25
Brigham Young University Brigham Young University BYU ScholarsArchive BYU ScholarsArchive Faculty Publications 2011-11-02 The Migratory Response of Labor to Special Economic Zones in The Migratory Response of Labor to Special Economic Zones in the Philippines, 1995–2005 the Philippines, 1995–2005 Scott R. Sanders Brigham Young University - Provo, [email protected] David L. Brown Cornell University Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarsarchive.byu.edu/facpub Part of the Migration Studies Commons, Other Sociology Commons, Regional Sociology Commons, and the Rural Sociology Commons BYU ScholarsArchive Citation BYU ScholarsArchive Citation Sanders, Scott R. and Brown, David L., "The Migratory Response of Labor to Special Economic Zones in the Philippines, 1995–2005" (2011). Faculty Publications. 4803. https://scholarsarchive.byu.edu/facpub/4803 This Peer-Reviewed Article is brought to you for free and open access by BYU ScholarsArchive. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of BYU ScholarsArchive. For more information, please contact [email protected], [email protected].

The Migratory Response of Labor to Special Economic Zones

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Brigham Young University Brigham Young University

BYU ScholarsArchive BYU ScholarsArchive

Faculty Publications

2011-11-02

The Migratory Response of Labor to Special Economic Zones in The Migratory Response of Labor to Special Economic Zones in

the Philippines, 1995–2005 the Philippines, 1995–2005

Scott R. Sanders Brigham Young University - Provo, [email protected]

David L. Brown Cornell University

Follow this and additional works at: https://scholarsarchive.byu.edu/facpub

Part of the Migration Studies Commons, Other Sociology Commons, Regional Sociology Commons,

and the Rural Sociology Commons

BYU ScholarsArchive Citation BYU ScholarsArchive Citation Sanders, Scott R. and Brown, David L., "The Migratory Response of Labor to Special Economic Zones in the Philippines, 1995–2005" (2011). Faculty Publications. 4803. https://scholarsarchive.byu.edu/facpub/4803

This Peer-Reviewed Article is brought to you for free and open access by BYU ScholarsArchive. It has been accepted for inclusion in Faculty Publications by an authorized administrator of BYU ScholarsArchive. For more information, please contact [email protected], [email protected].

The Migratory Response of Labor to Special EconomicZones in the Philippines, 1995–2005

Scott R. Sanders • David L. Brown

Received: 13 July 2009 / Accepted: 18 October 2011 / Published online: 2 November 2011

� Springer Science+Business Media B.V. 2011

Abstract In the mid 1990s the Filipino government adopted a new export-led

development policy in an attempt to attract new investments and lower the unem-

ployment rates throughout the country. The central idea was to provide foreign

investors more access to Filipino markets and labor by giving them investor tax

breaks and lowering trade tariffs. In return, the government hoped that investors

would bring large amounts of capital into designated areas thereby creating new

jobs and stimulating the domestic economy. The Filipino created the Philippine

Economic Zone Authority (PEZA) and Base Conversion Development Authority

(BCDA) to manage the operation of the Special Economic Zones (SEZ) throughout

the country. Between 1995 and 2005 PEZA and BCDA approved over 200 new SEZ

that have created over four million jobs throughout the country. However, these jobs

are concentrated in a small number of regions. This research uses a modified Harris-

Todaro model and GIS techniques to examine the inter-regional migration response

to the PEZA and BCDA programs’ geographically targeted investments. We show

that areas with the highest job growth have high rates of in-migration while regions

with low SEZ related investments have become migration-sending areas. In addi-

tion, our analysis shows that in-migration to SEZ affected areas has tended to

surpass available jobs resulting in high unemployment. We show how the Harris-

Todaro model in combination with GIS might be used to identify locations for

future PEZA and BCDA investments that are less likely to result in regional pop-

ulation loss or growth in unemployment.

S. R. Sanders (&)

Department of Development Sociology, Cornell University, 115 Warren Hall, Ithaca,

New York 14853, USA

e-mail: [email protected]

D. L. Brown

Department of Development Sociology, Cornell University,

338 Warren Hall, Ithaca, New York 14853, USA

123

Popul Res Policy Rev (2012) 31:141–164

DOI 10.1007/s11113-011-9220-7

Keywords Philippines � Labor migration � Special economic zones �Rural–urban migration � GIS

Introduction and Background

In the mid 1990s the Philippines adopted an export-led growth economic

development policy. Historically the Philippines engaged in protectionist policies

under the Marcos administration. These policies were designed to restrict foreign

ownership and control over business in the Philippines. However, with the fall of the

Marcos regime and the success of the Asian tigers, the Aquino and Ramos

administrations believed that Marcos’ longstanding protectionist policies had

prevented the Philippines from benefiting from the foreign direct investment led

economic boom in South East Asia during the late 1980s and early 1990s. The

Philippines inability to attract FDI was largely due to the remnant policy and

corruption from the Marcos era (Ringuet and Estrada 2003). As a result, in the mid

1990s the Filipino government adopted a new development policy in an attempt to

attract FDI.

The theory driving this new policy approach was centered on trade liberalization

and had the backing and encouragement of the World Bank and the United States.

These policies would also transform the Philippines economy from the inward

oriented policies of the Marcos regime to the outward export production-led model

that was succeeding in other South East Asian countries. The central idea was to

provide investors more access to Filipino markets and labor by easing restrictions on

property ownership, providing investors with tax breaks and lowering trade tariffs

(Guillermo 1996). In return, the government hoped that investors would focus their

investment of industrial capital in designated areas. These investments would create

new jobs that would then stimulate regional economies and eventually expand to

economic growth for the Philippines as a whole. In addition, the capital investments

needed to create new industrial jobs would provide funding for training,

infrastructure upgrades and utility improvements for the Philippines (Tolentino

1994). The allure of potential capital, together with pressure from the international

community, prompted the Filipino government to pursue large capital investments

and adopt an export-led growth strategy.

To implement this new strategy the Filipino government passed two major pieces

of legislation, Republic Act No. 7227, otherwise known as the Bases Conversion

and Development Act of 1992 and Republic Act No. 7916 (R.A. No. 7916 or the

‘‘Act’’) otherwise known as the Special Economic Zone Act of 1995. These bills

created the Base Conversion and Development Authority (BCDA) and the

Philippines Economic Zone Authority (PEZA) to help attract foreign investors,

and to target special areas within the Philippines thought to be particularly suitable

for special economic zones (SEZ). Foreign investments located within SEZ received

tax breaks and other financial incentives from the Filipino government. Today, over

200 SEZ have been created throughout the Philippines. These zones are directly

responsible for creating millions of new jobs and billions of dollars in foreign

investment (Philippines Congressional Planning and Budget Department 2003). At

142 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123

the national level, the Philippines’ strategy of export-led growth has succeeded in

attracting foreign investment and creating new jobs. However, it is unclear how the

influx of foreign capital has affected the regional distribution of the population and

migration flows within the Philippines. This paper examines how the establishment

of SEZ affected and facilitated the creation of new rural to urban migration flows in

the Philippines. These new rural to urban migration flows may have outpaced job

creation in regions with high concentrations of SEZ, and even lead to an increase in

unemployment. Because reliable migration data are not available at the provincial or

regional level for the Philippines, the examination of migration in the Philippines

can be difficult. However, this paper is able to map predicted changes in migration

flows using a modified Harris-Todaro model. Comparing regional wage discrep-

ancies, the Harris-Todaro model can estimate if there is a high propensity of

migration from one area to another. The scores estimated by the model are then

mapped to show changes in rural to urban migration flows for three different

periods, 1990–1995, 1995–2000, 2000–2005.

