The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

  • Upload
    iweinel

  • View
    216

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    1/25

    Working Paper Series

    The market premium to meeting or beatinganalysts forecasts: further evidence from the UK

    Young-soo ChoiStephen Lin

    Manchester Business School Working Paper No. 509June 2006

    Manchester Business SchoolCopyright 2006, Choi and Lin. All rights reserved.Do not quote or cite without permission from the author.

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    2/25

    Author(s) and affiliation

    Young-soo ChoiLancaster UniversityBailriggLancasterLA1 4YWTel: +44(0) 1524 65201

    Stephen LinAssociate Professor of AccountingCollege of Business AdministrationFlorida International UniversityMiamiFL 33199, USATel: (305) 348-2582E-mail: [email protected]

    Abstract

    Using a large UK sample during 1990-2003, we find UK firms that meet or beat earningsexpectation enjoy a positive and significant market premium especially for firms with positiveforecast revisions and errors. The market premium to beat expectations is higher than thepremium to meet earnings expectations. We also find some evidence that the premium tobeat earnings expectations is higher than the penalty to miss earnings expectations.Consistent with US evidence, UK firms also engage in expectations management to meet or

    beat earnings expectations. An important finding is that forecast revisions of future earningsare a more significant factor in explaining the abnormal share returns than the effect ofearnings surprises. This suggests that unlike US counterparts, UK investors do not simplyfixate on earnings surprises.

    How to quote or cite this document

    Choi, Young-soo, & Lin, Stephen. (2006). The market premium to meeting or beating analystsforecasts: further evidence from the UK. Manchester Business School Working Paper,Number 509, available: http://www.mbs.ac.uk/research/working-papers.aspx.

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    3/25

    1. Introduction

    Many US studies document that a significant proportion of US firms in recent years

    report their earnings either slightly above analysts forecasts or exactly on target (Brown,

    2001; Matsumoto, 2001), and that US firms engage in expectations management (e.g.

    Skinner, 1997; Kasznik and Lev, 1995, Francis et al, 1994; Soffer et al, 2000) or earnings

    management (Burgstahler and Eames, 2003; Payne and Robb, 2000; Kasznik, 1999) tomeet or beat current analysts earnings expectations (hereafter referred to as MBE). Some

    studies also investigate the potential benefit of MBE for company investors. For instance,

    Kasznik and McNichols (2002) document a valuation premium to MBE that is associated

    with future profitability, which is, however, not fully captured by analysts future

    forecasts of earnings. Lopez and Rees (2002) find that the earnings response coefficient

    (ERC) is significantly higher for firms that meet or beat analysts forecasts, indicating

    that earnings quality may have played an important role in MBE.

    A most recent study by Bartov, Givoly, and Hayn (2002, hereafter referred to as BGH)

    investigates the premium to MBE and examines the extent to which earnings and

    expectation management have impacted upon the premium to MBE. Using the portfolio

    tests, BGH find the abnormal returns for firms that beat earnings expectations are

    consistently higher than those that merely meet or miss earnings expectation in every

    error-size portfolio and expectation management path based on the direction of forecast

    revision and earnings surprise upon the earnings announcement.

    BGH also find before including earnings surprise the quarterly return for US firms that

    MBE during 1983-1997 is already 2.3% higher than other firms. BGH also document that

    1% earnings surprise is associated with an incremental quarterly return of about 0.5%.

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    4/25

    Consistent with the expectations management hypothesis, BGH show that the percentage

    of negative earnings surprises over the entire sample is significantly smaller than the

    percentage of negative forecast errors. They also show that the proportion of firm-

    quarters with a negative forecast error that end with a positive or zero earnings surprise is

    significantly higher than the proportion of cases with a positive or zero forecast error that

    end with a negative earnings surprise. These results indicate that analysts forecasts are

    dampened so as to increase the likelihood that the actual reported earnings will exceed or

    at least match analysts forecasts of earnings upon the earnings announcement.

