The Invisible Green Hand

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    1/42

    The Invisible Green Hand:

    How Individual Decisions and MarketsCan Reduce Greenhouse Gas Emissions

    Martha Amram, Ph.D.

    and Nalin Kulatilaka, Ph.D.

    April 2008

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    2/42

    Th Iviil Gr Had:

    How Individual Decisions and Markets Can Reduce

    Greenhouse Gas Emissions

    APRIL 2008

    Martha Amram, Ph.D.and Nalin Kulatilaka, Ph.D.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    3/42

    AbouT THe MILken InsTITuTe

    The Milken Institute is an independent economic think tank whose mission is to improve the lives and economicconditions o diverse populations in the United States and around the world by helping business and public policyleaders identiy and implement innovative ideas or creating broad-based prosperity. We put research to work with thegoal o revitalizing regions and nding new ways to generate capital or people with original ideas.

    By creating ways to spread the benets o human, nancial, and social capital to as many people as possiblethe democratization o capitalwe hope to contribute to prosperity and reedom in all corners o the globe.

    AbouT sAVe

    SAVE (Strategic Action Volunteer Eort) brings together teams o volunteers adept at deploying state-o-the-artnancial technologies and capital market solutions to tackle complex economic and public policy challenges. Its energyservices initiative is working to accelerate the adoption o clean, energy-ecient technologies through innovativebusiness models.

    2008 Milken Institute

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    4/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    1. Introduction .....................................................................................................................1

    2. Buying Time with Climate Change Policy ..........................................................................3

    3. Cheap Solutions, Broken Markets .....................................................................................9

    4. The Central Role of Private Investment Decisions ............................................................13

    5. New and Reconnected Markets to Support Private Decisions .........................................17

    6. Experiencing Climate Change Locally .............................................................................25

    7. A New Geometry for Climate Change Policy ...................................................................29

    8. Conclusions ....................................................................................................................35

    About the Authors ..............................................................................................................36

    Tal f Ctt

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    5/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    6/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    1

    1. Introduction

    Every day, each one o us makes a host o purchase and consumption decisions. Embedded in every purchase

    is some amount o greenhouse gasand so our many small, individual actions add up to global climate

    change.1 This paper outlines a strategy or reversing the course o climate change in exactly the same way,

    using the strength o our market economy to produce results quickly and cheaply.

    Our market-based approach is not just about the type o solution we avor; it brings an entirely new

    perspective to the problem. From global accords to legislative agendas, the current thinking sees a proposed

    solution to climate change as something to be imposed on a large, reewheeling, and global economy, as i

    it were a simple entity ready to receive constraints or the common good. But some companies, industries,

    and countries have large incentives to deeat the proposed solutions, so, not surprisingly, legislation and

    global accords stall. Meanwhile, at the micro level, progress is made through local policies and initiatives,

    and these shape many private investment decisions. In this paper we ocus on this nexus, the local actionsand small decisions that also aect climate change. We may achieve national legislation or a global accord

    in the uture, but the local level also presents a rich opportunity or infuencing the course o events.

    The purpose o this paper is to shit the debate on climate change. For policy analysts, we provide a new

    argument: that local policies are a tangible and eective solution, as they can be more tailored to local

    conditions and markets. For businesses, we provide a road map to protable business opportunities that are

    the result o new markets, or the knitting together o older, ragmented markets. And or concerned citizens,

    our analysis shows that grassroots lobbying eorts can produce signicant change. Our ramework shows

    citizens what they should ask o local leaders. A national policy or international accord will only help to

    accelerate the changes and incentives described here, deepening the prot opportunities and shiting the

    tipping point or many private decisions.

    A second goal o this paper is to remove a layer o abstraction that oten exists in climate change policy. We

    aim to connect the big ideas to micro decisions and local realities. It is at this level o detail that climate

    change solutions must workthey must be the best choice or private decision-makers. While local actions

    may be shaped or tipped by public policy or regulatory constraints, it is ultimately the many small decisions

    made by individuals that will drive emissions out o our purchases and consumption.

    By putting markets at the center o our analysis, and by dening climate change solutions in response to market

    strengths and gaps, we hope to demonstrate the scale, speed, and cost-eectiveness o market-based solutions.

    The invisible hand can lead to a sharp reduction in emissions, shiting the path o climate change itsel. With

    a little prodding and the help o both national and local policies, the invisible hand can go green.

    We will begin by stating the problem, relying on a clear policy ramework known as stabilization wedges (rst

    proposed by two Princeton University proessors, Stephen Pacala and Robert Socolow2). Their ramework

    1 For a vivid description o the impact o our daily actions, see Alex Shourmato, An Eco-System o Ones Own,Vanity Fair, May 2007.

    2 Stephen Pacala and Robert Socolow, Stabilization Wedges: Solving the Climate Problem or the Next 50 Yearswith Current Technologies, Science, Vol. 305, no. 5686 (December 2004), pp. 968972.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    7/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    2

    links climate science and policy actions, and has two salient conclusions: First, there is no single technology

    that will solve our emissions problem; it will take a portolio o solutions. Second, while complex and onerous,

    the climate policies currently being debated are only the rst step. These policies will serve only to slow

    down emissions growth so that we might strive or more aggressive emissions reductions in the uture. They

    will not be enough to halt or reverse climate change.

    In Part 3 o this paper, we turn to low-cost solutions or greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. Seemingly cheap

    and immediately available technologies are available, so why arent they widely used? The answer is broken

    markets. What looks cheap on paper is hard (and more expensive) to implement in the real world. To

    illustrate, we take a close look at the lowly household water heater and examine the drivers and barriers or

    early replacement with an energy-ecient model.

    Our central argument is that the private investment decision is the key driver o GHG emissions by humans.

    At a day-to-day level, emissions are largely set by behavior, which in turn is constrained by the existing

    capital stock. Because capital stock is so long-lived, the private investment decision is a moment o great

    consequence or determining urther emissions levels. Public inrastructure shapes private investment

    decisions, but we argue that public institutions typically respond ater the act; they have a poor track record

    o acting beore catastrophe strikes. This leaves us relying heavily on markets to tip private investment

    decisions toward clean technologies.

    In Part 5 we provide multiple examples o new and reconnected markets that can tip private decisions

    and accelerate the adoption o clean technologies. In contrast to many climate policy papers, we are not

    presenting technology solutionswe are providing solutions to market problems.

    The discussion to this point has considered the problem rom a macro or national level. But climate change is

    experienced locally, so Part 6 will explore the role o local conditions. Regional weather patterns or individual

    catastrophes are sometimes interpreted as evidence o climate change and can galvanize communities

    and individuals into action. Extreme weather can destroy inrastructure, leading to higher local taxes and

    depleting the asset base. Local conditionsinrastructure, wealth, regulations, and morewill determine

    the costs o adapting to a changing climate in a given area. Because we experience climate change at the

    community level, local policies and market dynamics become more important, as they are ways to tailor

    solutions to the conditions immediately at hand.

    We return to the macro policy level in Part 7, which contains a visual summary o our thinking. While

    the Pacala and Socolow ramework or climate change policy comprises seven wedges, a market-based

    policy looks like a mosaicthe aggregation o many private decisions. Looking urther into the uture andpreparing the groundwork or the second stage o a market-based climate policy, we outline the objectives

    or an intense, ambitious R&D eort that would develop the key technologies to be deployed.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    8/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    3

    2. Buying Time with Climate Change Policy

    In 2007 the United Nations issued a series o reports that revealed new scientic data, updated climate

    change models, and presented strategies or mitigation. The reports warned that the world must reverse the

    growth o greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions in the next ew years (by 2012 or 2015) to prevent serious climate

    disruptions.3 One o the clearest and most accessible ormulations o how we might quickly reverse global

    emissions trends was put orth by Pacala and Socolow (2004). Figure 1 is a stylization o their scheme.

    Figure 1: The Emissions Reduction Challenge

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    12

    14

    16

    1900 1950 2000 2050

    Year

    AnnualCarbonEmissions

    (gigatonsof CO)

    Current Trend

    Toward Doubling

    of Emissions

    Toward

    Stabilization

    of Emissions

    Great Depression

    Present Levels

    Source: Carbon data rom Carbon Dioxide Inormation Analysis Center, Oak Ridge National Laboratory,U.S. Department o Energy

    Figure 1 traces actual emissions between 1900 and 2005, and then shows alternate projections to 2055. The

    sharply increasing trajectory in the second hal o the twentieth century illustrates the size o the challenge

    we ace; reversing the long-term trend will be a huge endeavor. Emissions in 2005 were approximately 7

    gigatons o carbon per year (7GtC/year). Pacala and Socolow noted that i we continue along this trend line,

    the amount o carbon in the atmosphere in 2055 would be double the amount we have today and triple the

    atmospheric concentrations o the pre-industrial era (beore 1780 or so). On the other hand, we can halt

    emissions growth at current levels. The area inside the two scenarios sums up the climate change challenge.

