38
GEN - Governance and Economics research Network GEN Working Paper A 2015 – 5 webs.uvigo.es/infogen/WP THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY Jorge Martinez-Vazquez* Santiago Lago-Peñas** Agnese Sacchi*** * Georgia State University and GEN ** GEN, IEB and University of Vigo *** La Sapienza University of Rome (Italy) and GEN Original version: June 2015 Revised version: September 2016

THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

GEN - Governance and Economics research Network

GEN Working Paper A 2015 – 5 webs.uvigo.es/infogen/WP

THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

Jorge Martinez-Vazquez* Santiago Lago-Peñas** Agnese Sacchi***

* Georgia State University and GEN** GEN, IEB and University of Vigo*** La Sapienza University of Rome (Italy) and GEN

Original version: June 2015

Revised version: September 2016

Page 2: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

1

The Impact of Fiscal Decentralization: A Survey

Jorge Martinez-Vazquez,a Santiago Lago-Peñas.b and Agnese Sacchic

a International Center for Public Policy (Georgia State University) & Governance and

Economics research Network (GEN)

bGEN and University of Vigo

c La Sapienza University of Rome (Italy) and GEN

Abstract

In this article, we offer a comprehensive and updated review of the impact of fiscal

decentralization on the economy, society and politics. Our first target is the examination of two

crucial and yet unsolved issues in the empirical literature on decentralization: the proper

measurement of decentralization itself and its potential endogeneity in econometric estimates.

Then, we discuss the main existing findings on the effects of decentralization on a relevant list of

socio-economic issues. The impact of fiscal decentralization reforms on political institutions and

public policies is also considered. Complete answers on the impact of fiscal decentralization are

not likely to be certain but, overall, there are reasons to be optimistic about the net positive

result. Our survey by necessity has to be selective but it presents a balanced view of what is

known and what is not yet known opening room for further research and practice on fiscal

decentralization.

JEL classification: H70, H72, H77

Keywords: Fiscal federalism, political decentralization, sub-national governments,

macroeconomic stability, economic growth, politics, corruption, income inequality, service

delivery, tax morale.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS: This research has been financially supported by the Spanish Ministry

of Science and Innovation (CSO2013-4703-C2-2-R and ECO2012-37572). We are grateful to

two anonymous reviewers and the editor for very helpful comments and to Gabriel Leonardo,

Fernanda Martínez, and Alejandro Domínguez for able research assistance.

Page 3: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

2

1. INTRODUCTION

Over the last several decades many countries around the globe have devolved fiscal and political

powers to sub-national governments. According to data gathered by Garman et al. (2001), more

than 80 percent of the seventy-five developing countries analyzed had been undergoing some

decentralization of authority by the beginning of the millennium. The picture is quite the same in

developed countries. The index of regional authority computed by Hooghe et al. (2010) for 42

democracies and semi-democracies reveals that 70% of countries have decentralized since 1950.

Decentralization is motivated by quite different reasons. In the past several decades, a large

number of unitary countries have sought decentralization as a means of searching for a more

efficient and leaner public sector. Other countries became disenchanted with the performance of

former planning and centralized policies. Indeed, fiscal decentralization deals with how the

public sector is organized and how to create opportunities for higher growth and welfare.

Decentralizing governance can restore confidence in public policies and provide a basis for

broader policy consensus. There are often grassroots demands to achieve democratic ideals

through decentralization. On the other hand, some decentralization movements are designed to

contain centrifugal forces, ethnic conflicts, and/or separatist movements, and to smooth out

social and political tensions by means of allowing more local autonomy.

Since sub-national governments are now key actors in the delivery and provision of public

goods and services to citizens all over the world, it has become increasingly important to know

the impact of fiscal decentralization on the economy, the society and politics. The array of socio-

economic issues is wide and it includes growth and development, reducing poverty and

achieving the Millennium Development Goals), improving public sector efficiency and

governance, or achieving greater macroeconomic stability and fiscal sustainability. The

fundamental question is whether the ongoing decentralization trend is helping or hurting those

important policy goals. Moreover, there are other key institutional and political aspects affected

by fiscal decentralization and interacting with public choices that merit attention. The set of

issues is again wide and diverse, including country unity and separatism, the level of corruption,

accountability and political representation, and the nationalization of political party systems.

In this article, we offer a comprehensive review of what is known to date on the impact of

fiscal decentralization. We begin with a synthetic review of the main theories of fiscal federalism

in order to put into perspective the empirical work surveyed. In section 3 we deal with three

crucial and yet unsolved issues in the literature on decentralization: first, its proper measurement;

second, its potential endogeneity; and third, the lack of uniform data sets that capture the

multidimensionality of decentralization. In section 4, we critically review the main findings in

the literature on the effects of decentralization on a relevant list of socio-economic variables

(e.g., efficiency, economic growth and investment, income inequality and poverty,

macroeconomic stability, regional disparities). Political consequences (e.g., on the public sector

growth, government accountability and corruption, social capital and tax moral, voter turnout)

are discussed in section 5. Section 6 concludes.

2. FIRST AND SECOND GENERATION THEORIES OF FEDERALISM

Decentralization implies the devolution of decision-making powers to sub-national governments,

as opposed to “deconcentration” where central government operations are decentralized, but

Page 4: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

3

there is no devolution of any decision-making powers. In addition, decentralization is a

multifaceted phenomenon since it encompasses political, administrative, and fiscal dimensions

that are implemented at varying extents on the vertical structure of governments also interacting

with each other.

Traditional theory of fiscal federalism and intergovernmental fiscal relations draws heavily

from the seminal contributions of Tiebout (1956), Musgrave (1959), Oates (1972) and Olson

(1969) among others. In this literature, the economic case for decentralization is simply made by

arguing that the devolution of tax and expenditure authority yields greater public sector

efficiency. Viewing government as a benevolent agent, Oates’ well-known decentralization

theorem states that in the presence of diverse preferences and needs, provision of public services

by a decentralized government structure generally will lead to increased citizen welfare. This

fundamental result derives from the fact that decentralized government is assumed to lead to

information advantages and more flexibility in adapting to citizens’ needs and preferences. This

fact is reinforced by the mobility of households since as claimed by Tiebout (1956) individuals

can vote with their feet and sort themselves into homogenous communities where their

preferences are maximized.

The classical principles for decentralization design are well traveled across countries and over

time. Hundreds of decentralization programs proposed by multilateral international

organizations, bilateral donors, and policy advisers have been inspired by these principles. After

certain design issues have been addressed, such as imposing hard budget constraints, the

classical framework has been quite robust and successful.1

An important extension of this literature is what has become known as “second-generation”

fiscal federalism, a literature that brings a public choice perspective by assuming the presence of

selfish public officials with their own agenda, as opposed to the benevolent public officials

assumed in the previous literature.2 A good example of second generation work is the literature

on market-preserving federalism, which focuses on incentives for government officials not to

deviate from “good behavior” and emphasizes the role of decentralization as a mechanism to

control an expansive public sector and also support private market activity (Weingast 1995). The

second generation literature depicts a world where political and fiscal institutions work under

imperfect information and political agents have their own objective functions which are distinct

from that of the “society” as a whole (Oates 2005).

Incentives and knowledge are two important factors in determining how the institutions and

agents behave. For instance, Seabright (1996) views elections as incomplete contracts where

some information is not verifiable. The benefits and costs of decentralization are no longer

limited to efficiency gains and losses; the second wave literature identified other goals for

decentralization as well as tradeoffs. Limiting government size through competition might come

at the price of starting a “race to the bottom” with slashed taxes and service provision levels,

leading to an inefficient provision of public goods (Wilson, 1986; Zodrow and Mieszkowski,

1 In reality, countries differ considerably on how decentralized they are. There is a literature that explores the

determinants of fiscal decentralization, from a theoretical perspective (Arzaghi and Henderson, 2002; Panizza, 1999)

and empirically (Canavire-Bacarreza and Martinez-Vazquez, 2012). 2 The assumption of selfish public officials is the cornerstone of the public choice theory. Brennan and Buchanan

(1980) in their Leviathan hypothesis argued that the decentralization of tax and spending powers introduces

competition among governmental units seeking to attract citizens and other mobile resources, and thereby constrains

the reach and size of the public sector.

Page 5: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

4

1986). Moreover, increased decentralization can improve accountability of government officials

but it is likely to make policy coordination more complex (Oates, 2005).

The treatment of institutional characteristics has also been different. Whereas the first wave

has focused more on governance structure and its relation to fiscal and economic matters –

number of levels of government, jurisdiction size, both expenditure and revenue assignments –

the second wave focused more broadly on the design of those structures as political as well as

economic institutions (Weingast, 2009).

Another area where differences may be seen is how decentralization should be financed. The

first generation literature posited that revenue generation at the regional level should follow the

benefit principle because it enhances government accountability and reduces induced distortions

from taxing mobile tax bases. Grants are seen as addressing vertical imbalances and horizontal

disparities, and also as a way internalize benefit spillovers beyond regional borders. By contrast,

the second generation literature emphasizes the effects of grants on regional incentives to

economic growth, rent-seeking, and budget balance. And it considers hard budget constraints,

limits to issuing debt, and bankruptcy laws as devices to discipline and shape the incentive

structure of subnational governments.

Finally, it has been put into question that uniform central provision is the right counterfactual

for decentralization (Lockwood 2002; Besley and Coate, 2003). It may not be if central

governments are able to diversify and customize the provision of public services in a manner

similar to decentralized governments. Alternatively, privatization instead of decentralization

might be alternative to centralization (Tanzi, 2002). However, further questions are raised

regarding whether deconcentrating can be as efficient as decentralization because of lower

accountability and the lack of interest by central authorities in diversifying the provision of

public services (Seabright, 1996).

Recapping, there are in fact several theories of fiscal decentralization. And although these

theories are compatible in many fundamental issues, in some cases they might also lead to

different predictions in terms of the impact of fiscal decentralization and also the different

mechanisms which lead to those results. The impact of fiscal decentralization on government

size is an example of those differences in predictions and operating mechanisms.

3. ISSUES TO WORRY ABOUT: MEASURING DECENTRALIZATION AND

ADDRESSING ENDOGENEITY

Two basic issues continue to represent significant obstacles when analyzing the consequences of

fiscal decentralization from an empirical standpoint. The first is how to measure it and weather

the necessary data are actually available. Ideally, decentralization measures should take into

account its multi-dimensional nature, including political and administrative aspects, but also

looking at both sides of the budget and at the actual degree of autonomy given to sub-national

governments over tax and spending decisions (Ebel and Yilmaz, 2003). In particular, shared

taxes usually appear in official statistics as sub-national revenue, although the sub-national

government has no autonomy in determining the revenue base or rate.3

3 Revenues are reported based on which level of government ultimately receives the revenues.Some attempts to

overcome this shortcoming are those of Stegarescu (2005) and Gemmell et al. (2013), However, data coverage is

typically limited in terms of countries and years.

Page 6: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

5

Moreover, tax sharing links the budgets of the central and local governments in a complicated

way and creates a moral hazard and conflict of interest among different levels of government. In

this perspective, problems of soft budget constraints (Rodden et al., 2003), yardstick competition

(Bordignon at al., 2003) and tax competition (Köthenbürger, 2004) may arise and they should be

taken into account in dealing with fiscal decentralization consequences.

The second obstacle has to do with the problem of endogeneity. Because decentralization is

contemporaneous to many other forces and processes, it is far from clear how to isolate its effect

from these other phenomena and how to know whether decentralization is a cause or itself also

an effect of the policies and institutional changes in which we are interested.

