47
UNIVERSITEIT GENT FACULTEIT ECONOMIE EN BEDRIJFSKUNDE ACADEMIEJAAR 2009 2010 The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and Experience on Valuation Masterproef voorgedragen tot het bekomen van de graad van Master in de Toegepaste Economische Wetenschappen Jeroen Baert en Jan Dufourmont onder leiding van Prof. dr. ir. Sophie Manigart en Andy Heughebaert

The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

UNIVERSITEIT GENT

FACULTEIT ECONOMIE EN BEDRIJFSKUNDE

ACADEMIEJAAR 2009 – 2010

The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation

and Experience on Valuation

Masterproef voorgedragen tot het bekomen van de graad van

Master in de Toegepaste Economische Wetenschappen

Jeroen Baert en Jan Dufourmont

onder leiding van

Prof. dr. ir. Sophie Manigart en Andy Heughebaert

Page 2: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

II

Page 3: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

III

UNIVERSITEIT GENT

FACULTEIT ECONOMIE EN BEDRIJFSKUNDE

ACADEMIEJAAR 2009 – 2010

The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation

and Experience on Valuation

Masterproef voorgedragen tot het bekomen van de graad van

Master in de Toegepaste Economische Wetenschappen

Jeroen Baert en Jan Dufourmont

onder leiding van

Prof. dr. ir. Sophie Manigart en Andy Heughebaert

Page 4: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

IV

PERMISSION

Ondergetekenden verklaren dat de inhoud van deze masterproef mag geraadpleegd en/of

gereproduceerd worden, mits bronvermelding.

Jeroen Baert Jan Dufourmont

Page 5: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

V

Preface

Writing a dissertation in order to obtain a master‟s degree in applied economics was a challenge and

in many ways a great experience. Working in pair required a setting of mutual understanding and

respect, predefined rules and a correct task distribution. If not for these elements, this project would

have been a lost cause.

We would like to thank our promoter Prof. dr. Sophie Manigart and Andy Heughebaert for letting

us use an extensive dataset, for the useful comments and continuous follow-up. A special word of

thanks goes out to Joy Van Poucke, Sanne Verbiese and our parents for being patient and

understanding for the duration of our master dissertation and without whose unconditional support

we would not have been able to complete this project. Also, we would like to express our thanks to

Jan Willems and Maarten Tollenaere, two fellow students writing a related master dissertation,

whose insights and feedback helped us avoid certain pitfalls. Further, our reviewers Katrien Baert,

Sebastiaan Dooms and Liselot Pausenberger are hereby greatly thanked. Finally, we are thankful to

Ghent University, for making available all the resources needed to extend our dataset.

Page 6: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

VI

Inhoudsopgave

Abstract (Nederlands) ...................................................................................................................... 1

Abstract (English)............................................................................................................................ 2

1. Introduction ............................................................................................................................. 3

2. Theoretical Framework & Hypotheses ..................................................................................... 6

2.1 Reputation ......................................................................................................................... 6

2.1.1 Perceived Quality ....................................................................................................... 7

2.1.2 Prominence ................................................................................................................ 7

2.2 Experience ........................................................................................................................ 8

3. Data ....................................................................................................................................... 10

3.1 Sample and Data Sources ................................................................................................ 10

3.2 Measures ......................................................................................................................... 11

3.2.1 Dependent variable ................................................................................................... 11

3.2.2 Independent variables ............................................................................................... 12

3.2.3 Control variables ...................................................................................................... 14

4. Results ................................................................................................................................... 15

4.1 Descriptive statistics ........................................................................................................ 15

4.2 Method of analysis .......................................................................................................... 21

4.3 Dealing with a selection bias ........................................................................................... 25

5. Discussion, conclusions and limitations ................................................................................. 31

References ..................................................................................................................................... 34

Page 7: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

VII

List of Abbreviations

VC = Venture Capitalist

VCs = Venture Capitalists

VCF = Venture Capital Firm

EVCA = European Venture Capital Association

CVC = Corporate Venture Capitalist

M&A = Mergers & Acquisitions

IPO = Initial Public Offering

NACE = Nomenclature statistique des Activités économique dans la Communauté Européenne

ICT = Information and Communication Technology

OLS = Ordinary Least Squares

Page 8: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

VIII

List of tables and figures

Table 1. Descriptive statistics of the used variables…………………………………………….…..16

Figure 1. Average valuation per year………………………………………………………….……17

Table 2. Descriptive statistics at the company level……………………………………...…………19

Table 3. Univariate comparisons (based on Mann-Whitney tests)……………………………….…20

Table 4. Log-linear OLS regressions, with standard errors clustered on the lead VCF, from testing

the VC experience and reputation on pre-money valuation relationship..........................................22

Table 5. Probit regression modelling the probability of a company being selected by a more

reputable VCF (Heckman first step)………………………………………………………………..26

Table 6. Log-linear OLS regression, with standard errors clustered on the lead VCF, of pre-money

valuations while controlling for potential selection bias……………………………………………28

Page 9: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

1

Abstract (Nederlands)

Het opzet van deze masterproef is het opbouwen en testen van hypothesen betreffende de graad

waarin de waardering van een portfolio onderneming beïnvloed wordt door de ervaring en reputatie

van de risicokapitaalinvesteerder. Het onderzoek is gebaseerd op een steekproef van 140 pre-money

waarderingen in de Belgische durfkapitaalmarkt. Deze masterproef toont dat

risicokapitaalinvesteerders1 met een ruimere ervaring lagere waarderingen zullen bieden aan

ondernemingen, terwijl de reputatie van de investeerder een dubbelzinnig effect blijkt te hebben op

de pre-money waardering. Er blijkt geen significant resultaat voor het “geobserveerde kwaliteit”-

aspect van reputatie. Uit de onderzochte data blijkt echter wel een positieve relatie tussen de

prominentie van een durfkapitalist en de waardering van een onderneming.

1 De term risicokapitaalinvesteerder is niet volledig juist, gezien elke financiering met aandelenkapitaal risicokapitaal is. Het

Nederlands voorziet echter niet in een betere vertaling voor „venture capitalist‟.

Page 10: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

2

Abstract (English)

The goal of this master dissertation is to develop and test hypotheses concerning the degree to

which a portfolio company‟s valuation is affected by a venture capitalist‟s experience and

reputation. Our study is based on a sample of 140 pre-money valuations within the Belgian venture

capital market. The thesis of this paper is that venture capitalists with a higher experience tend to

value their ventures lower, whilst reputation seems to have an ambiguous effect on the pre-money

valuation. As for the perceived quality part of reputation, we find no significant result. The

prominence of a venture capitalist however, is positively related with a venture‟s valuation.

Page 11: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

3

1. Introduction

A large number of academic papers discuss the importance of an entrepreneur‟s ability to mobilize

resources as a key factor to success for young start-ups. This is especially a key issue for high tech

entrepreneurs since their collateral has an intangible and knowledge-based nature. The bring-in‟s

specific nature of these young start-ups and the high information asymmetries between investors

and entrepreneurs often makes their search for external monetary or other resources an uphill battle.

Entrepreneurs can overcome this problem through internal and external options. An internal

solution could be bootstrap financing (Bhide, 1992), while externally business angels (Aernoudt,

1999; ColleWaert & Manigart, 2009) and venture capitalists provide a possible alternative.

Venture capital is a subsector of private equity where typically equity investments are made

in young high technology firms (Sahlman, 1990). Lately however, the attention of venture capital

investors has shifted towards more mature companies (Collewaert & Manigart, 2009). At the time

of investment the venture capitalist acquires shares in the investee company in return for a monetary

injection. Within this paper, we define a venture capitalist as an institutional investor in privately

held entrepreneurial firms, which actively participates in the management of his portfolio

companies and often is represented on the board of directors (Gompers & Lerner, 1999).

The risk will increase due to the lack of collateral in comparison with more traditional types

of investment. Hence the venture capitalist will require a higher return: this form of financing will

come at a cost. This cost is shown in the venture‟s valuation. The valuation reflects the percentage

of shares the VC gets in return for the committed funds. Since both the investor and the target are

affected by the valuation, it is a vital part of the investment process. The ultimate goal for a venture

capitalist is to maximize the difference between payoffs at an exit - such as M&A or IPO- and the

price they initially paid. Higher pre-money valuation may hence lead to reduced future gains for the

VC. Conversely it seems rational for the entrepreneur to give up the smallest possible ownership

stake in exchange for the maximum possible capital injection, since a lower valuation will lead to a

greater cost of capital for the portfolio company.