    Is there a way to avoid the top path? Which technologies could soak up the anticipated emissions that lie

    between the top path and the fat path?

    3 U.N. Chie Seeks More Leadership on Climate Change,New York Times, November 18, 2007.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    9/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    4

    Figure 2: The Wedge/Technology Solution

    7 wedges (7 technologies)

    are needed to stabilize

    emissions

    1 wedge = 1 gigaton of

    CO2 emissions in 2050

    Stabilization of Emissions GrowthTODAY 2050

    Extrapolation of Historical

    Emissions Growth

    Figure 2 shows the ramework or the solution. The stabilization triangle has been divided into sevenwedges. Each wedge starts out as a thin sliver in the year 2005, but grows over time, eventually eliminating

    emissions o 1 gigaton o carbon dioxide (GtC) per year by 2055. Emissions in 2055 are expected to be 7

    GtC larger per year than 2005 levels, so seven wedges are needed to achieve emissions stabilization. In their

    paper, Pacala and Socolow suggested teen immediately available technologies that could serve as wedges,

    including solar energy, biouels, nuclear power, carbon sequestration, energy eciency in buildings, and

    so on. Their point was that we need not wait to achieve emissions stabilization. Acting today can arrest

    emissions growth, setting us on the fat path and buying time to nd new ways to create steeper emissions

    reductions ater 2055.

    As the authors detail, the technologies are currently available, but they must be deployed at historically

    unprecedented levels to achieve the emissions reduction o a wedge. For example, natural gas produces

    about hal the carbon emissions o coal per unit o energy, so one wedge might be the switch rom coal to

    gas. But to achieve a reduction o 1 GtC by 2055, the use o natural gas must grow to our times its current

    level. Photovoltaics (solar cells or producing electricity) might serve as another wedge, but similarly, the

    photovoltaics capacity installed and running in 2055 would have to be 700 times larger than todays capacity

    (equivalent to a 14 percent annual growth rate) to achieve a 1GtC emissions reduction by 2055. Because

    they are ocused on technology, Pacala and Socolow do not detail how these massive changes would be

    catalyzed or how deployment rates would be sustained or the next ty years. Their action plan is missing

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    10/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    5

    the incentives needed to begin and sustain this massive capital stock transormation. (An obvious rst step

    is to look or the lowest-cost solutions, which we will examine in the next section.)

    It is useul to compare the emissions stabilization strategy proposed by Pacala and Socolow to other policies

    currently enacted or proposed. While Pacala and Socolow base their analysis on a two-step solution, localand national polices are more aggressive one-step programs. These are shown in Figure 3.

    Figure 3: Massive Capital Stock Transormation Under Any Climate Change Policy

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    12

    14

    16

    1900 1950 2000 2050

    Year

    ExtrapolationTwice current level

    StabilizationCurrent level

    RPS1990s level

    Cap & trade1970s level

    Complete reversal1780s level

    Annual

    CarbonEmissions

    (gigatonsof CO)

    Historical Emissions

    Present Levels

    The rst reduction plan shown in the gure is the Renewable Portolio Standards (RPS), programs enacted

    by twenty-six states that are generally aimed at reducing emissions to 1990s levels. The cap-and-tradelegislation considered by Congress is more aggressive, with a goal o reducing emissions to 1970s levels.

    As todays emission rate is 70 percent higher than the rate in 1970s, these legislative proposals contain a

    signicant reversal o the capital stock choices made since then and a historically unprecedented decoupling

    o emissions growth and economic growth. And, as a nal note, because carbon takes decades to leave the

    atmosphere once it is emitted, it will require a severe reduction in emissions to achieve a reduction o carbon

    in the atmosphere.4

    The policy proposals illustrated in Figure 3 contain ambitious goals, but at least in the early stages, these

    goals are being met. Their early success conrms Pacala and Socolows initial contention: we already have

    the technologies today that can stabilize emissions. What is missing rom this picture is how to sustain and

    expand these early wins in a growing economy.

    4 A useul summary o climate status is: Summary or Policymakers o the Synthesis Report o the IPCC FourthAssessment Report, IPCC, November 15, 2007 (www.ipcc.ch/pd/assessment-report/ar4/syr/ar4_syr_spm.pd).

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    11/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    6

    Reducing Emissions: Now or Later? And Who Will Take the Lead?

    No one knows exactly how climate change will unold and what its eects will be, and emissions reduction is

    costly. Suppose breakthrough technologies that can cheaply and easily remove carbon rom our atmosphereare just around the corner. Why invest in emissions reduction today? One answer was provided by the Stern

    Review, a British report issued in early 2007 that translated rising temperatures and changes in climate

    patterns to economic losses.5 The report examined many potential outcomes, but one mid-range scenario in

    particular provides a useul summary: unless action is taken today, the size o the economy in 2050 will be

    signicantly smaller, a shrinkage that negatively impacts the standard o living and worsens the poverty rate.

    (Predicted outcomes range rom a 3 percent loss o GDP to a 20 percent reduction in capital consumption.)

    To avoid this catastrophe, the Stern Review argues that it is worthwhile to give up 1 percent o GDP today.

    When presented as a crisp trade-o, the choice seems clear, and the report argues or immediate action.

    But climate change is a very uncertain process, and this uncertainty rerames the question: do we want to

    sacrice todays GDP to insure against uture economic losses? Perhaps waiting to invest is a better choice,

    particularly when any reduction in GDP has a high immediate human cost. Insights into these trade-os

    can be gained rom considering a model on the value o waiting in the ace o environmental uncertainty

    presented by Robert Pindyck o MIT.6 Pindyck notes that there are two types o uncertainty: economic (the

    cost o various uels and output prices) and environmental. Economic uncertainty is reversibleprices go

    up and downwhile environmental uncertainty may not be so. Others, such as Gregg Easterbook, have

    argued that environmental damage (acid rain, the hole on the ozone layer, and so on) has been reversed

    through concerted action in the past, with aster results and a lower cost than was expected.7 Thus waiting

    to solve climate change may be less costly than we surmise. Pindycks model shows, however, that even a

    small amount o environmental irreversibility greatly diminishes the value o waiting. Certainly the news

    headlines suggest increasing concern by scientists that the point o irreversible damage is near.8

    5The Stern Review on the Economics o Climate Change, Oce o the Treasury, British government(http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/stern_review_economics_climate_change/sternreview_index.cm).

    6 Robert S. Pindyck, Uncertainty in Environmental Economics (December 2006): NBER Working Paper No.W12752. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=949761.

    7 Gregg Easterbook, Some Convenient Truths,Atlantic Monthly, September 2006.

    8 U.N. Chie Seeks More Leadership on Climate Change,New York Times, November 18, 2007, and In Greenland,Ice and Instability,New York Times, January 8, 2008. See also Summary or Policymakers o the Synthesis Reporto the IPCC Fourth Assessment Report, IPCC (www.ipcc.ch/pd/assessment-report/ar4/syr/ar4_syr_spm.pd).

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    12/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    7

    The Stern Reviews numbers and Pindycks model argue or immediate action. Meanwhile, newspaper

    headlines make the link between local weather, adverse outcomes, and climate changesuggesting that

    we have no time to wait.9 But what immediate actions should we take? And who should lead the way? Any

    social insurance policy will have uneven and immediate costs on current citizens. How can a representative

    institution link these tangible costs to vague and elusive benets? In a successul scenario, the costs are

    borne and disaster is averted, leaving many citizens eeling overtaxed. But in most scenarios, the costs are

    borne and damage is incurred anywayleaving citizens believing that their government ailed to prepare

    or disaster.

    The issue o social insurance, as with the stabilization ramework o Pacala and Socolow, raises questions

    about the actors. Later in the paper, we will provide examples o government actions that have been too

    little, too late when conronted with uncertain disaster orecasts. Leadership comes not only rom tough

    macro trade-os, but also rom micro-level policies that strengthen markets and tip private decisions to

    clean outcomes, making individual consumers the key actors.

    9 A random sampling rom theNew York Times: Inch by Inch, Great Lakes Shrink, and Cargo Carriers Face Losses,October 22, 2007; Precipitation Across U.S. Intensies Over 50 Years, December 5, 2007; World Food SupplyIs Shrinking, U.N. Agency Warns, December 18, 2007; U.N. Chie Seeks More Leadership on Climate Change,November 18, 2007; and In Greenland, Ice and Instability, January 8, 2008. See also the U.N. report cited in note 8.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    13/42

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    14/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    9

    3. Cheap Solutions, Broken Markets

    Technologists, who provide a list o possible technologies that could stabilize emissions, are oten ollowed

    by business analysts, who rank the available technologies by cost. Over the years there have been a number

    o detailed studies that provide a clear sorting o emissions-reducing technologies.10 Table 1 summarizes

    ndings rom a recent study by McKinsey & Co., a global consulting rm.