3.1 Measuring decentralization: Concepts, data sources and indicators

The debate surrounding the measurement of decentralization continues in both economics and

political science literatures. Most of the good measures essentially boil down to a few concepts:

locally raised own revenues, autonomy on expenditure decisions, locally spent national grants, or

even number and size of local units. The challenges are conceptual but also those related to data

availability.

Differences in how decentralization is defined and measured can result in widely differing

values of the decentralization variable (Liu et al., 2012; Voigt and Blume, 2012). As a point of

departure, Rodden (2004) proposes a sound three-category classification of decentralization.

First, fiscal decentralization as captured by means of expenditure and revenue data, often

adopted in empirical studies. Second, policy decentralization, focused on how and to what extent

higher levels of government affect or override policy decisions of lower levels of government.

Third, a political dimension for decentralization captured by the process by which the local

officials assume their offices.

However, this distinction is not so clear-cut in practice. The different aspects of

decentralization may interact with one another affecting the meaning and effectiveness of similar

measures of decentralization. For example, centrally determined standards of service and/or

federal laws may considerably limit sub-national governments’ discretion and autonomy, or

delegated responsibility for tax collection may over-state actual policy revenue autonomy. The

degree of party centralization may also exert a lot of influence over the independence of local

officials and the actual outcomes of otherwise identical systems of fiscal decentralization (Ponce-

Rodríguez et al., 2012).4

Narrowing the focus to fiscal decentralization does not necessarily lead to less ambiguity on

what is the relevant definition to be used. For example, Neyapti (2010) and Rodden (2002) both

addressed how fiscal decentralization affects governments’ fiscal discipline but the former

focuses on expenditure and revenue decentralization as shares of general government, while the

latter on the vertical imbalances and sub-national borrowing.

In addition, no single measure of decentralization can capture all the multiple dimensions that

decentralization offers. And even though composite measures of decentralization that may be

attractive and useful in some contexts they can also fall short when measuring the impact of

4 The political dimension of decentralization is most often measured by whether the constitution classifies a country

as a federation or as a unitary state and by whether sub-national officials are elected (Fan et al., 2009). The

importance and consequences of different degrees of party centralization have been given some attention in the

literature (Riker 1964; Enikolopov and Zhuravskaya 2007).

Page 7: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

6

decentralization on specific policy outcomes (Martinez-Vazquez and Timofeev, 2010; Liu et al.,

2012). The key message in these papers is that aggregating those distinct dimensions of

decentralization into a single indicator inevitably leads to a loss of information and that therefore

in a multivariate framework the distinct aspects of decentralization should enter the regression

separately in the most flexible functional form.

Regarding data availability, typically, cross-country and panel analyses are most commonly

based on OECD fiscal decentralization data – when focusing on advanced economies – and on

the IMF’s Government Finance Statistics (GFS) yearbooks together with the World Bank’s

decentralization indicators – when the sample includes both developed and developing countries

as well.

Starting from a pioneering study (OECD 1999) and providing recent updates (Blöchliger and

Nettley, 2015), with these data is possible to measure the different levels of sub-national taxing

power and suggest a categorization of sub-national taxes into five different types from more

“autonomous” taxes to “effectively federal (central) taxes or intergovernmental grants”.

However, even with this classification, the inconsistency in the definition of sub-national taxes

would be still problematic because a significant amount of sub-national revenue comes from tax

sharing arrangement in many OECD member countries.

The GFS data from the IMF contains annual time series of sub-national government fiscal

data for 1990 to the present; data in this series before 2000 are reclassified on an accrual basis.

Even though the GFS framework provides a good level of data standardization across countries,

the standardized available data are much less detailed for the purpose of constructing

comprehensive decentralization indicators.

Given the lack of information on effective fiscal autonomy and the incompleteness of the

data, a number of authors have made considerable efforts over the years to put together and make

available data sets to improve on the information available from the traditional sources of

IMF/GFS and OECD. Among others, Ivanyna and Shah (2014) developed wide raging data sets

for a variety of decentralization dimensions including also political and administrative variables

but only cross-section or for few years. Others like Stegarescu (2005) and Baskaran and Feld

(2013) have concentrated in collecting time series data on actual tax autonomy building on the

information available for OCDE countries. Unfortunately, none of these data sets has been kept

updated. Some recent work along the lines of a single index of decentralization is noteworthy.

The Regional Authority Index (RAI) designed and computed by Hooghe et al. (2016) addresses

both the multifaceted nature of decentralization and the need to combine several complementary

indicators.5 Using a synthetic index may be especially helpful when there is a limitation in the

number of degrees of freedom in the empirical analyses; nevertheless, it still does have the

limitations of not capturing all the potential dimensions of decentralization and discretionally

assigning weights to each of its components.

Summing up, the richness and multidimensionality of decentralization pose a very significant

challenge to the empirical work. Presently there continues to be a dearth of comparable data

beyond the two institutional sources of OECD and GFS, which in themselves are rather

problematic. Clearly, there is strong need for further work in this area.

5 The RAI is a global index of self-rule, which is based on the addition of partial indices measuring the different

dimensions of decentralization (e.g., the extent to which a regional government is autonomous rather than

deconcentrated; the extent to which a region is endowed with an independent legislature and executive; etc.).

Page 8: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

7

3.2 Endogeneity issue: Empirical strategy and instruments

The second issue to deal with is endogeneity. This means that there is a need to evaluate whether

decentralization is also caused by economic processes we are trying to evaluate, such as

economic growth. Endogeneity problems could arise due to the simultaneous effects of omitted

variables on both decentralization and some of the seemingly exogenous variables.

As an example, while fiscal decentralization may affect either economic growth,

governments could resort to decentralization reforms in an effort to increase their rate of growth,

or fiscal discipline or other processes. Similar cases of reverse causality issue may happen in

studying the relationship between decentralization and regional economic disparities (see,

recently, Kyriacou et al., 2015).

Earlier studies barely acknowledged the endogeneity issues, while later studies offered

possible, but often inadequate solutions. For example, some studies have used initial values of

the independent variables to reduce the endogeneity issue (Akai and Sakata, 2002), while other

studies proposed using lagged independent variables as instrumental variables (IVs) (Iimi, 2005;

Gemmell et al.. 2013). Using an IV approach is probably the most appropriate way to address

endogeneity. The challenge has been the scarcity of appropriate time-variant exogenous

instruments.6

Researchers have used a variety of IVs, including land area (Enikolopov and Zhuravskaya,

2007), country’s legal origin (Fisman and Gatti, 2002), or fiscal autonomy (Baskaran and Feld,

2013). However, in some cases it is far from obvious what is the correlation between those

instruments and fiscal decentralization; while, in other cases, it is not clear the exogeneity of the

instruments. Several recent studies have looked at geography as a possible exogenous identifier

of fiscal decentralization. Canavire-Bacarreza and Martinez-Vazquez (2012) explore the

empirical relevance of geography (elevation, land area, climate, and so on) as a determinant of

fiscal decentralization, and as geography is truly exogenous, its validity as an instrument for

decentralization cannot be questioned.7

However, an important problem with geography is that is time invariant and therefore not

helpful in panel estimation contexts; and creating and interactions with other variables such as

the development of infrastructure would bring us back to the endogeneity issue. Last but not

least, geographical area could be endogenous in the long run (Alesina and Spolaore, 2003).

Given the difficulty of finding suitable external instruments for fiscal decentralization, many

researchers have turned to utilizing estimation approaches that have the potential to mitigate if

not fully address the endogeneity issue. The most relevant has been the system-GMM estimator,

developed by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998). Examples of papers in

the fiscal decentralization literature using this approach include Strumpf and Oberholzer-Gee

(2002), Kyriacou et al. (2015), Filippetti and Sacchi, (2016). The virtue of the system-GMM

estimator in panel analysis is that it preserves the information which comes from the cross-

country dimension of the data as it can control for country specific effects, whereas such

information is normally lost when employing first difference GMM. On the other hand, other

6 A good instrument needs to be highly correlated with our variable of interest – fiscal decentralization –but

uncorrelated with the error term of the main equation. Of course, one can never be sure about the effectiveness of

IVs. Several statistical tests are available for checking for the presence of weak instruments. Ideally, one should

look for natural experiments or randomized experiments that could be used as instrumental variables. 7 Panizza (1999) and Arzaghi and Henderson (2005) find that the size of the country is an important determinant of

fiscal decentralization.

Page 9: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

8

researchers are skeptical about the ability of system-GMM to adequately address the problem of

endogeneity. The concern is that in using lagged values of fiscal decentralization as IVs, fiscal

decentralization may be stable over time and have a persistent impact on the dependent variable,

resulting in the correlation between the instrument and the error term, and therefore not meeting

the exclusion restriction.

Summing up, despite all the efforts so far in the literature, the issue of endogeneity in the

measurement of decentralization remains a critical obstacle to the wholesale validity of a

significant part of the burgeoning empirical literature reviewed next.

4. ECONOMIC AND FISCAL CONSEQUENCES OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION

The last two decades have witnessed a bourgeoning of the literature examining the impact of

fiscal decentralization on a wider array of fiscal and economic issues. In this section, we focus on

a selected number of economic areas based on both their importance and the attention that has

attracted.

4.1 The impact on service delivery, infrastructure, and expenditure composition

Oates’s (1972) theorem predicts a greater efficiency of decentralized service delivery in terms of

allocative efficiency. A second concept of efficiency with decentralization is that of production

efficiency; that is, delivering a particular bundle of public services at a minimum cost, then

translating into an increased quality and quantity of the services. Since education and health are

among the most important types of decentralized services (OECD, 2013), a lot of the empirical

literature has focused on those two areas.

The empirical studies on the effectiveness of decentralization process on education outcomes

vary in terms of their scope and focus. Most of them are just indirect tests of allocative

efficiency, and examine the overall impact of the reforms on expenditures and outcomes, such as

enrollment rates and students’ performance. Many researchers find decentralization affects

education outcomes positively (Faguet in Bolivia, 2004; Simatupang in Indonesia, 2009; Faguet

and Sánchez in Colombia, 2014; Barankay and Lockwood in Switzerland, 2007). In turn, cross-

country studies also tend to confirm the positive outcomes of decentralization on education (e.g.,

Falch and Fischer 2012 for OECD countries). More recently, OECD (2013) shows that, while

educational policies and functions can be delegated either to sub-central governments or to

schools, both strategies are equally beneficial for achieving high-quality primary and secondary

education.

The findings for health services confirm that decentralization has similar virtuous effects.

Positive results are found in Argentina by Habibi et al (2003), in Canada and OECD countries by

Jiménez-Rubio (2011a,b), in Italy by Porcelli (2014), and in Spain by Cantarero and Lago-Peñas

(2012). However, results are, overall, weaker than those for education and, in some cases, the

impact of decentralization is actually negative. This may be due to decentralized governments

giving lower priority to healthcare services with respect to education services. Such variability in

the empirical results is also described in Table 1, where we provide a selection of papers on this

topic.

[Insert Table 1]

Page 10: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

9

There is more consensus in the literature in terms of the effects of decentralization on

expenditure composition. The more common finding is that decentralization leads to relatively

higher spending on social sectors, such as education and health, with respect to other functions

(Faguet, 2004, 2008; Arze et al. 2016), but there are some exceptions, such as case studies by

Schwartz et al. (2002) for the Philippines, and Ferrario and Zanardi (2011) for Italy.

Regarding other public services, the evidence on the impact of decentralization is also mixed

but leaning fairly strongly to the positive side. For Korea, Wade (1998) finds increases in

efficiency in decentralized irrigation systems as opposed to relatively inefficient centralized

systems in India. Escaleras and Register (2012) test whether relatively more decentralized

countries fare better when natural disasters strike.