Valuation is driven by company characteristics, as well as VC characteristics, since it is the

result of a negotiation process. A sizeable part of firm valuations can be explained by accounting

information, as shown by Hand (2005). Seppä (2003) reasoned that early stage companies would

Page 12: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

4

receive lower valuations due to the higher implied risk. Also, previous literature showed that higher

quality companies get higher valuations, since the VC may pay a price premium for the reduced risk

(Hsu, 2007). Contrary to a bank, venture capitalists are able to provide expertise and other value-

added services (Nahata, 2009). Target companies often are advised to deal with the more reputable

VC(s), since they will most likely add more value (Stuart, Hoang & Hybels, 1999; Greene, 1999;

Hallen, 2008). Since cooperating with more reputable partners confers these performance benefits,

this comes at a certain cost, again often reflected in the firm‟s valuation. As Hsu (2004)

demonstrated, ventures may opt to accept a lower valuation or give up a bigger ownership stake, in

order to affiliate with a more reputable partner and hence receive greater value-added services. This

is supported by Fairchild (2004) who stated that welfare can be maximized when the venture

capitalist has high value-adding capabilities.2 Sahlman mentions: “From whom you raise capital

often is more important than the terms” (Sahlman (1997, p.107)).

Not only can venture capitalists build on reputational capital, research has also shown that

their experience plays an important part. The literature concerning the influence of experience on

valuation contains two main lines of research. The first line of research states that more experienced

venture capitalists will offer a lower valuation (Hsu, 2004). Here the concept of experience is

closely related to reputation. Ventures may accept a discount in valuation in the belief that a more

experienced VC will most likely be more successful. Vanacker (2008) examined the relationship

between growth and experience and concluded that companies backed by more experienced VCs

achieve higher growth rates than companies backed by less experienced VCs3. The second line of

research suggests that more experienced venture capitalists do not necessarily offer a lower

valuation, since they are able to select better companies (the matching principle) and thereby

enhance their chances of positive returns (Sorensen, 2007).

It is clear that there exists a great heterogeneity among the different venture capitalists. Not

only may they differ in reputation and experience levels, there also exist several types of venture

capitalists. Even the type of VC (government related, open-ended, university related, …) influences

valuation (Heughebaert & Manigart, 2009). However different, they share a common broad goal,

2 Following Fairchild (2004) welfare is maximized when the venture capitalist has high value-adding capabilities, the market for

reputation is informationally efficient, and the manager has bargaining power. 3 This is true for the asset growth rates, however he finds no substantial evidence for the employment part of growth.

Page 13: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

5

namely selling their participation after three to seven years (Black & Gilson, 1998) while

maximizing their returns.

This master dissertation is an attempt to capture the influence of both a venture capital firm‟s

reputation and its experience on a venture‟s valuation in venture capital backed deals in Belgium.

Our research relates measures of VC reputation and experience to the pre-money valuation of

companies whose funding took place between 1992 and 2009, while controlling for portfolio

company characteristics. Thus, the goal of this paper is twofold. We investigate a negative influence

of a venture capitalists‟ reputation on the venture‟s valuation, as well as an inverse relationship

between the VC‟s experience and the venture‟s valuation.

Recent literature distinguishes two distinct dimensions of reputation. The first dimension is

prominence and is concerned with the collective awareness and recognition (Rindova, Williamson,

Petkova & Sever, 2005). In order to measure prominence, we developed two proxies, MarketShare

and MediaCitations. The variable IndustryExperience measures the second dimension, perceived

quality, concerned with the perception of a VC‟s ability. We use several other variables to measure

experience, all based on previous literature. We introduce LnFundSize, OverallExperience,

IndustryExperience and VC_Age as four proxies to estimate experience. As for our controls, we

look at macro-economic data (a dummy is included to indicate whether the investment took place

during the bubble or not), and at the portfolio company characteristics, amongst others age and

balance total. We will elaborate on the variables in the next section of this dissertation.

This dissertation contributes to the literature by extending to the empirical research on

reputation and experience in the venture capital setting. By using a private setting, we try to fill the

gap in reputation literature that has largely ignored valuations of unquoted companies, although

reputation is probably more valuable in a private setting with high information asymmetries than in

a public setting. Sophisticated investors may have a larger influence on a venture‟s valuation in the

private, unquoted environment. We try to quantify the separate influences of a VC‟s experience,

respectively reputation, on the valuation he offers to his portfolio ventures. We combine Hsu‟s

(2004) method of analyzing reputation with Seppä‟s (2003) analysis of prominence, in order to

Page 14: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

6

measure the impact of perceived quality respectively prominence as two different dimensions of

reputation4 on a venture‟s valuation.

The rest of the dissertation is organized as follows. In the next section, we develop a theoretical

framework of previous literature in order to build testable hypotheses. Secondly, we present our

data collection methods and our variables. We next present our descriptive statistics followed by

outlining our methods of analysis. The fourth section demonstrates and discusses the main findings

of our research. Finally, conclusions and limitations are discussed in the last section.

2. Theoretical Framework & Hypotheses

This section describes the construction of a theoretical framework on which we will base ourselves

to develop our hypotheses. We will first focus on the literature concerning the reputation of a

venture capitalist, after which we will continue by building the experience hypothesis.

2.1 Reputation

In this dissertation we define reputation as an economic good resulting from past experience and

performance that can generate future returns, especially when there are high information

asymmetries between actors (Hsu, 2004). We investigate equity valuations in a private setting. In

the latter only an absolute minimum of information is available, making reputation more valuable.

What makes a partner, or in this case a venture capitalist, reputable? Early reputation research

linked reputation with certification. Certification is the ability of a third party (here a VC) to reduce

uncertainty over other parties associated with them. Megginson & Weiss (1991) argued that in order

for the certification to be credible (and therefore have a good reputation), a couple of conditions

must be fulfilled, more specifically: the certifying party needs to have reputational capital at stake

and needs to be at risk of being adversely and materially affected if the certification proves false.

More recent reputation literature identifies two distinct dimensions of reputation, each concerned

4 As defined by Rindova et al., 2005

Page 15: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

7

with different characteristics, namely: Perceived Quality and Prominence (Vanacker, 2009;

Rindova et al., 2005).

2.1.1 Perceived Quality

Perceived quality is concerned with the way in which stakeholders evaluate certain firm-specific

attributes. Stakeholders use signals to form expectations about unobservable firm characteristics,

and thus try to reduce uncertainty about the quality of the firm. Essentially, one of the attributes

stakeholders try to assess is the expected ability of the VC based on past experience (Vanacker,

2009). A higher perceived quality of the venture capitalist makes the VC more reputable. We

measure the perceived quality of the firm by looking at industry specific experience. More

specifically, we examine the total amount of deals in which the VC engaged in the eight year

preceding the investigated deal that are in the same industry as the investigated deal. Our measure

of perceived quality is hence tightly related with experience. In Hsu‟s (2004) closely related paper

he proposes that more reputable VCs offer a lower valuation and finds results supporting that

hypothesis. Contrary to this paper, Hsu does not make the distinction between the two dimensions

of reputation. He reasons that reputation and experience show a very high correlation and presumes

that proxies for experience can measure the construct reputation. Here, the perceived quality part of

reputation is largely based on past experience. Extending this line of reasoning and following Hsu

(2004) we argue:

H1: venture capitalists with higher perceived quality will offer lower valuations.

2.1.2 Prominence

Prominence, the second dimension of reputation, is related to the collective awareness and

recognition that a company has accumulated in its organizational field (Rindova et al., 2005). A

VC‟s reputational capital comprises the recognition, awareness and appreciation a VC has

accumulated during its activities. Prominence refers to this reputational capital, and is driven by

activity. Every time the VCF engages in an investment, it puts its reputational capital at stake. This

risk of losing reputational capital comes at a cost for the portfolio company. In the venture capital

industry, the compensation the VC gets for putting his „reputation on the line‟ is a potential discount

on the venture‟s valuation. This is in line with the criteria for reliable investor certification of

Page 16: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

8

Megginson & Weiss (1991), which state that the certification must be costly and is an increasing

function of the degree and quality of the certification. In the venture capital deal-making, VCs can

be considered as certifying agents. Therefore, the more prominent a venture capitalist becomes, the

larger his discount on valuation will be. Also, since prominent VCs often are considered valuable to

their portfolio companies, these venture capitalists will have greater bargaining power5 over their

portfolio ventures and will as such enter deals on more favourable conditions. This is an important

difference between public and private equity valuation. While public equity valuation is mostly

done on a liquid trading market, private equity valuations suffer from a complete lack of an efficient

pricing mechanism. Hence, negotiation processes between investors and entrepreneurs will shape

most valuations in the private equity market (Cumming & Dai, 2008). Prominent venture capitalists

are likely to use their negotiation power to lower pre-money valuation and consequently increase

their expected returns (Seppä, 2003). We thus hypothesize:

H2: The more prominent a venture capitalists becomes, the lower pre-money valuations he

will offer.

2.2 Experience

The second part of this study is focused on the influence of the experience of venture capitalists on

the valuation they will offer to their portfolio ventures. Recent experience research has contested

the homogeneity of investors. Vanacker (2008) showed that ventures funded by venture capital

firms with a high experience, show higher growth rates ex-post than ventures funded by less

experienced VCFs6. Sorensen (2007) found that companies backed by more experienced VCs are

more likely to go public and Dimov & Shepherd (2005) argued that portfolio companies of venture

capital firms with specific human capital are less likely to fail.