    Table 1: Technology Solutions Ranked by Cost

    Cost per ton

    of CO2

    abatedPositive return

    on investmentBelow $25 per ton $25 to $50 per ton

    Total Reduction

    (gigatons of CO2

    per year)1.3 0.8 1.0

    SelectedTechnologies

    Building insulation Nuclear Industrial motor systems

    Lighting systems Livestock Carbon capture

    and sequestration

    Air conditioning Forestation Coal plant retrots

    Water heating Enhanced oil recovery Waste

    Fuel eciencyWind

    (low cost penetration)Biodiesel

    Technologies that reduce emissions are listed in three columns in the table. The items in the rst group, on

    the let, have lietime benets that exceed their cost, providing a positive return on investment. Cumulatively,

    these technologies could reduce annual CO2

    emissions by 1.3 gigatons. Technologies in the middle group

    cost less than $25 per ton o CO2

    abated, and the third group, in the right column, costs less than $50 per

    ton abated. The total savings possible rom employing all o these technologies is 3.1 gigatons per year. Many

    o these technologies, such as building insulation or increased water heater eciency, are available right

    now. Others, such as coal plant retrots or biodiesel, are expected to reach a cost-eective scale by 2030.

    Results similar to those shown in the table have been ound by others as well; some technologies such as

    insulation and ecient water heating continually pop up as good personal investments that happen to be

    good or the environment as well. So the obvious question is: i these technologies are so cheap that they

    actually make us money, why arent they widely adopted, to the point o negative marginal returns?

    The answer to this question has been called the eciency gapthe dierence between the clear, avorable

    economics o many energy-eciency technologies and their low rate o deployment. The eciency gap has

    been noted in energy policy literature since the energy crisis o the mid-1970s.11

    10 An early study is Alan Manne and Richard Richels, Buying Greenhouse Insurance (MIT Press, 1992). See alsoClimate Map 2030 by Vattenall, January 2007 (http://www.vattenall.com/climatemap/) and Reducing U.S.Greenhouse Gas Emissions: How Much at What Cost?, McKinsey & Co., November 2007 (http://mckinsey.com/clientservice/ccsi/).

    11 Alan Manne and Richard Richels, Buying Greenhouse Insurance (MIT Press, 1992).

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    15/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    10

    In a recent article, Marilyn Brown succinctly laid out the reasons or the eciency gap, including

    misalignment o incentives (the principal-agent problem); weak price signals; insucient inormation; lack

    o capital; distortions through legislative or scal policies; unpriced costs; unpriced benets; and the relative

    unimportance o carbon reduction compared to other investment or purchase attributes.12

    Adam Jae and Robert Stavins examined the rational eatures o investment or consumer adoption behavior

    that could lead to the appearance o an energy-eciency gap. 13 For example, they noted that technologies

    come in bundles o attributes, and oten a prominent eature is unattractive. Many people, or example,

    understand that compact fuorescent bulbs save energy, but still wont buy them because they dont like the

    color o light the bulbs produce. In a similar vein, a recent article proled the green choices o a ski resort.

    Each year the green team presented ideas that lowered both costs and energy use to the resort owner, only

    to see them squeezed out o the budget by less green projects with higher returns.14 Finally, Jae and Stavins

    note that new technologies ace long adoption cycles, so a critical observer might see an energy-eciency

    gap, but the reality is a normal rate o adoptionone that remains incomplete or many years.

    To ully understand the notion o the energy-eciency gap, consider the lowly residential water heater. Every

    house has one, and on average they consume about 15 percent o the homeowners energy budget. 15 The

    EPA estimates that 60 percent o water heaters are replaced on an emergency basis. 16 The rustration o a

    homeowner temporarily without hot water no doubt puts energy eciency last on the list o buying actors.

    In the middle o the night, or on short notice, the homeowner calls the installer to replace the water heater.

    But the installers incentives have little to do with energy eciency. His perormance is being measured on

    speed, the reliability o his product, and his service demeanor. Meanwhile, many parties are trying to tip

    the homeowners decision: the utility oers a rebate or energy eciency; the U.S. government oers a tax

    credit; and a host o nonprot advocacy groups provide detailed inormation on ecient water heaters. Yet,in the panic o having no hot water, none o these actors matter greatly. Speed trumps other concerns.

    The water heater decision brings up another problem. There is so little dierentiation between standard gas

    and electric water heaters that, in 2004, the EPA declined to rate them or inclusion in their Energy Star

    program. Since 2004 a number o new technologies have been developed and marketed, but they have a

    combined market share o less than 1 percent. This urther conuses the marketplace, as the installers must

    act as pioneering adopters or their customersa very risky business proposition!

    12 Marilyn Brown, Market Failures and Barriers as a Basis or Clean Energy Policies, Energy Policy 29,pp. 1197 1207).

    13 Adam Jae and Robert Stavins. 1994. The Energy Eciency Gap: What Does It Mean? Energy Policy 22 (10):804810. A. Jae, R. Newell and R. Stavins, Energy-Ecient Technologies and Climate Change Policies: Issuesand Evidence, Resources or the Future (r.org), 1999.

    14 Little Green Lies, BusinessWeek, October 20, 2007, 4552.

    15 http://www.energystar.gov/index.cm?c=new_specs.water_heaters.

    16 EPA water heater drat 2 update.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    16/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    11

    Now lets look at the 40 percent o homes that do not replace their water heaters on an emergency basis.

    Table 1 shows two o the actors infuencing a replacement decisionthe outdoor water temperature and

    the cost o natural gasand the optimal replacement decision or three dierent locations. The results in

    the middle column show the number o occupants needed to warrant an early replacement. For example,

    in Palo Alto, Caliornia, where natural gas prices are high, early replacement is warranted in all homes. But

    in Brookline, Massachusetts, where gas prices are lower, early replacement is warranted only in homes with

    high hot water use.

    Table 2: The Water Heater Early Replacement Decision in Three Locations

    Cold watertemperature

    (F)

    Price ofnatual gas

    ($ per therm)

    Replace ifnumber ofresidentsexceeds

    Cost of water( per 10gallons)

    Replace ifnumber ofresidentsexceeds

    Brookline, MA 48 $1.30 5 13.7 6

    Sunnyvale, CA 56 $1.47 3 2.7 5

    Palo Alto, CA 62 $2.07 0 6.5 0

    Note: Assumes constant natural gas prices; early replacement is warranted when a price rise o more than 3 percent per year is orecast.Source: GreenNow USA

    The two right-hand columns o Table 2 illustrate the perversity o some energy-water links. First, examine

    the column showing the water costs to the homeowner. The costs are the highest in Brookline, where a per-

    gallon assessment was added to water bills to pay or a new sewage treatment plant in Boston Harbor. Palo

    Alto has the second-highest water rates, due to the presence o a wastewater treatment plant. Sunnyvale

    gets the majority o its water rom a local acquier. In all three locations, there are substantial savings to

    be gained by using less hot water in showers. This can be done by shortening shower time or replacing the

    shower head with an ultra-low fow unit (one that uses 1.25 gallons per minute instead o the fow rate o

    most shower heads, which is 2.5 gallons per minute). Ironically, once hot water use is reduced by a new

    shower head, there is less value in replacing a standard hot water heater with an energy-ecient one. This

    is shown by an increase in the number o occupants needed in each home to warrant early replacement in

    Brookline and Sunnyvale.

    The simple water heater market is a good illustration o the energy-eciency gap. Decisions are made or

    noneciency reasons, and there is an interaction between technologies (water heater vs. shower head) thatrationally slows diusion o the most ecient water heater models. Further, the optimal replacement decision

    varies by locale and depends on a number o local actors. The rebates, tax incentives, and inormation rom

    advocacy groups seem tangential to the issues driving purchase and replacement decisions in this market.

    The water heater market unctions, but is unresponsive to energy-eciency concerns.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    17/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    12

    Low-Tech and High-Tech Solutions for Air Conditioning Load

    Air conditioning is ubiquitous throughout the United States; in most regions, it is ound in almost

    every home. Nationally, air conditioning accounts or 15 percent o total residential electricity

    demand.17 In response to the heavy load air conditioning places on the power grid during peak

    hours and hot days, utilities are implementing smart meters that cycle air conditioners o or 15

    minutes per hour.18 At the same time, a recent study shows that air conditioning loads can be

    reduced by 15 to 30 percent by the use o awnings that prevent sunlight rom reaching into the

    home during the summer months.19 Alternately, homeowners can plant trees on the south and

    west sides o their homes, shade their air conditioning units, or install window shades.20

    Both low-tech and high-tech solutions are available to close the eciency gapbut the

    connections provided by markets to stimulate change are missing.

    17 U.S. Household Electricity Report,Energy Inormation Administration,U.S. Department o Energy, July 14,2005.

    18 See, or example, the smart meter web page or Southern Caliornia Edison(http://www.sce.com/PowerandEnvironment/ami/deault.htm?=rom=redirect).