In the case of infrastructure there has been a great decentralization push worldwide (Frank

and Martinez-Vazquez 2015). The share of sub-national governments in total capital

expenditures of a country is typically twice their share in total recurrent expenditures. However,

some countries execute up to 90 percent of their public investment through sub-national level

governments, while others not nearly 10 percent. The overarching trend that shapes the

development of infrastructure gaps is urbanization. All in all, fiscal decentralization imposes

significant intergovernmental coordination challenges regarding planning, regulation, spending,

financing, and especially maintenance. In addition, in most countries there are large up-and-

down-swings and volatility in the level of decentralized investment spending over the business

cycle. There is a limited empirical literature on the effect of decentralization on infrastructure

spending, and its composition and quality. The expectations often are that decentralization may

lead to higher production efficiency because of cost savings - cheaper local building materials

and local labor, more efficient project design and less bureaucracy (e.g., Peterson and Muzzini

2005). Empirically, the World Bank report (1994) provides support for numerous cases where

delivered infrastructure in decentralized settings is of better quality and completed at lower costs

than in centralized ones. In terms of quantity, Estache and Sinha (1995) for OECD and

developing countries and Kappeler and Välilä (2008) for European countries find that

decentralization tends to increase both total and sub-national spending on public infrastructure.

However, more recently, Viñuela (2015), using an extended sample of developed and developing

countries, finds that fiscal decentralization is associated with better quality although lower

amounts of fixed capital formation.

Instead of measuring changes in the amount and outcomes of public services, an alternative

way is to ask citizens and taxpayers directly how they feel about decentralized services delivery.

A growing number of household surveys typically have shown increased citizen satisfaction with

decentralized delivery of public services (e.g., Hellman et al., 2003 for Indonesia; Diaz-Serrano

and Rodríguez-Pose, 2015 for European countries). Similarly, other studies find that

decentralization is associated with improved citizens’ feelings of trust in government-related

institutions (Ligthart and van Oudheusden 2015 for OECD countries). Finally, some recent

contributions have focused on the implications of decentralization for happiness. Bjørnskov et al.

(2008) find that local autonomy may not be associated with greater levels of individuals’

happiness and may be detrimental in some cases.

Summing up, direct tests on the allocative and production efficiency of fiscal decentralization

have remained elusive in the literature and much work remains to be done. The indirect evidence

is that decentralization favors more spending on the social sectors and improved outcomes in

education and perhaps in public health. The evidence on other functional sectors is still too

Page 11: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

10

limited, but moderately optimistic in outcomes. In the case of infrastructure, the lion share of that

type of spending is now decentralized worldwide, and although its quality may have improved, it

is unclear that decentralization has led to more infrastructure spending. The analysis of survey

data tend to confirm that citizens perceived public services to have improved when they are

decentralized. Finally, the literature in this area has only partially addressed the endogeneity and

measurement issues discussed in Section 3. As shown in Table 1, the recurrent strategy to deal

with endogeneity between fiscal decentralization and different dependent variables is IV

estimations, where lag values of the former are used given the difficulty of finding time-variant

suitable external instruments.

4.2 The impact on economic growth

The proposition that fiscal decentralization enhances economic efficiency may have a

corresponding effect on the dynamic setting of economic growth (Oates 1993). Theoretically,

more fiscal autonomy may be associated with higher output per unit of labor and higher growth

rates (Brueckner, 2006). However, a causation path is not clear-cut, and decentralization may

affect growth indirectly through its impact on other socio-economic variables, such as macro

stability and government quality (Martinez-Vazquez and McNab, 2003), or through its

interaction with the institutional framework (Feld and Schnellenbach, 2011).

There is hardly any other topic on the impact of decentralization that has received more

attention in the empirical literature. However, the findings remain mixed as reported in the Table

2.

[Insert Table 2]

On the negative side, Xie et al. (1999), Zhang and Zou (1998), Ezcurra and Rodriguez-Pose

(2011) find fiscal decentralization to reduce GDP growth (for both a single case study such as

China and cross-country analyses on OECD sample). In addition, Thornton (2007) finds no

impact for revenue decentralization, but Baskaran and Feld (2013) show those results were not

robust.

Quite a few papers find positive effects on growth (Feld et al. 2004 for Switzerland, Qiao et

al. 2008 for China, Akai and Sakata 2002 for the U.S., Gemmell et al. 2013 for OECD

countries), whereas Thiessen (2003) shows that the relationship is positive when fiscal

decentralization is increasing from low levels, but then reaches a peak and turns negative.

There may be different reasons to explain the diverse results. For example jurisdiction

heterogeneity may be too hard to capture (Salmon 2013), or the institutional set up is too

complex and partially unobserved (Voigt and Blume, 2012) or simply because political and

administrative dimension are not properly considered (Filippetti and Sacchi 2016). Still another

possibility may be related to how some forms of decentralization (sub-national government

policies) affect economic efficiency by distorting resource allocation away from efficient uses.

Here, the evidence is very limited. For example, Day and Winer (2006) study the effect of

provincial unemployment schemes on labor mobility in Canada, and Abdullatif et al. (2013) find,

for a large panel of countries, that decentralization is generally associated with higher costs of

doing business. However, for the U.S. Sobel et al. (2013) find that decentralization at state-level

leads to better a business climates and faster growth.

Page 12: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

11

Beyond the reasons covered above, perhaps it should be no surprising that studies using

different data, estimation techniques and specifications and different definitions of

decentralization as well produce diverging results. Clearly, the results are not robust. The issue

of endogeneity is likely very prominent from growth (lack thereof) to decentralization and often

it has been ignored in this research. And when acknowledged, it has been handled basically with

the lack of good external instruments as reported in Table 2, putting into question the findings in

this area.

4.3 The impact on macroeconomic stability and fiscal sustainability

There are good reasons to expect that decentralization could challenge a country’s fiscal

sustainability, as illustrated by the experiences of Argentina and Brazil with hyperinflation

several decades back. Decentralized frameworks are more sensitive to the problem of soft budget

constraints, borrowing rules may not be effective enough, and central authorities may not be able

to commit to no bailout policies (Martinez-Vazquez and Vulovic, 2016; Goodspeed,

forthcoming).

On the other hand, decentralization itself could encourage governments’ fiscal discipline.

Providing all levels of government with sufficient tax autonomy would encourage fiscal

responsibility, while vertical and horizontal virtuous fiscal competition would shrink the

monopolistic power of the Leviathan (Brennan and Buchanan, 1980).

Beyond the theoretical expectations, the empirical evidence on the relationship between

decentralization and fiscal stability offers mixed results. Two strands of the literature can be

identified depending on the type of dependent variable analyzed: fiscal discipline versus the

inflation targeting, where the former is normally more addressed being more in the governments’

hands. Several studies find that tax autonomy and borrowing rules can lead to improved fiscal

discipline, including Rodden (2002), Neyapti (2010), Eyraud and Lusinyan (2014), and

Presbitero et al. (2014), all using cross country panel data. However, the effectiveness of tax

autonomy as a disciplining factor is questioned in several other studies, also using panel data, as

producing negative results (de Mello 2000) or being insignificant (Thornton, 2009). In Table 3

we summarize this variability.

[Insert Table 3]

As for fiscal decentralization and inflation issue, some studies find no effect (Treisman, 2000;

Rodden et al., 2003), while others find that sub-national tax autonomy leads to lower inflation

(Martinez-Vazquez and McNab, 2003; Baskaran, 2012).

Overall, far from being destabilizing, fiscal decentralization - especially on the revenue side -

could improve fiscal discipline and macroeconomic stability. However, untreated endogeneity

may weaken the results. Indeed, sources of possible endogeneity in the data could arise not only

between fiscal decentralization and fiscal discipline but also for other variables used in the

estimation (e.g., unemployment). As shown in Table 3 very few papers in this literature have

even attempted to address this issue. The challenge remains to find valid instruments beyond

using lag values.

Page 13: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

12

4.4 The impact on income inequality and poverty

Fiscal decentralization can directly affect poverty and income distribution by facilitating access

to basic services, but also indirectly in many ways (by means of growth, expenditure

composition, the quality of governance). Ultimately, those impacts will depend on the specific

characteristics of each decentralization process. The relevance of the question lies in the fact that

international organizations and many national governments have advised or embarked

simultaneously on income inequality and poverty reduction as well as fiscal decentralization

reforms (Ravallion, 1999; Rao, 2002; Galasso and Ravaillon, 2005). The big question is whether

these reforms are complementary or, perhaps, undermine each other.

Although closely related, income inequality and poverty do not need to move in the same

direction in response to fiscal decentralization. This will depend on how changes in the

distribution will affect the poorest. The empirical literature mostly looks at the two issues

separately. First, a good number of studies find a beneficial effect of decentralization on the Gini

coefficient (Von Braun and Grote, 2002; Lindaman and Thurmaier, 2002; Tselios et al., 2012). A

similar result is found in Sepúlveda and Martinez-Vazquez (2011), but only when government

size is at least 20 percent of GDP. In these cases, decentralization measures are mostly

expenditure-based. Nevertheless, other studies find that higher tax decentralization leads to

higher income inequality (Sacchi and Salotti, 2014; Neyapti, 2006), as highlighted in Table 4.

This is intuitive if sub-national taxes are less progressive than those at the central level.

[Insert Table 4]

On the direct impact of decentralization on poverty, the empirical evidence is so far even

more highly mixed. Some earlier studies by Crook and Manor (1998) find positive impacts of

political and administrative decentralization on poverty reduction in developing countries.

Positive outcomes also emerge in country case studies (Galasso and Ravallion 2005 for

Bangladesh’s food-for-education program; Bardhan and Mookherjee 2003 for India). However,

other studies find that decentralization can negatively affect poverty levels (Sepúlveda and

Martinez-Vazquez 2011 using panel data, West and Wong 1995 for China).

This is an area where more research clearly needs to be performed. Normative public finance

traditionally has reserved redistribution goals to the central government and, actually, many

programs affecting income distribution and the poor have been increasingly devolved to sub-

national governments. If the negative effects on poverty were confirmed, that should stop the

championing of decentralization by institutions concerned with poverty reduction. As shown in

Table 4, the empirical studies so far are too dispersed in the data used, estimation approaches and

in addressing endogeneity.

4.5 The impact on geographical and interregional disparities

Fiscal decentralization may also affect regional economic convergence and increase or dampen

disparities in public services availability (e.g., Gil Canaleta et al., 2004; Rodríguez-Pose and

Ezcurra, 2010). The net effect is far from evident from a theoretical standpoint.

On the one hand, decentralization may lead to increased regional disparities because it

strengthens the differences in institutional capacities and socio-economic endowments across

regions, as in the case of China (Zhang 2006). In addition, decentralization may lead to a

Page 14: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

13

reduction of the influence of poorer areas over the allocation of financial resources (Besley and

Ghatak, 2003). On the other hand, decentralization may contribute to reducing interregional

disparities because of higher transparency and by bringing more efficiency and equalization

across jurisdictions (Martinez-Vazquez and Timofeev 2008; Béland and Lecours 2010; Liu et al.,

2016).

Most studies show that decentralization is associated with a general reduction in territorial

disparities (Shankar and Shah, 2003; Rodríguez-Pose and Gill, 2005).Positive results also

emerge in single case studies (Bonet 2006 for Colombia, Hill 2008 for Indonesia; Qiao et al.

2008 for China). However, these positive effects may be dependent on the level of economic

development (Lessman 2012) or on the quality of governance (Kyriacou et al. 2015).

Although with some qualifications, this is an area where the evidence is quite robust.

Decentralization contributes to regional convergence and more equal access to services. This

strong result does not mean, however, that this research has solved the major problems, including

that of endogeneity, as summarized in Table 5.

[Insert Table 5]

5. POLITICAL AND POLICY CONSEQUENCES OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION

Over the last several decades, there has also been developing interest in the impact of fiscal

decentralization processes on political institutions and public policies. We focus on a selected

number of areas based on their importance and the attention received in the literature.

