be jobs for these individuals. The individuals that start searching for employment again are called “added workers”. The result of this is that we see increases from unemployment by both decrease in employment and increases in added workers.

Are Labor Markets Competitive?Labor markets are undoubtedly not perfectly competitive. The important idea here is not

necessarily whether or not markets are perfectly competitive, but rather how close they are to perfectly competitive. Though the world is filled with labor market frictions, sometimes these frictions are very small. The identical agents assumption for example, says that laborers are the same, i.e. have homogeneous preferences. The reality is that workers are not identical and do have heterogeneous preferences. To determine whether or not markets are competitive we would have to evaluate how different workers preferences are.

One friction that has been greatly diminished is lack of perfect information. The perfect information assumption is impossible. There is no way that laborers can know of every job available and the details of those jobs. Information is costly and difficult to attain. But because of technological developments this information friction has been greatly diminished. In the Internet age, information about job opportunities is available instantly and at an affordable price, if not for free. Additionally, technology has also made the friction of mobility less intense. People can now travel all over the world at the lowest prices in history and at the fastest speeds. So, despite labor markets not being perfectly competitive, this does not mean that labor markets are not competitive. Moreover, if labor markets are close to enough to the competitive assumptions, labor market models would look similar to the perfectly competitive model.

III. MINIMUM WAGE AND EMPLOYMENT UNDER MONOPSONY MODELWhat is monopsony theory? Competitive labor market theory tells us that if a market

looks similar to the assumptions of the model, individual firms will face perfectly elastic marginal cost curves. Monopsony theory purports to show us what cost structures firms face when markets are not competitive. The specific difference between a monopsonistic labor market and a competitive labor market is that in a monopsonistic labor market firms face upward sloping marginal cost curves as compared to a flat marginal cost curve in competitive labor markets. Upward Sloping Versus Perfectly Elastic Marginal Cost Curves

In a competitive market we saw that individual firms faced a perfectly elastic marginal cost curve that was established by the equilibrium of aggregate labor supply and aggregate labor demand. What this meant was that an individual firm could hire as much labor as it wanted at the market equilibrium wage. In a monopsonistic market, firms no longer face

Page 13

Page 14: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

perfectly elastic marginal cost curves. Instead the marginal cost curve that firms face is upward sloping.

The meaning of an upward sloping marginal cost curve is that if a firm wants to hire an additional laborer, it must raise the equilibrium wage. In essence, firms must increase wages to incentivize more laborers to work for them. Additionally, firms not only have to raise the wage for the new laborer, but they must also pay all of their identical current workers this new wage, i.e. a new market equilibrium wage is established.

We can illustrate this point further with an example. Suppose a firm is paying an identical set of workers $5 an hour and then the firm decides that they want to hire an additional laborer. In order to attract this new laborer, the firm must pay him $5.25. If the firm decides to hire this new laborer, the firm must not only pay this new laborer $5.25, but the firm must increase the wages of all of its other workers to $5.25. The validity of this idea will be discussed in more depth in a later section when we discuss wage discrimination.Why Do We See Differences in The Marginal Cost Curve?

Perhaps the most prominent economist who deals with monopsony theory is Alan Manning. Manning discusses the topic in-depth in his book “Monopsony in Motion” and a joint paper “Oligopsony and monopsonistic competition in labor markets”. Manning talks about the appearance of monopsony as a result of labor market frictions.

Labor market frictions are basically the antithesis of the assumptions put forth by the competitive markets theory. The presence of frictions means that the competitive markets assumptions do not hold. Laborers may not be indifferent between where they work. For example, let’s say that laborer A is deciding whether or not to take a nearly identical position at either McDonalds or Burger King. The only difference between these two choices is that this laborers father worked for Burger King when he was younger. We will assume this family history makes working at Burger King more attractive than working at McDonald's. The implication of this family history is that laborer A is more willing to work at Burger King than McDonald's. So, in order for McDonald's to entice laborer A to work at McDonald's, they must pay worker A more. This violates the assumption that firms can hire as much labor as they want at the market equilibrium wage and creates a situation where firms must pay higher wages to attract more laborers, an upward sloping marginal cost curve.

Obviously not all laborers are identical. Again this does not necessarily mean that a labor market is not competitive. In order for this to mean that a labor market is not competitive, there would have to be serious violations of the assumptions describing competitive markets.Monopsony and Employment

The importance of monopsony is that it has serious implications on firms hiring decisions. If firms are profit maximizing, they will always hire the amount of labor at where marginal cost equals marginal product. The marginal costs that firms face in a monopsony market have changed. The result of this change is that firms hire a different quantity of labor because the point of profit maximization has changed. Specifically, when a monopsony is present firms hire less labor because firms are facing higher marginal costs.

Chart 5A shows what a firm looks like in the presence of a monopsony. We see that instead of facing a perfectly elastic marginal cost curve, as seen in the competitive market model, the firm is facing an upward sloping marginal cost curve. This cost structure means that firms must increase wages to attract more workers. Again, the assumption is that if a firm hires

Page 14

Page 15: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

a new laborer at a higher wage, the firm must also increase the wages of all of its identical workers to the new laborers wage. In essence, when firms face upward sloping marginal cost curves it is more expensive to hire additional labor. This is unlike competitive labor markets because firms in a competitive market can hire ‘as much’ labor as they want at one wage. This difference is why will see less employment in a monopsonistic labor market, Chart 5A we see Q’ employment instead of Q* employment.Minimum Wage in a Monosponistic Labor Market

If monopsony theory holds, then a minimum wage could theoretically be used to increase employment. The idea here is that a minimum wage will institute a new cost structure. So instead of firms facing an upward sloping marginal cost curve, a minimum wage will result in a new flat, perfectly elastic marginal cost curve. Since firms are profit maximizing, firms will respond by hiring the amount of labor were the new marginal cost curve, the minimum wage, intersects the marginal product curve, i.e. the labor demand curve.

This concept is illustrated in both Charts 5B and Chart 5C. Minimum wages of M” and M^ are set, both of which are binding. These new marginal cost curves intersect the marginal product curve at (Q”, M”) and (Q^, M^) respectively. The result of this new cost structure is that firms employ different quantities of labor than they otherwise would. In fact, the more profitable decisions with these minimum wages would be to employ Q’-Q” and Q’-Q^ more labor, only because they must pay at least the minimum wage. In effect the minimum wage increases wages and employment in a monopsonistic labor market.

Now there are limits to positive effect. One limit is how high a minimum wage can be set and still result in employment increases. Chart 5D illustrates this limit. We will discuss this limit in more detail when we discuss the Joliet Corridor in the next section. Are Labor Markets Monopsonistic?

One way to test whether or not labor markets are monopsonistic is to get an estimate of the “wage elasticity of the labor supply curve facing the firm”(Manning 2003). While estimates have been made of the wage elasticity of labor supply that firms face, these estimates are not robust enough for us to form any definite conclusions(Manning 2003). Despite the lack of empirical evidence it is very likely that labor market frictions do create situations and/or markets where individual firms must raise wages in-order to attract more labor. These are the same frictions that were in our discussion of perfectly competitive markets.

Page 15

Page 16: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

CHART 5.

IV. Monopsony Model Problems and ConsiderationsIn the previous section we saw that in the presence of a monopsonistic labor market a

minimum wage could have positive employment effects while increasing wages. While monopsony theory does show that minimum wage legislation can have positive employment effects, the legislation must meet certain criteria. In this section we will discuss what criteria minimum wage legislation must meet in order to have optimal positive effects on employment. We will pay particular attention to the effects of differing labor demand elasticity and what this means for minimum wage legislation. State and local level variances in market characteristics and the implications on optimal minimum wages will also be discussed. Lastly, we will discuss whether or not FLSA actually fits the optimal minimum wage profile. Labor Demand Elasticity, the Joliet Corridor, and the Employment Window

Monopsony theory does indeed tell us that a minimum wage can increase employment and wages, but there is a specific range at which a minimum wage can have positive employment effects. This range will vary depending on the elasticities of labor supply and demand. Elasticity can be captured by the slope of the labor supply curve, percent change in

Page 16

Page 17: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

hours worked divided by percent change in wages, and the labor demand curve, percent change in employment divided by the percent change in wages.

Let’s first look at labor demand elasticity. Chart 6A is going to be our referencing monopsonistic labor market. In Chart 6A, labor demand is unit elastic where Q” labor will be supplied at P” wage. In Chart 6A there is a definite window in which a minimum wage can have a positive employment effects. I call this window the “Joliet Corridor”. The Joliet Corridor is the wages between the point at which the marginal cost curve intersects the labor demand curve, P””, and the monopsony wage, P”. A minimum wage set anywhere between P”” and P”, the Joliet Corridor, will have a positive employment effect. In sum, a minimum wage must be set in the Joliet Corridor to have positive employment effects. The size of the Joliet Corridor varies depending on the elasticity of labor supply and demand. Chart 6A, 6B, and 6C demonstrate the effect of changes in labor demand elasticity, but before were look at these charts let’s look at what influences labor demand elasticities.

Elasticity was first discussed by economist Alfred Marshall in his Principles of Economics in 1890. John Hicks extended Marshall’s insights in 1932(Hicks 1966). Their work forms the Hicks-Marshall Laws of Derived Demand and consists of four factors. The first law says that when the elasticity of product demand is high then the elasticity of labor demand is high. In other words if consumers are not willing to absorb higher product costs, then producers are less able to absorb higher production costs, like wages, so they are more sensitive to wage changes. Secondly, if labor substitutes are readily available, then labor demand elasticity will be greater. Essentially, if firms are able to replace labor with capital equipment easily then changes in wages will have larger impacts on employment. Third, if other factors of production are highly elastic then labor demand will be highly elastic. In other words, if a firm can increase the usage of other factors of production without it having a significant impact on costs of those inputs, the usage of labor will be much more sensitive to changes in wages. Lastly, if labor represents a large proportion of a firm’s total costs, labor demand elasticity will be higher. This means that if a firm is highly reliant on labor, an increase in labor costs will greatly increase total costs. This increase in total costs will either result in higher prices, which consumers may not be able to absorb, or a decrease in profits which the firm may not be able to absorb(Borjas 2008). An understanding of these four factors is needed to understand Chart@.