    19 Awnings in Residential Buildings: The Impact on Energy Use and Peak Demand, University o Minnesota,Center or Sustainable Building Research, June 2007.

    20 Donald R. Wulngho, Energy Efciency Manual (Energy Institute Press, March 2000).

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    18/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    13

    4. The Central Role of Private Investment Decisions

    We now present our conceptual ramework or linking private investment decisions, emissions, and policies.

    Public inrastructure plays an analogous role to private investment in this ramework. But it is dicult or

    institutions to make decisions when aced with large and shiting uncertainties, so their role in a dynamic

    and ast-changing environment is diminished. The private side o the eedback loop is where the action is.

    Figure 4: Emissions Reductions: The Central Role o Private Decisions

    Our ramework is shown in Figure 4. To trace through the links and fows, lets start at the bottom, with

    the physical world o climate change. In the pre-industrial world, net emissions were near zero; carbon

    emissions were in balance with the planets capacity to absorb carbon. In our modern world, net emissions

    are signicantly positive, as carbon emissions are ar larger than carbon sinks. The large amount o net

    emissions raises the stock o carbon in the atmosphere, which in turn raises temperatures and sea levels.21

    The second level o the ramework shows the two main drivers o human emissions: behavior and capital

    stock. Behavior (how much we drive, how high we set our thermostats, and so on) is fexible; behavior-driven

    emissions can be reduced in the short run by simple modications. Our capital stock (cars, buildings, and thelike) is xed and leads to persistent emissions. One o the clearest examples o this was an experiment run in

    a housing development in Lakeland, Florida.22 Two homes were completed in 1998 with the same foor plans

    21 Paul Falkowski, et al., The Global Carbon Cycle: A Test o Our Knowledge o Earth as a System, Science, Vol.290, No. 5490, pp. 291206. Nicholas Gruber, et al., Interannual Variability in the North Atlantic Ocean CarbonSink, Science, Vol. 298: 2378.

    22 See Building America: Research Is Leading the Way to Zero Energy Homes, U.S. Department o Energy(http://www.eere.energy.gov/buildings/building_america/pds/37547_zeh.pd).

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    19/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    14

    and orientation. Through specic energy-ecient choices during the building process, one home used only

    10 percent o the power consumed by the other. With an expected service lie o orty to sixty years, there

    will be a persistent dierence in energy consumption that even good habits cannot erase.

    The third layer o our ramework fags the two deciders or capital stock: the individuals who make private

    investment decisions and the institutions who make public inrastructure decisions. The challenge or

    climate change policy is to make emissions concerns a signicant actor in private decisions, or as we saw

    rom the water heater example, there are many other actors that drive capital stock decisions. The status

    o public inrastructure also tips private investment decisions. For example, water in the Los Angeles basin

    comes through a complex inrastructure, in which water is transported rom north to south through the

    Caliornia Aqueduct and rom the Colorado River on the eastern border o the state to the coast. These

    water suppliesvulnerable to earthquakes and energy-intensehave allowed the rapid population growth

    o Los Angeles. Without this inrastructure, Los Angeles would not be nearly as large; the presence o public

    inrastructure tipped private housing decisions.

    The top layer o the chart closes the eedback loops. Markets, regulatory policies, and public institutions set

    the stage or the economic considerations o private and public capital stock decisions. Climate outcomes,

    such as rising temperatures or extreme weather, infuence policies. Eective organizations and institutions

    at the top level can infuence private decisions toward reduced emissions.

    In Figure 4, the lines connecting the markets and private investment decisions are darker than those

    connecting institutions and public inrastructure. For several reasons, we see public institutions and

    inrastructure playing a secondary role to private decisions and markets in the dynamic selection o clean

    technologies. Here are some examples that cause us to question the decision-making possibilities o public

    entities given the uncertain trajectory o climate change.

    The problem is clear, but government action is not orthcoming:

    U.S. sewers need $500 billion in repairs, but local governments are reluctant to raise taxes or a

    problem voters cant see.23

    The southeastern region o the United States is just months away rom running out o water and

    local ocials are taking actions to drastically cut water use. Yet the Atlanta Journal-Constitution

    reports that the problem was entirely oreseeable. A 2007 article noted that, Georgias water

    shortage took decades to develop, with action thwarted by ocials short attention spans, euds

    between states, and the alse assurance o rainy years.24

    A prolonged lack o rain in the western United States led theNew York Times Magazine to wonder:

    Will population growth and climate change leave the West without water? The West is the

    astest-growing part o the country. Its also the driest.25

    23 Deteriorating Sewer Systems: A Dirty and Costly Secret, Wall Street Journal, November 20, 2007.

    24 Recipe or a Water Crisis: Plan. Fail. Repeat,Atlanta Journal-Constitution, December 16, 2007.

    25 The Future Is Drying Up,New York Times Magazine, October 21, 2007.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    20/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    15

    Scientists predict the collapse o 75 percent o the worlds sheries by 2050, which will have

    devastating consequences or 1 billion people who rely on sh or their major source o protein.26

    Yet coordinated global action on this international problem is entirely lacking, although the

    challenge is more clear and the solution more simple than what we ace with climate change.

    The problem is not seen by constituents:

    Nobel Prizewinning economist Daniel Kahneman has observed: The potential consequences

    o climate change are completely abstract, as ar as the population is concerned. Nobody is

    eeling a thing, yet. To mobilize public opinion to get anything done is extremely dicult. One

    has to question whether the social arrangements by which we live are adequate to cope with the

    threat.27

    Problems arise in maintaining the public policy/private markets balance ater extreme events. The insurance

    markets are an example rom the ront lines.

    Private insurers exited the Caliornia earthquake insurance market ater the 1994 Northridge

    earthquake. The state established its own program, but high deductibles ($50,000) and large

    premiums ($1,700 to $2,800 per year) have kept 89 percent o Caliornians rom buying in.

    Meanwhile, Caliornians keep making the private decision to build and buy homes in areas with

    high earthquake risk.28

    In Louisiana, high insurance premiums and greater restrictions have made insurance unattractive

    to homeowners ater Katrina. Insurers are not willing to cover parties new to the state, and this

    has hurt recovery eorts.29

    Floridas governor pleased voters by mandating lower insurance premiumsbut insurance

    companies responded by dropping customers. The one company that is picking up customers isunder-capitalized, leaving insured and uninsured homeowners in the state vulnerable to nancial

    ruin when the next large hurricane strikes.30

    This list could go on, but our basic point is clear: climate change is a tough issue or public institutions to

    tackle. Its uncertain trajectory, diuse costs, and complex causes make climate change ill-suited or public

    decision-making in a timely or adaptive manner. Decaying public inrastructure is vulnerable to extreme

    weather events, and ater such a disaster the path to recovery is not clear.

    Meanwhile, citizens continue to make private decisions, and markets help them rapidly adapt to changing

    conditions. For these reasons, we emphasize the eedback loop through market and private decisions that is

    illustrated in Figure 4.

    26 For a good summary, see Collapse: End o the Global Fish Stock by 2050?, an issue brie rom Globalization 101,the Carnegie Endowment or International Peace/the Levin Institute, December 2006(http://www.globalization101.org/index.php?le=news1&id=75).

    27 From Global Warming to Weight Watching, Milken Institute Review, September 2006, p. 29.

    28 Ater the Quake, Who Will Be the Chump? San Jose Mercury News, September 10, 2007.

    29 Risky Business: Insurers See the Big Easy as the Big Loser, Fortune, August 20, 2007, pp. 7785.

    30 Wishing the Wind Not to Blow, The Economist, August 11, 2007, p. 28.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    21/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    16

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    22/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    17

    5. New and Reconnected Markets to Support Private Decisions

    One o the most compelling eatures o the stabilization triangle analysis created by Pacala and Socolow is their

    menu o technologies that are ready to scale to achieve substantial emissions reduction. In this section, we

    will present a similarly immediate and compelling set o market opportunities to reduce emissions, including

    companies and new markets already at work. Our survey o opportunities covers ve areas: service-based

    business models; the creation o new markets through legislative and regulator at; the use o standards and

    transparent metrics to accelerate market growth; modernization o the utility business model; and restricted

    choices to integrate markets. When possible, in the discussion that ollows, the text provides the enduring

    economic insights, while the gures summarize the current status. We expect the gures to become rapidly

    out o date as the markets evolve.

    ESCOsIn other new or ragmented markets, the market players and issues have been connected through a service

    provider. Systems integrators played this role in past eras o the computer industry, providing expert knowledge

    to companies struggling with their hardware and sotware purchases. As the water heater example above

    demonstrated, there is a similar business opportunity in the energy markets.

    In energy markets serving industrial and large commercial customers, this service model already exists in the

    orm o ESCOs (energy service companies). An ESCO will perorm an on-site audit, recommend energy-

    and water-reduction strategies, and then, i the client approves, implement the changes. Water heating is a

    large end-use or this market segment, and there is a strong interaction between energy and water savings.