5.1 The impact on government size and public policies

Beyond the restraining effects that decentralization may have on government size according to

the Leviathan hypothesis, such impact may also depend on the nature of decentralization and on

how the public sector size is measured. For example, when size is measured by the level of

public employment, there is robust evidence that increases in sub-national employment following

decentralization often overwhelms the corresponding decreases at the central level (Martinez-

Vazquez and Yao 2009 for a panel of countries; Marqués and Rosselló 2004 for Spain;

Rajaraman and Saha 2008 for India). This may represent some inefficiency or, alternatively,

simply a response to the expansion of labor-intensive public services.

As for the nature of decentralization, there is evidence that higher revenue decentralization

leads to smaller size of the whole public sector (Jin and Zou, 2002). This may be due to

increased fiscal responsibility throughout but also to increased tax competition. The burgeoning

literature on this topic dates back to the pioneering work by Zodrow and Mieszkowski (1986)

and Wilson (1986). The most significant implication is that sub-national governments’

competition for mobile tax bases leads to lower tax rates through a process that has been dubbed

“a race to the bottom”. As a result government expenditures are inefficiently low. Subsequent

works have extended and refined this hypothesis in numerous directions. For example, smaller

jurisdictions may be more exposed to this sort of competition because of higher base mobility

(Bucovetsky and Haufler, 2007), that it may differ by the type of taxes (Liberati and Sacchi,

2013). Moreover, the outcomes may be not so pronounced if policy moves are initiated by

Stackelberg-leaders as opposed to non-cooperative players (Kempf and Rota-Graziosi 2010).

Page 15: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

14

The empirical research on tax competition typically identifies the existence of strategic

interactions by sub-national governments using spatial econometric models (Devereux et al.,

2007), and although the findings are mixed, there is no strong support for “a race to the bottom”.

On the contrary, just higher expenditure decentralization would seem to lead to larger

government size, perhaps for the opposite reasons. Sub-national transfer dependence would lead

to laxer fiscal responsibility (Jin and Zou 2002; Moesen and van Cauwenberge, 2000; Rodden,

2003), and it may be also explained by a different type of competition. Selected papers within

this literature are summarized in Table 6. When sub-national interjurisdictional competition takes

place using public infrastructure and other of private productivity-enhancing policies, the result

can be excessive public spending and larger government size (Bucovetsky, 2005; Egger and

Falkinger, 2006).

[Insert Table 6]

Other forms of jurisdictional competition can affect the level of expenditures. An interesting

case is that of what could be called (negative) welfare competition. To avoid being a magnet for

welfare seeking migrants, jurisdictions may set their welfare benefits to be less attractive vis-à-

vis those of their neighbors’. The evidence here is somewhat mixed. Earlier studies for the

United States did not find significant evidence of welfare-seeking migration (Levine and

Zimmerman, 1999). More recent evidence for the United States (Figlio et al., 1999; Saavedra,

2000) and for Norway (Fiva and Rattso, 2006) find that a jurisdictions’ responses to their

neighbor’s decrease in welfare benefits are significantly larger in magnitude than its response to

its neighbor’s increase in welfare benefits.

Summing up, decentralization is likely to lead to increases in public payroll, but this does not

have to mean a less efficient public sector. Decentralization can also affect government size

though a complex net of interjurisdictional competition modalities, which although not

insignificant, they appear to be small in size and working in opposite directions. As highlighted

in Table 6, the econometric issues are less constraining, especially in the case of tax and public

input competition literature.

5.2 The impact on governance, accountability, and corruption

Most countries that are fiscally decentralized are also politically decentralized; but with some

important exceptions like China. Thus, it is expected that governance and decentralization

support each other in a bidirectional causal relationship (Martinez-Vazquez and McNab, 2006).

One noticeable way in which decentralization can improve governance is by its impact on

enhancing accountability (Blair, 2000; Manor, 1999) and institutional quality (Kyriacou and

Roca-Sagalés, 2011). Greater accountability at the sub-national level can accrue in different

ways. One of these, and which has received much attention in the literature, is yardstick

competition (Besley and Case, 1995). Imperfectly informed voters may use information on

government performance in nearby jurisdictions as a yardstick or benchmark to evaluate their

own incumbent’s performance. In turn, there is solid empirical evidence that neighboring

jurisdictions do tend to mimic each other in taxes and other policies (Heyndels and Vuchelen,

1998; Revelli 2002; Solé-Ollé, 2003; Allers and Elhorst, 2005). And also that voters use the

information from neighboring jurisdictions to decide whether or not to re-elect the incumbent

politicians (Revelli, 2003; Bordignon et al., 2003; Bosch and Solé-Ollé, 2007).

Page 16: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

15

The strongest way to build accountability at the sub-national level is holding periodic

elections for office. However, electoral accountability of government officials may be

undermined when individuals do not know whom to assign blame or praise for policy outcomes:

In this sense, decentralized countries are more exigent for voters (Lago and Lago-Peñas, 2010a).

Hence, the most visible manifestation of good governance would be the absence of public

corruption. Much attention has been devoted in the literature to whether decentralization leads to

more corruption as also documented in Table 7. From a theoretical perspective, decentralization

may help reduce corruption because of enhanced accountability and competition among local

governments, the existence of additional “exit” and “voice” mechanisms, and higher levels of

information and transparency at the sub-national level (Weingast, 1995; Seabright, 1996). On the

negative side, fiscal decentralization may weaken monitoring, controls, and audits by central

agencies, thereby creating opportunities for corruption (Prud’homme, 1995). In addition,

political decentralization may favor higher incidence of corruption through involvement of a

larger number of officials in dealing with potential investors, because of higher incidence of

clientelism and because of interest group capture where elites dominate the local political scene

(Shleifer and Vishny, 1993; Litvack et al., 1998; Bardhan and Mookherjee, 2000). Empirically, a

good number of papers find that decentralization actually reduces the level of corruption (Fisman

and Gatti, 2002; Arikan, 2004; Ivanyna and Shah, 2011; Altunbas and Thornton, 2012). When

we shift the focus from corruption to the shadow economy, the empirical results also tend to

confirm the virtue of decentralization processes (Buehn et al., 2013; Dell’Anno and Teobaldelli,

2015).

[Insert Table 7]

Nevertheless, there is also some empirical evidence on decentralization and higher corruption.

In particular, countries with more tiers of sub-national governments are more corrupt (Fan et al.,

2009) as are countries with more intense fragmentation into small local governments (Nelson,

2013). In both cases, the opportunities for corruption are increased.

In short, there is a mutually reinforcing relationship between fiscal decentralization and

democratic governance. And governance is improved through increased accountability via

elections and yardstick competition. Beyond the theoretical positive and negative arguments,

decentralization is commonly believed to foster public sector corruption. The big surprise is the

solid empirical evidence proving that decentralization is robustly associated with both lower

corruption and shadow economy. However, the measurement of corruption mostly based on

perception surveys, as shown in Table 7, clearly needs to be improved. On the other hand, this

literature is less exposed to the problem of endogeneity.

5.3 The impact on social capital and tax morale

Does decentralization play a role on how individuals interact in society and view government?

Two fields of literature have developed looking at the impact on social capital and trust in

government including tax morale. While the seminal contribution by Putnam (1993) finds no

clear evidence for or against the impact of decentralization on social capital, Hooghe and Marks

(2003) show that decentralization may encourage more collective action, interaction, and,

ultimately, social capital. These results are confirmed by de Mello (2004) for a wide sample of

market economies.

Page 17: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

16

With respect to trust in government, Ligthart and van Oudheusden (2015) find that

decentralization increases trust in government and also in other political institutions such as

political parties and parliaments. In turn, the empirical evidence on tax morale provided by Güth

et al. (2005) reflects that people’s propensity to pay taxes is higher in a decentralized system,

wherein taxes collected in one region are spent exclusively on that region’s public goods, than in

a centralized setting, wherein taxes paid in all regions are pooled and spent on regional public

goods on a per capita basis. However, if fiscal equalization is strong enough, this mechanism

may be cancelled out. Residents in net fiscal contributor regions may tempted to think that the

federal fiscal menu is disadvantageous, with this opinion boosted by sub-national political

seeking changes in fiscal arrangements. Cheating on national taxes may be then socially justified

as a way of de facto increasing the fairness of the system in rich regions (Lago and Lago-Peñas

2010b).

Summing up, decentralization would appear to have virtuous effects on social capital and trust

in government, including tax morale as pointed out in Table 8. However, tax morale may be

reduced if there is a perception in some regions that decentralization carries out too much

interjurisdictional redistribution. All in all, this is a newer and much less explored area of

research which certainly would benefit from further study, where the econometric issues,

including endogeneity, are generally more straightforward.

[Insert Table 8]

5.4 The impact on voter turnout, party system nationalization, and national unity

Finally, we analyze the potential impact of decentralization on three important political

outcomes: voter turnout, strength of national parties, and national unity. Main results are

summarized in Table 9.

[Insert Table 9]

Concerning turnout, intuitively, people would seem more prone to vote when the legislature

and government to be elected have more power, resources and/or authority. This is what the

second-order elections model states (Reif and Schmitt, 1984). Hence granting more power to

sub-national governments should contribute to increased turnout in sub-national elections and to

lower participation in national elections. However, the empirical evidence reported by Blais et al.

(2011) does not show any significant effects of different indicators of decentralization on turnout

in national elections for a large sample of countries; the exception is in Canada and Spain with

slightly greater turnout in regional elections.8 Likewise, Schakel (2013) finds that regional

authority does not affect national vote shares in advanced economies.

Does decentralization reduce the spatial homogeneity of party systems? According to the

rational choice institutionalist approach (Chhibber and Kollman, 2004) as national governments

decentralize power, party system nationalization should decrease—the latter defined as the extent

to which parties compete with similar strength across sub-national geographic units (Kasuya and

Moenius, 2008). However, in a cross-country study of Western European countries, Lago and

8 Both countries subject to centrifugal regional forces in recent times.

Page 18: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

17

Lago-Peñas (2011) do not find robust relationships between the degree of decentralization and

party system nationalization. On the other hand, Harbers (2009) show that political and fiscal

decentralization hinder the development of nationalized party systems in Latin American

democracies.

Finally, there is a potential role played by decentralization as solutions to secessionist

pressures and to avoiding the breakup of nations (Alesina and Spolaore, 2003). The available

empirical evidence is scarce and it does not provide strong support for the conjecture. Sorens

(2008) finds that “regionalism” may be an alternative to secessionism by providing a political

protagonist role to regionalist and secessionist parties. However, Kymlicka (1998), focusing on

specific cases as Catalonia and Québec, concludes that federalism may not provide a viable

alternative to secession in multination states. Furthermore, asymmetrical decentralization

arrangements favoring secessionist regions can also boost perceptions of discrimination in other

regions and, eventually, lead to more conflict (Bird and Ebel, 2006).

In a nutshell, decentralization does not appear to much affect voter turnout or weaken party

system nationalization. In addition, the empirical literature does not provide strong support on

whether decentralization works as glue or solvent of countries’ unity. This field is still at an early

stage and would benefit from further research. However, the endogeneity issue may be more

stringent higher here, even though many of the studies so far have ignored it, as shown in Table

9.

6. CONCLUSIONS AND EXTENSIONS

Our survey on the impact of fiscal decentralization by necessity had to be selective but it tries to

provide a balanced view of what is known and what will be useful in advancing empirical

research and practice of fiscal decentralization.