Creation of Infrastructure to Stimulate Export-Led Development

In the mid 1990s, BCDA and PEZA actively pursued foreign investment and created

SEZ as locations for new development. In 1992, the BCDA began to convert former

United States (US) military bases into economic centers for future SEZ (Bases

Conversion Development Authority 2006b). The conversion mainly targeted the

former US naval base in Subic Bay, Angeles Airbase northwest of Manila and Fort

John Hay in the northern Cordillera Administrative Region (CAR).1 The conversion

of these military bases into SEZ began in 1992, but the first SEZ were not

established until after 1995.

In 1995, PEZA was created to establish and manage all SEZ that were not located

on former US military bases. While SEZ are the geographic locations of targeted

economic development, they vary from extensive economic districts to concentrated

development within a single building. PEZA or BCDA used a variety of fiscal

incentives to attract business and investors to SEZ in the Philippines. Once an

investment is approved by PEZA or BCDA a company can begin operations within

the designated SEZ and immediately receive the financial benefits granted to it by

PEZA and BCDA. These incentives are diverse and significant. For example,

foreign investors can obtain tax and duty-free importation of capital equipment, raw

materials, spare parts and supplies; income tax holidays of 4–6 years; a special tax

rate of 5% of gross income earned in lieu of all national and local taxes; tax credits

for import substitution; and discounted prices on ‘‘underutilized’’ land (Bases

Conversion Development Authority 2006a; Philippines Economic Zone Authority

2006a).

1 Based on the 2000 census, the Philippines is divided up into 14 regions, including the Metro Manila

area. These regions are administrative divisions that serve primarily to organize the 81 provinces for

administrative and statistical convenience. Although the number of regions has changed over time, this

paper holds the 14 regions defined in the 2000 census constant throughout the paper.

The Migratory Response of Labor 143

123

The SEZ program was also designed to redistribute investment away from the

Metro Manila area by developing ‘‘underutilized land’’ into industrial centers. By

introducing SEZ into largely rural regions outside of Metro Manila, the Filipino

government planned to transform the nation’s economy from one based on

agriculture to a much greater dependence on industry. This transformation would

occur by creating industrial jobs within the SEZ, and by establishing peripheral

industries to support the needs of the SEZ, their businesses and employees. For

example, the steel industry generated jobs in the mills as well as in other industries

providing essential inputs for the mills as well as in other establishments that

produce a variety of manufactured exports using the steel. In addition, the

government believed that PEZA would generate a positive multiplier stimulating

Filipino employers because the day-to-day needs of factory workers and their

families were expected to be supplied by Filipino owned establishments (Guillermo

1996). The Filipino government hoped it could transform agricultural regions with

relatively few employers per hectare into industrial centers employing thousands of

workers and attracting international trade and business.

SEZ created by both BCDA and PEZA vary in size and type of operation from

the East Cyber Gate Building in Metro-Manila that houses software engineering

firms to the Bataan Export Processing Zone which is over 1,700 hectares and houses

factories that produce a broad array of products ranging from garments to agro-

chemicals (Philippines Economic Zone Authority 2006b). The main investments in

SEZ between 1995 and 2001 included electronic parts and products (64.3%),

electrical machinery (13.8%), and transport/car parts (7.4%) (Philippines Economic

Zone Authority 2006b).

When PEZA and BCDA were created, they were responsible for the operation of

a handful of SEZ, however by 2005 the number had grown to over 200 (Fig. 1).2

While SEZ have been established throughout the Philippines, they tend to

concentrate in particular parts of the country. As can be seen in Fig. 1, PEZA

and BCDA especially targeted Regions 3 and 4 for the development of SEZ. One

explanation for this concentration is that two former US military bases, Subic Bay

and Angeles Airbase, are located in Region 3. These two former bases fall under the

BCDA and account for 17 of 45 SEZ in the Region. Another reason for the

concentration of SEZ in Regions 3 and 4 is their well-developed infrastructure. In a

2002 study, Makabenta determined that sound infrastructure was the strongest

determining factor for investors and PEZA when selecting SEZ sites. Accordingly,

strong infrastructure in Regions 3 and 4 made them attractive locations for foreign

investors, for PEZA and for BCDA (Makabenta 2002). In addition, PEZA selected

Regions 3 and 4 in a conscious effort to spread economic growth from the Metro

2 The map below shows the location of all SEZ in the Philippines and divides the Philippines by region.

The remainder of the paper will examine how SEZ have impacted the Philippines on a regional level, and

are based on the 14 regions defined in the 2000 census. These regions are strictly for statistical geography

and have no political offices associated with them. Senators, governors and other political officials are

elected at the provincial level. However, regions are used by the census office and other national

government agencies as a useful level for reporting sub-national statistics. As a result, the regional level

was selected for analysis because consistent and accurate data are available from the Philippines

government, while data at the provincial level are more difficult to obtain and are less reliable.

144 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123

Manila area into its surrounding regions. For example, Region 4 was targeted as the

location of new manufacturing plants that required large amounts of land because

such sites were not available in the Metro Manila area. BCDA and PEZA hoped that

this targeted approach for the development of Regions 3 and 4 would increase

economic prosperity and lower the region’s unemployment rates. The development

of these regions would then give investors alternatives to the Metro Manila area

(Philippines Economic Zone Authority 2006b).

Have BCDA and PEZA Succeeded in Generating Economic Development?

Between 1995 and 2005 the BCDA and PEZA reported that over 3.1 million jobs

were created within the nation’s 200 SEZ (Bases Conversion Development

Authority 2001; Bases Conversion Development Authority 2006b; Philippines

Economic Zone Authority 2006c). As shown in Table 1, 46.6% of the new jobs

were created in Region 4 and 34.7% in Region 3. One reason so many more jobs

were created there than in any other region, approximately two million between

1995 and 2005, is that the majority of investments in Region 4’s SEZ have been

manufacturing plants that require a large amount of labor. In contrast, those created

in regions such as Metro Manila (NRC) tend to be software engineering and service

oriented businesses with smaller staff requirements (Philippines Economic Zone

Authority 2006b).3

Fig. 1 Location of SEZ, 2005. (Bases Conversion Development Authority 2006a; Philippines EconomicZone Authority 2006a)

3 Note: Table 1 shows the number of jobs directly created within SEZ. It does not include peripheral

jobs. In addition, there is a discrepancy between Fig. 1, the number of regions reporting SEZ, and

The Migratory Response of Labor 145

123

Since 1995, SEZ-created jobs in Regions 3 and 4 have grown faster and increased

more in total jobs than in any of the Philippine’s other regions. Since these figures

do not include the peripheral/support jobs that economists and government officials

anticipated would be generated with the establishment of SEZ, the total number of

new jobs in these regions could be well over two million. Ironically, however, the

creation of new jobs in SEZ has not resulted in lower unemployment levels in the

affected regions. Not only has the unemployment rate increased in Regions 3 and 4

since the establishment of SEZ, but the rate of increase has been higher than

elsewhere in the Philippines (See Table 2).