    ESCOs are paid as consultants and/or or savings perormance.

    Table 3 shows the current innovative market variations on the ESCO business model.

    Table 3: Innovative ESCO Business Models

    Service Model Sample Companies Target Customers

    ESCO owns solar installation

    on customers roo, sells solar

    power back to customer.

    Sun Run, SunEdisonHome owners, small and

    medium-size businesses

    Nonprot entity (unded byutilities) acts as ull-service

    ESCO, including nancing.

    Oregon Energy Trust, Eciency

    VermontHomes and businesses

    Peak demand aggregators

    Energy Curtailment Services,

    EnerNOC, Consumer Powerline,

    Converge, Energy Connect

    Businesses in targeted

    geographic power markets

    Nonprot ESCO is role model

    o better practices.Clinton Foundation 44 cities around the world

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    23/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    18

    We have several comments on the current status o the ESCO endeavors. First, their market orce is growing

    rapidly. For example, peak-demand aggregators currently manage 2,600 MW o peak capacity, the energy

    equivalent o our and a hal average-sized coal plants. Second, there are some recent and important

    innovations in the ESCO business model. The Clinton Foundation, or example, pools together projects in

    a single city or a smoother construction schedule and increased purchasing power. The contract passes this

    savings on to the building owners, signicantly reducing the cost o energy eciency.

    Another innovative variant on the ESCO service model is the reworking o a xed cost to a variable cost.

    Sun Run and SunEdison, or example, dont sell solar systems; they sell solar power. Instead o incurring

    a large up-ront cost, the customer buys power as it is generated rom these companies; the companies

    themselves own and maintain the rootop systems. A similar xed-to-variable cost transormation in the

    insurance markets (pay-as-you-drive insurance) has decreased miles and emissions by 9 percent.31 Pay-as-

    you-drive insurance is available in Europe, and a pilot project is underway in Washington state. Further

    proposals include pay-as-you-pump insurance, so that drivers must requently conront the ull cost odriving. For both solar panels and auto insurance, the innovative service model uses a variable charge to

    elicit the desired behavior.

    31 Ian Parry, Pay as You Drive Insurance: A Better Way to Reduce Gasoline than Gas Taxes?, Resources or theFuture, April 2005.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    24/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    19

    New Markets Created by Fiat

    Several new markets or energy and emissions have been created at the state and regional level. Table 4

    summarizes.

    Table 4: New Markets or Emissions Reductions

    Market Rationale Scale of Adoption

    Renewable Energy

    Credits (RECs)

    State mandates renewable power

    generation and allows utilities to

    buy and sell RECs

    to meet goals.

    29 states, 1020% o local energy

    markets.

    White tags

    State mandates energy eciency

    and allows utilities to buy and sell

    tags to meet goals.

    Connecticut mandate; under

    consideration in other states.

    Needs verication protocol.

    Carbon credits (U.S.)

    Voluntary trading: More than

    300 companies have joined the

    Chicago Carbon Exchange (CCX).

    34 million tons o CO2

    eliminated

    since 2003; $2$5 per ton.

    Carbon credits

    (Europe)Mandatory trading

    100 million tons o CO2

    traded per

    month; $24$26 per ton.

    Green pricing

    Utility customers voluntarily agree

    to increased rates to secure power

    rom renewable energy.

    Retail option in 44 states.

    Incremental cost o 1.52 cents

    per kwh. Average adoption rate o

    1.5% to date.

    The new markets or emissions reduction can be used in several ways. First, they smooth the costs o mandated

    investments in renewable technologies, as the renewable energy credits (RECs) and carbon credits provide

    fexibility over geography and time. Second, the credits accelerate clean-technology adoption when used

    in project nancing. One example is the Oregon Energy Trusts use o voluntary carbon credits rom the

    Chicago Carbon Exchange (CCX). The ESCO has been able to monetize 5 to 7 percent o the capital

    improvements it subsidizes.32 Third, the markets are used to spur innovation.

    32 Production Eciency Program, Best Practices, Oregon Energy Trust Presentation at the Joint West Coast PublicUtility Commissions 2006 Energy Eciency Workshop in San Francisco, December 1, 2006.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    25/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    20

    Broadly, the new emissions markets are changing energy rom a single-dimensioned commodity to a multi-

    dimensioned product. Imagine a host o sub-scripts on a unit o energy:

    E BTU, RE, EE, PCO2, PK, STSt

    BTU = price o energy content

    RE = price premium or renewable energy (REC)

    EE = price premium or energy eciency (white tag)

    PCO2

    = price premium or carbon reduction (carbon credit on CCX)

    PK = price premium or peak demand reduction

    ST = state where power is generated (so as to comply with local mandates)

    With these sub-scripts, each unit o energy will be bought and sold in the emissions markets as well as on thecommodity markets. Fourteen Western states and eight New England states have ormed two wide trading

    zones or RECs that will allow increased trading and arbitrage opportunities. This rich market inrastructure

    will lead to more ecient energy use and greater reduction in emissions.

    Standards

    Inormation gaps oten lie at the heart o the market barriers to adopting energy eciency, but standards

    can be used to insert inormation into the fow o commerce. For example, in early January 2008, the

    Massachusetts State Senate passed a bill that would require home sellers to obtain an energy audit, so as to

    inorm potential buyers o the homes energy costs.33

    The European Union has had a similar measure in place since January 2006. 34 Figure 5 shows a certicate

    required or each home in the EU at the time o sale or rent. In the box on the let, the home is given an

    energy-eciency score, and a score or its potential. Each is accompanied by a letter grade. In the sample

    certicate, the home is rated E but could improve to a C. For this home, the A grade remains elusive, most

    likely due to retrot challenges. The box on the right shows the homes CO2

    emissions rating.

    33 Bill Seeks Home-Energy Use at Sale, Boston Globe, January 11, 2008.

    34 http://www.ecorating.co.uk/eco-house/energy-perormance-certicate/deault.aspx.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    26/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    21

    Figure 5: EU Home Perormance Ratings Make the Carbon Footprint Visible

    Source: Energy Perormance in Buildings Directive

    The EU standard does not require homes to meet a minimum level o perormance, but merely having

    access to this inormation can change the decisions o buyers and renters. Homes that are more energy

    ecient should command higher prices in the long run, as the energy savings are capitalized into the value

    o the house. With more rapid turnover, the rental market will more quickly dierentiate, and rental prices

    will all or homes and apartments with expected high energy costs.

    Table 5 shows the multiple eorts to create standards in the U.S. market.

    Table 5: Selected U.S. Standards Eforts

    Standard Sponsor Adopters

    LEED U.S. Green Building CouncilCommercial buildingsnationwide

    GreenPoints BuildItGreenNew constructionin Caliornia

    Home EnergyRating System (HERS)

    Resnet Nationwide

    Home Perormancewith Energy Star

    U.S. Department o EnergyLocal organizations,19 states

    International PerormanceMeasurement and VericationProtocol (IPMVP)

    Coordinated with U.S.government agencies

    Worldwide protocolor commercial sector

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    27/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    22

    There is a host o supporting technology to implement these standards, including test equipment, data loggers,

    and sotware models. This in turn has led to the creation o several start-up companies that specialize in these

    technologies, as well as market entry by established companies. Clean tech does not always mean power

    generation, and as markets and standards develop, it will require the presence o supporting inrastructure

    technologies.

    Modernizing the Utility Business Model

    Using less energy is a direct route to reduced carbon emissions. Forty percent o our nations energy

    consumption fows through electric and gas utilities, under their pricing structures and rate-o-return

    regulations.35 In most o the United States the only way a utility can increase revenues is by selling more

    power. Their fat or even downward tiered pricing systems discourage conservation. But Oregon and

    Caliornia have passed legislation that decouples electricity sales rom prots, making it possible or utilitiesin those states to prot rom the energy conservation o their customers.36 Ten states have similar policies to

    encourage natural gas savings.37 Decoupling allows utilities to avoid costly new construction i it is cheaper

    to purchase energy conservation and energy eciency rom its customers.

    A second mechanism to encourage energy conservation is through upward tiered energy pricing. Time-

    o-use pricing has been requently suggested as way or customers to pay their ull cost o service during

    peak periods. Strong opposition to time-o-use pricing can be expected, however, rom those industries that

    have heavily subsidized electricity rates under our current fat pricing scheme.38 Tiered pricing may be a

    more palatable political alternative because it provides low-cost energy or a base level o usage. As Figure

    6 shows, upward tiered pricing encourages energy conservation. In addition, research shows that upward

    tiered pricing can be made revenue-neutral or the average customer, even as it encourages high-consuming

    customers to be the early adopters o on-site renewable technology.39

    35 Energy Basics 101, Energy Inormation Administration (http://www.eia.doe.gov/basics/energybasics101.html).

    36 Martin Kushler, et al.,Aligning Utility Interests with Energy Eciency Objectives: A Review o Recent Eortsat Decoupling and Perormance Incentives, American Council or an Energy-Ecient Economy, October 2006,report U061.