Future developments should aim at improving upon institutional and methodological

dimensions of the topic. Concerning institutional advances, it would be important to improve the

standardization and overall quality of decentralization data. Something that international

organizations like the OECD and the World Bank have talked about doing in the past. Countries’

efforts to guarantee information availability according to international standards are a previous

key step in this respect, because the decentralization of powers itself challenges data

homogeneity and comparability. Besides, strengthening research networks could help with

harmonizing methodologies and data sources and, finally, with the quality and robustness of

results.

At a methodological level, a crucial issue is the use of more sophisticated econometric tools,

say based on a better instrumental variables approach to deal with potential endogeneity.

Replication studies should also play a more relevant role in the future as some of the diverging

findings are likely to be the result of inadequate estimation methods. Finally, meta-analysis on

existing research is possible in some areas where both the number of papers and methodological

convergence are significant (see Baskaran et al. 2016 for a fresh contribution on decentralization

and economic growth).

In comparative terms, research on the political consequences of decentralization is less

abundant than that relating to the economic consequences. In particular, we need to know more

about the influence of decentralization on the behavior of individuals as taxpayers and voters,

how decentralization affects the functioning of party systems, and the net effect of

Page 19: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

18

decentralization on accountability and electoral control. In contrast, there are already numerous

contributions on the effects of decentralization on key economic variables such as GDP growth,

income inequality and poverty, and fiscal stability. In this case, the recipe for future research

combines the need for replication studies that address particularly the problem of endogeneity

with meta-analysis. Finally, additional cross-country studies on the impact of decentralization on

spending efficiency and service delivery should complement the single case studies prevailing in

the area.

Definite answers to all the questions regarding the effects of fiscal decentralization are not

likely to become available, even after the additional research that is still required in many areas

is completed. But, overall, there are reasons to be optimistic about a net positive impact of

decentralized systems having been introduced all over the world in the past several decades,

especially when those decentralization processes have been well-designed and implemented. At

the end, there is still much work to be done on how to improve the design and implementation of

fiscal decentralization reforms precisely based on the information and knowledge of the

academic literature, part of which has been reviewed in this paper.

Page 20: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

19

REFERENCES

Abdullatif, L., Martinez-Vazquez, J. and Musharraf C. (2013) Is fiscal decentralization harmful

to business climate? International Center for Public Policy, Georgia State University.

Akai, N. and Sakata, M. (2002) Fiscal decentralization contributes to economic growth:

Evidence from state-level cross-section data for the Unites States, Journal of Urban

Economics, 52(1): 93-108.

Alesina, A. and Spolaore, E. (2003) The Size of Nations. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.

Allers, M.A., and Elhorst, J. P. (2005). Tax mimicking and yardstick competition among local

governments in the Netherlands. International Tax and Public Finance 12(4): 493-513.

Altunbas, Y. and Thornton, J. (2012) Fiscal decentralization and governance. Public Finance

Review 40(1): 66-85.

Arellano, M. and Bover, O. (1995) Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-

components models. Journal of Econometrics 68: 29–51.

Arikan, G. (2004) Fiscal decentralization: A remedy for corruption? International Tax and

Public Finance 11 (2): 175-195.

Arzaghi, M., Henderson, V. (2005) Why countries are fiscally decentralizing. Journal of Public

Economics 89: 1157–1189.

Arze del Granado, F. Martínez-Vázquez, J. and McNab, R. (2016). Decentralized governance,

expenditure composition and preferences for public goods. Public Finance Review

(forthcoming).

Barankay, I. and Lockwood, B. (2007) Decentralization and the productive efficiency of

government: Evidence from Swiss cantons. Journal of Public Economics 91 (5–6): 1197-

1218.

Bardhan, P. and Mookherjee, D. (2000) Capture and governance at local and national levels.

American Economic Review 90 (2): 135-139.

Bardhan, P. and Mookherjee, D. (2003) Decentralisation and accountability in infrastructure

delivery in developing countries. Economic Journal 116: 101-127.

Baskaran, T. (2012) Revenue decentralization and inflation: A re-evaluation. Economic Letters

116(3): 298-300.

Baskaran, T. and Feld, L.P. (2013) Fiscal decentralization and economic growth in OECD

countries: Is there a relationship? Public Finance Review 41(4): 421-445.

Baskaran, T., Feld, L. P., and Schnellenbach, J. (2016). Fiscal Federalism, Decentralization, and

Economic Growth: A Meta‐Analysis. Economic Inquiry 54(3): 1445–1463. Béland, D. and Lecours, A. (2010) Does nationalism trigger welfare-state disintegration? Social

policy and territorial mobilization in Belgium and Canada. Environment and Planning C:

Government and Policy 28 (3): 420–434.

Besley, T., and Case, A. (1995). Incumbent behavior: Vote-seeking, Tax-setting, and yardstick

competition. American Economic Review 85(1): 25-45.

Besley, T., and Coate, S. (2003), Centralized versus decentralized provision of local public

goods: a political economy approach, Journal of Public Economics 87: 2611-2637.

Besley, T. and Ghatak, M. (2003) Incentives, choice, and accountability in the provision of

public services. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 19 (2): 235-249.

Bird, R.M. and Ebel, R.D. (2006) Fiscal Fragmentation in Decentralized Countries:

Subsidiarity, Solidarity, and Assymetry. Chentelham: Edward Elgar.

Bjørnskov, C., Dreher, A. and Fischer, J.A.V. (2008) On decentralization and life satisfaction.

Page 21: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

20

Economics Letters 99 (1): 147-151.

Blair, H. (2000) Participation and accountability at the periphery: Democratic local governance

in six countries. World Development 28 (1): 21-39.

Blais, A, Anduiza, E. and Gallego, A. (2011) Decentralization and voter turnout. Environment

and Planning C: Government & Policy 29: 297-320.

Blöchliger, H. and Nettley, M. (2015). Sub-central Tax Autonomy: 2011 Update. OECD

Working Papers on Fiscal Federalism, No. 20, OECD Publishing, Paris.

Blundell, R. and Bond, S. (1998) initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel

data models. Journal of Econometrics 87: 115–143.

Bodman, P. (2011) Fiscal decentralization and economic growth in the OECD. Applied

Economics 43: 3021–3035.

Bonet, J. (2006). Fiscal decentralization and regional income disparities: Evidence from the

Colombian experience. The Annals of Regional Science 40 (3): 661-676.

Bordignon, M., Cerniglia, F. and Revelli, F. (2003). In search of yardstick competition: A spatial

analysis of Italian municipality property tax setting. Journal of Urban Economics 54(2): 199-

217.

Bosch, N., and Sole-Olle, A. (2007). Yardstick competition and the political costs of raising

taxes: An empirical analysis of Spanish municipalities. International Tax and Public Finance

14(1): 71-92.

Brennan, G. and Buchanan J.M. (1980) The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations of a Fiscal

Constitution. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Brueckner, J. (2006) Fiscal federalism and economic growth. Journal of Public Economics

90(10-11): 2107-2120.

Bucovetsky, S. (2005). Public input competition. Journal of Public Economics 89(9-10): 1763-

1787.

Bucovetsky, S., and A. Haufler. (2007). Preferential tax regimes with asymmetric countries.

National Tax Journal 60: 789-795.

Buehn, A. Lessman, C. and Markwardt, G. (2013) Decentralization and the shadow economy:

Oates meets Allingham-Sandmo. Applied Economics 45(18): 2567-2578.

Canavire-Bacarreza, G. and Martinez-Vazquez, J. (2012). Reexamining the determinants of

fiscal decentralization: what is the role of geography?. International Center for Public

Policy, Georgia State University Working Paper 1302.

Cantarero, D. and Lago-Peñas, S. (2012): Decomposing the determinants of health care

expenditure: The case of Spain. European Journal of Health Economics 13(1): 19-27.

Chhibber, P. and Kollman, K. (2004) The formation of national party systems: federalism and

party competition in Canada, Great Britain, India, and the United States. Princeton, NJ:

Princeton University Press.

Crook, R. and Manor, J. (1998) Democracy and Decentralization in South Asia and West Africa:

Participation, Accountability, and Performance. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University

Press.

Day, K. M., and Winer, S. (2006). Policy-induced internal migration: An empirical investigation

of the Canadian case. International Tax and Public Finance 13(5): 535-564.

de Mello, L.. (2000) Fiscal decentralization and intergovernmental fiscal relations: a cross-

country analysis. World Development 28 (2): 365-380.

de Mello, L. (2004) Can fiscal decentralization strengthen social capital?. Public Finance Review

32(1): 4-35.

Page 22: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

21

Dell’Anno R., and Teobaldelli, D. (2015). Keeping both corruption and the shadow economy in

check: the role of decentralization. International Tax and Public Finance 22(1): 1-40.

Devereux, M. P., B. Lockwood, and Redoano, M. (2007). Horizontal and vertical indirect tax

competition: Theory and some evidence from the USA. Journal of Public Economics 91 (3-

4): 451-479.

Diaz-Serrano, L. and Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2015). Decentralization and the welfare state: what do

citizens perceive?. Social Indicators Research 120 (2): 411-435.

Ebel, R. and Yilmaz, S. (2003) On the measurement and impact of fiscal decentralization. In

Public Finance in Developing and Transitional Countries, eds. Jorge Martinez-Vazquez, and

James Alm, Chentelham: Edward Elgar.

Egger, H., and Falkinger, J. (2006). The role of public infrastructure and subsidies for firm

location and international outsourcing. European Economic Review 50(8): 1993-2015.

Enikolopov, R. and Zhuravskaya, E. (2007). Decentralization and political institutions. Journal

of Public Economics 91, 2261–2290.

Escaleras, M. and Register, C.A. (2012) Fiscal decentralization and natural hazard risks. Public

Choice 151(1-2):165-183.

Estache, A. and Sinha, S. (1995). Does Decentralization Increase Spending on Infrastructure?

Policy Research Working Paper 1457, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Ezcurra, R. and Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2011) Is fiscal decentralization harmful for economic

growth? Evidence from the OECD countries. Journal of Economic Geography 11(4): 619-

643.

Eyraud, L. and Lusinyan, L. (2014) Vertical fiscal imbalances and fiscal performance in

advanced economies. Journal of Monetary Economics 60: 571-587.

Faguet, J.-P. (2004) Does decentralization increase government responsiveness to local needs?

Evidence from Bolivia. Journal of Public Economics 88 (3-4): 867-893.

Faguet, J.-P. (2008). Decentralisation’s effects on public investment: Evidence and policy

lessons from Bolivia and Colombia.” Journal of Development Studies 44 (8): 1100-1121.

Faguet, J.-P., and Sánchez, F. (2014). Decentralization and access to social services in Colombia.

Public Choice 160(1-2): 227-249.

Falch, T. and Fischer, J.A.V. (2012) Public sector decentralization and school performance:

International evidence. Economic Letters 114(3): 276-279.

Fan, C.S., Lin, C. and Treisman, D. (2009) Political decentralization and corruption: Evidence

from around the world. Journal of Public Economics 93(1-2):14-34.

Feld, L. P. and Schnellenbach, J. (2011) Fiscal federalism and long-run macroeconomic

performance: A survey of recent research. Environment and Planning C: Government and

Policy 29(2): 224-243.

Ferrario, C. and Zanardi, A. (2011): Fiscal decentralization in the Italian NHS: What happens to

interregional redistribution? Health Policy 100(1): 71-80.

Figlio, D. N., V.W. Kolpin., and Reid, W.E. (1999). Do States play welfare games? Journal of

Urban Economics 46(3): 437-454.

Filippetti, A. and Sacchi, A. (2016). Decentralization and economic growth reconsidered: The

role of regional authority. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy,

forthcoming, DOI: 10.1177/0263774X16642230.

Fisman, R. and Gatti, R. (2002) Decentralization and corruption: Evidence across countries.

Journal of Public Economics 83 (3): 325-345.

Fiva, J.H., and Rattso, J. (2006). Welfare Competition in Norway: Norms and Expenditures.