Paradoxically, at the same time that unemployment rates have increased in

Regions 3 and 4, these regions experienced the highest population growth rates in

the Philippines (2005 Philippines Statistical Yearbook, 2005). Moreover, our

analysis of the components of population change showed that population growth in

Regions 3 and 4 is largely the result of net in-migration.4 (See Table 3) Region 3

had a net migration of 8,51,757 between 2000 and 2005, 3,54,994 from 1995 to

2000 and 9,469 between 1990 and 1995. The same process showed that a net of

1,603,356 moved to Region 4 between 2000 and 2005, with an increase of

1,201,769 between 1995 and 2000 which is an increase of almost a million net in-

migrants compared with 2,16,099 between 1990 and 1995. In contrast, Regions such

Table 2 Unemployment rates

for Philippines, Regions 3 and 4,

1995–2005

National Statistical Coordination

Board 2006

Philippines (%) Region 3 (%) Region 4 (%)

1995 7.5 8.7 9

2000 8.4 10.1 11.3

2005 10.3 12.5 14.1

Table 1 Job growth attributed

to SEZ by selected Regions,

1995–2005

Bases Conversion Development

Authority (2006b); Philippines

Economic Zone Authority

(2006b)

Region Total SEZ Jobs Percentage of SEZ Jobs

CAR 44,686 1.1

NCR 1,21,747 2.9

Region 3 1,456,718 34.7

Region 4 1,958,764 46.6

Region 7 5,73,578 13.7

Region 8 30,906 0.7

Region 10 2,095 0.0

Region 12 13,263 0.3

Footnote 3 continued

Table 1, the number of regions reporting jobs. For example, Fig. 1 indicates that Region 11 had nine SEZ

but zero jobs. Any discrepancy between Fig. 1 and Table 1 can be attributed to one of two reasons. (1)

The SEZ in a region did not report the number of jobs created to BCDA or PEZA, or (2) the SEZ was

approved by BCDA or PEZA, but investors later pulled out. The later is the case of a number of SEZ in

Region 7 where plans to open shipyards to repair supertankers were relocated to Singapore (Philippines

Business Week, Nov. 11, 2004).4 We used the vital statistics method to estimate migration at the regional level between 1990 and 2005.

146 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123

Ta

ble

3N

etm

igra

tio

n,

nat

ura

lin

crea

sean

dg

row

thra

tes

for

all

Reg

ions,

19

90–

20

05

Net

mig

rati

on

Nat

ura

lin

crea

seG

row

thra

te

90

–9

59

5–

00

00

–05

90

–95

95

–00

00

–05

90

–95

95

–0

00

0–

05

Met

roM

anil

aa4

84

,01

02

60

,58

34

37

,64

71

,021

,63

87

17

,93

77

83

,22

03

.31

.56

2.1

1

CA

R-

20

,72

8-

14

,35

9-

45

,94

91

29

,37

51

24

,93

32

01

,28

01

.71

1.8

21

.5

Reg

.1

-1

18

,41

43

00

,31

13

2,6

28

37

1,6

62

96

,27

73

12

,80

01

.32

.15

1.1

Reg

.2

-6

7,3

92

47

,47

5-

12

4,9

26

26

2,8

82

22

9,6

49

36

3,2

54

1.5

12

.25

1.1

3

Reg

.3

9,4

69

35

4,9

94

85

1,7

57

72

4,0

84

74

3,3

81

83

8,2

80

2.1

23

.17

2.3

6

Reg

.4

21

6,0

99

1,2

01

,769

1,6

03

,356

96

3,8

98

1,0

48

,790

90

5,8

90

3.5

34

.03

3.2

4

Reg

.5

-4

5,9

16

-6

3,5

19

49

,07

84

61

,22

24

24

,88

13

74

,05

11

.91

1.6

81

.23

Reg

.6

-4

5,8

19

46

,92

72

01

,08

84

29

,42

43

87

,17

34

31

,51

71

.31

.56

1.3

5

Reg

.7

13

8,6

12

40

2,1

16

17

9,7

67

55

9,0

76

29

0,2

49

51

1,9

08

1.6

52

.81

1.5

9

Reg

.8

98

,64

13

6,0

08

5,4

25

21

3,7

86

20

7,4

30

29

7,1

56

1.8

41

.51

1.1

2

Reg

.9

77

,29

47

6,7

60

-7

8,2

10

25

7,6

75

21

9,7

89

21

7,0

96

2.4

22

.12

1.8

3

Reg

.1

0-

35

,24

01

0,0

80

18

7,7

14

32

0,9

58

25

4,2

33

25

9,1

38

2.3

21

.99

1.6

7

Reg

.1

11

06

,07

11

97

,85

8-

13

4,9

93

49

1,3

56

38

7,3

19

31

6,6

11

2.6

42

.41

1.7

1

Reg

.1

21

32

,29

91

96

,52

91

91

,64

01

94

,55

11

73

,88

02

25

,28

22

.83

2.6

92

.41

Nat

ion

alS

tati

stic

alC

oo

rdin

atio

nB

oar

d2

00

6;

Ph

ilip

pin

esN

atio

nal

Cen

sus

(19

98a,

b);

Ph

ilip

pin

esN

atio

nal

Cen

sus

(20

05)

aT

he

calc

ula

tio

ns

for

the

Met

roM

anil

aar

eaex

clu

de

the

mun

icip

alit

ies

of:

Pas

ig,

Pas

ayan

dM

anil

aci

ty.

Th

ese

thre

ear

eas

wer

en

etin

-mig

ran

tar

eas

wit

hp

osi

tiv

e

po

pu

lati

on

gro

wth

rate

sab

ov

e2

in1

99

5an

d2

00

5.

Ho

wev

er,

the

Ph

ilip

pin

es2

00

0C

ensu

sin

dic

ates

that

thes

ear

eas

exp

erie

nce

dn

egat

ive

gro

wth

rate

sas

hig

has

-3.

Itis

un

clea

rif

this

dat

ais

accu

rate

or

the

resu

lto

fm

easu

rem

ent

erro

r.A

sa

resu

lt,

Pas

ig,

Pas

ayan

dM

anil

aci

tyh

ave

bee

nre

mo

ved

fro

mth

eca

lcu

lati

on

s

The Migratory Response of Labor 147

123

as 10 and 12 which created fewer SEZ jobs had much lower rates of population

change and less net in-migration.

While these data show that Regions 3 and 4 were the destination for a substantial

increase in net in-migration, they do not show the migrant origins or how patterns of

migration flows have shifted since the establishment of the SEZ program in 1995.