Apart from Hsu (2004), experience literature has largely ignored the influence of experience

of a Venture Capitalist on its portfolio companies‟ valuations. Experience research mainly focused

on portfolio characteristics‟ influence on valuation (Hand, 2005; Armstrong, Davila & Foster, 2006;

5 For further research concerning the impact of bargaining power on valuation, we refer to Cumming & Dai (2008): “Fund Size,

Limited Attention and Valuation of Venture Capital Backed Firms”

6 This is true for the asset growth rates; however he finds no substantial evidence for the employment part of growth.

Page 17: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

9

Hsu, 2007). Hsu (2004) showed that entrepreneurs are willing to pay a substantial amount for

reputable Venture Capital affiliation. He argued that reputation and experience are closely related,

and thus measures „reputation‟ based on experience proxies. We believe that this concerns the

perceived quality part of reputation. Experience is undeniably correlated with perceived quality,

however not the entirely the same; for an experienced employee often is, but not necessarily, a good

employee. We include proxies for experience, as described by Sörensen (2007) and Vanacker

(2008), in order to estimate as complete an image of experience as possible. Incorporating

LnFundSize as a proxy for experience, allows us to examine the possibilities for follow-up

financing, while VC_Age is related with the network density. Since Gompers, Kovner, Lerner &

Scharfstein (2009) demonstrated that there is in fact a difference to be noticed between specialized

and generalized venture capitalists on performance ex-post, we distinguish between industry

specific deal experience and overall deal experience.7 It is important to note that these variables are

not mutually exclusive for the constructs „perceived quality‟ and „experience‟.

Follow-up financing and network density are two advantages that an entrepreneur can obtain

from a more experienced VC. Again, these value-added services, and the possibility of a better

outcome as found by Dimov & Shepherd (2005), Sörensen (2007) and Vanacker (2008), come at

the cost, more often than not in the form of accepting a discount in valuation. Also, affiliation with

a more experienced partner is a signal of the portfolio company‟s quality to future investors

(Megginson & Weiss, 1991). Therefore, the venture may again accept a lower valuation, only to be

rewarded with higher future returns.

We hence argue that experience and valuation are inversely related. By affiliating with more

experienced venture capitalists, the target companies might give up a larger equity stake in

exchange for improved value-added services, which they believe, will make their remaining stake

more valuable. This price-experience trade-off leads us to the following hypothesis:

H3: More experienced venture capitalists will offer a lower valuation to portfolio companies

in venture capital-backed deals.

7 Also, Vanacker (2008) distinguishes between industry specific and overall experience.

Page 18: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

10

3. Data

3.1 Sample and Data Sources

The hypotheses are tested on a unique hand-collected sample of Belgian VC backed companies that

received financing from a Belgian venture capitalist between 1988 and 2009. The primary sample

includes first round investments in 194 different investee companies. The uniqueness of the sample

arises from its richness in depth and quality. The sample has two important advantages compared to

previous VC valuation studies.

First, we retrieve the valuation data in the current research from the Belgian Law Gazette,

which reports official information on all capital increases in Belgian companies. This allows us to

put together an unbiased sample with high levels of reliability. Our dataset combines information

from several sources, including public and commercial databases with VC investments, annual

reports of VC firms and information from the Belgian Venturing Association. It therefore includes

investments from different types of VC investors, reducing the threat of biases induced by the use

of a single source of data. Second, unlike most U.S. studies, our sample includes unquoted firms,

regardless whether they later did an IPO. The sample hence includes successful as well as less

successful unquoted firms; that is firms that did an IPO, that failed, that were taken over or that are

still private. As such, any potential survivorship bias is eliminated.

Different sources of public information (press clippings, websites, annual reports of VC

companies), combined with the commercial databases of Thomson One (VentureXpert) and Zephyr

(i.e., a database of private equity deals similar to the Thomson ONE database, but with a special

focus on European transactions), are consulted to find the initial VC investment round in Belgian

firms between 1988 and 2009. The sample is limited to initial VC investments in firms younger

than ten years to ensure a focus on „pure‟ VC investments. All Belgian private firms are obliged by

law to announce capital increases in the official Belgian Law Gazette, ensuring a complete,

unbiased and reliable account of all initial equity investments in the VC portfolio companies. Based

on the total capital increase and as a result of this, the number of newly created shares, the value of

an investment round is calculated. The information provided by the Belgian Law Gazette further

allows to unambiguously identify all investors in each investment round in most cases.

Page 19: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

11

When multiple VCFs invest in an investment round, the investment round is assigned to the

venture capital firm investing the largest amount, the lead VCF (Wright & Lockett, 2003). Lead

venture capital firms have more decision-making powers, more formal and informal contact with

investee management and receive more information compared to non-lead investors (Wright &

Lockett, 2003). Hence, it seems rational to suppose that lead investors will occupy a more

predominant role in bargaining the valuation with the entrepreneurial management team. We thus

focus on the lead investor. In 27 cases it is not unambiguous who the lead investor is, because all

syndicate venture capitalists invest the same amount or because the invested amount of each

individual VC is unknown. In these situations, we randomly assign an investor as the lead investor8.

In order to collect data concerning the experience and reputation of the lead VC providing initial

venture capital finance, we combined multiple sources including the Thomson ONE database,

Zephyr, Graydon, Belfirst, Mediargus, EVCA-guides and Amadeus. Deals with a corporate venture

capitalist are excluded from the primary sample, since they differ largely from other VCs9. Further,

deals with missing information, mostly because of the fact that the databases do not provide

information before 1990, are also left out. Eventually, deals with a missing pre-money valuation are

not incorporated in the analyses. Missing pre-money valuations result from portfolio companies

where the information necessary to calculate the pre-money valuation was not available. This leaves

us with a final sample of 140 deals.

3.2 Measures

3.2.1 Dependent variable

The unit of analysis is the first investment round. In line with previous research, we utilize the pre-

money valuation of the target company as dependent variable (Lerner, 1994; Gompers and Lerner,

8 Unreported sensitivity analyses were performed including another investor in the multivariate regressions. The results remained

robust.

9 Information asymmetries tend to be extra high for corporate investors. High quality ventures often are reluctant to share details

about their key technologies or intangible assets in order to avoid the „theft‟ of their ideas (Dushnitsky, 2004). Also, the

compensation of corporate VC fund managers often differs from that of independent venture capitalist fund managers, resulting in

less strong incentives for corporate VCs. In some cases investments are made with specific motives, e.g. a manager may want to

invest in new companies just to enlarge his firm. Finally, CVCs‟ focus may lie on strategic synergies, the economic effect of which

we cannot quantify. For all these reasons – among others- it is hard to compare corporate VC valuations with other venture capitalist

valuations.

Page 20: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

12

2000; Seppä, 2003; Hand, 2005; Armstrong et al., 2006). In contrary to a post-money valuation, a

pre-money valuation is not directly dependent on the amount invested in the company during the

investment round (Lerner, 1994). Pre-money valuations are thus considered more appropriate than

post-money valuations since the amount invested may vary with many determinants, including the

fundraising environment. The pre-money valuation10

is calculated as the difference between the

post-money valuation and the invested amount. The post-money valuation represents the amount

that an investor would have paid to acquire 100% of the shares of the company and is calculated as

((investment) / (% of shares acquired)) * 100. As alternative, the pre-money valuation can be

measured by the total number of shares outstanding prior to the investment multiplied with the price

per share paid by venture capitalists in the focal investment round. All amounts used in the analyses

are inflation-adjusted. The mean pre-money valuation of the portfolio companies in the sample is

2.690.593,41 EUR, starting from a minimum valuation of 23.181,79 EUR going up to a maximum

valuation of 32.815.822,12 EUR (Table 1).

3.2.2 Independent variables

The key independent variables are correlates of venture capitalist prominence, perceived quality and

experience and are measured at the moment of investment. Venture capitalist prominence is

operationalized in two ways. First, we look at the absolute number of media citations of the venture

capitalist 8 years prior to investment (MediaCitations). The media tends to distribute information

more broadly than the opinions of average stakeholders, so they are likely to have a high degree of

influence on which organizations become more prominent in the minds of stakeholders (Rindova et

al., 2005). Only citations in „De Tijd‟, considered qualitatively the best financial newspaper in

Belgium, are taken into account. We make no distinction whether the article places the venture

capitalist in a „good‟ or „bad‟ daylight since Cook, Kieschnick and Van Ness (2006) showed that

the media provides non-negative coverage in 99% of the articles they studied in detail. Second, we

measure prominence from another perspective by considering the degree of presence on the venture

10 A simple example of a pre-money valuation: when an investor acquires 20% of the shares of a company for €100.000, the post-

and pre-money valuations are respectively equal to €500.000 and €400.000. So, the investor pays €100.000 to possess 20% of the

company shares after investment. No distinction is made between the acquired percentages of shares of different investors since this

doesn‟t affect the post-money valuation. In contrary, to come to the pre-money valuation, the total increase in capital is deducted

from the post-money valuation, irrespective if one or more venture capitalists were included in the deal.