Page 23: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

22

European Journal of Political Economy 22(1): 202-222.

Frank, J. and Martinez-Vazquez, J. (2015). Decentralization and Infrastructure: From Gaps to

Solutions, Routledge.

Galasso, E. and Ravallion, M. (2005). Decentralized targeting of an anti-poverty program.

Journal of Public Economics 89(4): 705-727.

Garman, C. Haggard, S. and Willis, E. (2001). Fiscal decentralization: A political theory with

Latin American cases. World Politics 53 (2): 205-236.

Gemmell, N., Kneller, R. and Sanz, I. (2013). Fiscal decentralization and economic growth:

spending versus revenue decentralization. Economic Inquiry 51 (4): 1915–1931.

Gil Canaleta, C., Pascual Arzoz, P.and Rapùn Gàrate, M. (2004). Regional economic disparities

and decentralization. Urban Studies 41: 71–94.

Goodspeed, T. J. (forthcoming). Bailouts and soft budget constraints in decentralized

government: A synthesis and survey of an alternative view of intergovernmental grant policy.

Hacienda Pública Española/Review of Public Economics.

Güth, W., Levatti, V. and Sausgruber, R. (2005): Tax morale and (de)centralization: An

experimental study. Public Choice 125: 171-188.

Habibi, N., Huang, C., Miranda, D., Murillo, V., Ranis, G., Sarkar, M., and Stewart, F. (2003).

Decentralization and human development in Argentina. Journal of Human Development

4(1): 73-101.

Harbers, I. (2010). Decentralization and the development of nationalized party systems in new

democracies: evidence from Latin America. Comparative Political Studies 43(5): 606-627.

Hellman, J. B. Hofman, Kaise, K. and Schulze, G.G. (2003) Decentralization, Governance, and

Public Services: An Assessment of Indonesian Experience. The World Bank: Jakarta.

Heyndels, B. and Vuchelen, J. (1998). Tax mimicking among Belgian municipalities. National

Tax Journal 51(1): 89-101.

Hill, H. (2008). Globalization, inequality, and local-level dynamics: Indonesia and the

Philippines. Asian Economic Policy Review 3(1): 42-61.

Hooghe, L. and Marks, G. (2003) Unraveling the central state, but How? Types of multi-level

governance. American Political Science Review 97 (2): 233-243.

Hooghe L, Marks, G. and Schakel, A. H. (2010) The Rise of Regional Authority: A Comparative

Study of 43 Democracies, London: Routledge.

Hooghe, L., Marks, G., Schakel, A. H., Chapman, S., Niedzwiecki, S., and Shair-Rosenfield, S.

(2016). A Postfunctionalist Theory of Governance. Volume I: Measuring Regional

Authority. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Iimi, A. (2005). Decentralization and economic growth revisited: an empirical note.” Journal of

Urban Economics, 57(3), 449-461.

Ivanyna, M. and Shah, A. (2011) Decentralization and corruption: New cross-country evidence.

Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 29(2): 344-362.

Ivanyna, M. and Shah, A. (2014). How close is your government to its people? Worldwide

indicators on localization and decentralization. Economics - The Open-Access, Open-

Assessment E-Journal 8: 1-61.

Jiménez-Rubio, D. (2011a) The impact of decentralization of health services on health outcomes:

Evidence from Canada. Applied Economics 43(26): 3907-3917.

Jiménez-Rubio, D. (2011b) The impact of fiscal decentralization on infant mortality rates:

Evidence from OECD countries. Social Science & Medicine 73(9): 1401-1407.

Jin, J. and Zou, H. (2002). How does fiscal decentralization affect aggregate, national, and

Page 24: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

23

subnational government size? Journal of Urban Economics 52(2): 270-293.

Kappeler, A., and Välilä, T. (2008). Fiscal federalism and the composition of public investment

in Europe. European Journal of Political Economy 24(3): 562-570.

Kasuya, Y. and Moenius, J. (2008) The nationalization of party systems: Conceptual issues and

alternative district-focused measures. Electoral Studies 27(1): 126-135.

Kempf, H., and Rota-Graziosi, G. (2010). Endogenizing leadership in tax competition. Journal

of Public Economics 94 (9-10): 768-776.

Köthenbürger, M. (2004). Tax competition in a fiscal union with decentralized leadership.

Journal of Urban Economics 55(3): 498-513.

Kymlicka, W. (1998) Multinational federalism in Canada: Rethinking the partnership. In R.

Gibbins and G. Laforest, eds. Beyond the Impasse, Toward Reconciliation. Montreal:

Institute for Research on Public Policy.

Kyriacou, A.P. and Roca-Sagalés, O. (2011) Fiscal decentralization and government quality in

the OECD. Economics Letters 111(3): 191-193.

Kyriacou, A.P., Muinelo‐Gallo, L. and Roca‐Sagalés, O. (2015) Fiscal decentralization and

regional disparities: The importance of good governance. Papers in Regional Science, 94(1):

89-107.

Lago, I. and Lago-Peñas S. (2010a) Decentralization and electoral accountability. Environment

and Planning C: Government and Policy 28:318-334.

Lago, I. and Lago-Peñas, S. (2010b) The determinants of tax morale in comparative perspective:

Evidence from European countries. European Journal of Political Economy 26(4):441-453.

Lago, I., and Lago-Peñas, S. (2011) Decentralization and nationalization of party systems

Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 29: 244-363.

Lessman, C. (2012) Regional inequality and decentralization: An empirical analysis.

Environment and Planning A 44(6): 1363-1388.

Levine, P. B. and Zimmerman, D. J. (1999). An empirical analysis of the welfare magnet debate

using the NLSY. Journal of Population Economics 12(3): 391-409.

Liberati, P. and Sacchi, A. (2013) Tax decentralization and local government size. Public Choice

157 (1-2): 183-205.

Lindaman, K. and Thurmaier, K. (2002) Beyond efficiency and economy: An examination of

basic needs and fiscal decentralization. Economic Development and Cultural Change. 50(4):

915-934.

Ligthart, J.E. and van Oudheusden, P. (2015). In government we trust: The role of fiscal

decentralization. European Journal of Political Economy 37: 116-128.

Litvack, J., Ahmad, J. and Bird, R. (1998). Rethinking Decentralization in Developing Countries.

Washington, DC: World Bank.

Liu, Y., Martinez-Vazquez, J. and Timofeev A. (2012). Measuring the extent of fiscal

decentralization: An application to the United States in Measuring Decentralization, J. Lotz

and J. Kim (eds.), OECD Fiscal Federalism Studies: Paris.

Liu, Y., Martinez-Vazquez J. and Wu, A.M. (2016). Fiscal decentralization, equalization, and

intra-provincial inequality in China. International Tax and Public Finance 23(3): 1-34.

Lockwood, B., (2002) Distributive politics and the benefits of decentralization. Review of

Economic Studies 69(2): 313– 338.

Manor, J. (1999) The Political Economy of Democratic Decentralization. Washington, DC:

World Bank.

Marqués, J. and Rosselló, J. (2004) Public employment and regional redistribution in Spain.

Hacienda Pública Española/ Review of Public economics 170 (3): 59-80.

Page 25: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

24

Martínez-Vázquez, J. and McNab, R. (2003) Fiscal decentralization and economic growth.

World Development 31 (9): 1597-1616.

Martínez-Vázquez, J. and McNab, R. (2006) Governance and decentralization. In

Decentralization in Asia and Latin America: Towards a Comparative Interdisciplinary

Perspective. E. Gomez, Peterson, G. and Smoke, P. (Eds.) London: Edward Elgar.

Martinez-Vazquez, J., & Timofeev, A. (2008). Regional-local dimension of Russia's fiscal

equalization. Journal of Comparative Economics, 36(1): 157-176

Martínez-Vázquez, J. and Yao, M. (2009) Fiscal decentralization and public sector employment.

Public Finance Review 37 (5): 539-571.

Martínez-Vázquez, J. and Timofeev, A. (2010) Decentralization measures revisited. Public

Finance and Management 10 (1): 13-47.

Martínez-Vazquez, J. and Vulovic, V. (2016): How Well Do Subnational Borrowing Regulations

Work? ADBI Working Papers Series, 563.

Moesen, W. and van Cauwenberge, P. (2000). The status of the budget constraint, federalism and

the relative size of government: A bureaucracy approach. Public Choice 104 (3): 207-224.

Musgrave, R. (1959) The Theory of Public Finance: A Study in Public Economy. New York:

McGraw-Hill.

Nelson, M. (2013). Corruption and the size of local governments: are they related? in Lago-

Peñas, S. and Martinez-Vazquez, J. (eds): The Challenge of Local Government Size:

Theoretical Perspectives, International Experience, and Policy Reform, Chentelham: Edward

Elgar.

Neyapti, B. (2006). Revenue decentralization and income distribution. Economics Letters 92:

409–416.

Neyapti. B. (2010). Fiscal decentralization and deficits: International evidence. European

Journal of Political Economy 26: 155-166.

Oates, W. (1972) Fiscal Federalism. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

Oates, W (1993). Decentralization and economic development. National Tax Journal 46: 237-

243

Oates, W. (2005) Toward a second-generation theory of fiscal federalism. International Tax and

Public Finance 12 (4): 349-373.

OECD (1999). Taxing Powers of State and Local Government, OECD Tax Policy Studies 1.

OECD Publishing, Paris.

OECD (2013). Fiscal Federalism 2014: Making Decentralisation Work, OECD Publishing.

Olson, M. (1969) The principle of ’fiscal equivalence: the division of responsibilities among

different levels of government. American Economic Review 59(2): 479-87.

Panizza, U. (1999) On the determinants of fiscal centralization: theory and evidence. Journal of

Public Economics 74 (1): 97–139.

Peterson, G. E., and Muzzini, E. (2005). Decentralizing Basic Infrastructure Services. In East

Asia Decentralizes: Making Local Government Work, The World Bank (ed.), Washington,

DC, 209-236.

Ponce-Rodríguez, R.A., Hankla, C. R., Martinez-Vazquez, J. and Heredia-Ortiz, E. (2012).

Rethinking the political economy of decentralization: how elections and parties shape the

provision of local public goods, International Center for Public Policy WP 1227, Georgia

State University.

Page 26: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

25

Porcelli, F. (2014). Electoral accountability and local government efficiency: Quasi-experimental

evidence from the Italian health care sector reforms. Economics of Governance 15(3): 221-

251.

Presbitero, A.F., Sacchi, A. and Zazzaro, A. (2014) Property tax and fiscal discipline in OECD

countries, Economics Letters 124 (3): 428-433.

Prud'homme, R. (1995) The dangers of decentralization. The World Bank Research Observer 10

(2): 201-220.

Putnam, R. (1993) Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton:

Princeton University Press.

Qiao, Y., Martínez-Vázquez, J. and Xu, J. (2008) The trade-off between growth and equity in

decentralization policy: China's experience. Journal of Development Economics 86 (1): 112-

128.

Rajaraman, I. and Saha, D. (2008). An empirical approach to the optimal size of the civil service.

Public Administration and Development 28 (3): 223-233.

Rao, M. G. (2002). Poverty alleviation under fiscal decentralization, in: M.G. Rao (ed.)

Development, Poverty and Fiscal Policy. Decentralization of Institutions, New Delhi, Oxford

University Press: 278–298.

Ravallion, M. (1999) Are poorer states worse at targeting their poor? Economic Letters 65 (3):

373–377.

Reif, K and Schmitt, H. (1984). Nine second-order national elections: A conceptual framework

for the analysis of European election results. European Journal of Political Research 8: 3-44.

Revelli, F. (2002). Testing the tax mimicking versus expenditure spill-over hypotheses using

English data. Applied Economics 34(14): 1723-1731.