Now that we know what causes changes in labor demand elasticity, let’s see what this means for the Joliet Corridor. Chart 6B demonstrates what happens to the Joliet Corridor when the elasticity of labor demand increases. Essentially, the Joliet Corridor shrinks to between P+

and P++. So, when elasticity increases the Joliet Corridor decreases. Chart 6C on the other hand demonstrates what happens when the demand for labor is relatively inelastic. In Chart 6C you see that the Joliet Corridor increases to P^^ to P^. So, when the demand for labor is inelastic, the Joliet Corridor is greater. Essentially what these three graphs show us is that as labor demand elasticity increases the Joliet Corridor shrinks and as labor demand elasticity decreases the Joliet Corridor expands. This means that the more inelastic labor demand is the more room legislators have for making a mistake in setting the minimum wage. One is less likely to set a minimum wage outside of the Joliet Corridor if the Corridor spans from $4 to $10 than if it spans from $4-$5.

The idea that the Joliet Corridor is larger when labor demand is more inelastic makes sense if we remember back to the Hicks-Marshall Laws of Derived Demand. For example, labor

Page 17

Page 18: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

demand is more inelastic when substitutes are not available, meaning labor is fairly valuable to firms because as an input it cannot be easily replaced. If labor is relatively more valuable to a firm, it is likely that they would be more ‘willing’ to put up with a minimum wage. Compare this to a firm that has relatively elastic labor demand. This firm is very sensitive to wage changes, possibly because it can replace labor with capital. Firms like this are likely not as flexible when it comes to minimum wages because they can more easily change their business structure away from labor. Charts 6A, 6B, and 6C show that optimal minimum wage legislation needs to take into consideration differences in labor demand elasticities because while a minimum wage set within the Joliet Corridor in Chart 6C would have positive employment effects, that same minimum would likely have negative effects in Chart 6B.

Another interesting observation that we can see is that changes in labor demand elasticity change the total possible employment impact of a minimum wage, meaning changes in labor demand elasticity change how large the positive employment effect a minimum wage can be. This implication is labeled as “EW” in Charts 6A, 6B, and 6C. I call this span the Employment Window. The Employment Window is defined as the largest possible positive employment effects a minimum wage can have. We see the largest Employment Window when labor demand is unit elastic, Chart 6A. We also see that as labor demand becomes less elastic, Chart 6C, and becomes more elastic, Chart 6B, in reference to Chart 6A, the Employment Window shrinks. So, the further away from unit elasticity9 the demand curve goes the smaller the Employment Window will become.

The Employment Window is an important factor to keep in mind when thinking about the implications of minimum wage legislation. We saw that as labor demand becomes more inelastic the Joliet Corridor increase, more opportunities to increase employment through minimum wage legislation. Interestingly, while the Joliet Corridor is larger, the Employment window is relatively smaller. So while the probability of setting a minimum wage that will increase employment is relatively high, the total possible employment effects are relatively low. Additionally, if labor demand is relatively elastic both Joliet Corridor and the Employment Window will be relatively small, meaning when labor demand is relatively elastic the probability of setting an optimal minimum wage is low and the total possible positive employment effects are low. The idea that we can take away from this is that if labor demand is relatively elastic, there is a high probability that minimum wage legislation will produce negative employment effects because both the Joliet Corridor and Employment Window are relatively small.

9 Unit elasticity is a curve with a slope of 1 or -1.

Page 18

Page 19: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

CHART 6.

Labor Supply ElasticityAs discussed earlier the main condition for minimum wage legislation to be effective in a

labor market is that firms face an upward sloping marginal cost curve. The slope of the marginal cost curve depends on the degree of elasticity of the labor supply curve. Charts 7 and 8 illustrate the impact of differing elasticities on the Joliet Corridor and the Employment Window. In Chart 7 we see a labor market with relatively elastic labor supply.10 This results in a Joliet Corridor of about $20, “JC” and an Employment Window a little over one. So in this market a minimum wage set between about $23 and $43 can employment up to a little over 1. In Chart 8 we see a labor market with a relatively inelastic labor supply curve resulting in a steeper marginal cost curve. The span of the Joliet Corridor in this labor market is about $31 and an Employment Window a little under one. In this labor market wages set between about $47 and $78 can produce a little under one in positive employment effects.

So, what we see is that as the labor supply curve becomes more inelastic the Joliet Corridor increases in size, but the Employment Window decreases in size. In other words, the more inelastic labor supply is the greater the possibility for setting a minimum wage with positive employment effects, but the total employment effects will be relatively small. Additionally, the

10 The prices in this example are completely arbitrary and are meant for descriptive purposes only.

Page 19

Page 20: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

more elastic labor supply is the smaller the Joliet Corridor and the larger the Employment Window. So while you may be able to produce relatively large positive employment effects when labor supply is relatively elastic, the minimum wages that could produce that effect are relatively small in size and in scope.

CHART 7.

CHART 8.

Since the elasticity of labor supply does have an impact on the Joliet Corridor and the Employment Window, it must be taken into consideration when setting a minimum wage. If legislation does not take this factor into consideration optimal outcomes will not be seen across all labor markets. One factor that effect labor supply elasticity is marginal tax rate. People in areas that can keep larger proportions of their earnings are more likely to respond to wage changes. Specifically, localities with higher marginal tax rates are likely to see more inelastic labor supply curves versus localities with lower marginal tax rates.11 So, since tax rates vary from state to state Federal legislation may want to take this into account when setting an overarching Federal minimum wage.

11 When comparing how much Americans age 15 to 64 versus French aged 15 to 64, Americans were found to work

50% more, “marginal tax rates explain virtually all of this difference”(Prescott).

Page 20

Page 21: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Industry & Firm ConsiderationsWe have seen that both labor demand and labor supply elasticities matter when

considering the structure of minimum wage legislation. In order to promote optimal employment outcomes these factors need to be incorporated into the law. Labor demand can be incorporated by setting minimum wages by industry and firm.

What the labor demand curve really tells us is what the cost structure of a firm is. It tells us how sensitive firms are to varying cost changes. Since all firms and all industries have cost structures that greatly vary, it would be reasonable to expect that we would see varying labor demand elasticities across industries and firms. The sensitivity to labor wages is likely very different when comparing car manufacturing to fast-food restaurants because of the differing applicability of the Hicks-Marshall Laws.

There have been several studies that look specifically at the impact of minimum wages on different industries. We would expect that if labor demand elasticity varies from industry to industry, that a flat, over-arching minimum wage would have varying effects from industry to industry. Two studies in particular have had wide focuses on this topic. One of the studies looked at the varying employment effects of a minimum wage on four industries. They found a 10% increase in the minimum wage decreases employment in retail by 8-25%, eating and drinking by 5-20%, other retail by 9-26%, and total non-farm by 10-21%(Partidge & Partridge 1999). A more recent study found a 10% increase in the minimum wage decreased eating and drinking employment by 2% and increased hotel and lodging employment by 15-16%(Singell & Terborg 2006). This evidence shows that a minimum wage affects different industries differently12.

What does this evidence mean for minimum wage legislation? What we have seen is that labor demand elasticity changes the both the Joliet Corridor and the Employment Window. Additionally, we have discussed that labor demand elasticity likely differs by industry and firm. So, a minimum wage that would produce positive results in one industry or firm might not do so in another industry or firm. Chart 9 shows how a minimum wage, M*, set within the Joliet Corridor for an industry with relatively inelastic labor demand produces positive results, Q#-Q+ more employment, while it produces negative employment results in an industry with unit elastic labor demand, Q”-Q$ less employment. The policy implication of this is that minimum wages should be set on the industry and firm levels. It would not make sense even in the presence of a monopsonistic market to have one over-arching minimum wage for all industries and businesses because of the differing labor demand elasticities. FLSA does this to an extent by having a lower minimum for tipping jobs and having some agricultural jobs exempt, but this likely does not go far enough.

Interestingly, FLSA once implemented a minimum wage strategy that took the above concerns into consideration. An amendment to FLSA established 40 industry committees in

CHART 9.

12 These differences are necessary evidence, but they are not sufficient evidence in determining the impact of labor demand elasticity. Other factors could be at work here.

Page 21

Page 22: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Puerto Rico which set industry level minimum wages. This amendment was discontinued in 1974 when congress amended FLSA to have Puerto Rico conform to US standards.13

Some work has been done on this transition for industry boards to an overarching standard. It was found that industries in Puerto Rico whose minimum was at or within $.10 of the United States minimum saw between 1-2% reductions in employment after the implementation of the 1974 amendment. Furthermore, it was found that industries that had minimums set more than $.10 below what the United States minimum wage was faced decreases in employment of 32% in the following years(Castillo-Freeman & Freeman 1992). This is further evidence that industry labor demand elasticity should likely be taken into consideration when structuring minimum wage legislation. Locality Considerations

In addition to labor demand elasticity, another important factor affecting the viability of minimum wage legislation is locality. The characteristics of economies are vastly different when observing individual states in the US. Moreover, the characteristics of individual regions, counties, and cities are very different across the US. The economy of Houston, Texas with a population of 2.2 million and a median income of $42,945.00 (City Data, 2011a) differs greatly from Cuevitas, Texas with a population of 45 and a median income of $10,720.00 (City Data, 2011b). These differences have serious implications when considering the viability of a nationwide minimum wage.

These implications can be observed by looking at simple supply and demand in Chart 6. These graphs look at the minimum wage window when the supply and demand for labor is either high or low. In Charts 10A and 10B illustrate communities/states with high and low labor demand. Charts 10C, 10D, and 10E on the other hand illustrate communities/states with differing labor supply.

We see by comparing Charts 10A and 10B that as demand for labor increases so does the Joliet Corridor and the Employment Window. This means that with a larger demand for

13 Similar industry standards were established in the United Kingdom when they passed the Trade Boards Act in 1909. This established industry wage boards which set minimum wages by industry. In 1986 the Wages Act of 1986 was passed which put limits to these wage boards and eventually ended them in 1993. Trade unions saw these industry councils as a threat against collective bargaining(Deakin 2009).

Page 22

Page 23: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

labor there is greater probability of setting an effective minimum wage and there is a greater total possible positive employment effect.14 Larger wealthier communities usually have higher demand for labor because; their economies can support such a demand. The ironic implication here is that smaller less wealthy communities with lower labor demand, communities that FLSA is intended to help, have a higher probability of being hurt because of the small span of the Joliet Corridor in these economies and the lower wage levels within the span.