    Finally, BGH also document that a market premium to MBE, although somewhat

    smaller, exists in the cases where MBE is likely to have been achieved through either

    earnings or expectations management. Their finding also indicates that the premium to

    MBE is a leading indicator of future performance. This premium and its predictive ability

    are only marginally affected by whether the MBE is genuine or the result of earnings or

    expectations management.

    There is no study so far investigating whether a market premium to MBE exists in the

    UK. Given a significant market premium to MBE in the US, it is interesting to see

    whether it exits outside the US. Although the UK market is somewhat similar to its US

    counterpart, it is widely believed that differences in business culture, institutional factors,

    market structure, investors behavior between these two countries may lead to different

    empirical finding. For example, US companies are active players of managing analysts

    earnings expectation (McGee, 1997; Vickers, 1999) because they might be sued if theyhave unfavorable earnings surprises. In the UK, it is very rare that investors sue their

    investing companies due to unfavorable earnings surprise. In addition, previous studies

    have not found the reasons for the market premium to MBE. For example, BGH find that

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    5/25

    This study examines the following four research questions in relation to the market

    premium to MBE in the UK.

    (1)What is the recurrence of MBE?

    (2) Is there a market premium to MBE?

    (3) If there is a market premium to MBE, then whether the premium to meet earnings

    expectations is different from the premium to beat earnings expectations.

    (4)Do UK investors assign higher weight for earnings surprises than forecast

    revisions or forecast errors as their US counterparts?

    Using a large UK sample during1990-2003, we find the proportion of UK firms that

    MBE is higher than those firms that fail to do so, although the proportion of former firmsslightly declined during 2000-2001. Unlike US evidence, we find only a very small

    proportion of UK firms that have their reported earnings on target (around 4% of the total

    examined firms), indicating that there might be a fundamental difference in market

    expectations from investors between these two countries. We find UK firms also enjoy a

    market premium to MBE especially for firms with positive forecast revisions (the latest

    forecasted earnings before current year earnings announcement minus the earliest

    forecasted earnings after prior year earnings announcements) and positive forecast errors

    (actual earnings minus the earliest forecasted earnings after prior year earnings

    announcements).The premium to beat expectations is higher than the premium to meet

    earnings expectation. We also find some evidence that the premium to beat earnings

    expectations is marginally higher than the penalty to miss earnings expectations.

    Consistent with US evidence, the relative frequency of negative earnings surprises is

    smaller than the relative frequency of negative forecast errors. In addition, the proportion

    of negative forecast error cases that end with a zero or positive surprise is greater than the

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    6/25

    significant factor in explaining the abnormal returns in comparison with the effect of

    earnings surprises. This suggests UK investors do not simply fixate on earnings surprises.

    The paper is organized as follows. The next presents the empirical design and prediction.

    Section 3 describes sample selection criteria and data collection. Results are reported in

    Section 4. The final section concludes with a short summary.

    2. Research method and prediction

    This study closely follows the research design used by BGH. The abnormal return is

    derived from the market adjusted method instead of the market model to simplify our

    empirical tests. We first use both descriptive and univariate analyses to investigate

    whether abnormal share return is correlated with MBE, forecast revisions, and forecast

    errors. The main empirical results are derived from the following OLS regression model

    suggested by BGH, shown as follows.

    Model 1a:

    ++++++= itit5it4it3it2it10it DMBE*SURPDBEATDMBESURPERRORCAR

    Where

    CARit: Cumulative market adjusted share return for company i for the following periods:

    a. Event period 1: a 12 month event period ending 4 months after the financial

    d

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    7/25

    d. Event period 4: the event period starting the day after prior year earnings

    announcements and ending the day after current year earnings

    announcements. This is the test period used by BHG (2002).

    e. Event period 5: the event period between interim and final earnings

    announcement dates

    f. Event period 6: the event period starting the day after the financial year end

    date and ending the day after the final earnings announcements.

    We find the results using the above six different test periods have provided qualitatively

    consistent conclusion, and therefore only reports the results using the event periods 1 and

    4 for simplicity reason.