Page 21: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

13

capital market. This second measure of prominence is based on the VC‟s investment share in the

venture capital industry. MarketShare is operationalized as the quotient of the number of

investments by a certain venture capitalist two years prior to investment and the total number of

investments in the Belgian venture capital market in the same period. Hence, venture capitalists

with a higher investment share are likely to be more prominent since they are able to attract capital

from more limited partners, which contributes to a higher awareness concerning the VC.

Furthermore, a higher investment share seems more likely to positively contribute to the perception

of the unobserved qualities of the venture capitalist. Gompers (1996) used the venture capitalist‟s

age as an alternative measure of prominence; we however believe that age as such is not an

unambiguous estimator of reputation. After all, this would mean that the reputation building process

is automatic and linear without a connection to the performance of the VC (Seppä, 2003).

Venture capitalist perceived quality is operationalized as the absolute number of investments made

by the venture capitalist 8 years before investment in the same industry as the target company (4-

digit industry codes reclassified into EVCA-classification11

, using a conversion key12

).

IndustryExperience is in line with the concept of venture capitalist reputation as perceived quality

based on previous experience (Vanacker, 2009; Hsu, 2004). The successful development of

portfolio ventures is a powerful signal of the quality of the venture capitalist and a strong

contributor to the VC‟s perceived quality. Since the expertise needed to help portfolio companies

mature successfully grows with every investment, investment experience is a good proxy for

perceived quality. It is well known that people make judgements about certain entities based on past

observations and use these signals to form beliefs in predicting future performance (Weigelt &

Camerer, 1988).

Experience leads to knowledge accumulation. The accumulated competences are expected to have

11 The EVCA divides companies into 7 industry groups at baseline: “Agriculture, Chemicals and Materials”, “ICT”, “Business and

Industrial Products and Services”, “Consumer Products, Services and Retail”, “Energy and Environment”, “Financial Services” and

“Life Sciences”

12 The conversion key was found on the official EVCA-website:

http://www.evca.eu/uploadedFiles/Home/Knowledge_Center/EVCA_Research/Current_Surveys/sectoral_classification.pdf

Page 22: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

14

an influence on the valuation. Venture capitalist experience is measured in four ways. First, we look

at the overall deal experience (Sorensen 2007; Vanacker 2008). The variable OverallExperience is

operationalized as the absolute number of completed venture capital investment rounds, eight years

before investment, in which the lead VC participated. Secondly, similar to the previous proxy the

industry specific deal experience is utilized to measure experience. IndustryExperience also only

focuses on a period of eight years before investment. Thus, in line with Vanacker (2008) we

distinguish between overall and specific experience. This distinction is supported by Gompers &

Lerner (2009) who showed that there are differences in performance between specialized and

generalized venture capitalists. As third proxy for experience we include the total funds committed

of the lead investor (Cumming & Dai, 2008). The higher the venture capitalist‟s fund size the more

commitments it has engaged with limited partners who are likely to select and invest in VC funds

with a greater experience, whose accumulated competences pump up the expected returns, implying

lower risks. The fund sizes in our dataset range from 924.780 EUR up to 1.129.029.510 EUR with

an average of 130.260.380 EUR. In order to reduce the spread of these values, we thought it

appropriate to perform a log transformation. Also, Cumming & Dai (2008) found that the fund size

of a VC is convexly related with the log transformed pre-money valuation. The log-transformed

variable LnFundSize helps us avoid non-linearities between the independent and dependent

variables, as is the case. Incorporating fund size allows us to indirectly examine the possibilities for

follow-up financing. Fourth, consistent with previous literature (Janney & Folta, 2006) we also

incorporate the age of the venture capitalist as a proxy of its investment experience (VC_Age). It

appears logical that the longer a VC has been in the venture capital industry, the more knowledge

and experience he or she has accumulated. Additionally, incorporating the venture capital firm‟s

age, allows us to indirectly measure the network density of the VC firm.

3.2.3 Control variables

Proxies that drive differences in the dependent variable other than those measuring reputation and

experience are included as control variables in order to capture the most representative effects of

reputation and experience. Our control variables represent a combination of variables tested in

Page 23: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

15

univariate tests13

, variables used in previous literature and variables that intuitively seem

appropriate. Most of these control variables represent characteristics of the portfolio company.

Previous research has shown that valuations of risk-capital backed companies can be significantly

affected by company characteristics (Armstrong et al. 2006; Hand 2005). To overcome this

potential bias, we include a start-up dummy14

dividing the portfolio companies according to their

age at the time of investment (companies younger than two years, are labeled start-up and get a

value of 1; 0 otherwise). Second, two dummies15

(HIGH_TECH and LIFE_SCIENCES) are added

to control for the sector of the portfolio company. These dummies take on the value 1 if the

company is classified as a high-tech, respectively life sciences company, and 0 otherwise. Next, the

balance total of the company is incorporated to control for the size of the portfolio company at the

time of investment. Further, the number of investors engaged in the focal investment round and the

number of patent applications are inserted. We include number of investors because it is possible

that VCs will only share the best deals with their peers due to the fact that reputation is a very

fragile economic good. Since the number of patent applications at the time of investment is

generally low, we include a dummy variable taking on the value 1 when the company had applied

for patents prior to investment and 0 if it had not. Finally, valuations of unquoted ventures are

affected by valuations in the stock markets (Hand, 2005), hence we control for the timing of the

venture capital investment by a dummy variable taking on the value 1 if the investment took place

during the bubble period, i.e. 1999 up to 2001, and 0 otherwise.

4. Results

4.1 Descriptive statistics

Table 1 provides an overview of the mean, standard deviation, minimum and maximum of the used

variables. This table uncovers that 40% of the sample concerns start-up investments. 64% of the

13 These tests are presented later.

14 We ran another model replacing the start-up dummy by the actual age of the company as a robustness check and the results

remained qualitatively similar.

15 We ran another model replacing the two sector dummies by the EVCA sectoral classification as a robustness check. Apart from the

fact that the life sciences industry lost its significance, results stayed qualitatively unchanged.

Page 24: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

16

companies‟ activities in the sample are classified as high-tech, while only 13% are categorized as

life sciences. Close to one third of the investments took place during the Internet bubble period, i.e.

between 1999 and 2001, signalling an appropriate distribution in terms of time of investments,

considering that more investments took place during the bubble. Further, only 12% of the studied

companies applied for at least one patent, prior to investment. Finally, 31 companies (22%)

received financing from more than one venture capitalist and the average portfolio company in the

sample has a balance total of 835,280 EUR.

Table 1. Descriptive statistics on the used variables

Variables Mean s.d. Min Max N

a) Dependent 1. Pre-money Valuation (000 EUR) 2,690.59 6,164.00 23.18 32,815.82 140

b) Independent

2. MarketShare 3.06 4.02 0.00 17.31 140

3. MediaCitations 154.32 396.93 0.00 2,269.00 140

4. IndustryDeals 6.95 9.35 0.00 50.00 140

5. OverallDeals 23.84 31.94 0.00 224.00 140

6. FundSize (000 EUR) 130,260.38 211,329.75 924.78 1,129,030.00 140

7. VC_Age 8.22 6.07 0.23 26.82 140

c) Control

8. PATENT 0.12 0.33 0.00 1.00 140

9. START-UP 0.40 0.49 0.00 1.00 140

10. HIGH-TECH 0.64 0.48 0.00 1.00 140

11. LIFE_SCIENCES 0.13 0.33 0.00 1.00 140

12. BUBBLE 0.29 0.46 0.00 1.00 140

13. NumberOfInvestors 1.38 0.87 1.00 7.00 140

14. BalanceTotal (000 EUR) 835.28 1,555.26 0.00 10,694.51 140 Table 1 shows an overview of the mean, standard deviation, minimum and maximum of the used variables

Our sample covers deals from February 1992 to April 2009. Figure 116

portrays the distribution of

the average pre-money valuation of the 140 deals over those 18 years and the curve is largely

parallel with numbers reported by the European Venture Capital Association. The high amount

invested in 2000 is explained by the millennium bubble or dot-com hype. Periodically, the

16 The minimum number of investments per year is set at one, so years without investments are excluded.

Page 25: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

17

seemingly irrational behaviour of investors results in a speculative mania evidenced by

skyrocketing stock prices and exaggerated investor enthusiasm, until the bubble “bursts” (Lipton,

2003). Since valuations follow stock market prices (Hand, 2005), the remarkable drop in value after

2001 could be clarified by the effect of the burst. A Kruskal-Wallis-test17

indicates that there is a

significant difference in pre-money valuations among the different years. When looking at the graph

below we indeed see very high valuations during the bubble and remarkably low average valuations

afterwards.