A community/state with a relatively large labor force would be described by Chart 10C and a community/state with a relatively small labor force would be described by Chart 10E. We see that in both of these situations the Joliet Corridor and Employment Window are about the same span, but at different wage levels. While a minimum wage set within the Joliet Corridor in Chart 10E would provide positive employment effects, it would be well above the Joliet Corridor in Chart 10C, resulting in a decrease in employment. We see that the span of the Joliet Corridor is relatively small when there are relatively small quantities of labor and relatively large quantities of labor. So, when an economy can be described by this extreme situation, low and high labor supplies, the probability of setting an optimal minimum wage is much lower.15

There is a definite policy implication to the differences seen in Charts 10A through 10E. These charts show that a Federal minimum wage in a country with varying state, county, and city economies may have positive impacts in some localities, but negative impacts in others. For example if the minimum wage was set within the Joliet Corridor in Charts 10A and 10D produces positive employment effects, this wage floor would be well above the Joliet Corridor for localities whose economies look more like Chart 10B and 10C, producing negative employment effects. What this tells us is that in order for Federal minimum wage legislation to produce optimal positive employment effects, there must be different minimums set for different localities even in the presence of a monopsony market.

To put some meat on this argument we will look at state variations in low-skill wages, Chart 11. This chart looks at state median hourly wages in “Food Preparation and Serving Related Occupations”(FPSRO) and compares these wages to the Federal minimum. As you can see in the third column, states differ significantly in what wages they pay in the same industry. The median wage for FPSRO in Alabama is 7.86% higher than the Federal minimum wage, while the median wage for FPSRO in Nevada is 47.17% higher than the Federal minimum wage. A 10% increase in the Federal minimum wage is likely to be more binding for FPSRO jobs in Alabama than in than FPSRO jobs in Nevada because average wages are much closer to the Federal minimum. If both of these states have monopsonistic labor markets in FPSRO and we want to maximize employment, we need to set the minimum wage within the Joliet Corridor, which is very likely, different in Alabama versus Nevada.

14 All firms have particular amounts of capital and labor. If a economic conditions allow a firm to expand it will change

the amounts of capital and labor it employs. This can result in an upward shift in labor demand. If labor demand shifts the firm would have determined hiring more labor would increase profits. It is possible that with greater profits firms are better able to absorb the imposed extra costs of minimum wage.15 This ‘anomaly’ is interesting. It likely has serious implications for economies with large labor supplies like China

and economies with relatively small labor supplies like New York City.

Page 23

Page 24: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

CHART 10.

Page 24

Page 25: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

CHART 11.

Wage DiscriminationOne last consideration is whether or not firms actually have to increase the wages of all

workers when they hire a new worker. This is a very important factor that needs to hold in-order for minimum wage to have positive employment effects. If for example a firm could carry out a form of price discrimination where they pay different wages to identical laborers, firms would no longer face an upward sloping marginal cost curve. For example, let’s say laborer A is willing to accept a wage of $1 and worker laborer B is willing to accept a wage of $2, a firm could hire both for a total cost of $3. If firms could discriminate on this level, they would be able to change their marginal cost curve to perfectly reflect the labor supply curve. This would result in a scenario where a minimum wage could not increase employment. This is a topic the needs to be seriously investigated if we truly want to know the implications of minimum wages in monopsonistic labor markets.

Page 25

Page 26: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

V. MINIMUM WAGE AND ITS EFFECT ON EMPLOYMENT SUMMARYThe debate over minimum wage has traditionally focused on the employment effects of

minimum wage legislation. Two camps have appeared to emerge in this debate. These two camps can be personified by two groups of researchers. In one camp sits David Card and Alan Krueger. The empirical results of their research and the theoretical justifications for their results point towards the conclusion that minimum wages have no effects to positive effects on employment due to the presence of a monopsony(Card 1992a) (Card 1992b) (Card & Krueger 1994) (Card & Krueger 1995a) (Card & Krueger 1995b) (Card & Kreuger 2000).16 David Neumark and William Wascher appear lead the other camp. The results of their research give modern econometric backing to the argument that minimum wage legislation has significant negative effects on employment (Neumark & Wascher 1992). Their results appear justify the traditional competitive market model, though we will discuss later why we may see negative results even in the presence of a monopsony.

The empirical research on minimum wage dates back to the 1950’s. The majority of the empirical research from the 1950’s through the 1980’s regularly finds negative employment effects. In general, the results of the research from the 1950’s through the 1980’s showed that with a 10% increase in minimum wage there is a 1% to 3% decrease in teenage employment with additional disemployment effects in other demographics(Neumark & Wascher 2007). It was not until the early 1990’s that these results began to face serious empirical challenges.

This challenge came from David Card in 1992. David Card looked at the 1989 Federal minimum wage hike and its effects on regional levels(Card 1992a). He was able use states with state minimum wages already over the federal minimum wage as controls. He also controlled for differences in regional economic characteristics. According to his model, if minimum wage does have employment effects, then we should see more drastic changes in employment in states that have minimum wages below the Federal level. This is because a new Federal minimum wage would not be binding or as binding for states already above the Federal minimum. His study was not able to find statistically significant employment effects caused by the minimum wage, challenging the theoretical models and traditional research which almost always found significant negative effects. Card and Krueger followed Card’s original paper with several other research papers in which they found similar results. These empirical results appear to give legitimacy to looking at minimum wages using a monopsony model or at least reason to question competitive market theory. Since 1992, I was able to find empirical 32 papers have been published which have results similar to Card & Krueger. These papers have posed a new challenge to the traditional competitive model approach.

Card and Krueger’s results were met almost instantly with criticism. These criticisms ranged from not incorporating lagged effects17(Neumark & Waschler 1992) to simply the year that the research was conducted18(Wessels 1997). Neumark and Waschler were the first to

16 As discussed earlier a binding minimum wage minimum wage sends a price signal. This could result in laborer

who had stopped looking for work to start looking again, added workers. This could result in an increase in the number employed and an increase in number of unemployed, if these added workers cannot find employment. This effect could result in seeing smaller employment effects in the research. 17The idea here is that the employment effects of a minimum wage may take a particular amount of time. Neumark

and Waschler argue that Card did not appropriately control for this lagged effect.18 Wessels actually replicated the model used by Card and Krueger in their 1995 study which looked at the 1990-

1991 Federal hike. Wessels found that when using the same model to look at 1996-1997 Federal minimum wage

Page 26

Page 27: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

empirically challenge Card in their 1992 paper looking at the effects of minimum wage using state level panel data. Using differences in state level minimum wages and Federal minimum wages as a means of control, Neumark and Waschler found results that backed the traditional empirical work on minimum wage(Neumark & Waschler 1992). Since 1992, Neumark and Waschler have produced 13 other empirical studies/reviews that have drawn similar conclusions on the negative effects of minimum wages. A total of 52 papers since 1992 have drawn similar conclusions. These results appear to give backing to competitive markets theory or reason to believe that FLSA is very poorly structured. Survey

I collected 138 empirical papers that deal with minimum wage and its impact on employment. These studies date from 1957-2011. They test minimum wages effects in over 21 countries.19 This survey can be found in Appendix 1. Graph 6 gives a summary of the results of the research from 1957-2011. My survey found that 64% of the research from this time period resulted in negative employment effects, 19% found no effect, 12% found mixed effects, and 5% found positive effects. This is seen in Graph 6. When the time period is narrowed to 1992-201120, 52% of the research found negative employment effects, 25% found no effect, 16% found mixed effects, and 7% found positive effects. These results are seen in Graph 7.

This survey gives us an estimation of whether or not competitive markets theory or monopsony theory is correct. What we see is that the vast majority of research backs the competitive markets theory or the idea that FLSA is poorly structured, even when looking just at research from 1992-2011. Fortunately, as we saw in the beginning of this paper, minimum wage workers make up a very small portion of the total labor force. Due to this fact, these overall negative impacts are not that large. Graph 6.

hike, negative employment results are produced. Wessels says that, “the fraction affected changed in a significant way between the two sets of minimum wage hikes.” which helps explain the different results.19 United States, France, Indonesia, Canada, United Kingdom, Mexico, Columbia, Finland, New Zealand, Chile,

Czech Republic, Brazil, Honduras, Greece, Japan, Germany, China, Portugal, Sweden, Trinidad & Tobago, and the Netherlands.20 From David Card’s paper to present.

Page 27

Page 28: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Graph 7.

VI. MINIMUM WAGE AND ITS EFFECTS ON JOB TRAINING“Even if an individual were to “buy” on-the-job training by taking a very low wage…the

minimum wage law would not permit him to do so…”(Feldstein 1973). Ones compensation for work does not just include a monetary income. Compensation can take the form of health benefits, work environment, vacation days, job training, etc. These are all considerations that laborers and employers take into consideration when determining wages according to human capital theory. For example, a pleasant work environment would likely result in lower monetary compensation. Working in a pleasant work environment is a real benefit that costs money for an employer to provide. Some workers are likely to give up some of their salary in order to have that benefit.21

The topic of training and compensation is discussed in depth by economist Gary Becker. Assuming a competitive labor market, ones marginal productivity equals ones wage. Becker argues that “Persons receiving general training would be willing to pay these costs[lower wages] since training raises their future wages.”(Becker 1994). So, at times a laborer may be receiving less than their marginal productivity in monetary wages, but it is made up for through training that an employer provides.

Assuming that a laborers marginal productivity is $7 in a competitive market a worker will receive $7 in compensation. According to Beckers model, workers will receive $7 in compensation, but compensation specification may differ. The laborer may by paid $5 in wages and $2 dollars in training. Many laborers are willing to do this because acquiring general skills increases their marginal productivity and their future wages.

21 There are two types of skills that laborers can get through training: general skills and specific skills. General skills

are skills that can be utilized at more than on job. Knowing how to use a cash register for example is skill that can be used in many different businesses. Specific skills are skills that are firm specific. Knowing where the storage closet is. This is something that can only be used at a specific firm. Laborers are more willing to give up monetary compensation for general skills which increase their marginal productivity across firms.