    ERRORit: forecast errors, the difference between actual reported earnings and the earliest

    forecasted earnings made soon after prior year earnings announcements, deflated by prior

    year end share price.

    SURPit: earnings surprise, the difference between actual reported earnings and the latest

    forecasted earnings made soon before current year earnings announcements, deflated by

    prior year end share price.

    DMBEit: a dummy variable for firms that MBE. It equals 1 if SURP it 0, 0 otherwise

    DBEATit: a dummy variable for firms that beat earnings expectations. It equals 1 ifSURPit > 0, 0 otherwise.

    We also obtain the following model after replacing forecast errors with earnings surprises

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    8/25

    Model 1b:

    ++++++= itit5it4it3it2it10it DMBE*SURPDBEATDMBEREVISIONSURPCAR

    Where

    REVISIONit: the latest forecasted earnings soon before current year earnings

    announcements minus the earliest forecasted earnings subsequent to prior year earnings

    announcements, deflated by prior year end share price. It is true that 1 in model 1a equal

    1 plus 2 in model 1b.

    If the premium to MBE exists in the UK, then we should observe a positive and

    significant 2 and 3 in model 1a (1 and 3 in model 1b). A positive and significant 4

    in both models indicate firms who beat earnings expectation have higher market premium

    than firms who only meet earnings expectation. We also compare 1 and 2 in both

    models to investigate whether the market places a higher weight on forecast errors or

    earnings surprise. BGH find that US investors place higher weight on earnings surprises

    than forecast errors.

    Since the direction of forecast revision of future earnings (DREV) is found to be an

    important indicator for expectations management in the BGH paper, this study further

    investigates the role of DREV in determining the premium to MBE through the following

    modified model:

    Model 2:

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    9/25

    DREVit: direction of forecast revision of future earnings. It equals 1 if forecast revision is

    positive, 0 otherwise.

    3. Sample selection, data, and descriptive analysis

    Table 1 summarizes the sample selection criteria. Only industrial firms who are followed

    by IBES and have Datastream code are included in this study. There are 14,756 firm

    years during 1990-2003 that meet these criteria. After deleting firms with less than two

    earnings forecasts and deleting extreme1 share returns, forecast revisions, and forecast

    errors in each test period, only 13,684, 13,497, 12,776, 6,497, 7,569, and 8,208 firm years

    are left for the test periods 1-6, respectively. The test period 4 has much smaller number

    of observations than the test period 1 because the latter period requires actual earnings

    announcement dates. Market adjusted share returns are the difference between firm share

    return and market return, both were obtained from Datastream. Forecasted earnings and

    actual earnings from the IBES database are used to construct forecast revisions, forecast

    errors, and earnings surprises.

    Table 2 reports the results of descriptive analysis. Panel A shows that both forecast errors

    and forecast revisions have negative mean, consistent with previous studies in the sense

    that analysts forecasted earnings are generally optimistic. Median forecast errors and

    revisions for the six test periods appear to be inconsistent. Both median forecast errorsand revisions for the test periods 1, 4, and 5 are negative. Both event periods 1 and 4

    include the forecasted earnings that were made early in the year, which produce relatively

    higher negative forecast errors than other event periods. This indicates that forecasted

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    10/25

    reported in panel B. Market adjusted returns for the six test periods appear to be

    inconsistent. Events 1, 4, and 5 have negative mean and median abnormal share returns.

    Panel B reports the frequency of firms who meet, beat, or miss analysts forecasts. We

    find that on average 54% of UK firms during 1990-2003 meet analysts forecasts and only

    4% of firms have actual earnings on target. In contrast, 42% of UK firms during the same

    period failed to meet or beat earnings expectations. Using the binary test, we find the

    difference in frequency between firms that MBE and firms that miss earnings expectation

    is significant at the 1% level. The above finding is robust across different test periods

    and generally consistent with US evidence. BGH documents that around 40% of US

    firms failed to MBE during the 1983-1997 period.