Figure 1. Average valuation per year

Figure 1 plots the average valuation over the different years in our

sample

Finally, an unreported box plot concerning the pre-money valuations in the different industries

shows that companies in the financial services sector clearly obtain higher valuations although there

is no significant difference reported by the Kruskal-Wallis-test. This contradiction could be

attributed to the very small number of investments in this sector included in our sample.

Table 2 describes the sample at the company level. Panel A shows the number of

investments broken down by investment year. During the millennium bubble a higher number

17 The results of the test are not included in this research.

Page 26: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

18

investments are completed. Apart from that, there are no significant concentrations in any given

year. Panel B exhibits the distribution of our sample according to the European Venture Capital

Association‟s sectoral classification. 4-digit NACE-Bel-codes are collected on the portfolio

companies and through an official conversion key –found on the EVCA website- we divide these

industry codes in the seven sectors the EVCA distinguishes at baseline. Noteworthy is that over

40% of the sample handles deals completed in the ICT industry. The segment „Business and

Industrial Products and Services‟ covers one fourth of the sample. Less important industries are

„Energy and Environment‟ and „Financial Services‟, both approximately 2% of the sample.

Companies are classified by age at time of investment in Panel C. Three distinct categories are

designed; firms less than two years, between two and five years and older than five years (Manigart

et al., 2002). We can see that our sample mostly includes young companies since the first category

represents about 40% of the sample. This is strengthened by a median value of three year. About

36% of the sample consists of companies older than five year. Panel D categorizes the companies

by their legal status at the beginning of 2009. More than half of the firms are still private, while

almost 27% failed. 10% have been acquired and only about 4% have done an IPO. Unfortunately,

there is a potential bias concerning private firms. Failures and IPOs are easy to track from public

information. Acquisitions however are not always that easy to identify. As a consequence, it might

be that some firms were acquired but are nevertheless improperly classified as still private firms in

this sample. Finally, Panel E splits the sample in two distinct groups; companies that have received

follow-up finance and companies that have not. This reveals that more than half of the companies

were able to attract at least a second investment round.

The average venture capital firm in this sample was 8.22 years old at the time of investment,

had done 24 deals and was cited 154 times in „De Tijd‟ prior to investment and had funds available

for a value of 130,260,000 EUR. Half of the examined venture capitalists had done 4 or more

investments in the same industry as the one their respective target company operated in. The

average market share of the venture capitalists in our sample is approximately equal to 3%.

Page 27: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

19

Table 2. Descriptive Statistics at the company level

Panel A: Deals distributed by investment-year: actual number and cumulative percentage

1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

6 3 9 12 13 8 8 10 18

4.29% 6.43% 12.86% 21.43% 30.71% 36.43% 42.14% 49.29% 62.14%

2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009

13 13 10 3 0 5 6 2 1

71.43% 80.71% 87.86% 90.00% 90.00% 93.57% 97.86% 99.29% 100.00%

Panel B: Sectoral classification of the companies

Sectors Distribution of companies

Agriculture, Chemicals and Materials 9 6.43%

ICT 59 42.14%

Business and Industrial Products and Services 37 26.43%

Consumer Products, Services and Retail 13 9.29%

Energy and Environment 3 2.14%

Financial Services 4 2.86%

Life Sciences 15 10.71%

Panel C: Number of firms classified by age

Age Distribution of companies

0-2 years 55 39.29%

2-5 years 34 24.29%

> 5 years 51 36.43%

Panel D: Number of firms classified by legal status

Legal Status Distribution of companies

Failure 38 27.14%

Private 82 58.57%

M&A 14 10.00%

IPO 6 4.29%

Panel E: Number of firms receiving follow-on finance

Follow-on Financing Distribution of companies

Yes 77 55.00%

No 63 45.00% Table 2 discloses descriptive statistics for the sample of 140 first round venture capital investments in 140

Belgian companies. Panel A distributes the number of investments by year. Panel B classifies the number of

target companies according to the sectoral classification of EVCA. In panel C, target companies are divided

into three groups; 0-2 years, 2-5 years and >5 years. Panel D distributes the companies by legal status. In

panel E, we split the sample by looking if the target company received follow-on finance or not.

Page 28: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

20

Table 3. Univariate comparisons (based on Mann-Whitney tests)

Variables N Average Pre-money P-Value

BUBBLE 43 7,2967 0,001

NON_BUBBLE 101 6,3366

START-UP 56 6,7765 0,541

NON_START 84 6,5943

MULTIPLE_INVESTORS 31 7,1810 0,023

SINGLE_INVESTOR 109 6,4634

LIFE_SCIENCES 18 6,3460 0,365

NON_LIFE_SCIENCES 122 6,6630

HIGH_BALANCE_TOTAL 70 6,3372 0,029

LOW_BALANCE_TOTAL 70 6,9074

NON-PATENT 123 6,6062 0,743

PATENT 17 6,7388

HIGH-TECH 89 6,6571 0,72

NON_HIGH_TECH 51 6,5615 Table 3 splits each control variable in two groups and shows univariate

comparisons between the difference in average pre-money valuation

(ln(Premoney/1000)) of those groups. For BalanceTotal a dummy is created

taking on the value 1 if the observation exceeds the median and 0 otherwise.

Table 3 largely confirms our presumptions. The average valuation during the bubble is significantly

higher than in the post- and pre-bubble periods. Also when multiple investors18

participate in the

studied investment round, valuations are on average significantly higher than when only one

investor participates. We hence include the number of investors as a control variable in our final

model. We take a median split dummy of the balance total of the investee company to examine

whether higher balance total will lead to higher valuations. The latter is confirmed on the 5% level

by the results presented above. We find no significant results confirming that there is a difference in

average valuation for the high-tech dummy, the life-sciences dummy and the patent dummy.

However, we incorporate them in our final model based on previous literature. Also, these result do

not indicate a difference in average valuation when distinguishing between start-ups and more

mature companies. Nevertheless, we integrate the start-up dummy as a control variable since we

believe that the higher risk levels will lead to lower valuations when controlling for other factors.

18 We mentioned in part 3.2.3 why multiple investors might influence valuation.

Page 29: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

21

.

4.2 Method of analysis

In the three previous tables we presented the main descriptive statistics of our data. While these

results are suggestive, they do not systematically control for a variety of factors. We therefore

analyze the relationship between correlates of reputation and experience and firm valuation in a

more systematic way using multivariate regressions. Using a log-linear OLS regression, we test our

hypotheses. The use of a log-linear model conforms to nearly every analysis of venture capital

valuation undertaken in the entrepreneurial finance literature (Gompers & Lerner, 1999; Collewaert

& Manigart, 2009; Cumming & Dai, 2008). The log-transformation‟s main advantages include its

capability to dramatically reduce the skewness of the dependent variable. Both the Kolmogorov-

Smirnov and the Shapiro-Wilkinson tests of normality show that the transformed dependent

variable follows a normal distribution, which is one of the conditions to execute an OLS. OLS

regression, a commonly used technique, allows us to estimate the unknown parameters in a linear

regression model. The regressions that we estimate characterize pre-money valuation as a function

of the major components of reputation and experience of a VC, while controlling for macro-

economic and portfolio firm characteristics. Finally, we cluster on the lead VC level in order to

obtain the level at which we have maximum randomness19

. The hypothesized model consists of the

following exogenous independent and control variables: Market Share, Industry Specific Deal

Experience, Overall Deal Experience, Fund Size, Media Citations, VC Age, balance total, number

of investors, and dummies for bubble, high-tech, life sciences, start-up and patent applications:

Ln [Premoney/1000]= ß0 +p

ß1 [MediaCitations] +n

ß2 [MarketShare]

+ j

ß3 [IndustryExperience] +k

ß4 [OverallExperience] +m

ß5 Ln [FundSize/1000] +i

ß6

[VC_Age] +i

ß6 [Controls] + ε0

19 In order to be able to correctly analyze our data, the correlation between the observations needs to be taken into account. Else, the

standard errors of the estimates will be wrong, making significance tests invalid. This occurs because the standard errors normally

assume perfect independency between all observations. The larger the correlation between observations, the less unique information

each observation contains.

Page 30: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

22

Table 4. Log-linear OLS regressions, with standard errors clustered on the lead VCF, from testing the VC experience and reputation on pre-money valuation relationship

Model I Model II

MediaCitations 0,0010233 †

(0,0005347)

MarketShare 0,1498861 ** (0,0504728)

IndustryDeals 0,0142192 (0,0162205)

OverallDeals -0,0190733 * (0,0090765)

LnFundSize 0,0001092 (0,0006231)

AgeVC -0,0460678 † (0,0260473)

PATENT 0,3460964 0,4277831 (0,3659973) (0,3649221)

BUBBLE 1,091766 ** 1,478682 *** (0,3851997) (0,2871965)

START-UP -0,2436154 -0,5545467 † (0,3304477) (0,285154)

HIGH-TECH 0,2579318 0,1545695 (0,2713809) (0,2686488)

LIFE_SCIENCES -0,6974213 † -0,6400793 † (0,3853765) (0,3432336)

BalanceTotal 0,000319 *** 0,0003396 *** (0,0000794) (0,0000916)

NumberOfInvestors 0,4675226 † 0,221238 (0,3816242) (0,1577421)

_cons 5,303477 *** 5,492845 ***

(0,2717051) (0,3569295)

Number of Observations 140 140

F-value 5,65 6,02

R-squared 0,205 0,316

Adj. R-squared 0,163 0,246

Change in Adjusted R-squared 0,083

Change in F 2,32 *

Number of clusters (leadinvestor) 63 63

Table 3 presents the results of the log-linear OLS regression. Model 1 only contains the control variables

while model 2 also includes the reputation and experience variables.