Page 28

Page 29: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

This model is used in most of the research to justify why we would see negative effects on job training(Hashimoto 82) (Mincer & Leighton 81) (Neumark &Wascher 98). The argument is made that by putting a wage floor in makes less room for variety in components of compensation. For example, a laborer whose marginal productivity is $7 in a world with a $6 minimum wage, could only receive up to $1 in non-monetary compensation. Furthermore, if the minimum wage is increased to $7 that worker would have to receive $7 in monetary compensation. If a firm were to train this worker it would be compensating that worker above his marginal productivity because during training, the worker is not as productive. Therefore, when the minimum wage is raised theory suggests that we would see less and less job training as room for varying compensation specification is diminished. Specifically, general training would likely be reduced because this training decreases a laborers marginal productivity while the training is taking place, compared to specific training where a laborers marginal productivity is increased very quickly.

A seminal paper by Masanori Hashimoto measures the effect of minimum wage on training by using “work-experience-induced growth rate” as a proxy for training(Hashimoto 1982). The intuition is that we would be able to see a decrease in experience induced earnings if training was decreased. He uses the National Longitudinal Survey as his data source. He specifically looks at the effects of the 1967 amendment to FLSA. He finds that the 1967 amendment reduced job training by $.23 to $1.27 or 2.7% to 15%, supporting traditional theory(Hashimoto 1982).

The problem with Hashimotos research is a problem that has faced most of the research, lack of good data. Specifically the research has not been able to generally use good measures of job training(Fairris 2004).22 Lastly, Hashimoto does not use data to look at cross-state variations, which most recent research uses to control for variables, but cross-state variations are used in Neumark and Wascher’s research and they still find some negative effects(Neumark & Wascher 1998).

More recent research has produced different results. Fairris and Pedace (2004) have particularly interesting results. They were able to utilize a new/different data set23 which showed the percentage of workforce receiving training and the average number of hours of training received. In addition, they use cross-state variations as an instrument to look specifically at minimum wages effect. They find that minimum wages decrease the total number of people receiving training, but total hours of training remain constant. This means that the allocation of training appears to change. According to a paper by Lechthaler and Snower (2007) the allocation of training goes from low-skill workers to intermediate skill workers creating a skill gap. So while a minimum wage increase may not have an effect on total training, it may have an effect on who is getting trained and the type of training, they receive.

The research on minimum wages effect on job training is mixed. There do not appear to be any definite conclusions that we can draw from the research so far. While more research is clearly needed, if minimum wages prevent firms from offering training or alter the way firms train

22 Job training is not always directly observable. Hours at work for example can be directly measured. One only

needs to calculate the difference between when one arrives and leaves work and then multiply by the days spent at work. Training on the other had is not as concrete. Training could be learning to communicate over the phone. This is not something that is directly measurable.23 They used 1997 National Employer Survey. They supplemented this data with the Standard Establishment List

data collected by the U.S. Census Bureau.

Page 29

Page 30: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

workers we might expect to see decreases in income mobility. If laborers are not able to receive the general training that they once were able to, it seems likely that they would not be able to increases their marginal productivity’s resulting in a lag in income growth. Young people would most likely be disproportionately hurt by this effect, seeing that a large proportion of minimum wage workers are under the age of 25. This may result in a generation of young people increasing their earnings less than the previous generation.

Lastly, these training effects are likely not specific to competitive markets. When a minimum wage is set it changes the costs that firms face, both in competitive and monopsonistic markets. A minimum wage in the Joliet Corridor means both wages and employment will go up, meaning that the costs facing a firm have increased. When we looked at determining the labor demand curve we saw that as wages increased demand for labor decreased because to this added cost. If firms are not decreasing employment to compensate for wage rate increases it seems reasonable for a firm to change its behavior in another way to adjust for these cost changes, possibly by training less. TABLE 1.

Survey

Page 30

Page 31: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

The empirical research on minimum wages effect on job training is very limited. I was only able to find ten papers that had attempted to analyze the data on this topic. Of these ten papers four showed negative effects, three showed no effects, two showed no to some positive effects, and one showed negative to no effects. Moreover, in almost every paper the researchers say that there is not enough evidence to draw a conclusion on this subject and that further research must be conducted. These results can be seen in Table 1.

VII. MINIMUM WAGE AND ITS EFFECTS ON SCHOOLINGA minimum wage creates a price floor. This price floor in a competitive labor market

prevents employers from hiring anyone whose marginal productivity is lower than the minimum wage. Laborers have limited choices in their response to the wage floor. They can: move to an uncovered part of the economy(there are a limited number of employment options that are exempted from FLSA), they can go unemployed, or they can go to school to increase their marginal productivity. In response to the limitations in employment, theory suggests that laborers stay in school longer or return to school in order to overcome the employment barrier that the minimum wage creates(Mattila 1981).

Similar to training, schooling is another topic related to minimum wage that there is little empirical research on. In my research I was able to find a total of 14 papers analyzing this subject. These 14 papers varied in results from significant negative effects on schooling to significant positive effects on schooling, as seen in Table 2. In the following paragraphs we will take a look at the theories that support these differing results. Additionally, we will take a look at the empirical evidence that is available.

We will first look at the evidence and theory of positive effects of minimum wage on schooling. One of the first papers that looks at minimum wages relation to schooling is “The Impact of Minimum Wages on Teenage Schooling and on the Part-Time/Full-Time Employment of Youths” (Mattila 1981). Using a regression analysis and data from the Current Population survey, Mattilla found that a minimum wage increased schooling.24 These results were theoretically justified by looking at what every good economist looks at, how consumers and producers respond to prices.

The counter argument to the evidence that Mattila provides says that minimum wages decrease the schooling that individuals receive. This theory takes a more in-depth look at the supply side. It looks at how laborers, the suppliers of labor, respond to increases in wages.Arguably the most important aspect of prices is their ability to send information across a diverse and wide group of market actors. Prices tell us how much labor needs to be supplied and how much is demanded. In Chart 4B25 we see a competitive labor market with a binding minimum wage. The question we should now ask is what does this tell employers and laborers? The answer to this question is fairly intuitive. Someone demanding labor, an employer, is going to want less because of an increase in prices, but someone providing labor, a laborer, will want to supply more because of the opportunity for higher profits.

TABLE 2.

24 He found that a 10% increase in the minimum wage increase the proportion of 18-19 year olds in school by 1.33%

(males) and 1.26%(Females). Both of these estimates are statistically significant.25 This is on page 13.

Page 31

Page 32: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Neumark and Wascher use this theory as the justification for the results in their papers on this topic. They argue that market actors with higher marginal productivities are going to leave school and join the labor force when they see higher prices imposed by a minimum wage. The intuition is that minimum wages make working more attractive than going to school because of the now higher pay.

One of the first empirical papers on this topic was produced by James Cunningham in 1981. Cunningham used the US Census to do a cross-sectional examination of minimum wage effects on schooling. The result of his research was that minimum wage increases have a negative effect on schooling. He added to the traditional theoretical justification by looking at changes in part-time and full-time employment. He found that part-time workers are normally paid less than full-time workers. Furthermore, when a minimum wage is imposed, part-time positions are diminished. Students who formally worked part-time to pay for their education are

Page 32

Page 33: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

now no longer able to do so. As a result, more people drop-out and take full-time positions(Cunningham 1981).

This effect of minimum wage is particularly concerning. Minimum wage is a method that is purported to help the lowest-skilled in the labor force. If minimum wage decreases schooling it may have the impact of increasing the amount of low-skilled workers. This may result in lower income mobility and increase the gap between rich and poor.

In summary, we can draw no definite conclusions from the research on minimum wages effect on schooling. While most of the research does seem to be leaning in the direction of negative effects on schooling, there is not enough evidence to make a definite conclusion. Like training, more research needs to be done in order to draw a substantive conclusion on minimum wages effect on schooling.

Despite the lack of definitive evidence on this effect, if we assume that the effect does happen we would likely see it in monopsonistic markets as well as competitive markets. A price signal is still being sent in monopsonistic markets. Depending on where the minimum wage is set in a monopsonistic market, it may result in added workers entering the labor force who were formally in school. This is seen for a minimum wage set above where the labor supply and labor demand curves intersect. Minimums set above that point will result in firms wanting less labor than laborers want to provide. Bottom line, prices are not arbitrary and have serious implications in both competitive and monopsonistic markets.

VIII. MINIMUM WAGE AND ITS EFFECT ON PRICESUnlike the previous two sections, the research on minimum wages effects on prices

appears to be much clearer because of the more uniform results and the greater amount of research done. In this section we will go over the economic theory that would explain minimum wages effect on prices. Additionally, I will present a survey of the research that has been conducted on this subject

What happens to a firms cost structure when a minimum wage is instituted? Chart 9 shows a firms total cost and total revenue schedule with and without a binding minimum wage.26

What we see is that a binding minimum wage shifts the total cost curve that a firm faces up. This diminishes the amount of profits that a firm can make. Firms, especially corporations, need to make certain amounts profits to stay in business. Firms can respond to this change in costs by changing the amount of people they employ, buying more capital equipment, and looking for other cost saving techniques.

According to monopsony theory, a firm will increase employment when its total costs go up from minimum wage legislation. If this new cost cannot be absorbed through lower employment and firms need to maintain a particular level of profits, firms can increase prices to do this. If a firm increases its prices its total revenue curve will shift upwards increasing profits, though there are definite limitations to this strategy.

CHART 9.

26 This is similar, but different than when we looked at total cost and total product at the beginning of this paper.

Page 33

Page 34: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

SurveyIf our assumptions on the effects of minimum wage in the previous example hold, then

the empirical research should show similar results. In my research I was able to find 28 unique papers on minimum wages impact on prices. Of these 28 papers, 20 found that minimum wage increased prices, 7 found it had no effect, and 1 found mixed effects. None of these papers found decreases in prices. These results can be seen in more depth in Table 3.

Thinking back on what industries are effected by minimum wage, Appendix 1 Graph 1, makes for interesting implications of minimum wage legislation. What we saw was that the vast majority of minimum wage workers are concentrated in “Food preparation and serving related occupations”. So if the results from the papers in my survey are correct, “Food preparation and serving related occupations” are going to likely increase the prices of their products. So, minimum wages may increase employment, but these newly employed persons along with other market participants are going to be facing higher food/restaurant prices. Interestingly, poor/minority communities that minimum wage legislation is supposed to help have high concentrations of fast-food restaurants and convenience stores(Block et al 2004). So, the very people minimum wage is supposed to be helping through employment, it is likely hurting through higher food prices.