    4. Empirical results

    Table 3 reports univariate analyses over the association between abnormal share returns,

    forecast errors, forecast revisions, and earnings surprises. Panel A suggests that the

    average market adjusted return is consistently higher (between 5.5% and 17.1%) when

    UK firms beat instead of missing analysts forecasts. In addition, the average market

    adjusted return is consistently higher (between 5.2% and 12.2%) when UK firms beat

    instead of meeting analysts forecasts. Finally, firms that meet earnings expectations have

    consistently higher average abnormal share returns (between 1% and 6.2%) than firms

    that fail to do so. Consistent with US evidence, this finding indicates that a market

    premium to MBE indeed exists in the UK. Panel B shows that firms with upward forecast

    revisions (17.5% and 15.8% respectively) enjoy much higher average abnormal share

    returns than firms with downward revisions (-10%and -10 8% respectively) and zero

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    11/25

    negative (i.e. optimistic forecasted earnings, -11.5% and -12.9% respectively) or zero

    forecast errors (between -2.7% and -6.6%). This finding suggests that the market does

    rewards firms that beat earnings expectation and have positive forecast revisions or

    positive forecast errors (i.e. pessimistic forecasted earnings).

    Panel D reports the correlations between abnormal share returns, forecast revisions, and

    MBE. It shows that firms who have positive forecast revisions and beat analysts forecasts

    enjoy the highest average abnormal returns (21% and 19.6% respectively) across the two

    test periods. However, firms who have negative forecast revisions and miss analysts

    forecasts appear to have the worst average abnormal share returns (-16.6% for both test

    periods). Firms who have zero forecast revisions but beat analysts forecasts appear to

    have second highest average abnormal share returns (12.7% and 13.6%). In addition,

    firms who have positive forecast revisions but meet analyst forecasts also appear to have

    positive and relatively high average abnormal share return (15.9% and 6.2%). Again the

    above findings are consistent with our previous findings in the sense that firms that have

    upward forecast revisions and beat analysts forecasts are rewarded with an economically

    significant market premium.

    Panel E reports the correlations between abnormal share returns, forecast errors, and

    MBE. The results are less clear cut. We find firms that have positive forecast errors

    (pessimistic forecasts) and beat analyst forecasts have highest average abnormal returns

    16.6% and 16.4% respectively). On the other hand, firms that have negative forecast

    errors (optimistic forecasts) and miss analysts forecasts have lowest median abnormalreturns (-16.3% and -16.6% respectively).

    Finally we investigate firm abnormal share returns conditional on forecast errors, forecast

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    12/25

    both periods (-16.6%). Untabulated results show that firms that have zero forecast errors

    and upward forecast revisions but miss analyst forecasts have the highest mean abnormal

    share returns in periods 2, 3, and 6 (between 6.6% and 11.8%).

    In summary, the panels in Table 3 have provided evidence suggesting that firms that have

    upward forecast revisions, positive forecast errors ( pessimistic forecasts), and beat

    analysts forecasts have higher abnormal returns than firms that have downward forecast

    revisions, negative forecast errors, and miss analyst forecasts. In addition, firms that have

    upward forecast revisions, positive forecast errors, and meet analyst forecast generally

    have higher (lower) abnormal share return than their counterparts that miss (beat)

    earnings expectations. We observe a market premium for firms that beat or meet earnings

    expectations although the magnitude of the premium is conditional on the sign of forecast

    errors and forecast revisions.