Revelli, F. (2003). Reaction or interaction? Spatial process identification in multi-tiered

government structures. Journal of Urban Economics 53(1): 29-53.

Riker, W. (1964). Federalism: Origins, Operation, Significance. Little, Brown and Co, Boston,

MA.

Rodden, J. (2002). The dilemma of fiscal federalism: Grants and fiscal performance around the

world. American Journal of Political Science 46 (3): 670-687.

Rodden, J. (2003). Reviving Leviathan: Fiscal federalism and the growth of government.

International Organization 57 (4): 695-729.

Rodden, J. (2004). Comparative federalism and decentralization: On meaning and measurement.

Comparative Politics 36 (4): 481-500.

Rodden, J., Eskeland, G. and Litwack, J. (2003). Fiscal Decentralization and the Challenge of

Hard Budget Constraints. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Rodríguez-Pose, A. and Gill, N. (2005) On the economic dividend of devolution. Regional

Studies 39 (4): 405-420.

Rodríguez-Pose, A. and Ezcurra, R. (2010) Does decentralization matter for regional disparities?

A cross-country Analysis Journal of Economic Geography 10 (5): 619-644.

Saavedra, L. A. (2000). A model of welfare competition with evidence from AFDC. Journal of

Urban Economics 47(2): 248-279.

Sacchi, A. and Salotti, S. (2014). The effects of fiscal decentralization on household income

inequality: Some empirical evidence. Spatial Economic Analysis 9(2): 202-222.

Salmon, P. (2013) Decentralization and growth: What if the cross-jurisdiction approach had met

a dead end?. Constitutional Political Economy 24: 87–107.

Page 27: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

26

Schakel, A. H. (2013). Nationalisation of multilevel party systems: A conceptual and empirical

analysis. European Journal of Political Research 52(2): 212-236.

Schwartz, J. Guilkey, D. and Racelis, R. (2002) Decentralization, Allocative Efficiency and

Health Service Outcomes in the Philippines. MEASURE Evaluation. Chapel Hill, NC:

Carolina Population Center, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.

Seabright, P. (1996) Accountability and decentralization in government: An incomplete contracts

model. European Economic Review 40 (1): 61–89.

Sepúlveda, C. and Martínez-Vázquez, J. (2011) The consequences of fiscal decentralization on

poverty and income inequality. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 29(2):

321-343.

Shankar, R. and Shah, A. (2003). Bridging the economic divide within countries: A scorecard on

the performance of regional policies in reducing regional income disparities. World

Development 31(8): 1421-1441.

Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1993) Corruption. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108 (3):

599-617.

Simatupang, R. (2009) Evaluation of Decentralization Outcomes in Indonesia: Analysis of

Health and Education Sectors. Atlanta: Department of Economics, Georgia State University.

Sobel, R.S. Dutta, N. and Roy, S. (2013) Does fiscal decentralization result in a better business

climate? Applied Economics Letters 20(1): 84-91.

Solé-Ollé, A. (2003). Electoral accountability and tax Mimicking: The effects of electoral

margins, coalition government, and ideology. European Journal of Political Economy 19(4):

685-713.

Sorens, J. (2008) Regionalists against secession: The political economy of territory in advanced

democracies. Nationalism and Ethnic Politics 14 (3): 325–360.

Stegarescu D. (2005) Public sector decentralization: Measurement concepts and recent

international trends. Fiscal Studies 26: 301–333.

Strumpf, K.S. and Oberholzer-Gee, F. (2002) Endogenous policy decentralization: testing the

central tenet of economic federalism. Journal of Political Economy 110: 1–36.

Tanzi, V. (2002) Pitfalls on the road to fiscal decentralization. In Managing Fiscal

Decentralization, edited by E. Ahmad and V. Tanzi. New York: Routledge.

Thiessen, U. (2003) Fiscal decentralization and economic growth in high-income OECD

countries. Fiscal Studies 24 (3): 237-274.

Thornton, J. (2007) Fiscal decentralization and economic growth reconsidered. Journal of Urban

Economics 61(1): 64-70.

Thornton, J. (2009) The (non) impact of revenue decentralization on fiscal deficits: some

evidence from OECD countries. Applied Economics Letters 16 (14): 1461-1466.

Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditures. The Journal of Political Economy

64: 416-424.

Treisman, D. (2000) Decentralization and inflation: Commitment, collective action, or

Ccntinuity. American Political Science Review 94(4), 837-857.

Tselios, V. Rodríguez-Pose, A. Pike, A. Tomaney, J. and Torrisi, G. (2012) Income inequality,

decentralization and regional development in Western Europe. Environment and Planning A

44(6): 1278-1301.

Viñuela, L. (2015). Trends and quality of decentralized public investment. In: J. Frank and J.

Martinez-Vazquez, Decentralization and Infrastructure in the Global Economy: From Gaps

to Solutions, 54-98.

Page 28: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

27

Voigt, S. and Blume, L. (2012) The economic effects of federalism and decentralization: A

cross-country assessment. Public Choice 151(1): 229-254.

Von Braun, J. and Grote, U. (2002) Does decentralization serve the poor? In E. Ahmad and V.

Tanzi, eds. Managing Fiscal Decentralization. London: Routledge.

Wade, R. (1998). The Asian debt-and-development crisis of 1997: Causes and consequences.

World Development 26(8): 1535-1553.

Weingast, B. (1995) The economic role of political institutions: Market-preserving federalism

and economic development. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization. 11(1): 1-31.

Weingast, B. R. (2009) Second generation fiscal federalism: The implications of fiscal

incentives. Journal of Urban Economics 65 (3):279-293.

West, L. and Wong, C. (1995) Fiscal decentralization and growing regional disparities in rural

China: Some evidence in the provision of social services. Oxford Review of Economic Policy

11 (4): 70-84.

Wilson, J. D. (1986) A theory of interregional tax competition. Journal of Urban Economics 19

(3): 296-315.

World Bank (1994) World Development Report 1994: Infrastructure for Development.

Washington, DC.

Xie, D., Zou, H., and Davoodi, H. (1999). Fiscal decentralization and economic growth in the

United States. Journal of Urban Economics 45(2): 228-239.

Zhang, T. and Zou, H. (1998) Fiscal decentralization, public spending, and economic growth in

China. Journal of Public Economics 67 (2): 221-240.

Zhang, X. (2006) Fiscal decentralization and political centralization in China: Implications for

growth and inequality. Journal of Comparative Economics 34(4): 713-726.

Zodrow, G. R., and P. Mieszkowski (1986). Pigou, Tiebout, property taxation, and the

underprovision of local public goods. Journal of Urban Economics 19(3): 356-370.

Page 29: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

28

Table 1: Selected papers on the impact on service delivery, infrastructure, and expenditure composition

Authors Main

dependent variables Decentralization variables

Data & econometric

technique

Endogeneity

issue

Main results

Faguet

(2004)

Resources spent on education and other public investment projects (13

sectors).

Dummy variable (1 after 1994, i.e. post-

decentralization).

Sample: 311 municipalities

Period: 1987-1996

Method: Principal component

analysis, OLS

Not treated Decentralization makes public investment in education and other services more

responsive to local needs.

Habibi

et al. (2003)

Infant mortality rate.

i) % of revenue raised locally.

ii) % of locally controlled revenue over

the total.

Sample: 23

Argentinean provinces

Period: 1970-1994

Method: Panel FE

Not treated Decentralization decreases infant mortality

rates.

Falch

&

Fischer (2012)

School quality (students aged 13-15 test scores:

PISA and TIMSS).

Share of sub-national government spending of general government

spending.

Sample: 25 OECD countries

Period: 1980 – 2000

Method: Panel FE

Not treated Decentralization is beneficial to student

performance.

Faguet

&

Sánchez (2014)

Access to education and health

(change in the number of students enrolled in public schools; change in

the poor population covered by

public health insurance).

i) Own local resources/

Total municipal education expenditures

ii) Own local resources/

Total municipal health expenditures

iii) Municipal independence (dummy 1

for municipalities subject to regional government interventions).

Sample: Colombian municipalities

Period: 1994-2004

Method: Panel RE; IV

Treated by IV: the

mineral and hydrocarbon

royalties received

by a municipality as instrument of

decentralization.

Decentralization improves enrollment rates

in public schools and access of the poor to

public health services.

Arze

et al. (2016)

i) Ratio of education expenditures to

total public expenditures.

ii) Ratio of health expenditures to

total public expenditures.

iii) Ratio of both expenditures to total public expenditures.

Share of sub-national government

expenditures to general government expenditures.

Sample: 42 developed and

developing countries

Period: 1990-2012

Method: GMM; Quasi-Maximum Likelihood estimators.

Treated by GMM:

lags of decentralization.

Decentralization positively influences the

share of education and health expenditures in

consolidated government budgets.

Escaleras &

Register

(2012)

Natural disasters (number of deaths per 100,000 persons due to

earthquakes, floods, landslides,

volcanoes, etc.)

Expenditures of local/regional

governments relative to the total of spending by all levels of government.

Sample: 79 countries

Period: 1972–

2000

Method: OLS; Quantile

regression; IV

Treated by IV:

legal origins

Decentralization is associated with lower

natural disaster death rates. (Robust only for developing countries).

Bjørnskov Life satisfaction (subjective well- i) Political decentralization Sample: 66 countries (survey of Not treated More spending or revenue decentralization

Page 30: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

29

et al.

(2008)

being on a scale

from 1–10)).

(constitutional stipulations which grant

exclusive rights to legislate)

ii) Fiscal decentralization

60,000 individuals)

Period (survey data): 1997-2001

Method: Weighted ordered probit.

raises well-being.

Ligthart

& van

Oudheusden

(2015)

Trust in government related institutions (confidence in: national

government; civil services;

parliament; political parties).

Share of sub-national government

expenditures to general government expenditures.

Sample: 42 countries

Period: 1994-2007

Method: OLS; Ordered logit; IV.

Treated by IV: lags

of decentralization.

Fiscal decentralization increases citizens’

trust in government related institutions.

Page 31: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

30

Table 2: Selected papers on the impact on economic growth

Authors Main

dependent variables Decentralization variables

Data &

econometric technique

Endogeneity issue

Main results

Thiessen

(2003)

i) Growth rate of real GDP

ii) Average annual investment

to GDP ratio.

ii) Average annual TFP growth.

i) The share of sub-national government

expenditures (revenues)

ii) Unweighted average of both

iii) Local own revenues as a share of local total revenues.

Sample: high-income OECD

countries

Period: 1973-1998

Method: OLS

Not treated

Positive relationship but turning negative at some point.

Gemmell et al.

(2013)

Annual rate of growth of GDP i) Expenditure share

ii) Revenue share

Sample: 23 OECD countries

Period: 1972-2005

Method: Pooled Mean Group; IV

Treated by IV: lags of decentralization

Positive relationship for revenue decentralization, but negative for

expenditure decentralization.

Filippetti &

Sacchi

(2016)

Real per capita GDP growth

rate (5-years average)

i) Sub-central governments’ own tax revenue

over general government total tax revenue

ii) Property tax or income tax decentralization

(over general government total tax revenue)

iv) Administrative & political decentralization

Sample: 21 OECD countries

Period: 1970-2010

Method: OLS; panel FE; GMM; IV.

Treated by GMM: lags

of tax decentralization.

Property tax decentralization leads to

higher growth when coupled with high administrative & political

decentralization.

Zhang

& Zou

(1998)

Provincial real income growth rate

Ratios of provincial to central spending.

Sample: 28 Chinese provinces

Period: 1980-1992

Method: Panel LSDV; GLS

Not treated Negative impact on growth.

Qiao

et al. (2008)

Percent growth rate of nominal

provincial per capita GDP

Share of provincial fiscal expenditure in total

fiscal expenditure (per capita).