IX. Does Minimum Wage Legislation Help the Poor?: A SurveyWe have seen that minimum wage legislation can have a variety of impacts that vary in

scope depending on whether labor markets are competitive or monopsonistic and whether or not legislation is structured properly. There are those who say that minimum wage may have these negative impacts, but it is still a good policy on grounds that it reduces poverty. Though minimum wages may reduce employment, the idea is that those workers who continue working are now making higher monetary wages than they were. The position says those who are receiving this now higher wage are primarily poor people. If this is true a minimum wage could have negative effects with respect to employment and aid the working poor at the same time.

Proponents of this theory say that minimum wage hikes will specifically help single mothers and fathers and other hard working families. Proponents argue that it is too difficult to live off of a minimum wage in today's economy. Interestingly, these populations usually either make more than the minimum wage individually or they have multiple wage earners in their family, according to some research(Sabia & Burkhauser 2010).

Page 34

Page 35: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Sabia and Burkhauser (2010) did a study that looked at who was impacted by a minimum wage increase. They estimated the effects of raising the minimum wage to $9.50 an hour and the effects of the most recent minimum wage increase to $7.25. What they found was that those affected by a minimum wage increase were likely to not be the only earner in a family and were not likely to be the highest earner in that family. They estimated that in the most recent minimum wage increase, 57.3% of the minimum wage hourly paid workers affected were not the highest wage earners in their families. So, most workers who were affected by the increase had other wage earners in their family, earning more. They estimated that if the minimum wage were to be raised to $9.50 an hour, 42.3% of those affected would live in households with incomes of $50,233.00. This is three times the poverty line for these households.

Additionally, they looked at the minimum wage hike’s effect specifically on single mothers and fathers. They found that only 12.5% of women and 5.5% men who are minimum wage earners, who are unmarried, and who have children were affected positively by the most recent increase in minimum wage. These are relatively small numbers when one considers that minimum wage workers make up less than 3% of the total labor force. One of the main reasons for these results is that single mothers tend to earn more than state and federal minimum wages. Many single mothers, over 50%, from 1991-2004 had earnings above the 2004 Federal minimum wage of $5.15(Sabia 2008). Additionally, there tend to be lower labor participation rates among the poorest American households, which explains why minimum wage likely does not have a significant effect on poverty(Leigh 2007).Survey

The findings of most of the research indicate that minimum wage legislation is likely a poor way of helping the poor. I was able to collect 28 empirical studies that tested whether or not minimum wage legislation had a beneficial impact on poverty. These papers date from 1989 to 2011 and are conducted eight countries. The survey can be found in Table 1A in the appendix. The results are summarized below in Graph 8. Out of the 28 studies 16, 59.3%, concluded that minimum wage was ineffective at reducing poverty, 6, 22.2%, found that it was effective, 4, 14.8%, found small effectiveness, and 1, 3.7%, found mixed results.

We have now looked at who is affected by minimum wage legislation. We have seen that minimum wage workers tend to be young. Most, 49%, are under 25 years old. We also saw that most, 57.3%, workers affected by minimum wage legislation are not the only or highest earners in their families. Moreover, very few single mothers,12.5%, and fathers, 5.5%, are effected by minimum wage increases. These results raise serious questions to the argument that minimum wages help raise people out of poverty.

GRAPH 8.

Page 35

Page 36: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

X. ConclusionThe public should be very weary of politicians and economists promising employment

increases and poverty decreases from minimum wage legislation. These claims are based off of economic models that might not accurately describe labor markets and evidence that appears to be pointing in the other direction. Moreover, the legislation that has been and is being proposed does not fit with monopsony theory. Even if we could restructure FLSA so that it would take locality, industry, and individual firms into consideration and even if it had no negative unintended consequences, the positive impacts of the minimum wage legislation would likely be minuscule because of the small size of the minimum wage labor force. The lack of our understanding of labor markets, our inability to pass rational legislation, and the small size of the minimum wage labor force are why it is a myth that we can manipulate this labor market to produce meaningful outcomes.

References

Page 36

Page 37: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Aaronson, Daniel, Eric French, and James MacDonald. 2005. “The Minimum Wage, Restaurant Prices, and Labor Market Structure.” Unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago.

Aaronson, Daniel, and Eric French. 2007. “Product Market Evidence on the Employment Effects of the Minimum Wage.” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 25, No. 1 (January), pp. 167- 200.

Abowd, John M., Francis Kramarz, Thomas Lemieux, and David N. Margolis. 2000a. “Minimum Wages and Youth Employment in France and the United States.” In David Blanchflower and Richard Freeman, eds. Youth Employment and Joblessness in Advanced Countries. pp. 427-72. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Abowd, John M., Francis Kramarz, David N. Margolis, and Thomas Phillipon. 2000b. “The Tail of Two Countries: Minimum Wages and Employment in France and the United States.” Discussion Paper No. 203. Institute

for the Study of Labor (IZA).

Adams, F. Gerard. 1987. Increasing the Minimum Wage: The Macroeconomic Impacts. Briefing Paper, Economic Policy Institute (July).

Adams, Scott, and David Neumark, 2005. “Living Wage Effects: New and Improved Evidence.” Economic Development Quarterly. Vol. 19, No. 1 (February), pp. 80-102.

Addison, John T., and McKinley L. Blackburn. 1999. Minimum wages and poverty. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 52(3):393-409.

Addison, John T., McKinley L. Blackburn, and Chad D. Cotti. 2009. “Do Minimum Wages Raise Employment? Evidence from the U.S. Retail-Trade Sector.” Labour Economics. Vol. 16, No. 4 (August), pp. 397-

408.

Adie, Douglas K. 1973. Teen-Age Unemployment and Real Federal Minimum Wages. Journal of Political Economy, vol. 81 (March/April): 435-441.

A.L.A. SCHECHTER POULTRY CORPORATION v. UNITED STATES, 295 U.S. 495 (1935), http://caselaw.lp.find law. com/cgi -bin/getcase.pl?court=US&vol=295&invol=495.

Alatas, V. and L. Cameron. 2003. “The Impact of Minimum Wages on Employment in a Low Income Country: Exploiting a Quasi-Natural Experiment.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2985.

Baker, Michael, Dwayne Benjamin, and Shuchita Stanger. 1999. “The Highs and Lows of the Minimum Wage Effect: A Time-Series Cross-Section Study of the Canadian Law.” Journal of Labor Economics. Vol. 17, No. 2 (April), pp. 318-50.

Bazen, Stephan, and Nicolas Skourias. 1997. “Is There a Negative Effect of Minimum Wages in France?” European Economic Review, Vol. 57, Nos. 3-5 (April), pp.723-732.

Bazen, Stephen, and Velayoudom Marimoutou. 2002. “Looking for a Needle in a Haystack? A Reexamination of the Time Series Relationship between Teenage Employment and Minimum Wages in the United States.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics. Vol. 64, Supplement, pp. 699-725.

Bazen, Stephen, and Julie Le Gallo. 2006. “The Differential Impact of Federal and State Minimum Wages on Teenage Employment.” Unpublished paper, University of Savoie.

Becker, Gary S. Human Capital A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education. N.p.: The University of Chicago Press, 1994.

Page 37

Page 38: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Bell, Linda. 1997. “The Impact of Minimum Wages in Mexico and Colombia.” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 15, No.3, Part 2 (July), pp. S102-S135.

Bernstein, Jared, and John Schmitt. 2000. “The Impact of the Minimum Wage: Policy Lifts Wages, Maintains Floor for Low-Wage Labor Market.” Economic Policy Institute Briefing Paper.

Bernstein, Jared and John Schmitt. 1998. “Making Work Pay: The Impact of the 1996-97 Minimum Wage Increase.” Economic Policy Institute, Washington, D.C.

Bhaskar, V., Alan Manning, and Ted To. 2004. “Oligopsony and Monopsonistic Competition in Labor Markets.” http://theo.to/imperfect/jep.pdf

Bird, Kelly and Chris Manning. 2008. “Minimum Wages and Poverty in a Developing Country: Simulations from Indonesia’s Household Survey.” World Development. Vol. 36, No. 5. (May) pp. 916-993.

Block, J. P., Schribner, R. A., & DeSalvo, K. B. (2004). Fast Food, Race/Ethnicity, and Income A Geographic Analysis. Retrieved from American Journal of Preventive Medicine.

Bockerman, Petri and Roope Uusitalo 2009. “Minimum Wages and Youth Employment: Evidence from the Finnish Retail Trade Sector.” British Journal of Industrial Relations. Vol. 47, No. 2 (June) pp. 388-405.

Brown, Charles; Gilroy, Curtis; and Kohen, Andrew. 1981a. Effects of the Minimum Wage on Youth Employment and Unemployment. In Minimum Wage Study Commission (1981), vol. 5, pp. 1-26.

Brown, Charles; Gilroy, Curtis; and Kohen, Andrew. 1981b. Time-Series Evidence of the Effect of the Minimum Wage on Teenage Employment and Unemployment. In Minimum Wage Study Commission (1981), vol. 5, pp. 103-127.

Brown, Charles, Curtis Gilroy, and Andrew Kohen. 1982. "The Effect of the Minimum Wage on Employment and Unemployment." Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 20, No. 2 (June), pp.487-528.

Brown, Charles, Curtis Gilroy, and Andrew Kohen. 1983. "Time Series Evidence on the Effect of the' Minimum Wage on Youth Employment and Unemployment." Journal of Human Resources, Vol.18, No. 2

(Winter), pp. 3-31.

Brown, Charles. 1988. Minimum Wage Laws: Are They Overrated? Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 2 (Summer): 133-145.

Burkhauser, Richard V., and T. Aldrich Finegan. 1989. The minimum wage and the poor: The end of a relationship. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 8:53-71.

Burkhauser, Richard V., Kenneth A. Couch, and Andrew J. Glenn. 1996. Public policies for the working poor: The earned income tax credit versus minimum wage legislation, in Research in Labor Economics, volume 15, edited by Solomon W. Polachek. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, pp. 65-109.

Burkhauser, Richard V., Kenneth A. Couch, and David C. Wittenburg. 2000a. “A Reassessment of the New Economics of the Minimum Wage Literature with Monthly Data from the Current Population Survey.” Journal of Labor Economics. Vol. 18, No. 4 (October), pp. 653-680.

Burkhauser, Richard V., Kenneth A. Couch, and David C. Wittenburg. 2000b. “Who Minimum Wage Increases Bite: An Analysis Using Monthly Data from the SIPP and the CPS.” Southern Economic Journal. Vol. 67, No. 1 (January), pp. 16-40.