    To confirm the above findings, we report the results using the OLS regressions in Table

    4. Panel A shows that using the model 1, the slope coefficient of forecast errors (i.e. 2),

    measured by the difference between actual earnings and the earliest forecasted earnings

    subsequent to prior year earnings announcement, is consistently positive and significant

    at the 1% level across the two test periods. Firms that have positive forecast errors appear

    to have a market premium ranging between 2% and 2.3%, which is much smaller than the

    finding of 40.7% by BGH. This finding could be caused by two reasons. First, our study

    uses market adjusted return instead of the return from the market model. Second, we use

    annual instead of quarterly data. Future research may consider using returns from themarket model. Unlike the finding documented by BGH, the slope coefficient of earnings

    surprises (1) are consistently negative and significant at the 1% level. Untabulated result

    shows that the coefficient of regressing CAR on earnings surprise alone is positive, but

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    13/25

    our study than BGH. The slope coefficients of MBE dummy (i.e. 3) are consistently

    positive but insignificant for the test periods 1 and 4. However it is statistically

    significant at around the 5% when using the test periods 2 and 3. It shows that firms that

    MBE have market premium of 2.1 or 2.4%. This is rather consistent with the finding by

    BGH that the market premium is 2.3% after controlling for forecast errors. The slope

    coefficients of beat dummy (4) are consistently positive and significant at the 1% level.

    This indicates that firms that beat earnings expectations enjoy very high market premium

    (7.7% and 10.2% respectively). BGH finds a market premium of 3.4% for firms that beat

    earnings expectations. The coefficient of the interaction between earnings surprise and

    firms that either meet or beat earnings expectation is positive but marginally significant

    only when the test period 4 is used. The premium to beat earnings expectations appear to

    be marginally higher (0.5%) than the penalty to miss earnings expectations. This is much

    smaller than the finding of 43.4% by BGH.

    After replacing forecast errors with forecast revisions and earnings surprises, the slope

    coefficient of earnings surprises becomes consistently positive and significant at the 1%

    level. The market premium to earnings surprises is only around 0.6%, so much smaller

    than the finding of 94.1% by BGH. Same to forecast errors, the slope coefficients of

    forecast revisions are consistently positive and significant at the 1% level. The size of the

    slope coefficient of forecast revisions is, however, at least three times higher than that of

    the slope coefficient of earnings surprises. This is somewhat different from the finding of

    BGH in the US that earnings surprise has twice higher slope coefficient than forecast

    errors and revisions. UK investors appear to value forecast revisions more than earningssurprises. Unlike US evidence, UK investors do not appear to fixate on earnings

    surprises.

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    14/25

    results after considering the direction of forecast revision and separate dummies for firms

    that beat or meet analyst forecasts. We find forecast revisions and earnings surprises are

    consistently positive and significant at the 1% level. The slope coefficient of forecast

    revisions is at least twice higher than that of earnings surprises. Dummy for firms that

    beat analyst forecasts is consistently positive and significant at the 1% level; dummy for

    firms who meet analyst forecast is only insignificant when using the event periods 1 and

    4 (but is significant at the 10% level when using the event periods 2 and 3). Upward

    forecast revisions appear to have very high slope coefficients when using the event

    periods 1 and 4. Again the interaction between earnings surprises and firms that MBE is

    positive and significant only when using the event period 4. There is some evidence that

    the premium to beat earnings expectations (0.7%) is higher than the penalty to miss

    earnings expectations.

    In summary, table 4 suggests that unlike US evidence earnings surprises do not appear to

    as important as forecast revisions in explaining abnormal share returns. Earnings

    surprises appear to have positive and significant explanatory power for abnormal share

    return only after controlling for forecast revisions. This result indicates that UK investors

    are able to differentiate the information contained in forecast revisions and earnings

    surprises. Different from the US counterparts, UK investors do not appear to fixate on

    earnings figures. We also find that firms that MBE enjoy higher abnormal share returns

    than firms that miss. In addition, UK firms that beat earnings expectations enjoy higher

    abnormal share returns than firms that only meet their targets. There is some evidence

    that the premium to beat earnings expectations is higher than the penalty to miss earningsexpectations when the abnormal share returns are calculated for the period between the

    day after prior year earnings announcements and the day after current year earnings

    announcement. This test period is consistent with the one used by BGH except that we

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    15/25

    earning surprises; the slope coefficient of upward (or positive) forecast revisions is at

    least eight times higher than that of forecast revisions.