This information is needed to determine if the creation of SEZ by PEZA and BCDA

resulted in new flows of in-migration and to identify regions of continuing out-

migration where development policy might focus in the future. In addition, as is

known from network-based theories of migration like cumulative causation, once a

new migration stream is created, it will persist over time (Massey 1990; Massey

1999). This is because social networks are created that break down barriers to

migration, increase the flow of information about economic and social conditions in

the destination and reduce the overall risk of migrating to new areas. As a result, to

understand the SEZ’s effect on migration flows it is essential to know more than just

net migration. We use the Harris and Todaro (1970) model to predict the origin,

destination, magnitude and direction of migration flows in the Philippines between

1995 and 2005, since the inception of the PEZA and BCDA programs.

Why Job Growth and Growth of Unemployment Rates Coincidein the Same Regions

In cases where the job growth and the unemployment rate have both increased, the

Harris-Todaro model can be used to predict the propensity of migration based on the

expectation of wage gains. The model implies that if there is a sufficient difference

between expected urban and rural wages it is economically rational for migration to

occur from rural areas to urban areas even if both have high levels of

unemployment.5 In other words, net rural to urban migration results in an increase

in both urban population size and unemployment because the increased number of

job seekers that migrate to an urban area and compete for available jobs will swell

the unemployment rate’s denominator.

The original Harris-Todaro model has been modified and simplified to fit varying

market and labor conditions (Bell 1991; Fields 1975; Stiglitz 1974). The simplified

Harris-Todaro model states that equilibrium is reached when the expected rural

wage is equal to the expected urban wage when adjusted for the urban area’s

unemployment rates. The formal statement of the Harris-Todaro model is as

follows:

• wr = the wage in the rural agricultural sector

• lue = the total number of employed urban workers

• lus = the total number of job seekers in the urban sector

• wu = the wage in the urban sector

5 The Harris-Todaro model was developed to explain rural–urban migration in developing contexts. The

terms ‘‘urban’’ and ‘‘rural,’’ hence are generic labels for origin and destination. The model is not limited

for use on rural–urban migration.

148 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123

At equilibrium,

wr ¼lue

lus

wu

In other words, equilibrium is reached when the expected rural wage (wr) equals

the expected urban wage (wu), when the urban wage is multiplied by the number of

available urban jobs (lue) over the total number of both unemployed and employed

laborers in the urban sector (lus) or lue

lus

� �. If the urban wage (wu) after it has been

adjusted for urban unemployment lue

lus

� �is higher than the rural wage (wr), then rural

to urban migration is expected to occur:

wr\lue

lus

wu

Conversely, urban to rural migration will occur if:

wr [lue

lus

wu

Therefore, migration from rural areas to urban areas will increase if:

• Urban wages (wu) increase, increasing the expected urban income

• Urban unemployment (lus) decreases, increasing the expected urban income

• Urban job creation increases the number of available jobs in the urban sector

(lue), increasing the expected urban income

• Agricultural productivity decreases, lowering wages in the agricultural sector

(wr), decreasing the expected rural income

Also, rural to urban migration is possible if the urban wage after it is discounted

for the urban unemployment rate lue

lus

wu

� �is lower than the rural wage rate (wr).

Therefore, equilibrium is achieved when the discounted urban wage is equal to the

rural wage.

The model is based on three assumptions: (1) that the labor pool has the skills

needed to fill any job opening in either rural or urban labor markets, (2) agrarian

employment, subsistence farming, day laborer etc., is always an option for people in

rural areas and (3) migration is risk neutral. The first assumption is realistic with

respect to SEZ. The overwhelming majority of the jobs created are low skill

manufacturing and service jobs, and the skill set needed to obtain these jobs is

common to most of the Filipino labor force. Therefore, it is unlikely that a

significant number of urban jobs are being created that cannot be filled by rural

migrants. The second assumption holds for many parts of the Philippines because

employment rates in primarily rural regions rage from 96 to 99% (Philippines

National Statistics Office 1998a). However, regions like Metro Manila and Regions

3 and 4, which are largely urban, have employment rates lower than 90%.

Therefore, to ensure that the model produces reliable migration estimates a modified

Harris-Todaro model will be used where both rural and urban wage rates will be

discounted by unemployment.

The Migratory Response of Labor 149

123

In the modified Harris-Todaro model lre equals the total number of employed

rural workers and lrs equals the total number of job seekers in the rural sector. Rural

unemployment, lrs and lrs, will then discount the rural wage, wr, and be compared to

the urban sector lue

lus

wu

� �. Therefore, at equilibrium the modified model is:

lre

lrswr¼

lue

lus

wu

Finally, the third assumption assumes there is no risk or loss associated with

migration. This assumption is not practical in the real world. There are many

obvious risks associated in migration. Migrants could be promised a job, but none

are available when they arrive in the new area, theft or accidents can occur during

the actual migration, migrants could be socially rejected in their new communities

or adequate housing may not be available in the new area. This assumption that

migration is risk neutral causes the model to overstate the likelihood of migration. In

order to adjust for this, we will only map significant migration flows, e.g., those with

an HT-score that is B1.10.

Applying the Harris-Todaro Model to Inter-Regional Migrationin the Philippines

The Harris-Todaro model is a two-sector analysis between pairs of urban and rural

regions. In order to apply the model and map the resulting migration flows

throughout the Philippines, the model is calculated between pairs of regions, for

example the Metro Manila area and Region 1. In every calculation the regional

weighted average minimum wage is calculated from government data and used for

either wr or wu depending on whether the region is considered to be urban or rural.

The regional weighted average minimum wage is calculated by first determining the

provincial average minimum wage by taking the provincial minimum wage for both

rural and urban sectors and weighting them according to their respective

populations. Once the provincial average minimum wage has been created for all

the provinces in a region, the regional weighted average minimum wage is

calculated by averaging the provincial weighted average minimum wages and

weighting them by their respective total populations.

The selection of the urban labor sector or,lue

lus

wu is based on the percentage of

urban population for each region. For each calculation between two regions, the

region with the higher percentage of urban population in each pair is designated as

the urban sector and its regional weighted average wage is used to calculate wu.6

6 Urban and rural populations are based on 2005 PopCen definitions and held constant through each time

period. The Philippine National Statistics Coordination Board defines barangay (similar to a village or

neighborhood) as urban if a barangay: (1) has a population size of 5,000 or more, or (2) has at least one

establishment with a minimum of 100 employees, or (3) has 5 or more establishments with a minimum of

10 employees, and 5 or more facilities within the 2 km radius from the barangay hall. Using this

definition, the total urban and rural populations were aggregated to the regional level for 1995, 2000 and

2005.

150 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123

Therefore the region with the lower percentage of urban population in each pair is

selected as rural sector and its regional weighted average wage used as wr. For

example Metro Manila area, which has the highest percentage of urban population,

is always selected as the urban region and its regional weighted average wage is

used as wu. For selection of the rural region, Cordillera Administrative Region

(CAR) is always selected as the rural sector and wr because it has the lowest

percentage of urban population. This process was used to determine the urban and

rural sectors in each pair of the 91 possible pairings of regions in the Philippines.

Each paired comparison was calculated for three time points: 1995, 2000 and 2005.