Page 38

Page 39: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Burkhauser, Richard V., and Joseph J. Sabia. 2007. The effectiveness of minimum wage increases in reducing poverty: Past, present, and future. Contemporary Economic Policy 25(2):262-81.

Ted Kennedy for Senate. (2006, September 10). Support the Fair Minimum Wage Act [Video file]. Retrieved from youtube database.

Campolieti, Michele, Tony Fang, and Morley Gunderson. 2005a. “How Minimum Wages Affect Schooling-Employment Outcomes in Canada, 1993-1999.” Journal of Labor Research. Vol. 26, No. 3 (Summer), pp. 169-82.

Campolieti, Michele, Tony Fang, and Morley Gunderson. 2005b. “Minimum Wage Impacts on Youth Employment Transitions, 1993-1999.” Canadian Journal of Economics. Vol. 38, No. 1 (February), pp. 81-104.

Campolieti, Michele, Morley Gunderson, and Chris Riddell. 2006. “Minimum Wage Impacts from a Prespecified Research Design: Canada 1981-1997.” Industrial Relations, Vol. 45, No. 2 (April), pp. 195-216.

Card, D., 1992a. Using regional variations in wages to measure the effects of the federal minimum wage. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46, 22–37.

Card, D., 1992b. Do minimum wages reduce employment? A case study of California, 1987–1989. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46, 38–54.

Card, D., Krueger, A., 1994a. Minimumwages and employment: a case study of the fast-food industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania. American Economic Review 84, 772–793.

Card, D., Krueger, A., 1994b. “A Living Wage? The Effects of the Minimum Wage on the Distribution of Wages, the Distribution of Family Earnings, and Poverty.” Princeton University, Department of Economics, Industrial Relations Section., Working Papers.

Card, David, and Alan B. Krueger. 1995a. Myth and Measurement: The New Economics of the Minimum Wage. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Card, David, and Alan B. Krueger. 1995b. “Time-Series Minimum Wage Studies: A Meta-analysis.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings. Vol. 85, No. 2 (May), pp. 238-43.

Card, David, and Alan B. Krueger. 2000. “Minimum Wages and Employment: A Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania: Reply.” American Economic Review. Vol. 90, No. 5

(December), pp. 1397-1420.

Castillo-Freeman, Alida, and Richard B. Freeman. 1992. “When the Minimum Wage Really Bites: the effect of the US-Level Minimum on Puerto Rico.” In George Borjas and Richard Freeman, eds. Immigration and the Work Force: Economic Consequences for the United States and Source Areas. pp.177-211. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Congressional Budget Office (CBO). 2007. "Response to a Request by Senator Grassley about the Effects of Increasing the Federal Minimum Wage versus Expanding the Earned Income Tax Credit." Accessed 20 April 2008. Available at http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/77xx /doc772l/01-09-MinimumWageEITC.pdf.

Chapman, Jeff. 2004. “Employment and the Minimum Wage: Evidence from Recent State Labor Market Trends.” Economic Policy Institute Briefing Paper.

Chapple, Simon. 1997. “Do Minimum Wages Have an Adverse Impact on Employment? Evidence from New Zealand.” Labour Market Bulletin, No. 2, pp. 25-50.

Page 39

Page 40: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

City Data. 2011a. Houston, Texas. Retrieved April 16, 2011, from http://www.city-data.com/city/Houston-Texas.html

City Data. 2011b. Cuevitas, Texas. Retrieved April 14, 2011, from http://www.city-data.com/city/Cuevitas-Texas.html

Colberg, Marshall R. 1960. Minimum Wage Effects on Florida's Economic Development. Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 3 (October): 106-117.

Colberg, Marshall. 1981. Minimum Wages and the Distribution of Economic Activity. In Rottenberg (1981a): 247-263.

Corbo, Vittorio. 1981. The Impact of Minimum Wages on Industrial Employment in Chile. In Rottenberg (1981a): 340-356.

Cox, James C., and Oaxaca, Ronald L. 1986. Minimum Wage Effects With Output Stabilization. Economic Inquiry, vol. 24 (July): 443-453.

Cunningham, James. 1981. The Impact of Minimum Wages on Youth Employment, Hours of Work, and School Attendance: Cross-sectional Evidence from the 1960 and 1970 Censuses. In Rottenberg (1981a): 88-123.

Cunningham, Wendy, David Neumark, and Lucas Siga. 2006. “The effects of the minimum wage in Brazil on the distribution of family incomes: 1996–2001.” Journal of Development Economics. Vol. 80, No.1.

(June) pp. 136-159.

Currie, Janet, and Fallick, Bruce. 1993. A Note on the New Minimum Wage Research. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 4348 (April).

Currie, Janet, and Bruce Fallick. 1996. “The Minimum Wage and the Employment of Youth: Evidence from the NLSY.” Journal of Human Resources. Vol. 31, No. 2 (Spring), pp. 404-28.

Deakin, Simon, and Francis Green. "A century of minimum wages in Britain." CentrePiece, August 2009, 6-8. http://cep.lse.ac.uk/pubs/download/cp291.pdf.

De Fraja, G. (1999). ‘Minimum wage legislation, productivity and employment’. Economica, 66: 473–88.

Deere, Donald, Kevin M. Murphy, and Finis Welch. 1995. “Employment and the 1990-1991 Minimum-Wage Hike.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings. Vol. 85, No. 2 (May), pp. 232-37.

Dickens, R., Machin, S., Manning, A., 1999. The effect of minimum wages on employment: Theory and evidence from Britain. Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Paper No. 183. Journal of Labour

Economics, forthcoming.

Dickens, Richard and Mirko Draca. 2005. “The Employment Effects of the October 2003 Increase in the National Minimum Wage.” Centre for Economic Performance, LSE, CEP Discussion Papers.

Dolado, Juan, Francis Kramarz, Stephen Machin, Alan Manning, David Margolis, Coen Teulings, Gilles Saint-Paul, and Michael Keen. 1996. “The Economic Impact of Minimum Wages in Europe.” Economic Policy, Vol. 11, No. 23 (October), pp. 317-72.

Dolton, Peter, Chiara Rosazza-Bondibene, and Jonathan Wadsworth. 2010. “Employment, Inequality and the UK National Minimum Wage over the Medium-Term.” Centre for Economic Performance, LSE, CEP Discussion Papers

Douty, H.M. 1960. Some Effects of the $1.00 Minimum Wage in the United States. Economica, vol. 27 (May): 137-147.

Page 40

Page 41: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Dube, Arindrajit, Suresh Naidu, and Michael Reich. “The Economic Impacts of a Citywide Minimum Wage.” Forthcoming in Industrial and Labor Relations Review.

Ericksson, Tor, and Mariola Pytlikova. 2004. “Firm-Level Consequences of Large Minimum-Wage Increases in the Czech and Slovak Republics.” Labour, Vol. 18, No. 1 (March), pp. 75-103.

Fajnzylber, Pablo. 2001. “Minimum Wage Effects Throughout the Wage Distribution: Evidence from Brazil’s Formal and Informal Sectors.” Unpublished paper, Department of Economics and CEDEPLAR, Universidade Federal do Belo Horizonte.

Feliciano, Zadia M. 1998. “Does the Minimum Wage Affect Employment in Mexico?” Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 24, No. 2, Spring, pp. 165-80.

Fialova, Kamila and Martina Mysikova. 2009. “The Minimum Wage: Labor Market Consequences in the Czech Republic.” Finance a Uver/Czech Journal of Economics and Finance. Vol. 59, No. 3, pp. 255-74.

Fields, Gary S. 2005. “Minimum Wages and Poverty.” Cornell University.

Fleisher, Belton M. 1981. Minimum Wage Regulation in Retail Trade. Washington: American Enterprise Institute.

Freeman, Alida Castillo, and Freeman, Richard B. 1991. Minimum Wages in Puerto Rico: Textbook Case of a Wage Floor? National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 3759 (June).

Forrest, David. 1982. Minimum Wages and Youth Unemployment: Will Britain Learn from Canada? Journal of Economic Affairs, vol. 2 (July): 247-250.

Fougere, Denis, Erwan Gautier, and, Herve Le Bihan. 2010. “Restaurant Prices and the Minimum Wage.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking. Vol. 42, No. 7. (October) pp. 1199-1234.

Gallasch, H.F., Jr. 1975. Minimum Wages and the Farm Labor Market. Southern Economic Journal, vol. 41 (January) pp. 480-491.

Gardner, Bruce. 1981. What Have Minimum Wages Done in Agriculture? In Rottenberg (1981a): 210-232.

Gindling, T. H., and Katherine Terrell. 2004. “The Effects of Multiple Minimum Wages Throughout the Labor Market.” Discussion Paper No. 1159, IZA, May.

Gindling, T. H. and Katherine Terrell. 2009. “Minimum Wages, Wages and Employment in Various Sectors in Honduras.” Labour Economics. Vol. 16, No. 3 (June) pp. 291-303.

Gindling, T. H. and Katherine Terrell. 2010. “The Impact of Minimum Wages on Wages, Work and Poverty in Nicaragua.” UMBC Department of Economics.

Gordon, Kenneth. 1981. The Impact of Minimum Wages on Private Household Workers. In Rottenberg (1981a): 191-209

Gramlich, Edward M. 1976. Impact of Minimum Wages on Other Wages, Employment, and Family Incomes. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (No. 2): 409-461.

Grossman, Jonathan. "Fair Labor Standards Act of 1938: Maximum Struggle for a Minimum Wage." United States Department of Labor. http://www.dol.gov/oasam/programs/ history/flsa1938.htm.

Page 41

Page 42: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Hammermesh, Daniel S. 1981. Employment Demand, the Minimum Wage and Labor Costs. In Minimum Wage Study Commission (1981), vol. 5, pp. 27-84.

Hammermesh, Daniel S. 1982. Minimum Wages and the Demand for Labor. Economic Inquiry, vol. 20 (July): 365-380.

Harding, Don, and Glenys Harding. 2004. Minimum Wages in Australia: An Analysis of the Impact on Small and Medium Sized Businesses. Turning Point Research Pty Ltd., Australia.

Harrison, Ann, and Jason Scorse. 2005. “Moving Up or Moving Out? Anti-Sweatshop Activists and Labor Market Outcomes.” NBER Working paper No. 10492.