P < 0,1 = †

P < 0,05 = *

P < 0,01 = **

P < 0,001 = ***

Page 31: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

23

This log-linear model shows next to none heteroscedasticity in comparison with other, non-

transformed models. In an unreported analysis, the Variance Inflating Factors (VIF) for all

regressors show no severe collinearity problem. Table 4 examines the coefficients of the regressors

with standard errors clustered on the lead VC level.

The first model (Model I), containing only the control variables, explains 16.3% of the

variation in pre-money valuations in this sample and shows one significant firm characteristic: a

positive coefficient for the balance total variable (<0.001). The number of investors and the life

sciences dummy both are marginally significant. The negative sign of the life science dummy can

be explained by a higher perceived risk. Companies whose activities are classified as life sciences

are characterized by a higher volatility and thus risk, implying that when investing in a life sciences

portfolio company, a VC will require a higher expected rate of return, reflected in a lower valuation.

The coefficient of NumberOfInvestors is positive, indicating that a higher number of investors will

lead to a higher valuation. Indirectly, this confirms our presumption that the number of investors is

a sign of company quality. The bubble dummy‟s coefficient is also positive and significant (<0.01),

which is in concordance with Lipton (2003) who argued that stock prices skyrocket during the

bubble while valuations of unquoted ventures follow stock market prices (Hand, 2005). The high-

tech dummy, the start-up dummy and the patent dummy seem to have no influence whatsoever on

the pre-money valuations. This latter is in contrast with previous valuation studies (Hsu, 2004; Hsu,

2007; Collewaert & Manigart, 2009), in which the number of patents applications prior to

investment was a highly significant predictor of pre-money valuation. When introducing the control

variables in the full model (model II) the control variables remain largely unchanged. The bubble

dummy gains in significance, the number of investors loses its significance, while the negative

coefficient of the start-up dummy becomes marginally significant. The negative coefficient of the

start-up dummy, which receives the value one when the investment took place in the first two years

of the company‟s existence, is to be expected, since the younger the venture, the higher the implied

risk. As mentioned earlier, the higher the risk, the higher the cost, often in the form of a discount in

the valuation (Seppä, 2003).

In addition to the control variables, model II also contains the VC characteristics. This

model explains 24,6% of the variation in the pre-money valuation in this sample. Since the number

Page 32: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

24

of observations is equal in the two models, both models can be compared and the change in R2 is

significant at the 0,05 level. Our proxies for VC experience and reputation hence explain a

significant part of the variation in the sample. The coefficients of the venture capitalist‟s

characteristics are not unambiguous. We find evidence to support our experience hypothesis.

However, not all experience proxies have a negative coefficient. Both LnFundSize and

IndustryExperience have a positive sign. Since both coefficients are not significant, we assume that

the negative and significant coefficient of OverallExperience (<0.05) and VC_Age (<0.10) is

sufficient empirical evidence to support the proposed hypothesis 3: VC experience is negatively

correlated with the pre-money valuation it offers to its portfolio ventures. Since VC_Age is largely

related with the density of the VC‟s network, this finding is consistent with Hsu (2007) who argued

that VCs‟ overall deal experience and network density may be more distinctive assets than their

functionally equivalent financial capital. Hence, venture capitalists who can count on a broader deal

experience and who can mobilize more resources through their more extensive network will be able

to demand a discount in valuation. We find no evidence to support our predicted relationships

between both dimensions of reputation and valuation. We find a positive and significant (<0,01)

coefficient for MarketShare and MediaCitations (<0,10), indicating the opposite of what was

hypothesized concerning prominent VCs. We hence reject hypothesis 2. The coefficient of our

perceived quality proxy is not significant which leads to rejection of hypothesis 1. Empirical

evidence of previous research showed that ventures backed by VCs with a higher perceived quality

show steeper growth curves (Vanacker, 2008) and are able to raise more follow-on equity

(Vanacker, 2009). We find no evidence to support the theory that entrepreneurs would be willing to

accept a discount in valuation in return for these improved prospects. Hence, our results do not

support Hsu‟s (2004) findings that more reputable20

venture capitalists will offer lower valuations to

its portfolio companies.21

20 Again, we have to point out that Hsu measured reputation based on past experience.

21 We hereby point out that in his paper “What do entrepreneurs pay for venture capital association”, Hsu made use of a very specific

dataset, only looking at startup companies, of which more than 80% received funding during the bubble.

Page 33: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

25

The economic interpretation of the coefficients of a log-linear model differs slightly from an

ordinary OLS-regression. While a linear-linear model indicates absolute effects, a log-linear model

demonstrates relative effects, expressed in percentages. We next interpret the results of model II.

If the investment took place during the bubble, the pre-money valuation was on average

close to 150% higher than pre- or post-bubble investments. When the investment concerned a start-

up, valuation offered was on average 55% lower than a more mature venture. Finally, each

incremental thousand Euros on the balance total before investment, means an average incline of

0,03% in valuation. The valuation of a company classified under the life sciences category, will on

average be 64% lower than a non-life sciences company.

An incline in OverallDeals by one unit will cause a decline in the average offered valuation

of roughly 2%. However only marginally significant, each additional year of operations will lead to

a decrease of 4,6% in valuation offered. An incremental unit in media citations in the clustered

model leads to an increase of 0,10% in valuation. The small percentage is not remarkable, for it is

obvious that only one sole citation cannot have a large effect on valuation. An increase in

MarketShare by one unit – here one percent - leads to a predicted increase in the dependent value

pre-money valuation of approximately 15%, when all other regressors are held constant. The latter

results concerning investor prominence are in complete contradiction with Seppä (2003) and thus

have several implications.

Nahata (2008) found that more reputable VCs are able to select better quality deals and

hence are willing to pay a price premium for the reduced risk. Our model so far did not control for

selection. We next try to eliminate a possible selection bias, and thus investigate whether more

reputable venture capitalists are in fact better at selecting higher quality companies.

4.3 Dealing with a selection bias

The result that more prominent VCs offer higher valuations to their portfolio ventures might suffer

from endogeneity problems. Because of the likely matching between more reputable venture

capitalists and better quality companies, selection bias could arise. The higher valuation might thus

be a simple result of the portfolio company characteristics, instead of being related to prominence.

We will use a two-stage approach proposed by Heckman (1979) to overcome this problem. This

technique deals with endogeneity in two steps: first we estimate the likelihood of prominent venture

Page 34: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

26

capitalists making an investment in a higher quality firm, after which we add an additional regressor

(the inverse Mills ratio) to estimate the pre-money valuation. A significant inverse Mills ratio‟s

coefficient suggests the possible existence selection bias. The results of the Heckman two-stage

approach are presented in tables 5 and 6 below.

Table 5. Probit regression modelling the probability of a company being selected by a more reputable VCF (Heckman first step)

Probit regression

Number of observations 140

Probability > Chi² 0,0366

PATENT_APPLICATIONS 0,0906347

(-0,3350082)

AmountInvested 1,67 **

(8,50E-08)

FOLLOW-UP 0,4896869 **

(0,2259162)

NumberOfInvestors -0,1446888

(0,1570836)

CompanyAge 0,0738899 **

(0,0368653)

_cons -0,5596181 *

(0,313871) Table 4 provides the results of a probit regression performed to investigate if

company characteristics influence the likelihood of being selected by a more

reputable VC.

P < 0,1 = †

P < 0,05 = *

P < 0,01 = **

P < 0,001 = ***

In the first step we run a probit regression in order to investigate whether company quality

characteristics influence the chance of being selected by a more prominent VC firm. A dummy that

takes the value 1 when both the VC‟s market share and media citations is above the median,

measures prominence. High growth companies usually have greater financing needs. Since different

VCs have different amounts of cash available to them, they might have to pass an otherwise good

opportunity due to financing constraints. Thus it is interesting to incorporate the amount invested in

Page 35: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

27

the portfolio company as a company characteristic (Heughebaert & Manigart, 2009). As mentioned

earlier, less mature firms are riskier, which may lead to an increased required return on investment,

in itself leading to lower valuations (Wright & Lockett, 2001). Hence, CompanyAge is included as a

proxy for maturity. Since reputation is a very fragile economic good, it is possible that VCs will

only share the best deals with their peers. The number of investors is hence included to measure

company quality. For young high-growth firms, their intellectual property often is a very important

asset. The perfect way to protect these assets is by applying for a patent. Patent applications are

therefore incorporated as proxy for the venture‟s quality. We also include a dummy to investigate

whether the investee company receives any follow-on financing. A company able to attract follow-

on financing is likely to be a company that reached several milestones. Attaining a milestone – and

in extension next round financing- can hence be a signal of company quality. This process will

naturally be affected by the VC‟s input; however the effect of the portfolio venture‟s input will be

more important (Sapienza & Gupta, 1994).