In order to map migration flows and determine the significance of their changes

over time, the results of each Harris-Todaro model are expressed as the proportionlue

lus

wu over lrelrs

wr (see below). The resulting number is termed the HT score. To

produce this score the equilibrium model was modified to:

lue

luswu

lrelrs

wr

¼ 1 ; where 1 = HT score

Rural to urban migration occurs when the HT score is greater than one, with the

tendency for migration increasing with higher HT scores:

lue

luswu

lrelrs

wr

[ 1

Conversely, urban to rural migration will occur if the HT score is lower than one:

lue

luswu

lrelrs

wr

\1

1990–1995 Net Migration Flows According to the Harris-Todaro Model

The resulting HT scores were used to map the migration predictions throughout the

Philippines. By using ArcGIS and Tobler’s Flow Mapper the variation and change

of migration flows was mapped for the periods 1990–1995, 1995–2000 and

2000–2005.

The mapped flows (see Fig. 2) represent calculated differences between the

expected wages in Regions 2, 8, 9, 10 and 12 and the expected wage in Metro

Manila area between 1990 and 1995, and range from five to eight pesos per day.

Figure three shows all migration flows with significant HT scores. All other regions

reported either zero migration or insignificant HT scores. The data in Fig. 2 show

migration flows to Manila predicted by the Harris-Todaro model between 1990 and

1995, when PEZA had just been established. As can be seen, only minor flows from

smaller rural regions to Metro Manila area are predicted at that time. The map

shows predicted migration flows with a HT score of 0.91–0.95 which equals a 5–9%

difference in expected average daily regional wage. For example, the average

regional wage after being discounted for unemployment in Region 8 is 88 pesos a

The Migratory Response of Labor 151

123

day while in Metro Manila Area the average wage after unemployment is accounted

for is 101 pesos. That means the average worker in Region 8 can expect to earn 40

extra pesos a week if they choose to migrate to the Metro Manila Area.

These predictions are consistent with census migration data from 1990 to 1995

which show that most large migration flows within the Philippines originated in

southern regions. In addition, the Harris-Todaro model indicates that Regions 8 and 9

had the highest propensity for migration. This finding is consistent with 1995 census

data that indicated that Regions 8 and 9 had the highest number of migrants to the

Metro Manila Area. The 1995 census indicated that Metro Manila gained 52,541

migrants from Region 9 and 46,452 migrants from Region 8 (Philippines National

Statistical Coordination Board, 1997). These predictions are also consistent with

Fig. 2 Significant inter-regional HT migration flows Between 1990 and 1995

152 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123

population growth patterns for this time period. The Metro Manila Area reported

higher annual growth rates than any other region between 1990 and 1995, 3.3%

compared with a national average of 2.3%. Therefore, the migration tendencies

predicted by the model are supported by census data and appear to accurately depict

overall migration trends between 1990 and 1995.

1995–2000 Migration Flows Centered on the Metro Manila Area

The Harris-Todaro model predicts an increase in the amount of interregional

migration between 1995 and 2000 (see Fig. 3). The Metro Manila Area continued to

be the largest destination for net in-migration with increased volumes of predicted

Fig. 3 Significant inter-regional HT migration flows Between 1995 and 2000

The Migratory Response of Labor 153

123

in-migration from the existing 1990–1995 migration origin areas as well as from

new regions. Region 5, located southeast of Manila, is predicted to have the highest

propensity for out migration to Manila. Its HT Score of 1.32 equals a 43%

difference in expected wages compared with the Metro Manila Area after

unemployment in Metro Manila is accounted for. Even after unemployment is

controlled, the expected average daily wage in Metro Manila compared with Region

5 is greater than 38 pesos a day, or a net gain of 192 pesos per week. Considering

the average daily income for Region 5 was 89 pesos, this difference in income helps

to illustrate why migration to the Metro Manila Area makes economic sense

(Philippines National Statistical Coordination Board 2001).

1995–2000 Migration Flows Centered on Region 3

The data in Fig. 3 show that Region 3 had the largest flows of in-migration from

Regions 5, and 8 during 1995–2000 as well as other minor flows from CAR,

Regions 1, 9 and 12. This is strikingly different than between 1990 and 1995 when

Region 3 received very little migration from other regions. During this time Region

3 went from 9,469 net in-migrants between 1990 and 1995 to 354,994 net in-

migrants between 1995 and 2000. It seems likely that increased migration to Region

3 is a result of job generation associated with SEZ established by both BCDA and

PEZA. The largest flow to Region 3 originated from Region 8. The HT Score for

migration from Region 8 to Region 3 is 1.32 or a 21.5% difference in the expected

daily wage. This is equal to 19 pesos a day or 95 pesos a week.

This predicted migration flow between Regions 3 and 8 based on the HT model is

supported by census data on ethnicity. Region 8 is the home of one of the

Philippine’s major ethnic groups, the Eastern Visayan and Waray. Between 1995

and 2000 Region 3 reported a 47% increase in the number of Visayans, and a 10%

in the number of Waray (Philippines National Statistical Coordination Board 1998b;

Philippines National Statistical Coordination Board 2006). Hence, the census

ethnicity data provide corroborating support to the HT migration predictions for

Region 3.7

1995–2000 Migration Flows Centered on Region 4

Region 4 also experienced a dramatic increase in the amount of net in-migration

between 1995 and 2000 (see Fig. 3). Migration flows to Region 4 are consistent

with the region’s increased population growth rate between 1995 and 2000. During

7 We acknowledge that there are limitations using ethnicity as means to support the models predicted

findings. Due to the limitation of data, we do not know the specific origin of these new ethnic households.

Many residents in Northern Mindanao, including Region 10, speak the Visayan language. We were not

able to obtain more detailed migration and ethnicity census ‘‘public use data’’ from the NSO. However,

while the data used to support the models findings are limited, results do show an increased south to north

migration pattern consistent with the models findings and the theory of cumulative causation.

154 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123

this time, the annual population growth rate of Region 4 surpassed the growth rate

of the Metro Manila Area and became the country’s fastest growing region. It is

likely that the rapid increase of jobs created within SEZ located in Region 4

contributed significantly to the increased number of migrants to Region 4.

The strongest predicted migration in-flows to Region 4 are from Regions 5 and 8.

The difference in expected average daily wage when unemployment is account for

in Region 4 is 19% or 17 pesos a day in Region 5, and 18% or 16 pesos a day in

Region 8. Similar to Region 3, census data on ethnicity provide corroborating

evidence consistent with the HT model’s migration prediction for Region 4. In

2000, the National Statistics Office reported that Region 4 experienced a 45%

increase in the number of people who classify themselves as Visayan and a 14%

increase in Waray, the major ethnic groups in Region 8, and a 37% increase in the

number of people classifying themselves as Bikol, the major ethnic group in Region

5 (Philippines National Census 1998b; Philippines National Census 2006). The

increase in Visayan and Bikol populations helps to account for the two largest

migration in-flows to Region 4. The likelihood of migration to Region 4 from

Region 5 and 8 is also supported by the fact that the national highway runs from

Region 8 through Region 5 and directly into Region 4. Issah et al. (2005) report that

the presence of infrastructure facilitates migration by removing potential logistical

barriers for migrants and by increasing the flow of employment information

between urban and rural areas (Issah et al. 2005). Accordingly, the 1995–2000

Harris-Todaro migration predictions for Region 4 are consistent with census data

and other research findings.