    5. Summary and conclusion

    This paper investigates whether UK firms that meet or beat analysts forecasts enjoy a

    market premium and whether firms that beat earnings expectations have a higher market

    premium than firms that meet them. Consistent with the US evidence, we find very

    similar magnitude of the market premium for firms that meet or beat analysts forecasts

    (i.e. 2.1% or 2.4% in the UK in comparison with 2.3% in the US). In addition, UK firms

    that beat earnings expectations have a higher market premium than firms that meet

    earnings expectations. The magnitude of the market premium due to beating earnings

    expectations in the UK (7.7% or 10.2%) is much higher than that in the US (3.4%).However, the market premium to beat earnings expectations appears to be higher (0.7%)

    than the penalty to miss earnings expectations, although the magnitude of the market

    premium is much smaller than the US finding of 43.4% (BGH 2002). Finally, unlike the

    finding in the US we find UK investors place a much higher weight on forecast revisions

    than earnings surprises when valuing their investing firms, indicating that they do not

    fixate on earnings surprises.

    Kasznik and McNichols (2002) document a valuation premium to MBE that is associated

    with future profitability although the above premium is not actually captured by analysts

    forecasts of future earnings. Analysts appear to have ignored the information contained in

    the market premium to MBE about a firms future operating performance. BGH also find

    that the market premium to MBE is a leading indicator of firm future operating

    performance. Both studies do not investigate the underlying reasons for the observed

    market premium Our results suggest that although the market premium to MBE indeed

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    16/25

    reflect the information contained in the market premium into their forecasts of future

    earnings. Both are important issues to further understand the nature of and the reasons for

    the market premium to MBE under different reporting settings, which have been largely

    ignored in the literature.

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    17/25

    References:

    Abarbanell, J. and Leahvy, R. 2003. Biased forecasts or biased earnings? The role of

    reported earnings in explaining apparent bias and over/underreaction in analysts earnings

    forecasts.Journal of Accounting and Economics 35: 105-146.

    Brown, L.D., 2001. A temporal analysis of earnings surprises: profits versus losses.

    Journal of Accounting Research, 39 (2): 221241.

    Bartov, E., Givoly, D., and Hayn, C., 2002, The rewards to meet or beat earnings

    expectation,Journal of Accounting and Economics 33: 173204

    Burgstahler, D. and Eames,M.J., 2003. Earnings management to avoid losses and

    earnings decreases: Are analysts fooled? Contemporary Accounting Research 20(2): 253-

    294.

    Francis, J., Philbrick, D., Schipper, K., 1994. Shareholder litigation and corporate

    disclosures.Journal of Accounting Research 32 (2): 137164.

    Kasznik, R., 1999. On the association between voluntary disclosures and earnings

    management.Journal of Accounting Research 37: 57-82.

    Kasznik, R., Lev, B., 1995. To warn or not warn: management disclosures in the face of

    an earnings surprise. The Accounting Review 70 (1): 113134.

    Kasznik, R. and McNichols, M., 2002. Does meeting earnings expectations matter?

    Evidence from analyst forecast revisions and share prices.Journal of Accounting

    Research 40(3): 727-759.

    Lopez, T.J. and Rees, L., 2002. The effect of beating and missing analysts forecasts in

    the information content of unexpected earnings.Journal of Accounting, Auditing and

    Finance 17(2): 155-184.

    Matsumoto, D.A., 2002. Managers incentives to avoid negative earnings surprises. The

    Accounting Review 77(3): 483-514.

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    18/25

    Skinner, D.J., 1997. Earnings disclosures and stockholder lawsuits.Journal of

    Accounting and Economics 23 (3): 249282.

    Soffer, L.C., Thiagarajan, S.R., Walther, B.R., 2000. Earnings preannouncement

    strategies.Review of Accounting Studies 5 (1): 526.

    Vickers, M., 1999. Ho-hum, another earnings surprise.Business WeekM3630: 8384.