Hashimoto, Masanori. 1982. Minimum Wage Effects on Training on the Job. American Economic Review, vol. 72 (December): 1070-1087.

Hicks, J R. Theory of Wages. New York: St. Martin's Press, 1966.

Hoffman, Saul D. and Diane M. Trace. 2009. “NJ and PA Once Again: What Happened to Employment When the PA-NJ Minimum Wage Differential Disappeared?” Eastern Economic Journal. Vol. 35, No. 1

(Winter) pp. 115-28.

Hyslop, Dean, and Steven Stillman. 2004. “Youth Minimum Wage Reform and the Labour Market.” IZA Discussion Paper No. 1091, March.

Hyslop, Dean, and Steven Stillman. 2007. “Youth Minimum wage reform and the labour market in New Zealand.”

Iden, George. 1980. The Labor Force Experience of Black Youth: A Review. Monthly Labor Review, vol. 103 (August): 10-16.

Junankar, P. N., Matthew Waite, and Grant Belchamber. 2000. “The Youth Labour Market: Anecdotes, Fables and Evidence.” Economic and Labour Relations Review, Vol. 11, Supplement, pp. S159-S186.

Karageorgiou, Lazaros. 2004. “The Impact of Minimum Wage on Youth and Teenage Employment in Greece.” Spoudai, Vol. 54, No. 4 (October-December), pp. 39-67.

Katz, Lawrence F., and Alan B. Krueger. 1992. “The Effect of the Minimum Wage on the Fast Food Industry.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 46, No. 1 (October), pp. 6-21.

Kaufman RT (1989) The effects of statutory minimum rates of pay on employment in Great Britain. Econ J 99(398):1040–1053

Kawaguchi, Daiji and Yuko Mori. 2009. “Is Minimum Wage an Effective Anti-poverty Policy in Japan?” Pacific Economic Review. Vol. 14, No. 4 (October), pp. 532-54.

Keil, Manfred, Donald Robertson, and James Symons. 2001. “Minimum Wages and Employment.” CEPR Working Paper No. 497.

Kim, Taeil, and Lowell J. Taylor. 1995. “The Employment Effect in Retail Trade of California’s 1988 Minimum Wage Increase.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, vol. 13, No. 2 (April), pp. 175-82.

Knabe, Andreas and Ronnie Schob. 2008. “Minimum Wages and their Alternatives: A Critical Assessment.” CESifo Working Paper Series: CESifo Working.

Page 42

Page 43: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Knabe, Andreas and Ronnie Schob. 2009. “Minimum Wage Incidence: The Case for Germany.” FinanzArchiv. Vol. 65, No. 4 (December), pp. 403-41.

Kosters, Marvin, and Welch, Finis. 1972. The Effects of Minimum Wages on the Distribution of Changes in Aggregate Employment. American Economic Review, vol. 62 (June): 323-332.

Leigh, Andrew. 2003. “Employment Effects of Minimum Wages: Evidence from a Quasi-Experiment.” The Australian Economic Review, Vol. 36, No. 4 (December), pp. 361-73.

Leigh, Andrew. 2007. Does raising the minimum wage help the poor? Economie Reeord 83(263):432-45.

Lemos, Sara. 2004. “Minimum Wage Policy and Employment Effects: Evidence from Brazil.” Economia. Vol. 5, No. 1 (Fall), pp. 219-66.

Lemos, Sara. 2007 “The Effects of the Minimum Wage in the Private and Public Sectors in Brazil.” Forthcoming in Journal of Development Studies.

Lemos, Sara. 2008. “A Survey of the Effects of the Minimum Wage on Prices.” Journal of Economic Surveys. Vol. 22, No. 1 (February), pp. 187-212.

Lemos, Sara. 2009. “Minimum Wage Effects in a Developing Country.” University of Leicester Discussion Paper 01/06.

Machin, S., Manning, A., 1994. Minimum wages, wage dispersion and employment: Evidence from the UK wages councils. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 47, 319–329.

Machin, Stephen, and Alan Manning. 1997. “Minimum Wages and Economic Outcomes in Europe.” European Economic Review. Vol. 41, Nos. 3-5 (April), pp. 733-42.

Machin, Stephen, Alan Manning, and Lupin Rahman. 2003. “Where the Minimum Wage Bites Hard: Introduction of Minimum Wages to a Low Wage Sector.” Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 1, No. 1 (March), pp. 154-80.

Machin, Stephen, and Joan Wilson. 2004. “Minimum Wages in a Low-Wage Labour Market: Care Homes in the UK.” Economic Journal. Vol. 114 (March), pp. C102-09.

Maloney, Tim. 1995. “Does the Minimum Wage Affect Employment and Unemployment in New Zealand.” New Zealand Economic Papers, Vol. 29, No. 1 (June), pp. 1-19.

Maloney, Tim. 1997. “The New Economics of the Minimum Wage? Evidence from New Zealand. Agenda, Vol. 4, No. 2 (June), pp. 185-96.

Maloney, William F., and Jairo Nuñez Mendez. 2004. “Measuring the Impact of Minimum Wages: Evidence from Latin America.” In James Heckman and Carmen Pagés, eds., Law and Employment: Lessons from Latin America and the Caribbean, pp. 109-30. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Mangan, John, and John Johnston. 1999. “Minimum Wages, Training Wages and Youth Employment.”International Journal of Social Economics, Vol. 26, No. 1/2/3, January-March, pp. 415-429.

Manning, Alan. 2003. Monopsony in Motion: Imperfect Competition in Labor Markets. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Mascella, Allison, Shahzia Teja, and Brennan S. Thompson. 2009. “Minimum Wage Increases as an Anti-poverty Policy in Ontario.” Canadian Public Policy. Vol. 35, No. 3. (September) pp. 373-79.

Page 43

Page 44: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Mattila, J. Peter. 1981. The Impact of Minimum Wages on Teenage Schooling and on the Part-Time/Full-Time Employment of Youths. In Rottenberg (1981a): 61-87.

McCulloch, J. Huston. 1981. Macroeconomic Implications of the Minimum Wage. In Rottenberg (1981a): 317-326.

Mehregan, Nader and Ruholah Rezaee. 2009. “Does Minimum Wage Cause Inflation?” Tahghighat-e-Eghtesadi. Vol. 44, No. 86. (Spring) pp. 253-66.

Meyer, Robert H., and Wise, David A. 1981. Discontinuous Distributions and Missing Persons: The Minimum Wage and Unemployed Youth. In Minimum Wage Study Commission (1981), vol. 5, pp. 175-201.

Meyer, R., Wise, D., 1983a. The effects of the minimum wage on the employment and earnings of youth. Journal of Labor Economics 1, 66–100.

Meyer, R., Wise, D., 1983b. Discontinuous distributions and missing persons: The minimum wage and unemployed youth. Econometrica 61, 1677–1698.

Michl, Thomas R. 2000. “Can Rescheduling Explain the New Jersey Minimum Wage Studies?” Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 26, No. 3, Summer, pp. 265-76.

Mincer, Jacob and Leighton, Linda. "The Effects of Minimum Wages on Human Capital Formation," in Simon Rottenberg, ed., The economics of legal minimum wages. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute. 1981, pp. 155-73.

Mincy, Ronald B. 1990. “Raising the Minimum Wage: Effects on Family Poverty.” Monthly Labor Review. Vol. 113, No. 7. (July) pp. 18-25.

Moore, Thomas G. 1971. The Effect of Minimum Wages on Teenage Unemployment Rates. Journal of Political Economy, vol. 79 (July/August): 897-902.

Muller, Kai-Uwe and Viktor Steiner. 2009. “Would a Legal Minimum Wage Reduce Poverty? A Micro-simulation Study for Germany.” Journal of Income Distribution. Vol. 18, No. 3-4. (September-December) pp.

131-51. Neumark, D., Wascher, W., 1992. Employment effects of minimum and sub-minimum wages: Panel data on state

minimum wage laws. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46, 55–81.

Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 1994. “Employment Effects of Minimum and Subminimum Wages: Reply to Card, Katz, and Krueger.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review. Vol. 47, No. 3 (April), pp. 497-512.

Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 1995a. “Minimum Wage Effects on Employment and School Enrollment.” Journal of Business and Economics Statistics. Vol. 13, No. 2 (April), pp. 199-206.

Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 1995b. “Minimum Wage Effects on School and Work Transitions of Teenagers.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings. Vol. 85, no. 2 (May), pp. 244-49.

Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 1996a. “Minimum Wage Effects on Employment and School Enrollment: Reply to Evans and Turner.” FEDS Working Paper 1996-28. Board of Governors of the Federal

Reserve System.

Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 1996b. “The Effects of Minimum Wages on Teenage Employment and Enrollment: Evidence from Matched CPS Surveys.” In Solomon Polachek, ed. Research in Labor

Page 44

Page 45: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Economics Vol. 15. Greenwich, Conn.: JAI Press.

Neumark, D. and Wascher, W. (1998). ‘Is time-series evidence on minimum wage effects contaminated by publication bias?’ Economic Inquiry, 36: 458–70.

—— and —— (2000). ‘Minimum wages and employment: a case study of the fastfood industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania: comment’. American EconomicReview, 90: 1362–96.

Neumark, David. 2001. “The Employment Effects of Minimum Wages: Evidence from a Prespecified Research Design.” Industrial Relations, Vol. 40, No. 1, January, pp. 121-44.

Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 2001. Using the EITC to help poor families: New evidence and a comparison with the minimum wage. National Tax Journal 54(3):281-317.

Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 2002. “State-Level Estimates of Minimum Wage Effects: New Evidence and Interpretations from Disequilibrium Models.” Journal of Human Resources. Vol. 37, No. 1 (Winter), pp. 35-62.

Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 2002. Do minimum wages fight poverty? Economic Inquiry 40(3):315-33.

Neumark, David, and William L. Wascher. 2003. “Minimum Wages and Skill Acquisition: Another Look at Schooling Effects.” Economics of Education Review. Vol. 22, No. 1 (February), pp. 1-10.

Neumark, David, and William Wascher. 2004. “Minimum Wages, Labor Market Institutions, and Youth Employment: A Cross-National Analysis.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 57, No. 2 (January), pp. 223-48.

Neumark, David, Mark Schweitzer, and William Wascher. 2005. “The Effects of Minimum Wages on the Distribution of Family Incomes: A Non-parametric Analysis.” Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 40, No. 4, pp. 867-917.