1995–2000 Migration Flows and Estimates by the Residual Method

Migration estimates using the residual method confirm the results derived from the

Harris-Todaro method. While residual estimates yield a net migration figure for

each region, they do not produce flows data between various origin and destination

regions as is possible with the Harris-Todaro method. Accordingly, the residual

migration analysis is presented as a way of evaluating the reliability of the Harris-

Todaro estimates shown above. The residual population was calculated for all

regions between 1995 and 2000. This was done for each region by subtracting the

total number of registered deaths from the total number of registered births. The

resulting natural increase was then subtracted from the difference in population

between 1995 and 2000. Compared with 1995, Region 4 had a residual population

of 1,201,769 in 2000 while Region 3 had a residual population of 3,54,944. These

two regions had the highest net in-migration in the Philippines between 1995 and

2000. In contrast, Region 5 had a substantial net migration loss with a residual of -

63,519. Regions 8, 9 and CAR also recorded negative residual populations or a

decrease in net in-migration, which are consistent with the 2000 HT-scores. While

these data do not show origins and destinations of the migration flows, they confirm

that net in-migration is occurring to Regions 3 and 4 at the same time that net out-

migration is occurring in Regions 5, 8, 9 and CAR.

The Migratory Response of Labor 155

123

Migration Flows Between 2000 and 2005

The data in Fig. 4 show that the migration flows to the Metro Manila Area predicted

by the HT model for 2000–2005 are similar to those predicted during the previous

5 years. Although there are some slight variations in the magnitude of the flows, the

overall trends are similar to those predicted between 1995 and 2000. The 2005

model predicts that Metro Manila has remained the Philippines major destination for

internal migration.

The data in Fig. 4 also show migration flows to Regions 3 and 4 during 2000 and

2005. These data indicate that Region 3 continued to attract migrants from southern

regions between 2000 and 2005. However, the largest source of in-migration shifted

from Regions 5 and 8 in 2000 to Region 9 during the 2000–2005 period. All other

Fig. 4 Significant inter-regional HT migration flows Between 2000 and 2005

156 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123

2005 migration predictions for Region 3 were similar to those shown for 2000. The

2000–2005 HT model predictions for Region 4 show that migration flows to the

region originated in an increased number of locations. Overall, the model shows that

migration to Region 4 continued to increase in 2005 and are consistent with residual

estimations of migration that show negative net migration in Region 9 with

decreased net migration in Regions 1, 8 and 12.

Mapping predicted migration flows with the modified Harris-Todaro model

illustrated that migration flows have shifted to Regions 3 and 4 after PEZA and

BCDA began locating SEZ in these regions. This indicates that the jobs created in

the SEZ in Regions 3 and 4 have increased the number of migrants to the area,

which helps to explain why both population and the rate of unemployment have

steadily increased in Regions 3 and 4 since 1995.

In addition, it is likely that increased migration to Regions 3 and 4 will continue.

Consistent with Massey’s theory of cumulative causation, each additional migrant

helps to create the social structure needed to sustain further migration flows (Massey

1990; Massey 1999). Social networks and capital flows between origins and

destinations increase the flow of information about the job market, housing and

other living conditions, thereby reducing the costs and risks associated with

migration. As a result, once a new migration flow is created it will increase in

strength over time. The analysis shows that Regions 3 and 4 became new

destinations for internal migrants during 1995 and 2000, subsequent to the

establishment of the PEZA and BCDA development programs and their resulting

SEZ. Moreover, these new migration flows to Regions 3 and 4 between 1995 and

2000 increased in strength during the next 5 years, indicating that the social

structures promoting migration to these areas has strengthened. Hence, the Harris-

Todaro predictions of Filipino migration flows between 1995 and 2005 are

consistent with migration theory and reflect PEZAs and BCDAs roles in

redistributing the nation’s population.

Conclusions and Policy Implications

The implementation of PEZA and BCDA in 1995 has resulted in substantial

population redistribution within the Philippines. Consistent with the Harris-Todaro

model, rural workers moved from low wage rural areas to more highly urbanized

regions where the PEZA and BCDA programs had established SEZ as the location

of highly subsidized economic development schemes. This research shows that this

population redistribution increases the pressure on urban labor markets to integrate a

growing number of potential workers. Accordingly, the urban unemployment rate

has tended to increase because the number of in-migrating workers has exceeded the

number of new jobs created. Our analysis shows that high levels of rural to urban

migration result between 1995 and 2005 in regions where the PEZA and BCDA

programs have produced the most jobs. Moreover, the research showed that these

same regions experienced increased higher than average increases in unemployment

despite the large number of jobs created by PEZA and BCDA. If reduced

unemployment is one of PEZA’s and BCDA’s goals, we believe that program

The Migratory Response of Labor 157

123

managers should take the geo-spatial location of SEZ into consideration, and direct

FDI into areas with a lower propensity for in-migration. Because migration data

from the Philippines national census is limited, this research suggests that PEZA

and BCDA consider using the modified Harris-Todaro model to identify

geographical areas with a low current migration potential. As a result, they would

be able to map internal migration between origins and destinations thereby

identifying locations where economic development would absorb excess rural labor

rather than stimulating rural out-migration to Manila or Regions 3 and 4 where SEZ

are currently concentrated. In addition, since the model is based on quarterlyprovincial minimum wages, inter-provincial migration estimates could be updated

frequently thereby providing an accurate representation of current migration trends

and potentials.

Using the HT Scores to Identify Potential SEZ Sites

Figure 5 demonstrates how PEZA and BCDA officials could use the modified

Harris-Todaro model to identify future SEZ locations. By using an advanced

interpolation technique in ArcGIS called kriging, a map can be produced that shows

the variation of migration likelihoods throughout the Philippines (ESRI 2007).

Kriging uses the average HT score for each region, and then calculates the value of

unknown cells across a statistical surface. The resulting map then shows the average

HT score for 2005 across the entire Philippines. From this map it is easy to

recognize areas that have an average HT score below 1 indicating a low propensity

for in-migration. PEZA, BCDA and potential investors can then overlay the location

of national highways, major ports, airports and other variables that investors require

to find a location that meets both the business and logistical needs of future investors

and is located in an area currently experiencing low in-migration (Philippines

Economic Zone Authority 2006b).

Figure 5 was calculated using the 2005 HT scores. Areas with the highest

propensity for in-migration are shown in black; areas with the lowest potential are

colored white. As expected, the map shows that the Metro-Manila area and parts of

Region 3 and 4 have the highest tendency for in-migration. According to the Harris-

Todaro model, any additional development or job creation in these areas is likely to

increase the migration flow, causing additional pressure on urban labor markets and

a probable increase in unemployment rates. In contrast, the analysis identifies four

areas with low migration potential that might be good locations for future SEZ sites.

Starting in the north, the analysis identifies the Laoag metropolitan area as a

potential location for future SEZ. The city is connected with the Metro Manila area

by national highways and has convenient access to a number of ports in the region.