    37 American Gas Association.

    38 Severin Borenstein, Wealth Transers rom Implementing Real-Time Retail Electricity Pricing,(September 2005). NBER Working Paper No. W11594 (available at Social Science Research Network:http://ssrn.com/abstract=800449).

    39 Thomas Hu and Christy Herig, Electricity Rate Structures Can Be Used to Promote Solar PV: Lessons romCaliornia, June 19, 2002 (clean-power.com). For example, in northern Caliornia the early adopters o photo-voltaics are requently at the top price levels shown in Figure 12. For these homes, photovoltaics (at an average 22cents per kwh) are immediately cost-eective.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    28/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    23

    Figure 6: Tiered Pricing Changes Consumption

    8.25.4 5.1

    11.413

    22.7

    31.7

    36.4

    16 66 kwh/day

    /kwh

    13 16 26 38 kwh/day

    Pricing to encourage consumption

    Otter Tail Power Co.

    (Northern Minnesota)

    Pricing to discourage consumption

    PG&E

    (Northern California)

    /kwh

    Restricted Choice Sets

    Landlords buy appliances, but renters actually pay the electricity bills. The housing developer saves $2,000 in

    construction costs, but it is the home buyer who will ultimately pay an extra $600 per year in heating bills due

    to inadequate insulation. The uninormed consumer goes to the appliance store and saves $300 by buying the

    low-cost unit, only to pay $75 per year in extra energy costs. An eective way to close these principal-agent

    and inormation gaps is through appliance and building standards. Appliance standards are estimated to save1 to 3 percent o the nations energy use, but have an outsized impact, as sometimes a demand decrease o this

    size can remove congestion in the natural gas markets and drop prices by 10 to 20 percent.40

    During the energy crisis o the 1970s, Caliornia adopted the nations tightest building codes. Since then,

    Caliornias per-capita energy consumption has remained fat, while the U.S. average per-capita consumption

    has increased by 50 percent.41 About hal o Caliornias savings are estimated to come rom the states

    building standards and eciency standards or appliances. The other hal o the savings came rom regulator

    incentives to encourage customer energy conservation. Caliornias experience shows that local building

    codeswhile not nearly as glamorous as solar and wind powerhave played an important role in decreasing

    energy use.

    40 Leading the Way: Continued Opportunities or New State Appliance and Equipment Eciency Standards,American Council or an Energy-Ecient Economy, March 2006. See also Jae, Newell, and Stavins, Energy-Ecient Technologies and Climate Change Policies: Issues and Evidence, Resources or the Future (r.org), 1999.

    41 Caliornia Energy Commission presentation on March 4, 2007, to the Caliornia Assemblys Utility and CommerceCommittee (http://www.energy.ca.gov/2007publications/CEC-999-2007-010/CEC-999-2007-010.ppt#10).

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    29/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    24

    To conclude this section, we note that markets dier rom technologies in how they aggregate. While the

    emissions-reduction capacity o technology is simply additive, market changes are synergistic. The many new

    and reconnected markets listed above work together, and the presence o one market innovation can cause

    others to grow aster and on a larger scale. Other market areas, not mentioned here, could do the same.

    Broken Markets and Policy Stumbles

    It is useul to briefy consider two policy stumbles, attempts to close market gaps that ailed:

    solar hot water subsidies in Caliornia and energy-ecient mortgages. In response to the energy

    crisis o the 1970s, Caliornia heavily subsidized solar hot water.42 This technology is much more

    energy-ecient than photovoltaics, and a good match or this sunny state. But the programs

    implementation stumbled at contractor certication and training and inspection o installations.

    This led to a great deal o raud (only hal o installations still worked ve years later) and taintedthe solar hot water market. Only in 2007, thirty years later, did the state legislature reconsider

    solar hot water subsidies.

    Energy-ecient mortgages also ailed to catch on; a pilot initiative closed with little notice in

    June 2007. The goal o the program was to expand the borrowing capacity o home buyers who

    wanted to make home improvements to increase energy eciency. The ederally guaranteed

    program added up to $15,000 to the amount borrowed or a home purchase. But it simply proved

    to be too dicult to get the paperwork done during home-buying transactions. In a situation

    with multiple bids on a home, program users were at a disadvantage because their paperwork was

    processed more slowly than other bidders. Coordination between the ederal agency, the banks,

    and mortgage brokers was dicult, so even eco-riendly mortgage brokers did not advertise the

    program.43

    These two policy ailures highlight how the natural stream o commerce dominates the transaction

    fow. To be eective, policies must slot in to an existing stream o commerce and work at its

    speed. Expecting to change the stream o commerce or a new attributeenergy savings or energy

    eciencywont work.

    42 Margaret Taylor, et al., The Role o Technological Innovation in Meeting Caliornias Greenhouse Gas EmissionTargets, Managing Greenhouse Gas Emissions in Caliornia, Caliornia Climate Change Center at UC, Berkeley(March 2006).

    43 Source: Private communication, Tomek Randio, CEO o MortgageGreen, October 2007.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    30/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    25

    6. Experiencing Climate Change Locally

    A amous saying holds that all politics is local; the same is true or climate change. In this section we ocus

    on the experience o living through climate change in a particular locale, and the actors that will shape

    private decisions. We argue that the local environment has implications beyond simply the weather. For

    example, the NIMBY (Not In My Back Yard) sentiment prevents local siting o coal and nuclear power

    plants, leading to a plethora o lawsuits.44 Without these power sources, regions scramble or alternatives.

    And as with the water heater/shower head example we cited in Part 3, local inrastructure changes local

    costs and tips private decisions.

    As citizens and residents, we are most concerned with the experience o local weatherwe typically have

    only a passing interest in the big snowstorm somewhere else. But we also make large inerences about events

    taking place elsewhere, such as linking Hurricane Katrina and the Caliornia wildres to climate change.

    In a world o climate change uncertainty, it is easy to conuse local weather variations and a longer-termtrajectory. So part o the local experience is a large amount o uncertainty about the real eects o climate

    change, and uncertainty tends to delay investment in new technologies. Local policies tailored to conditions

    on the ground can reconnect markets and break through this inertia.

    While it might seem that the enormous, ully integrated climate change models are the sum o many local

    outcomes, they are in act high-level models that rely on smoothly growing trajectories. These trajectories

    dier rom each other by relatively small amounts. Population growth might be 1.8 percent per year in

    one scenario and 2.1 percent in another. But with 50- and 100-year horizons, these small dierences are

    compounded, becoming a large change. By contrast, a local recessionsuch as the 20 percent drop in

    employment experienced in Silicon Valley during the dot-com busthas no eect in the broader models.

    But in real lie, it did impact responses. A local recession can halt new construction or a ew years, andwhen building resumes, a dierent technology set is available or capital stock decisions. Because o the long

    service lives o buildings and machinery, this blip in investment patterns has local energy-use consequences

    or years to come. So, unlike the smooth climate change models, the local experience is path-dependent;

    the particular history o a locale matters or uture investment decisions.

    Local Outcomes for Climate Change, Local Concerns

    The University o Maryland recently completed a study on the variation o climate change by U.S. region.

    Table 6 shows a ew illustrative ndings or three diverse regions.45 It highlights the large regional variations

    and the many sources o local stresses rom a climate shit. The examples also illustrate the tight connectionbetween water and climate, with water issues hitting local economies hard. This is not surprising, as nearly

    40 percent o water use is or power generation and 80 percent o the cost o water goes toward energy.46

    44 Lawsuits Aim to Slow New Coal Boom, Associated Press, January 14, 2008; Strangers as Allies: Fight AgainstCoal Plants Is Creating Diverse Partnerships, New York Times, October 20, 2007.

    45 The U.S. Economic Impacts o Climate Change and the Costs o Inaction, Center or Integrative EnviornmentalResearch, University o Maryland (October 2007).

    46 Energy-Water Nexus Overview, Sandia National Laboratories (2006).

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    31/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    26

    Similar studies have been completed by a number o state and regional agencies, and a common nding is

    that climate change presents a daunting challenge or local resources and inrastructure.

    Table 6: Varied Local Consequences o Climate Change

    West Great Plains Mid-Atlantic

    Smaller snowpack in mountains;

    less stored water or agriculture

    and urban areas.

    Higher temperatures increase

    water needed or agriculture by

    50%; water conficts decrease

    arm income.

    More requent hurricanes in major

    metro areas; expected damages

    $50$66M per event.

    Lack o water causes armland

    values to all by 30% or more.

    Drought-stressed eco-systems

    susceptible to invasive species;

    crops destroyed.

    Sea level rise o 20 inches; damages

    o $8B$58B.

    Rising sea water; $1.5B cost to

    protect San Francisco Bay Area.

    Decreased soybean productivity

    (70% decline); decreased wheat

    productivity (1050% decline).