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    19/25

    Table 1: Sample Selection

    Event 1 Event 2 Event 3 Event 4 Event 5 Event 6

    All UK firm-years from 1990 to 2003 in IBESsummary file where one-year ahead consensusEPS forecasts and EPS actuals are available

    15165Less: Datastream code is not available 409

    Merged set with Datastream code 14756

    Less: Firm-years with only one forecast 206

    Firm-years with at least two forecasts 14550

    Firm-years with at least two forecasts within aspecific event period 14456 14024 13249 6690 7792 8448

    Less: Datastream returns are not available 406 162 114 14 17 15

    Merged set with Datastream returns data 14050 13862 13135 6676 7775 8433

    Less: Firm-years with extrem outliers onforecast error, forecast revision, earningssurprise or market adjusted returns 366 365 359 179 206 225

    Firm-years for data analysis 13684 13497 12776 6497 7569 8208

    Note:1) Event 1, 2 and 3 are, respectivly, a fixed 12-month, 6-month and 4-month period until 4 months after the fiscal year

    end. Event 4, 5 and 6 are, respectively, an event period from the previous annual earnings announcement date (AED) tothe current annual AED, from the current interim AED to the current annual AED, from the current fiscal year end tothe current annual AED.2) Datastream market returns are market adjusted buy-and-hold period returns.

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    20/25

    20

    Table 2: Descriptive Statistics

    Panel A: Forecast error, forecast revision, earnings surprise and returns

    Event 1 (N = 13684) Event 4 (N = 6497)

    Mean Median Std Mean Median Std

    Error -2.313 -0.453 8.009 -1.830 -0.290 7.219

    Revision -1.774 -0.320 5.165 -1.458 -0.240 4.843

    Surprise -0.539 0.092 5.602 -0.373 0.165 4.942

    Returns -0.001 -0.040 0.443 -0.001 -0.042 0.427

    Panel B: Meeting or beating earnings forecasts (%)

    Event 1 Event 4

    N Beat % Meet % Fail % MBE % MBE %1990 826 372 0.45 82 0.10 372 0.45 0.55 -

    1991 848 416 0.49 77 0.09 355 0.42 0.58 1.00*

    1992 895 437 0.49 101 0.11 357 0.40 0.60 1.00*

    1993 918 496 0.54 62 0.07 360 0.39 0.61 0.60

    1994 975 581 0.60 44 0.05 350 0.36 0.64 0.641995 1027 593 0.58 38 0.04 396 0.39 0.61 0.631996 1104 655 0.59 45 0.04 404 0.37 0.63 0.661997 1222 773 0.63 23 0.02 426 0.35 0.65 0.681998 1218 709 0.58 37 0.03 472 0.39 0.61 0.631999 1110 651 0.59 21 0.02 438 0.39 0.61 0.622000 1041 516 0.50 10 0.01 515 0.49 0.51 0.522001 920 377 0.41 5 0.01 538 0.58 0.42 0.402002 789 386 0.49 3 0.00 400 0.51 0.49 0.50

    2003 791 463 0.59 2 0.00 326 0.41 0.59 0.57Total 13684 7425 0.54 550 0.04 5709 0.42 0.58 0.59

    Note: * only one beating case exists.

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    21/25

    21

    Table 3: Returns by MBE, forecast revision and forecast error

    Panel A: Returns by MBE

    Event 1 (N = 13684) Event 4 (N = 6497)

    N Mean Median N Mean Median

    Beat 7425 0.075 0.029 3726 0.069 0.024

    Meet 550 -0.034 -0.060 137 -0.053 -0.036Fail 5709 -0.096 -0.131 2634 -0.097 -0.131

    Panel B: Returns by forecast revision

    Event 1 (N = 13684) Event 4 (N = 6497)

    N Mean Median N Mean Median

    Downward

    7956

    -

    0.100 -0.126 3653

    -

    0.108 -0.142

    Same 1536 0.036 -0.020 484 0.028 -0.028Upward 4192 0.175 0.113 2360 0.158 0.093

    Panel C: Returns by forecast error

    Event 1 (N = 13684) Event 4 (N = 6497)