The small probability of encountering a test statistic as extreme as the observed statistic

under the null hypothesis – i.e. all the regression coefficients are simultaneously equal to zero- leads

us to conclude that at least one of the coefficients is significantly different from zero. The positive

and significant sign of AmountInvested, CompanyAge and FOLLOW-UP mean that a rise in the

predictor variable will lead to an increase in the predicted probability of the dependent variable. The

constant amounts approximately -0,56, meaning that if all other variables are held constant at zero,

i.e. a “low” quality company, the foretold probability of a prominent VC investing in a company is

F(-0,56)= 0,2877. It is important to note that we are only able to control for a limited number of

company quality characteristics; for example we have no information whatsoever on the quality of

the company, which can be noticeable in ex-post information, nor on the quality of the management

team of the portfolio venture. However, in the past the latter has proven to significantly affect

valuation (Collewaert & Manigart, 2009; Hsu, 2007).

Page 36: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

28

Table 6. Log-linear OLS regression, with standard errors clustered on the lead VCF, of pre-money valuations while controlling for potential selection bias

Model II

MediaCitations 0,0008184 †

(0,0004803)

MarketShare 0,1362237 ** (0,0499729)

IndustryDeals 0,0166497 (0,0139661)

OverallDeals -0,0197285 * (0,0084179)

LnFundSize -0,0002991 (0,0009851)

AgeVC -0,030879 (0,0248817)

PATENT 0,4967988 †

(0,3295656)

BUBBLE 1,558899 *** (0,2776064)

START-UP -0,3535733 (0,2976686)

HIGH-TECH 0,0872257 (0,2517956)

LIFE_SCIENCES -0,5680404 †

(0,3072157)

BalanceTotal 0,0002806 *** (0,0000772)

NumberOfInvestors 0,2012116 (0,1412481)

InverseMillsRatio -1,769177 ** (0,5420663)

_cons 6,88824 ***

(0,5515831)

Number of Observations 140

F-value 8,18

R-squared 0,3672

Adj. R-squared 0,2963

Number of clusters (leadinvestor) 63

Table 5 presents the results of the log-linear OLS regression. In addition to

table 3, the inverse mills ratio is included to control for a possible selection

bias.

P < 0,1 = †

P < 0,05 = *

P < 0,01 = **

P < 0,001 = ***

Page 37: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

29

In the second step we include the inverse Mills ratio in our original model to control for a

possible selection bias. Table 6 presents the results. The coefficient of the inverse Mills ratio,

estimated from the first stage probit regression, is significant, indicating the existence of a selection

bias. More prominent venture capitalists will hence invest in different companies than their less

prominent peers; in this case „different‟ equals better quality (Cf. the selection model). After

controlling for selection bias the results remain fairly robust, that is, the sign of the coefficients does

not change. However, the coefficient of VC_Age loses its significance. The significant MarketShare

coefficient amounts approximately 0,14, meaning that if the market share of a VCF would increase

by one percent, the pre-money valuation would increase by 14%. The number of overall deals a

venture capitalist performs in the eight years preceding the date of investment is economically

significant at the 5% level. This indicates that every extra deal the VC engages in, causes the pre-

money valuation to decrease with approximately 2%. The control variables BUBBLE and

BalanceTotal still remain highly significant, with an economically significant increase in valuation,

amounting 156%, respectively 0,03%. The number of media citations stays marginally significant,

while the patent dummy becomes marginally significant, for an increase in valuation of

approximately 50% when the portfolio company has applied for at least one patent. The life

sciences dummy, indicating whether a firm operates in the life sciences sector, remains marginally

significant. The decrease in valuation of 56,8% is probably due to the fact that the life sciences

sector is perceived as one of the riskiest industries.22

The discount in valuation will hence serve as a

buffer to obtain higher returns ex-post.

We conclude that there in fact exists a selection bias influencing the results. When

controlling for selection our model explains close to 30 percent of the observed variation in the

sample. The age of the venture capitalist loses its significance and the patent dummy becomes

marginally significant, while the rest of the results only change in significance level, but largely

remain qualitatively unchanged. The coefficients of both our proxies measuring prominence remain

positive and significant, even after controlling for selection.

22 For a more elaborate description of the life sciences sector, we refer to Baeyens, Vanacker & Manigart (2006); Senker (1998) and

Brierley (2001)

Page 38: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

30

We explain this result, based on previous literature. The set of investment opportunities is

likely to be larger for more reputable venture capitalists (Hochberg, Ljungqvist & Lu, 2007), since

companies want to affiliate with the „better‟ partner. This might leave their less reputable peers with

investment opportunities in younger and riskier ventures. Less reputable VCs will hence offer lower

valuations, explaining the positive relationship. In a private, unquoted setting where information

asymmetries are very high, it is in the VC‟s best interest to build a reputation as quickly as possible.

(Gompers & Lerner, 2000) Also, Gompers (1996) has shown that a venture capitalist that

underperforms the market will experience great difficulties raising new funds. Therefore, in order to

be able to raise new funds, generate greater returns ex post and thus a good reputation, less

reputable VCs will offer lower valuations. Also, MarketShare is, in contrast with previous studies

(Nahata, 2008), constructed using the absolute number of investments - due to data limitations -

instead of the accumulated amount. This measure is based on the idea that every investment is

equal, which is obviously not the case. Having a large market share does hence not necessarily

mean that the venture capitalist invested the most in absolute monetary terms. The total invested

amount in many smaller investments may be smaller than the amount invested in one large

investment. More reputable firms might invest in larger portfolio companies for larger amounts.

Thus it is possible that our MarketShare proxy for reputation might surface the exact opposite

results than market share proxies used in earlier studies using the invested amount. As for now, the

needed information is not available, but it might be an interesting topic for future research.

Page 39: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

31

5. Discussion, conclusions and limitations

In addition to previous research, we separate experience from reputation to examine their respective

impact on pre-money valuations. Furthermore, we distinguish between two distinct dimensions of

venture capitalist reputation: prominence and perceived quality. We address the influence of these

two different dimensions on pre-money valuations within the venture capital industry. We base

ourselves on a unique dataset free of survivorship bias containing 140 Belgian venture capital-

backed companies. Results demonstrate that venture capitalists with a higher experience tend to

offer lower valuations to companies, whilst reputation shows an ambiguous effect on the pre-money

valuation. The perceived quality of a VCF seems to have no impact. However, more prominent VCs

appear to offer higher valuations.

Several valuable contributions are added to previous research through this study. First,

although prior studies have focused on the impact of different dimensions of firm reputation on the

ability to mobilize resources (Vanacker, 2009) and on the ability of firms to demand a premium in

order to affiliate with them (Rindova et al., 2005), to our knowledge this is one of the first studies

examining the influence of distinct dimensions of reputation on valuations within the venture

capital-setting. Second, in contrast with previous research (Hsu, 2004) this study also distinguishes

between experience and reputation as different venture capitalist characteristics. Third, using a

private setting in our study tries to fill a gap in the literature. Certification becomes more valuable in

this environment due to higher information asymmetries, so reputation and experience are likely to

have different –stronger- effects from those in a public setting.

This study offers a valuable insight for entrepreneurial companies. Greene (1999) argued that

entrepreneurial companies often are likely to accept financing from whoever is willing to offer it

since it can be complicated to find enough financing due to high growth ambitions. However, such

reasoning can stand in the way of a successful ex-post development, given that an investor of lower

reputation could be unable to mobilize sufficient resources other than providing capital (Vanacker,

2009). Furthermore, Vanacker (2008) demonstrated that companies backed by venture capitalists

Page 40: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

32

with higher experience grow significantly faster23

. We offer further evidence that the heterogeneity

in reputation and experience between VCs has an impact on valuation and that it is hence not only

about the amount of money raised, nor about the minimization of the dilution of capital.

Several limitations of this study open windows for further research. First, the sample only considers

Belgian venture capital-backed companies, which restricts the external validity of the results. This

is especially the case for the more developed Anglo-Saxon venture capital industries. However, the

VC industry in most Continental Europe countries has a similar structure and analogous procedures

compared to the Belgian venture capital industry since most VCFs are independent with a closed-

end structure (Heughebaert & Manigart, 2009).

Second, the sample comprehends a period of about 20 years (1988-2009). Within this

timeframe, the Belgian venture capital industry did not remain static. It evolved from an emerging

industry during the late 80s to a booming industry in the late 90s. After the market correction in the

beginning of the 21st century, VC activity first dropped significantly and grew in later years at a

moderate pace (Heughebaert & Manigart, 2009). Furthermore, the pending financial crisis is

expected to have a relevant influence as well, as Hand (2005) points out the correlation between

company valuations and stock market performance. Our data comprises only three deals in the latest

crisis, which makes it hard to make solid predictions.