    Rising ocean temperatures and poor

    water quality; $63B regional ocean-

    based economy at risk.

    Local Resources Color Local Experience

    As we enter 2008, two acts collide at the local and state levels. Scientists are calling or climate change

    policies that reduce emissions immediately. But state budgets are quickly alling into decits due to theslump in the housing market and stagnant income growth. Unlike the ederal government, states cant run

    large persistent decits, so there is a conspicuous lack o resources or new climate change policies just as

    the call to action has become acute.

    The lack o local resources will change outcomes. One small but clear example can be seen in the resort

    town o Sisters, Oregon. Surrounded by the Cascade Mountains, Sisters sits directly below a large mountain

    lake that is nestled in a rock bed. Currently the rocks are held together with rozen ice. But as climate

    change progresses, experts worry that the ice will warm and the lake waters will race down the mountain

    and food the town.47 The population o Sisters (2,400 people) is too small to galvanize authorities into

    building a dam to slow the food waters. Perhaps the town will put a sensor on the mountain lake to gain a

    twenty-minute warning o the impending food. Local residents and institutions can see but not prevent this

    potential disaster. I Sisters or another town in the area experienced a signicant food, property values or

    vacation homes would all sharply, urther eroding the local tax base. The mountainside would be scraped

    clean o trees and oliage, setting the town up or a stream o mudslides in years to come. Extreme weather

    and local resources are signicantly mismatched.

    47 Lake Threat Looms Above Sisters, The Nugget, August 1, 2007.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    32/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    27

    Public Infrastructure Failures, Private Investment Solutions

    Previously we noted the extreme drought in the southeastern United States. A similar prolonged drought

    in Australia illustrates the role o private investment decisions in adapting to new conditions.48 During theAustralian drought, a water desalinization plant was constructed in Perth, but another one in Sydney was

    rejected by voters. The government has responded to the water shortage by instituting rationing rather than

    signicant increases in water prices. As a result o stalled inrastructure development and water rationing,

    Australian companies have developed a number o interesting technologies to make the best use o scarce

    water. These include small-scale wastewater recycling systems or agricultural use (purchased by armers);

    in-home gray-water treatment systems (purchased by home owners); and oce water coolers that create

    water through condensation (purchased by companies). These technologies illustrate the strong climate/

    markets/private-decision eedback loop presented earlier in Figure 7.

    In sum, local climate change is the version we actually experience, and the constraints and challenges

    encountered at the local level are more acute than aggregate climate change models can capture. The

    mismatch between local resources and the magnitude o the challenges presented by extreme weather

    is worrisome. The technology innovations rom Australia illustrate the shit toward market and private

    investment decisions in these cases, but they do not completely address the large public inrastructure gap

    that is becoming more apparent as the climate shits.

    48 Kathryn Marks, Australias Epic Drought: The Situation Is Grim, The Independent, April 20, 2007 (http://www.independent.co.uk/news/world/australasia/australias-epic-drought-the-situation-is-grim-445450.html).

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    33/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    28

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    34/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    29

    7. A New Geometry for Climate Change Policy

    In Section 2 o this paper, we introduced the stabilization triangle and the wedge solution o Pacala and

    Socolow (2004). In this section we bring together the insights about markets and private investment

    decisions to create an alternate depiction o climate change policy.

    To begin, we review the scope o policy action. Jeery Greenblatt and other researchers have reconciled the

    stabilization-triangle ramework with the baseline scenarios o the IPCC.49 The IPCC baselines are known as

    Business as Usual, and represent a climate uture i no policy action is taken. Figure 7 shows the result.

    Figure 7: Expected Decarbonization Reduces the Role of Active Policy

    Stabilization of Emissions Growth

    Ex

    trapolatio

    nof

    Hist

    orica

    lEmmiss

    ions

    Growth

    IPCC BAU scenario

    No climate policy

    Active climate policy

    The IPCCs BAU scenario does not depict an economy that is simply running on autopilot. It represents

    expectations that: a) across the economy, units o commodity input per unit o output continue to decline

    at historical rates; and b) there is signicant adoption o low-emission technologies, at rates that exceed

    historical precedent. In contrast to the top line (labeled the current path), the BAU scenario actually

    includes the eects o global modernization and substitution o renewables. Yet the very dismal prognosis

    rom the IPCC is that the BAU outcome will bring signicant increases in temperature, ice melt and rising

    seawater.50 So the BAU scenario represents a furry o activitybut not enough o it.

    49 Jeery Greenblatt, et al., Wedge Analysis o IPCC SRES and Post-SRES Scenarios, Fourth Annual Conerenceon Carbon Capture and Sequestration, U.S. Department o Energy (May 2005).

    50 See U.N. Chie Seeks More Leadership on Climate Change,New York Times, November 18, 2007, and InGreenland, Ice and Instability,New York Times, January 8, 2008.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    35/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    30

    Figure 7 is divided by the BAU scenario. Four o the seven wedges prescribed by Pacala and Socolow are

    above the IPCCs BAU scenario. Three additional wedges are needed or emissions stabilization, and these

    will require policy action. But both above and below the BAU line, our economy must undergo signicant

    change to deliver emissions reductions.

    Figure 8 is a depiction o how markets and private investment decisions will ll the stabilization triangle.

    Instead o the smoothly growing wedges o Pacala and Socolow, Figure 8 shows an almost chaotic mosaic

    o shapes and colors: the result o rapid technology change in a dynamic market. Two geometric shapes in

    the mosaic represent the demise o new technologies. The wedgelet, or small triangle, represents a small

    growth in adoption ollowed by sudden displacement. (An example o such rapid demise is the ax machine,

    once considered a breakthrough in communications; its sales plummeted once the Internet took hold.) The

    diamond represents a small growth in adoption ollowed by a slow demise. (Think o phones with corded

    handsets; these are slowly replaced as wireless handsets continue to take over the home market.) Over time

    the stabilization triangle becomes a collage o new and then abandoned technologies.

    On the right side o the gure are large right triangles. These are the ruits o intensive R&D programs

    or clean technologies. The stabilization triangle is only the rst stage in emissions reduction. Under this

    two-stage plan, aggressive emissions reductions are avoided until 2055, whenit is ervently hopednew

    technologies will reduce emissions more cheaply. The right triangles represent technologies poised or rapid

    and large deployment at mid-century.

    The market dynamics create a collage o shapes above and below the IPCCs BAU scenario. To those

    experiencing this economic transormation, it will appear that some emissions-reduction technologies are

    cheap (these are in the area above the BAU line) and some are more expensive, requiring policy action

    to tip private decisions (these are shown in the area below the BAU line). Regardless, the marketplacebecomes a rapid arbiter o winning and losing technologies.

    Figure 8: The Mosaic o a Markets-Based Policy or Climate Change

    Extrapolation

    of Historical

    Emissions Growth

    Dominant Technology

    New Technology,

    Abandoned Slowly

    New Technology,

    Abrupt Displacement

    IPCC

    BAU

    Scenario

    Today 2050

    Stabilization of

    Emissions Growth

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    36/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    31

    While the Pacala and Socolow wedge approach ocuses on energy sources and energy eciency, the opportunities

    to reduce emissions span a much wider set o decisions and technologies. Figure 9 is an abstraction o the ull

    range o technologies that will be part o the market dynamics in the next hal-century.

    Figure 9: A Broad Spectrum o Innovations Will Reduce Emissions

    COMPANY EXAMPLES

    ServicesRecycle BankPay customers to recycle

    TransportationTesla MotorsElectric car

    Eciency InfrastructureEnerNOCAggregate d emand reduction

    Energy StorageUnited TechnologiesSolar with molten salt storage

    Building MaterialsSerious MaterialsLow-carbon drywall for buildings

    Recycling and WasteGreen CitizenCorporate recycling of electronics

    WaterAir2WaterOce water cooler from condensate

    Power GenerationNanosolarLaser-printed solar cells

    MARKET TAXONOMY

    The vertical layers in Figure 9 show the many market segments o clean, emissions-reducing technology.

    The two layers marked with stars are the types o clean technology in the wedge ramework. But the six

    other layers represent signicant opportunities or emissions reduction as well. Examples o companies

    currently oering these services or products are to the right. While some o the carbon-reducing eatures o

    the innovations are obvious, others are less so. This is a salient eature o the market-based approach: with

    broad-based standards, innovations will emerge rom all quarters to supply reductions. For example, Recycle

    Bank pays residential customers to recycle and splits the proceeds o selling the waste stream with local

    municipalities. Serious Materials is a company that reduces the energy input and thus the carbon emissions

    o drywall (used in construction) by 90 percent.51 Figure 9 illustrates that while we currently have a carbon-

    based inrastructure, innovations are underway at many levels to make the shit to a non-carbon uture.