It also has the third largest international airport in the Philippines with regularly

scheduled flights to Taiwan. San Fernando metropolitan area is another possible

sight for SEZ in the northern Philippines. The city has the largest port in the

northern Philippines and is connected to Manila by multiple highways. Locating

SEZ in either of these locations would help to establish an economic center for the

northern Philippines. In addition, because of the region’s current low propensity of

158 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123

in-migration, new jobs created in either of these locations are not likely to result in

increased unemployment rates and regional out-migration.

The Iloilo metropolitan area and Metropolitan Cebu are also possible locations

for future SEZ given that have the second and third largest ports in the Philippines

respectfully. Cebu also has the second largest airport in the Philippines. The one

drawback of locating in this area is a lack of national highway connections with the

rest of the nation’s spatial economy. Because these two cities are located on islands,

ground transportation is limited. However, because companies in SEZ must be

engaged in exportation, the large ports and airports located there would seem to be

Fig. 5 Map of 2005 HT scores showing migration tendencies

The Migratory Response of Labor 159

123

strong inducement for many investors. Also, based on the Harris-Todaro model,

these areas have some of the highest current out-migration flows in the country. The

formation of an economic center in the southern tier of the Philippines similar to the

one established by PEZA in Region 4 would help to alleviate migration to Metro-

Manila as well as to Regions 3 and 4. As a result, economic development would be

spread more widely throughout the nation, and the pressure on urban labor markets

might be lessened thereby diminishing the urban unemployment rate.

This paper demonstrates the benefits of considering policy impacts at a

disaggregated regional level. The regional level migration model used in this

research illuminates how the Philippines’ regional development policies (PEZA and

BCDA) have affected regions differently by placing SEZ in some regions rather

than in others. As a consequence, PEZA and BCDA contribute to regional

inequality, stimulating job and population growth in some areas and out-migration

from others. The Harris-Todaro model and GIS techniques used in this research

demonstrate how spatial models can be used by policymakers for gaining insights

into the relative merits of alternative locations as sites of future SEZ.

Appendix

See Appendix Table 4, 5 and 6.

160 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123

Ta

ble

4H

Tsc

ore

s,1

99

0–

19

95

NC

RC

AR

Reg

ion

1R

egio

n2

Reg

ion

3R

egio

n4

Reg

ion

5R

egio

n6

Reg

ion

7R

egio

n8

Reg

ion

9R

egio

n1

0R

egio

n1

1R

egio

n1

2

NC

R–

0.9

60

.99

0.9

20

.99

0.9

80

.99

0.9

30

.90

0.9

30

.94

0.9

50

.95

0.9

4

CA

R1

.03

–1

.04

1.0

21

.03

1.0

01

.00

1.0

41

.07

1.0

31

.04

1.0

61

.06

1.0

5

Reg

ion

11

.08

1.0

2–

0.9

71

.03

1.0

21

.05

0.9

91

.06

0.9

80

.99

1.0

11

.01

1.0

0

Reg

ion

21

.11

1.0

71

.04

–1

.09

1.0

91

.01

1.0

41

.01

1.0

31

.05

1.0

61

.07

1.0

5

Reg

ion

30

.95

1.0

50

.96

1.0

5–

0.9

80

.95

1.0

51

.01

1.0

51

.05

1.0

51

.05

1.0

5

Reg

ion

41

.06

0.9

91

.06

0.9

51

.01

–1

.03

0.9

71

.03

0.9

60

.97

0.9

80

.99

0.9

7

Reg

ion

51

.08

1.0

21

.08

0.9

81

.00

1.0

3–

0.9

91

.01

0.9

91

.00

1.0

11

.02

1.0

0

Reg

ion

61

.03

1.0

31

.02

1.0

81

.02

1.0

51

.07

–1

.07

1.0

91

.01

1.0

21

.02

1.0

1

Reg

ion

71

.09

1.0

21

.09

0.9

81

.03

1.0

31

.06

0.9

9–

0.9

81

.00

1.0

11

.02

1.0

0

Reg

ion

81

.12

1.0

11

.07

1.0

51

.02

1.0

21

.04

1.0

71

.04

–1

.07

1.0

91

.09

1.0

8

Reg

ion

91

.13

1.0

11

.07

1.0

51

.02

1.0

11

.04

1.0

71

.04

1.0

6–

1.0

91

.09

1.0

8

Reg

ion

10

1.1

11

.07

1.0

41

.02

1.0

81

.09

1.1

11

.04

1.0

91

.03

1.0

4–

1.0

61

.05

Reg

ion

11

1.0

81

.08

1.0

51

.04

1.0

21

.03

1.0

01

.05

1.0

11

.04

1.0

61

.07

–1

.06

Reg

ion

12

1.1

21

.08

1.0

01

.03

1.0

11

.08

1.0

91

.05

1.0

21

.04

1.0

51

.07

1.0

7–

So

urc

e:P

hil

ippin

esN

atio

nal

Sta

tist

icO

ffice

(19

97)

The Migratory Response of Labor 161

123

Ta

ble

5H

Tsc

ore

s,1

99

5–

200

0

NC

RC

AR

Reg

ion

1R

egio

n2

Reg

ion

3R

egio

n4

Reg

ion

5R

egio

n6

Reg

ion

7R

egio

n8

Reg

ion

9R

egio

n1

0R

egio

n1

1R

egio

n1

2

NC

R–

1.2

81

.24

1.2

31

.02

1.0

61

.34

1.1

41

.17

1.3

91

.18

1.1

71

.19

1.2

8

CA

R0

.79

–1

.06

1.0

10

.92

1.1

71

.09

1.0

81

.01

1.0

21

.01

1.0

11

.02

1.0

4

Reg

ion

10

.75

1.0

2–

0.9

50

.87

0.9

01

.09

1.0

10

.96

1.0

51

.07

0.9

50

.96

1.0

8

Reg

ion

20

.83

1.0

31

.02

–0

.97

1.0

01

.09

1.0

31

.06

1.0

81

.19

1.0

51

.06

1.0

0

Reg

ion

30

.95

1.1

91

.14

1.0

8–

1.0

41

.27

1.0

91

.03

1.3

51

.26

1.0

21

.02

1.1

8

Reg

ion

40

.94

1.1

81

.25

1.0

21

.08

–1

.37

1.0

81

.02

1.3

71

.14

1.0

91

.03

1.1

5

Reg

ion

50

.70

0.9

51

.03

0.8

90

.81

0.8

4–

0.9

50

.89

1.0

71

.00

0.8

90

.90

1.0

1

Reg

ion

60

.81

1.0

91

.09

1.0

30

.94

0.9

71

.09

–1

.04

1.0

41

.06

1.0

31

.04

1.0

7

Reg

ion

70

.87

1.0

91

.08

1.1

11

.02

1.0

51

.09

1.0

8–

1.0

51

.05

1.0

11

.03

1.0

6

Reg

ion

80

.71

0.9

61

.03

0.9

00

.82

0.8

51

.09

0.9

60

.90

–1

.01

0.9

00

.90

1.0

2

Reg

ion

90

.75

1.0

21

.01

0.9

60

.88

0.9

01

.09

1.0

20

.96

1.0

6–

0.9

60

.96

1.0

8

Reg

ion

10

0.8

41

.04

1.0

31

.07

0.9

81

.01

1.0

91

.04

1.0

71

.09

1.0

8–

1.0

81

.03

Reg

ion

11

0.8

61

.06

1.0

61

.09

1.0

01

.03

1.0

91

.06

1.0

91

.04

1.0

31

.09

–1

.05

Reg

ion

12

0.7

61

.03

1.0

90

.97

0.8

90

.91

1.0

91

.03

0.9

71

.07

1.0

90

.97

0.9

7–

So

urc

e:P

hil

ipp

ines

Nat

ion

alS

tati

stic

sO

ffice

(20

02)