Sample: 28 Chinese provinces

Period: 1985-1998

Method: Panel FE; RE.

Hausman test revealing

no endogeneity. Positive effect on growth.

Xie

et al.

(1999)

Real per capita GDP annual growth rate

Expenditure shares at different levels.

Sample: 50 states of USA

Period: 1948-1994

Method: OLS

Not treated Negative effect on growth.

Akai

& Sakata

(2002)

Average annual growth rate of per capita Gross State Product.

i) Ratio of local government revenue

(expenditure) to combined state and local government revenue (expenditure).

ii) Mean of both indicators sub i).

iii) Local own revenue to total revenue.

Sample: 50 states of USA

Period: 1992-1996

Method: OLS

Using initial values of decentralization.

Only expenditure ratio positively affects

growth.

Page 32: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

31

Table 3: Selected papers on the impact on macroeconomic stability and fiscal sustainability

Authors Main

dependent variables Decentralization variables

Data & econometric

technique

Endogeneity issue

Main results

Rodden

(2002)

Sub-national surplus/deficit

over expenditures.

Vertical fiscal imbalance, borrowing autonomy

and federal dummy.

Sample: 43 OECD, developing, transitional countries

Period: 1986-1996

Method: OLS; 3-stage least

squares; GMM.

Treated by GMM.

Larger deficits associated with

transfer dependence and free borrowing.

Neyapti (2010)

General government budget deficit over GDP

Sub-national government spending and revenue shares

Sample: 43 OECD, developing,

transitional countries

Period: 1980-1998

Method: OLS

Hausman test revealing no endogeneity.

Expenditure and revenue

decentralization reduce budget

deficits.

Eyraud &

Lusinyan

(2014)

General government primary

balance over GDP

Expenditure share or Vertical Fiscal Imbalance (VFI)

Sample: 28 OECD countries.

Period: 1969-2007.

Method: Panel FE; IV.

Treated by IV: lagged VFI and

lagged control variables

Fiscal balance improves when VFI

decreases.

Presbitero et al.

(2014)

General government primary

balance over GDP

i) Total or local property taxes as share of

general government tax revenues.

ii) Tax decentralization

Sample: 22 OECD countries

Period: 1973-2011

Method: panel FE, FGLS

Not treated

Local property taxes and tax decentralization contribute to fiscal

discipline.

de Mello (2000)

Central and sub-central government budget balances

over GDP.

Sub-national tax autonomy, fiscal dependency or spending share

Sample: 30 OECD and non-

OECD countries.

Period: 1970-1995.

Method: SURE estimations

Not treated Sub-national tax autonomy worsens the fiscal position.

Thornton (2009)

Fiscal balance of the

consolidated government over

GDP.

Share of own or total revenues accruing to

sub-national governments

Sample: 19 OECD countries

Period: 1980-2000

Method: Panel FE

Not treated

No statistically significant of

revenue decentralization.

Page 33: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

32

Table 4: Selected papers on the impact on income inequality and poverty

Authors Main

dependent variables Decentralization variables

Data & econometric

technique

Endogeneity issue

Main results

Tselios

et al.

(2012)

Within-region income inequality

i) Sub-national expenditure and revenue shares

ii) Political decentralization (regional authority by Hooghe et al. 2008).

Sample: 102 regions in the

European Union

Period: 1995-2000.

Method: Panel FE; GMM.

Treated by GMM.

Fiscal decentralization lowers

interpersonal income inequality.

Sepúlveda

& Martinez-

Vazquez

(2011)

i) Poverty (headcount ratio; poverty gap; Human

Development Index).

ii) Gini coefficient (on

disposable income).

Sub-national expenditure

decentralization share.

Sample: 56 countries (inequality)/

65 countries (poverty)

Period: 1971-2000 (inequality)/

1976-2000 (poverty).

Method: Panel FE; panel GLS; IV.

Treated by IV: land area,

population, openness

Decentralization

reduces income inequality (when size of

government is over 20% but leads to increased poverty counts

Sacchi &

Salotti (2014)

Gini coefficient (on gross

household income).

Expenditure and tax decentralization

measures based on Stegarescu(2005).

Sample: 23 OECD countries Period: 1971-2000.

Method: Panel FE; panel FGLS; IV.

Treated by IV: lags of

decentralization

Higher tax decentralization increases

household income inequality

Neyapti

(2006) Gini coefficient Sub-national revenue share.

Sample: 37 countries

Period: three decades (1970s,

1980s, 1990s).

Method: Panel RE; Cross-section

analysis.

Hausman test revealing no

endogeneity.

Revenue decentralization increases income

inequality but, with good governance, it

reduces it

Page 34: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

33

Table 5: Selected papers on the impact on geographical and interregional disparities

Authors Main

dependent variables Decentralization variables

Data & econometric

technique

Endogeneity issue

Main results

Lessmann

(2012)

i) Coefficient of variation of

regional GDP

ii) GINI index

i) Expenditure and revenue shares and tax decentralization

ii) Sub-national transfer dependence

Sample: 56 countries (developed

and developing)

Period: 1980-2009

Method: Panel FE; Cross-section analysis; IV

Treated by IV: institutions, colonial origin;

composition of the society

Decentralization decreases regional inequalities but varies with economic

development.

Kyriacou et al.

(2015)

Population-weighted coefficient of variation of regional GDP per

capita.

Share of sub-national revenues net

of grants.

Sample: 24 OECD countries

Period: 1984-2006

Method: Panel FGLS; SUR; GMM.

Treated by GMM Decentralization promotes regional convergence but only with good governance.

Ezcurra & Pascual

(2008)

Population-weighted coefficient of variation of regional GDP per

capita.

Sub-national expenditure share

Sample: 132 regions in 12 European

countries. Period: 1980-1999

Method: Panel FE; OLS.

Not treated Devolution of fiscal power reduces regional inequality.

Rodríguez-Pose

&

Ezcurra (2010)

Population-weighted coefficient of variation of regional GDP per

capita.

i) Sub-national expenditure share.

ii) Political decentralization index (Schneider 2003)

Sample: 26 countries (developed and developing)

Period: 1990-2006

Method: IV

Treated by IV: lags of decentralization.

Fiscal and political decentralization are

dissociated from the evolution of regional disparities.

Page 35: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

34

Table 6: Selected papers on the impact on government size and public policies

Authors Main dependent

variables Decentralization variables

Data & econometric

technique

Endogeneity issue

Main results

Martinez-Vazquez

& Yao

(2009)

Public sector employees as %

of population over labor force.

Sub-national expenditures and revenues shares.

Sample: 74 countries

(developed and developing)

Period: 1985-2005

Method: IV

Treated by IV: ethnic,

language and religion fractionalization

Total public sector employees increase with fiscal decentralization.

Devereux

et al.

(2007)

Competition at state level in

tax rates on cigarettes and

gasoline.

Weighted average of other states'

taxes on cigarettes and gasoline.

Sample: 48 US states

Period: 1977-1997

Method: IV.

Treated by IV: federal

deficit % GDP and federal unemployment

rate

Taxes in neighboring states have a significant and large effect in the case of cigarettes but not so for gasoline.

Jin

& Zou

(2002)

i) Sub-national, ii) national,

iii) total government

expenditures % GDP.

i) Sub-national expenditures and

revenues shares

ii) Transfer dependence.

Sample: 32 countries

(industrial and developing)

Period: 1980-1994

Method: Panel FE; FGLS

Not treated

i) Expenditure decentralization leads to smaller national

governments, larger sub-national and aggregate governments.

ii) Revenue decentralization increases sub-national governments, reduces more national governments, so

reduces aggregate governments

iii) Transfer dependence increase the sizes of all

government levels.

Page 36: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

35

Table 7: Selected papers on the impact on governance, accountability, and corruption

Authors Main dependent

variables Decentralization variables

Data & econometric

technique

Endogeneity issue

Main results

Kyriacou

&

Roca-Sagalés (2011)

Government quality (control

of corruption, rule of law,

regulatory quality and government effectiveness).

Sub-national expenditure and revenue

shares.

Sample: 27 OECD

countries

Period: 1996-2005

Method: Panel FE; GLS; IV method

Treated by IV: lags of

decentralization. Positive impact on government quality.

Dell’Anno

&

Teobaldelli (2015)

Corruption (perceived); shadow economy (by Buehn

and Schneider 2012).

i) Sub-national expenditure and

revenue shares.

ii) Political and administrative

decentralization.

Sample: 145 countries

(developed and developing)

Period: 1999-2007 (cross-country analysis)

Method: OLS; IV.

Treated by IV: legal origins

Decentralization is associated with lower

shadow economy and corruption.

Fan

et al. (2009)

Corruption (based on firms’

survey).

i) Number of tiers of government

ii) Sub-national revenue share and public payroll.

Sample: 80 developed

and developing countries

Period: 1999-2000

(cross-country analysis)

Method: ordered probit

model

Not treated

More tiers of sub-national governments

and larger public payrolls associated with more corruption.

Page 37: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

36

Table 8: Selected papers on the impact on social capital and tax morale

Authors Main

dependent variables Decentralization variables

Data &

econometric technique

Endogeneity issue

Main results

de Mello (2004)

Social capital (attitudes and trust on survey data).

Dummy for federal country

Sample: 34 developed and developing

countries

Period: 2005 wave

Method: Probit analysis

Not treated Positive federalism-social capital nexus.

Ligthart

&

van Oudheusden

(2015)

Trust in government related

institutions (survey data).

Sub-national expenditures

share.

Sample: 42 developed and developing

countries

Period: 1994-2007 (cross-country

analysis)

Method: OLS; ordered logit model;

IV

Treated by IV: lags of

decentralization.

Decentralization increases trust in

government.

Güth

et al.

(2005)

Tax morale index

Dummy for centralization

Sample: 132 German individuals

Period: 2002

Method: OLS (experimental analysis).

Not treated Decentralization induces higher tax morale.

Lago &

Lago-Peñas (2010b)

Tax morale index Interregional fiscal

redistribution

Sample: 17 European countries

Period: 2004-2005 wave

Method: Ordered logit

Not treated Tax morale is weaker for residents in

net contributing regions.

Page 38: THE IMPACT OF FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION: A SURVEY

37

Table 9: Selected papers on the impact on voter turnout, party system nationalization, and national unity

Authors Main

dependent variables Decentralization variables

Data &

econometric technique

Endogeneity issue

Main results

Blais et al.

(2011)

Voter turnout in national and

regional elections.

i) Regional authority index (by

Hooghe et al. 2008).

ii) Sub-national expenditures and

revenues share

Sample: 88 developed and developing

countries + Canada and Spain (case

studies).

Period: 1972-2005

Method: OLS; Panel FE.

Not treated

Decentralization reduces the turnout gap

between regional and national elections in

Canada and Spain. No effect on turnout in national elections for cross-country analysis.

Schakel (2013)

i) Party system nationalization.

ii) Regional elections.

iii) National vote shares

Regional authority index (by

Hooghe et al. 2008).

Sample: 18 advanced economies

Period: 1945-2009

Method: PCSE; Multilevel mixed-effects linear model.

Not treated Regional authority does not affect party systems or national vote shares.

Lago

& Lago-Peñas

(2011)

Party system nationalization

Regional authority index (by

Hooghe et al. 2008).

Sample: 17 Western European countries

Period: 1945 -1998

Method: OLS; TSCS; QMLE.

Not treated No effect of regional authority on party system nationalization.

Harbers (2009)

Party system nationalization

i) Sub-national expenditure and revenue shares.

ii) Political decentralization

iii) Size of public payroll

Sample: 16 Latin American democracies.

Period: 89 elections

Method: PCSE.

Not treated Political and fiscal decentralization inhibit nationalized party systems.