Third, the valuation a VC offers for a certain equity stake may not be the only factor that

matters when entrepreneurs select a venture capitalist, as term sheet covenants may not be „priced

in‟ to the offered valuation (Hsu, 2004). The investor may structure financial contracts in a manner

that minimizes principal agent problems (Kaplan & Stromberg, 2001). Our dataset does not cover

information concerning potential clauses incorporated in the negotiated contract, so it could be that

the interpretation of the studied valuations is not straightforward, since these clauses may impact

the entrepreneurial interpretation of a term sheet. It may well be that higher initial valuations go

hand in hand with tougher contractual clauses and it seems defensible that more experienced or

reputable investors are able to negotiate much tougher contract with entrepreneurial management

teams through accumulated knowledge on the subject.

23 This is true for the asset growth rates, he finds no evidence for the employment part of growth.

Page 41: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

33

Further, variables on the venture capitalists‟ characteristics are undoubtedly no perfect

reflections of their reputation and experience. We measure perceived quality using a variable that

also proxies experience. It would have been of superior value if we were able to use a distinct

variable for perceived quality such as the quality of the venture capital firm‟s management team, a

ranking by peers or a ranking by portfolio management teams. More generally, in contrary with

Anglo-Saxon countries it could be that in Belgium there exists another perception of a venture

capital firm‟s reputation and experience. For example, it may be that entrepreneurial companies in

Belgium are more concerned with the broadness of a VC‟s network to form a perception of his

reputation.

Fifth, venture capitalists often valuate their potential investments in terms of the quality of

the entrepreneurial management team, customer acceptance and potential market share (Sörensen,

2007). We are, due to data limitations, not capable of researching these important proxies for

company quality. It would have been of superior value in our research.

Finally, we did not control for the unobserved characteristics of the portfolio companies‟

quality, which may be noticeable in ex-post information. This might influence the selection effect

even further. Also, we did not control for VC characteristics apart from reputation and experience.

Heughebaert & Manigart (2009) however, demonstrated that the type of investor drives valuation.

Page 42: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

34

References

Armstrong, C., Davila, A. and Foster, G. (2006). Venture-backed private equity valuation and

financial statement information. Review of Accounting Studies 11(1), 119-154.

Aernoudt, R. (1999). Business Angels, Should They Fly on Their Own Wings? Venture Capital, an

international journal of entrepreneurial finance 1(2), 187 - 196.

Baeyens, K. Vanacker, T. and Manigart, S. (2006). Venture capitalists‟ selection process: the case

of biotechnology proposals. International Journal of Technology Management 34, 28-46.

Bhide, A. (1992). Bootstrap finance: the art of start-ups. Harvard Business Review 70 (6), p109-

117.

Black, B.S. and Gilson, R.J. (1998). Venture capital and the structure of capital markets: banks

versus stock markets. Journal of Financial Economics 47, 243-277.

Brierley, P. (2001). The financing of technology-based small firms: a review of the literature. Bank

of England Quarterly Bulletin 41, 64-76.

Collewaert, V. and Manigart, S. (2009). First round valuations of angel backed companies. Working

paper, Ghent University.

Cook, D., Kieschnick, R. and Van Ness, R. (2006). On the marketing of IPOs. Journal of Financial

Economics 82, 35-61.

Cumming, D. and Dai, N. (2008). Fund size, limited attention and valuation of venture capital

backed firms. Working paper.

Page 43: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

35

Dimov, D., and Shepherd, D. (2005). Human capital theory and venture capital firms: Exploring

“home runs” and “strike outs”. Journal of Business Venturing 20, 1-21.

Dushnitsky, G. and Lenox, M.J. (2005). When do incumbents learn from entrepreneurial ventures?

Corporate venture capital and investing firm innovation rates. Research policy 34, 615-639.

EVCA, European Venture Capital Association Yearbook 1992-2009, Zaventem, Brussel.

Fairchild, R. (2004). Financial contracting between managers and venture capitalists the role of

value-added services, reputation seeking, and bargaining power. The Journal of Financial

Research 27(4), 481-495.

Gompers, P. (1996). Grandstanding in the venture capital industry. Journal of Financial Economics

42, 133-156.

Gompers, P. and Lerner, J. (2000). Money chasing deals? The impact of fund inflows on the

valuation of private equity investments. Journal of Financial Economics 55 (2), 281-325.

Gompers, P. and Lerner, J. (1999). The Venture Capital Cycle. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Gompers, P., Kovner, A., Lerner, J. and Scharfstein, D. (2009). Specialization and succes: evidence

from venture capital. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 18, 817-844.

Greene, H.E. (1999). Picking your VC. Nature Biotechnology 17, BE25-BE26.

Hallen, B. (2008). The causes and consequences of the initial network positions of new

organizations: From whom do entrepreneurs receive investments? Administrative Science Quarterly

53, 685-718.

Page 44: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

36

Hand, J. (2005). The value relevance of financial statements in the venture capital market. The

Accounting Review 80(2), 613-648.

Heckman, J. (1979). Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error. Econometrica 47, 153-162.

Heughebaert, A. and Manigart, S. (2010). Investee firm value in venture capital financing rounds:

the impact of VC firm type. Working paper, Ghent University.

Hochberg, Y., Ljungqvist, A. and Lu, Y. (2007). Whom you know matters: venture capital networks

and investment performance. Journal of Finance 62, 251-301.

Hsu, D.H. (2007). Experienced entrepreneurial founders, organizational capital, and venture capital

funding. Research Policy 36(5), 722-741.

Hsu, D.H. (2004). What do entrepreneurs pay for venture capital affiliation? Journal of Finance 59,

1805-1844.

Janney, J. and Folta, T. (2006). Moderating effects of investor experience on the signaling value of

private equity placements. Journal of Business Venturing 21, 27– 44.

Kaplan, S. and Strömberg, P. (2001). Venture capitalists as principals: contracting, screening, and

monitoring. American Economic Review 91, 426-430.

Lerner, J. (1994). Venture capitalists and the decision to go public. Journal of Financial Economics

35, 293–316.

Lipton, M. (2003). The Millennium Bubble And Its Aftermath: Reforming Corporate America And

Getting Back To Business. Unpublished working paper.

Page 45: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

37

Manigart, S., De Waele, K., Wright, M., Robbie, K., Desbrières, P., Sapienza, H. and Beekman, A.

(2002). Determinants of required return in venture capital investments: a five-country study.

Journal of Business Venturing 17, 291-312.

Megginson, W. and Weiss, K. (1991). Venture capitalist certification in initial public Offerings.

Journal of Finance 46, 879 903.

Nahata, R. (2009). Reputation in financial intermediation: evidence from venture capital.

Companion to Venture Capital (Wiley, Chapter 15, forthcoming).

Nahata, R. (2008). Venture capital reputation and investment performance. Journal of Financial

Economics 90, 127-151.

Rindova, V., Williamson, I., Petkova, A. and Sever, J. (2005). Being good or being known: an

empirical examination of the dimensions, antecedents, and consequences of organizational

reputation. Academy of Management Journal 48, 1033-1049.

Sapienza, H.J. and Gupta, A.K. (1994). Impact of agency risks and task uncertainty on venture

capitalist-CEO interaction. Academy of Management Journal 37 (4), 1618-1632.

Sahlman, W. A. (1997). How to write a great business plan. Harvard Business Review 75, 98–108.

Sahlman, W. A. (1990). The structure and governance of venture capital organizations. Journal of

Financial Economics 27, 473 524.

Senker, J. (1998). Biotechnology and competitive advantage. Edward Elgar Publisher.

Seppä, T.J. (2003). Essays on the valuation and syndication of venture capital investments.

Unpublished doctoral dissertation.

Page 46: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

38

Sorensen, M. (2007). How smart is smart money? A two-sided matching model of venture capital.

Journal of Finance 62, 2725-2762.

Stuart, T. E., Hoang, H., & Hybels, R. C. (1999). Interorganizational endorsements and the

performance of entrepreneurial ventures. Administrative Science Quarterly 44 , 315–349.

Vanacker, T. (2009). Seeking good or known partners? A longitudinal study on the impact of

partner reputation on entrepeneurial company growth. Ph.D.: Financing unquoted high-growth

companies: from extending existing finance theory towards an evolutionary theory of the finance

process, unpublished doctoral dissertation.

Vanacker, T. (2008). Venture capital firm experience and company growth. Frontiers of

Entrepreneurship Research.

Weigelt, K., & Camerer, C. (1988). Reputation and corporate strategy: A review of recent theory

and applications. Strategic Management Journal 9, 443–454.

Wright, M., &Lockett, A. (2003). The structure and management of alliances: Syndication in the

venture capital industry. Journal of Management Studies 40(8), 2073-2102.

Page 47: The Influence of Venture Capitalist Reputation and

39