162 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123

Ta

ble

6H

Tsc

ore

s,2

00

0–

20

05

NC

RC

AR

Reg

ion

1R

egio

n2

Reg

ion

3R

egio

n4

Reg

ion

5R

egio

n6

Reg

ion

7R

egio

n8

Reg

ion

9R

egio

n1

0R

egio

n1

1R

egio

n1

2

NC

R–

1.2

91

.27

1.2

31

.07

1.0

41

.39

1.1

51

.16

1.3

71

.14

1.1

41

.15

1.2

3

CA

R0

.81

–1

.02

1.0

80

.93

0.9

01

.04

1.0

71

.09

1.0

41

.08

1.0

51

.08

1.0

3

Reg

ion

10

.74

0.9

8–

0.9

90

.85

0.8

21

.04

1.0

90

.99

1.0

41

.08

0.9

60

.99

1.0

3

Reg

ion

20

.79

1.0

41

.08

–0

.90

0.8

71

.01

1.0

51

.05

1.0

01

.14

1.0

11

.05

1.0

8

Reg

ion

30

.99

1.1

81

.19

1.0

9–

1.0

21

.27

1.0

91

.08

1.3

81

.34

1.0

71

.05

1.1

8

Reg

ion

41

.03

1.1

31

.13

1.0

51

.07

–1

.39

1.2

61

.17

1.3

81

.32

1.0

81

.07

1.1

5

Reg

ion

50

.77

1.0

11

.06

1.0

20

.87

0.8

5–

1.1

21

.02

1.0

71

.09

0.9

81

.02

1.0

6

Reg

ion

60

.74

0.9

31

.05

0.9

30

.80

0.7

80

.98

–0

.94

0.9

81

.02

0.9

00

.93

0.9

7

Reg

ion

70

.85

1.0

21

.07

1.0

30

.97

0.9

41

.09

1.0

4–

1.0

91

.03

1.0

91

.03

1.0

8

Reg

ion

80

.77

1.0

21

.06

1.0

30

.88

0.8

61

.08

1.0

81

.03

–1

.02

1.0

01

.03

1.0

8

Reg

ion

90

.73

0.9

71

.09

0.9

70

.83

0.8

11

.02

1.0

70

.98

1.0

2–

0.9

40

.97

1.0

2

Reg

ion

10

0.8

31

.09

1.0

41

.01

0.9

50

.92

1.0

61

.02

1.0

11

.06

1.0

2–

1.0

11

.06

Reg

ion

11

0.8

21

.09

1.0

31

.09

0.9

40

.91

1.0

51

.02

1.0

11

.05

1.0

91

.06

–1

.04

Reg

ion

12

0.7

91

.04

1.0

81

.05

0.9

00

.87

1.0

91

.05

1.0

51

.05

1.0

41

.01

1.0

5–

So

urc

e:P

hil

ippin

esN

atio

nal

Sta

tist

icO

ffice

(20

07)

The Migratory Response of Labor 163

123

References

Bases Conversion Development Authority. (2001). Annual report 2000.Bases Conversion Development Authority. (2006a). About the BCDA. Retrieved March, 19, 2006, from

http://www.bcda.gov.ph.

Bases Conversion Development Authority. (2006b). Annual report 2005.Bell, C. (1991). Regional heterogeneity, migration, and shadow prices. Journal of Public Economics,

46(1), 1–27.

ESRI. (2007). Understanding different kriging models. Retrieved September 6, 2007, from http://web

help.esri.com/arcgisdesktop/9.2/index.cfm?TopicName=Understanding_different_kriging_models.

Fields, G. S. (1975). Rural-urban migration, urban unemployment and underemployment, and job-search

activity in LDCs. Journal of Development Economics, 2(2), 165–187.

Guillermo, V. (1996). Checking out employment strategies. Manila: Press Foundation of Asia.

Harris, J. R., & Todaro, M. P. (1970). Migration, unemployment and development: A two-sector analysis.

The American Economic Review, 60(1), 126–142.

Issah, I., Khan, T. Y., & Sasaki, K. (2005). Do migrants react to infrastructure difference between urban

and rural areas? Development of an extended Harris-Todaro model. Review of Urban and RegionalDevelopment Studies, 17(1), 68–88.

Makabenta, M. P. (2002). FDI location and special economic zones in the Philippines. Review of Urbanand Regional Development Studies, 14(1), 59.

Massey, D. S. (1990). Social structure, household strategies, and the cumulative causation of migration.

Population Index, 56(1), 3–26.

Massey, D. S. (1999). Why does immigration occur? In C. Hirschman, P. Kasinitz, & J. DeWind (Eds.),

The handbook of international migration: The American experience (pp. 34–52). New York: New

Russell Sage Foundation.

National Statistical Coordination Board. (2001). 2000 Philippines statistical yearbook. Manila: National

Statistical Coordination Board.

Philippines Congressional Planning and Budget Department. (2003). Economic and employment statusreport.

Philippines Economic Zone Authority. (2006a). About PEZA. Retrieved April, 23, 2006, from

http://www.peza.ph.gov.

Philippines Economic Zone Authority. (2006b). Philippines special economic zones. Retrieved April 23,

2006, from http://www.peza.gov.ph.

Philippines Economic Zone Authority.(2006c). SEZ employment totals. Unpublished report.

Philippines National Census. (1997). Provincial profile: National capital region. Manila: National

Statistical Board.

Philippines National Census. (1998a). PopCens 95. Manila: National Statistical Board.

Philippines National Census. (1998b). Socio-economic and demographic characteristics, 1995. Manila:

National Statistical Board.

Philippines National Statistics Office. (2002). Philippines statistical yearbook, 2001. Manila: Bureau of

the Census and Statistics.

Philippines National Census. (2005). Socio-economic and demographic characteristics, 2000. Manila:

Bureau of the Census and Statistics.

Philippines National Census. (2006). Socio-economic and demographic characteristics, 2000. Manila:

National Statistical Board.

Ringuet, D. J., & Estrada, E. (2003). Understanding the Philippines’ economy and politics since the return

of democracy in 1986. Contemporary Southeast Asia, 25(2), 233.

Stiglitz, J. E. (1974). Alternative theories of wage determination and unemployment in LDC’s: The labor

turnover model. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 88(2), 194–227.

Tolentino, M. P. (1994). Developing agriculture toward sustainable industrialization. Economics andbusiness in the Philippines (pp. 57–68). San Francisco: The Asia Foundation.

164 S. R. Sanders, D. L. Brown

123