    51 Eort to Build Greener, San Jose Mercury News, January 5, 2008.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    37/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    32

    Buying an Option to Exercise in Mid-Century

    Let us return or a moment to the large right triangles in Figure 8. Many voices have called or an intense,

    ederally unded eort to accelerate research and development o clean technologies. In a recent speech,Proessor Socolow laid out a rough sketch o the sources o emissions in 2030. This mental model can also

    be used to direct the resources o an all-out R&D eort to have their largest impact. Figure 10 is a stylization

    o Socolows projections o where uture emissions will originate under the BAU scenario.

    Figure 10: Focused R&D Delivers Results or 2030

    Source: Socolow, E&ETV, March 2007; Pacala and Socolow, 2006.

    The rst group in Figure 10 is made up o developing countries, regions with rapid population growth

    and increasing levels o per-capita consumption. Emissions growth rom this group will be high, but with

    signicant pieces o inrastructure yet to be built, there is an opportunity to install clean technology that

    will reduce emissions or decades to come. (But that opportunity cuts both ways: missing this moment o

    development will lead to the installation o dirty technology that will most likely remain in place, polluting

    or decades to come.) A major R&D eort could have a signicant impact on this group.

    Modernizing countries: 2.4 billion people

    2007 emissions: 3.9 gigatons o CO2

    per year

    2030 emissions: 6.5 gigatons o CO2

    per year

    Climate change investment goal:

    New, energy-ecient inrastructure to support increased (clean) consumption

    Industrialized countries: 1 billion people

    2007 emissions: 3.8 gigatons o CO2

    per year

    2030 emissions: 4.5 gigatons o CO2

    per year

    Climate change investment goal:

    Early retirement o aging (dirty) inrastructure and capital stock

    Impoverished countries: 2.6 billion people

    2007 emissions: 0.2 gigatons o CO2

    per year

    2030 emissions: 0.2 gigatons o CO2

    per year

    Climate change investment goal:

    Clean and cheap cooking uel to improve indoor air quality

    and eliminate the brown cloud over Southeast Asia

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    38/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    33

    Industrialized countries make up the second group. They are expected to grow their emissions rom 3.75 GtC

    per year to nearly 7GtC per year during the next twenty-ve years. With capital stock and inrastructure in

    place, clean technologies will only be adopted at a rapid pace i they t into the existing inrastructure and

    oer such compelling economics that early retirement o the existing capital stock is justied.

    The nal group consists o impoverished countries, which are expected to have no emissions growthbut

    or harsh reasons. While 1 billion people in this group live in urban areas, they do not have reliable power

    or indoor running water. The other 1.6 billion people in impoverished countries live in rural areas. Simple

    and low-cost technologies or clean cooking uel, water, and on-site power or lighting could dramatically

    change their lives. Despite their poverty, this group produces a particularly important source o emissions:

    the soot and particulate rom cooking uel, which blocks the sun and is now believed to be a signicant

    health hazard and contributor to global warming.52 R&D ocused on these problems could have a signicant

    eect on climate change.

    Consider the case o Tata Motors, the Indian car company that recently announced it was selling a vehicle

    or $2,500.53 Called the Peoples Car, it is giving environmental leaders nightmares since it has the potential

    to add so many cars to the road. A concentrated R&D eort or clean and cheap technologies aimed at the

    developing worlds ast-growing middle class could ocus Indias considerable intellectual talentand the

    brainpower o several countrieson these emissions problems.

    As Figure 10 makes clear, an ambitious R&D eort could have a disproportionately large impact. For each o

    the three groups o nations, private decisions will dictate the pace o changeand private decisions coupled

    with cutting-edge research could have ar-reaching global benets. While policy analysts have assumed

    that a clean-tech eort depends on increased ederal spending, this paper has shown that strengthening

    markets and tipping private decisions in developing and impoverished countries could serve to draw outnew products based on privately unded R&D.

    Our eorts need to limit themselves to technology alone. It is clear that technology is only hal the picture.

    As Thomas Schelling, a Nobel laureate in economics, asks:

    How well can people, businesses, governments, and communities adapt to the

    climate changes, especially in countries heavily dependent on ood production,

    in countries with poor educational and technological attainment, poor fscal or

    legal systems?54

    Although the task at hand is considerably less dened at this time, we need two eorts to run concurrently:

    one or technology and one or organizations.

    52 See the press release by the National Science Foundation describing the latest research on this topic athttp://www.ns.gov/news/news_summ.jsp?cntn_id=109712.

    53 The $2,500 Car: An Environmental Nightmare?, ABC News, January 10, 2008 (http://abcnews.go.com/Business/GadgetGuide/wireStory?id=4113059).

    54 Thomas C. Schelling, Climate Change: The Uncertainties, the Certainties and What They Imply About Action,Berkeley Electronic Press (July 2007).

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    39/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    34

    Beore concluding, lets be careul about the economics o an intense R&D and organizational eort. The

    strategy is to invest in R&D today so as to create an opportunity or additional investment at mid-century.

    While burdensome, todays cost is only the purchase o an option. Exercising that optionby deploying

    mid-centurys brightest technologieswill be even more expensive. Despite the large costs, an option to

    invest in the uture can be extremely valuable in an uncertain world. By ocusing our R&D and institutional

    development eorts today, we can signicantly improve the lives o our children and grandchildren. Without

    stabilization o emissions and R&D investments, uture generations will be making a set o dicult choices

    in a world saturated with carbon.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    40/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    35

    8. Conclusions

    We have endeavored to bring a new and unique perspective to bear on climate change policy by putting

    private investment decisions at the center o the analysis and examining policies, institutions, and

    inrastructure rom that vantage point. Unlike technology prescriptions or climate change, this perspective

    has a clear central actor: the individual who makes a huge number o consumption decisions every day.

    A host o policies, new markets, and supporting technologies can tip many o those decisions toward a

    greener outcome.

    Our perspective is that climate change is experienced in micro settingsour homes, our communities, our

    regionsso we need policies tailored to address local conditions. Globally, the way orward will be the sum

    o decisions made by millions o individuals in response to the situation at hand.

    We hope that this paper sparks discussion and action. National policies and global accords can accelerate

    the positive trends identied here. But in the meantime, and as a complement to national policy, citizens

    have the power to act both in their private decisions and in their demand or local policies to support new

    markets and business models, unleashing the invisible green hand.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand

    41/42

    Mil ItittTh Iviil Gr Had

    36

    About the Authors

    Martha Amram is the CEO and co-ounder o GreenNow USA, a company that helps home owners save

    energy and reduce carbon emissions. She is also a senior ellow o the Milken Institute. An expert on

    valuation and strategy, she has had a wide range o business experience in management consulting, start-up

    ventures, and academia. She is the author oValue Sweep: Mapping Corporate Growth Opportunities (Harvard

    Business School Press, 2002; translated into ve languages) and the co-author, with Nalin Kulatilaka, o

    Real Options: Managing Strategic Investment in an Uncertain World (Harvard Business School Press, 1998;

    translated into ve languages). Amrams work is widely published, including recent articles in Strategic

    Finance,the Harvard Business Review,and theJournal o Applied Corporate Finance.

    Previously Amram was chie economist at PLX Systems, where her algorithms or valuing intellectual

    property were incorporated into the rms sotware products. She also served as CEO o Vocomo Sotware

    Corp., which provided sotware and services or voice applications. Amram was managing director atNavigant Consulting, where she was head o the real options practice area and managed strategy consulting

    teams across a number o industries, rom consumer goods to energy to high-tech.

    Amram was a co-ounder o Glaze Creek Partners, a consulting rm that was sold to Navigant in 1999.

    She also served as an expert witness on valuation while vice president at Analysis Group and was a aculty

    member specializing in corporate nance at the School o Management at Boston University. Amram holds

    a Ph.D. in applied economics rom the Massachusetts Institute o Technology (MIT) and is a graduate with

    honors in mathematics and economics rom the University o Washington.

    Nalin Kulatilaka is the Wing Tat Lee Family Proessor o Management and Proessor o Finance in the

    School o Management at Boston University. He serves as the research director o Boston Universitys

    Institute or Leading in a Dynamic Economy. His current research interests include investments in clean

    technology, the economics o business platorms, the valuations o early-stage rms, the role o energy

    intermediaries, technology licensing, and nancial contracting.

    Kulatilaka has published more than 75 papers in scholarly journals, and is the co-author o the book

    Real Options: Managing Strategic Investment in an Uncertain World (Harvard Business School Press, 1998).

    He received the Association or Investment Management and Researchs Graham and Dodd Award in

    recognition o outstanding eature articles published in the Financial Analysts Journal. He also served as the

    Bertil Danielsson Proessor at the Stockholm School o Economics and Gteborg University, and as theTamkang Chair at the Tamkang University in Taiwan.

    Kulatilaka co-ounded Glaze Creek Partners LLC and International Internet Services. He received a

    bachelors degree in electrical engineering rom Imperial College, London; a masters degree in decision and

    control rom Harvard University; and a Ph.D. in applied economics rom MIT.

  • 8/9/2019 The Invisible Green Hand