Neumark, David, Wendy Cunningham, and Lucas Siga. 2006. “The Effects of the Minimum Wage in Brazil on the Distribution of Family Incomes: 1996-2001.” Journal of Development Economics. Vol. 80, No. 1

(June), pp. 136-59.—— and—— (2007). ‘Minimum Wages and Employment’. Institute for the Study of Labor Discussion Paper No.

2570. Also as (2006) NBER Working Paper No. 12663.

Ni, Jinlan, Guangxin Wang, and Xianguo Yao. 2011. “Impact of Minimum Wages on Employment: Evidence from China.” Chinese Economy. Vol. 4, No. 1 (January-February) pp. 18-38.

OECD, 1994. The OECD Jobs Study: Evidence and Explanations. OECD, Paris.

Orazem, Peter F., and J. Peter Mattila. 2002. “Minimum Wage Effects on Hours, Employment, and Number of Firms: The Iowa Case.” Journal of Labor Research. Vol. 23, No. 1 (Winter), pp. 3-23.

Pabilonia, Sabrina Wulff. 2002. “The Effects of Federal and State Minimum Wages Upon Teen Employment and Earnings.” Unpublished manuscript. Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Partridge, Mark D., and Jamie S. Partridge. 1999a. “Do Low-Income Families Benefit from Minimum Wage Increases? Evidence from State-Level Minimum Wage Laws.” Review of Regional Studies. Vol. 29, No. 1. (Summer) pp. 37-50.

Page 45

Page 46: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Partridge, Mark D., and Jamie S. Partridge. 1999b. “Do Minimum Wage Hikes Reduce Employment? State-Level Evidence from the Low-Wage Retail Sector.” Journal of Labor Research. Vol. 20, No. 3 (Summer), pp. 393-413.

PBS. "Adkins v. Children's Hospital (1923)." PBS.http://www.pbs.org/wnet/supremecourt/capitalism/landmark_ adkins.html.

Pereira, Sonia C. 2003. “The Impact of Minimum Wages on Youth Employment in Portugal.” European Economic Review, Vol. 47, No. 2 (April) , pp. 229-44.

Potter, Nicholas. 2006. “Measuring the Employment Impacts of the Living Wage Ordinance in Santa Fe, New Mexico.” Unpublished paper, University of New Mexico Bureau of Business and Economic Research.

Prescott, Edward C. " The Elasticity of Labor Supply and the Consequences for Tax Polic." Minneapolis Federal Reserve Bank. http://www.minneapolisfed.org/research /prescott/papers/LaborSupply.pdf.

Ragan, J. F. (1981). ‘The effect of the legal minimum wage on the pay and employmentof teenage students and nonstudents’. In S. Rottenberg (ed.), The Economics of Legal Minimum Wages. Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute, pp. 11–41.

Rama, Martin. 2001. “The Consequences of Doubling the Minimum Wage: The Case of Indonesia.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 54, No. 4 (July), pp. 864-81.

Sabia, Joseph J. 2006. “The Effect of Minimum Wage Increases on Teenage, Retail, and Small Business Employment.” Unpublished paper, University of Georgia.

Sabia, Joseph J. 2008. Minimum wages and the economic well being of single mothers. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 27:848-66.

Sabia, Joseph J. 2009. “The Effects of Minimum Wage Increases on Retail Employment and Hours: New Evidence from Monthly CPS Data.” Journal of Labor Research. Vol. 30, No. 1 (Winter) pp. 75-97.

Sabia, Joseph J. and Richard V. Burkhauser. 2010. “Mínimum Wages and Poverty: Will a $9.50 Federal Minimum Wage Really Help the Working Poor?” Southern Economic Journal. Vol. 76, No. 3. pp. 592-623.

Saget, Catherine. 2001. “Poverty Reduction and Decent Work in Developing Countries: Do Minimum Wages Help?” International Labour Review. Vol. 140, No. 3 pp. 237-69.

Schiller, Bradley R. 1994. “State Minimum Wage Laws: Youth Coverage and Impact.” Journal of Labor Research. Vol. 15, No. 4 (Fall), pp. 317-329.

Sen, Aninyda, Kathleen Rybczynski, and Corey Van De Waal. 2011. “Teen employment, poverty, and the minimum wage: Evidence from Canada.” Labour Economics. Vol. 18, No. 1. (January) pp. 36-47.  

Singell, Larry D., and James R. Terborg. 2006. “Employment Effects of Two Northwest Minimum Wage Initiatives: Eating and Drinking and Hotel and Lodging.” Unpublished paper, University of Oregon.

Skedinger, Per. 2006. “Minimum Wages and Employment in Swedish Hotels and Restaurants.” Labour Economics, Vol. 13, No. 2 (April), pp. 259-90.

Page 46

Page 47: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Smith, Ralph E. and Bruce Vavichek. 1987. “The Minimum Wage: Its Relation to Incomes and Poverty.” Monthly Labor Review. Vol. 110, No. 6. (June) pp. 24-30.

Solon, G. (1985). ‘The minimum wage and teenage employment: a reanalysis with attention to serial correlation and seasonality’. Journal of Human Resources, 20: 292–7.

Spriggs, William E., and Bruce W. Klein. 1994. “Raising the Floor: The Effects of the Minimum Wage on Low-Wage Workers.” Washington DC: Economic Policy Institute.

Stevans, Lonnie K. and David N. Sessions. 2001. “Minimum Wage Policy and Poverty in the United States.” International Review of Applied Economics. Vol. 15, No. 1. (January) pp. 65-75.

Stewart, Mark B. 2002. “Estimating the Impact of the Minimum Wage Using Geographical Wage Variation.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics & Statistics, Vol. 64, Supplement, pp. 583-605.

Stewart, Mark B. 2004a. “The Impact of the Introduction of the U.K. Minimum Wage on the Employment Probabilities of Low-Wage Workers.” Journal of the European Economic Association, Volume 2, No. 1 (March), pp. 67-97.

Stewart, Mark B. 2004b. “The Employment Effects of the National Minimum Wage.” The Economic Journal, Vol. 114, No. 494 (March), pp. C110-116.

Stigler, George J. 1946. “The Economics of Minimum Wage Legislation.” American Economic Review. Vol. 36, No. 3 (June), pp. 358-65.

Strobl, Eric and Frank Walsh. 2003. “Minimum Wages and Compliance: The Case of Trinidad and Tobago.” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 51, No. 2 (January), pp. 427-50.

Suryahadi, Asep, Wenefrida Widyanti, Daniel Perwira, and Sudarno Sumarto. 2003. “Minimum Wage Policy and Its Impact on Employment in the Urban Formal Sector.” Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, Vol. 39, No. 1 (April), pp. 29-50.

Sutherland, H. 2001. “The National Minimum Wage and In-work Poverty.” Cambridge Working Papers in Economics.

Taylor, Jason E, and Peter G Klein. "An Anatomy of a Cartel: The National Industrial Recovery Act of 1933 and the Compliance Crisis of 1934." Research in Economic History 26 (2008): 1-46. http://web.missouri.edu/

~kleinp/papers/08021.pdf.

Turner, Mark D., and Berna Demiralp. 2001. “Do Higher Minimum Wages Harm Minority and Inner City Teens?” Review of Black Political Economy. Vol. 28, No. 4 (Spring), pp. 95-121.

Van Soest, A., Kapteyn, A., 1989. The Impact of Minimum Wage Regulations on Employment and the Wage Rate Distribution. Tilburg Discussion Paper No. 8947.

Wadsworth, Jonathan. 2010. “Did the National Minimum Wage Affect UK Prices?” Fiscal Studies. Vol. 31, No. 1. (March) pp. 81-120.

Warr, Peter. 2004. “Globalization, Growth, and Poverty Reduction in Thailand.” ASEAN Economic Bulletin. Vol. 21, No. 1. (April) pp. 1-18.

Page 47

Page 48: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Wellington, Alison. 1991. “Effects of the Minimum Wage on the Employment Status of Youths: An Update.” Journal of Human Resources. Vol. 26, No. 1 (Winter), pp. 27-46.

Wessels, Walter J. “A Reexamination of Card and Krueger’s State-Level Study of the Minimum Wage.” Forthcoming in Journal of Labor Research.

West Coast Hotel Co. v. Parrish, 300 U.S. 379 (1936), http://www.law.cornell.edu/supct/htm l/historics/USSC_CR_0300_0379_ZO.html.

Williams, Nicolas. 1993. “Regional Effects of the Minimum Wage on Teenage Employment.” Applied Economics. Vol. 25, No. 12 (December), pp. 1517-28.

Williams, Nicolas, and Jeffrey A. Mills. 2001. “The Minimum Wage and Teenage Employment: Evidence from Time Series.” Applied Economics. Vol. 33, No.3 (February), pp. 285-300.

Wolfson, Paul, and Dale Belman. 2004. “The Minimum Wage: Consequences for Prices and Quantities in Low-Wage Labor Markets.” Journal of Business and Economics Statistics. Vol. 22, No. 3 (July), pp. 296-311.

Yelowitz, Aaron S. 2005. “How Did the $8.50 Citywide Minimum Wage Affect the Santa Fe Labor Market.” Employment Policies Institute, Washington, D.C.

Yuen, Terence. 2003. “The Effect of Minimum Wages on Youth Employment in Canada: A Panel Study.” Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 38, No. 3 (Summer), pp. 647-72.

Zavodny, Madeline. 2000. “The Effect of the Minimum Wage on Employment and Hours.” Labour Economics. Vol. 7, No. 6 (November), pp. 729-750.

Page 48

Page 49: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

APPENDIX 1.GRAPH 1A.

Page 49

Page 50: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

GRAPH 2A.

Page 50

Page 51: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 51

Page 52: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

27

Page 52

Page 53: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

27 TABLE 1A

Page 53

Page 54: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

2829

28 TABLE 2A. Many of the results were taken from abstracts. Additionally, several of the papers and results were found in Neumark and Wschlers paper “Minimum Wages and Employment” (2007)29 TABLE 2A

Page 54

Page 55: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 55

Page 56: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 56

Page 57: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 57

Page 58: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 58

Page 59: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 59

Page 60: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 60

Page 61: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 61

Page 62: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 62

Page 63: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 63

Page 64: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 64

Page 65: The Myth of Manipulation The Economics of Minimum Wage

Page 65