    N Mean Median N Mean Median

    Optimistic

    7966

    -

    0.115 -0.146 3545

    -

    0.129 -0.161

    Zero

    126

    -

    0.027 -0.064 62

    -

    0.066 -0.109

    Pessimistic 5592 0.163 0.098 2890 0.157 0.094

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    22/25

    22

    Panel D: Returns by forecast revision and MBE

    Event 1 (N = 13684) Event 4 (N = 6497)

    N Mean Median N Mean Median

    D B

    3849

    -

    0.034 -0.062 1851

    -

    0.053 -0.093

    M

    338

    -

    0.129 -0.140 70

    -

    0.134 -0.151

    F

    3769

    -

    0.166 -0.197 1732

    -

    0.166 -0.201

    S B 760 0.127 0.049 222 0.136 0.072

    M

    37

    -

    0.073 -0.078 10

    -

    0.144 -0.069

    F

    739

    -

    0.052 -0.117 252

    -

    0.059 -0.104

    U B 2816 0.210 0.136 1653 0.196 0.122M 175 0.159 0.104 57 0.062 0.058F 1201 0.096 0.056 650 0.071 0.004

    Panel E: Returns by forecast error and MBE

    Event 1 (N = 13684) Event 4 (N = 6497)

    N Mean Median N Mean Median

    O B

    2562

    -

    0.092 -0.121 1217

    -

    0.122 -0.148

    M

    338

    -

    0.129 -0.140 70

    -

    0.134 -0.151

    F

    5066

    -

    0.126 -0.163 2258

    -

    0.133 -0.166Z B

    54

    -

    0.084 -0.163 35

    -

    0.033 -0.110

    M

    37

    -

    0.073 -0.078 10

    -

    0.144 -0.069

    F

    35 0.109 0.133 17

    -

    0.087 -0.120

    P B 4809 0.166 0.099 2474 0.164 0.101

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    23/25

    23

    M 175 0.159 0.104 57 0.062 0.058F 608 0.139 0.092 359 0.127 0.055

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    24/25

    24

    Panel F: Returns by forecast error, forecast revision and MBE

    Event 1 (N = 13684) Event 4 (N = 6497)

    N Mean Median N Mean Median

    O D B

    2562

    -

    0.092 -0.121 1217

    -

    0.122 -0.148

    M

    338

    -

    0.129 -0.140 70

    -

    0.134 -0.151

    F

    3769

    -

    0.166 -0.197 1732

    -

    0.166 -0.201

    S F739

    -

    0.052 -0.117 252

    -

    0.059 -0.104

    U F 558 0.047 -0.025 274 0.009 -0.052

    Z D B

    54

    -

    0.084 -0.163 35

    -

    0.033 -0.110

    S M

    37

    -

    0.073 -0.078 10

    -

    0.144 -0.069

    U F

    35 0.109 0.133 17

    -

    0.087 -0.120

    P D B 1233 0.091 0.041 599 0.086 0.042S B 760 0.127 0.049 222 0.136 0.072U B 2816 0.210 0.136 1653 0.196 0.122

    M 175 0.159 0.104 57 0.062 0.058F 608 0.139 0.092 359 0.127 0.055

    Note:

    1) O, Z and P represent optimistic, zero and pessimistic forecast error, respectively. D, S and U represent downward, same and upward forecast revision,

    respectively. B, M and F represent beat, meet and fail earnings forecasts, respectively.

  • 7/28/2019 The Market Premium to Meeting or Beating Analysts

    25/25

    25

    Table 4: Regression Analysis

    Panel A: Replication of Bartov et al

    DMBESURPDBEATDMBEREVISIONSURP

    DMBESURPDBEATDMBEERRORSURPR

    *)(

    *

    5432210

    543210

    ++++++=

    +++++=

    Event 1 (N = 13684) Event 4 (N = 6497)

    coefficient p-value Coefficient p-value

    0 -0.021 0.001 -0.027 0.0037

    1 -0.013