28
1 The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an institutionalist explanation for the creation of a new financial institution Feliciano de SáGuimarães Assistant Professor Institute of International Relations University of São Paulo, Brazil [email protected] Abstract: Did the lack of reform ofthe Bretton-Woods institutions have any influence on the creation of a new international financial institution - the BRICS Bank? In this paper wediscuss how the lack of quota reform of the IMF and the World Bank has created strong incentives for unsatisfied developing countries, such as BRICS countries, that they bypass these institutions and design a new financial institution. This new institution mimics the responsibilities of both the IMF and the World Bank, but with a more equal power distribution (quotas shares) among its new members. Theoretically, we designed a model that explains the reasons behind the BRICS Bank creation.Methodologically, we used qualitative instrumentsto understand the circumstances behind the creation of a new international financial institution. Our dependent variable is BRICS Bank creation. The independent variables are exogenous shocks (redistribution of economic power and financial crisis) and internal problems of Bretton-Woods institutions.

The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

1

The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an institutionalist

explanation for the creation of a new financial institution

Feliciano de SáGuimarães

Assistant Professor

Institute of International Relations

University of São Paulo, Brazil

[email protected]

Abstract: Did the lack of reform ofthe Bretton-Woods institutions have any

influence on the creation of a new international financial institution - the BRICS

Bank? In this paper wediscuss how the lack of quota reform of the IMF and the

World Bank has created strong incentives for unsatisfied developing countries, such

as BRICS countries, that they bypass these institutions and design a new financial

institution. This new institution mimics the responsibilities of both the IMF and the

World Bank, but with a more equal power distribution (quotas shares) among its

new members. Theoretically, we designed a model that explains the reasons behind

the BRICS Bank creation.Methodologically, we used qualitative instrumentsto

understand the circumstances behind the creation of a new international financial

institution. Our dependent variable is BRICS Bank creation. The independent

variables are exogenous shocks (redistribution of economic power and financial

crisis) and internal problems of Bretton-Woods institutions.

Page 2: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

2

Introduction

In this paper we aim to explain why the BRICS Bank institutions, Contingent

Reserve Arrangement (CRA) and New Development Bank (NDB), were created. We

provide an institutionalist explanation based on the strategic decisions using

institutional change and institutional making theories. Our hypothesis is that the

sum of powerful exogenous shocks and endogenous institutional problems has

created the opportunity for making new institutions. The paper is divided in three

parts. First, we develop our theoretical argument for the BRICS Bank creation.

Second, we discuss the endogenous shocks and endogenous problems of the

Bretton-Woods institutions. Finally, we discuss the chain of events that lead to the

creation of both the CRA and the NDB.

1. The argument

The study of international organizations is an important research area in the

field of international relations. Traditionally, researchers have sought to explain

why states establish international organizations (Keohane 1984; Abbott and Snidal

1998) and how they design international organizations (Koremenos et al. 2001).

Less attention has been devoted to the question of how international organizations

evolve or change after they have been founded(Van de Graaf and Lesage

2009,Barnett and Coleman 2005, Barnett and Finnemore2004). More importantly,

no attention has been given to the unintended consequences of the lack of

institutional change in international organizations. There are no studies to our

knowledge that explain the effects of not reforming institutions.How will unsatisfied

states with the status quo react to the situation of institutional inertia? In this paper

we argue that the absence of institutional reforms at the Bretton Woods institutions

increased the chances of new institutional making by BRICS states. Empirically, we

show this process using the example of the BRICS Bank creation.

Theories of institutional change aim to understand how

institutionstransform through exogenous and endogenous mechanisms (Greif and

Laitin 2004; Ostrom 2005) and in turn, theories of institutional making understand

institutional creation as a result of market failures(Keohane 1984; Axelrod and

Page 3: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

3

Keohane 1985). The BRICS Bank case does not fit entirely ineither ofthetwo groups.

Although market failures can be an important reason for the BRICS Bank creation, it

does not answer completely its constitution.A more complete view needs to

incorporate aspects not entirely understood by institutional change approach,the

unintended consequences of lack of reforms. In this sense, we have found no studies

that directly accountforthe effects of insufficientinstitutional change overnew

institutional making.

There are two types of studies that are somewhat similar to our approach:

nested institutions studies and strategic institutional alternatives studies. The first

one tries to explain how nested and parallel institutions are createdby states

(Aggarwal 1998; Abbott and Snidal 2006). However, these nested institutions are

usually created by the same states that had created the original institutions;so

nested institution studies do not face the problem of effects of institutional inertia

on the performance of rising powers or unsatisfied countries. The second group of

studies tries to move beyond traditional theories that implicitly focus on a single

(optimal) institution toemphasize the potentially rich range of institutional

alternatives available to states. That is, states can accomplish their goalsstrategically

choosing, reforming or creating institutions around the issue area (Jupille and Snidal

2006).Nonetheless, once more creating new institutionsis an exclusive alternative of

dominant powers and creation by developing countries is not the center of the

analysis. We argue that none of these two groups triesto answer why non-reforming

institutions create incentives for rising powers to create new institutions.

The literature points out two actors that can promotesuch variation and

institutional change, states and bureaucracies(Sweet et al 2001, Goldstein et al

2000, Haftel and Thompson 2006, Shanks et al. 1996). The first wave of studies of

IOs detailed their internal characteristics and how states mattered most in the

process of institutional reform (Cox and Jacobson 1974). Also Realism claims that

any change in the mandate or design of IOs owes to demands imposed by Great

Powers (Mearsheimer1995), andneoliberal institutionalism emphasizes howstates

design IOs assigning them various functions in order to overcome problemsof

collaboration and coordination. As a result, any change must be initiated and

Page 4: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

4

conducted by states,although it recognizes that institutions are resilient(Keohane

1984,Keohane and Martin 1995). A secondview ofinstitutional change does not

recognizestates as the only actors capable of reforming institutional settings;

bureaucracies also play their role. More recently, some authors show that

bureaucrats seek to expand their responsibilities and political power through a

series of incremental changes, sometimes acting against states interests(Guimarães

2012; Barnett and Coleman 2005; Weaver 2008; Hawkins et al 2006). None of these

studies, however, try to understand institutional change or creation by the sole

perspective of rising powers trapped in organizations that do not adjust according

to their interests.

It is important to know how institutions are created in order to understand

how they change. According to institutionalist theory, states create institutions in

anticipation of the cooperation gains they will be able to achieve in the future. When

states are involved in situations of market failures where the outcomes of their

interactions are suboptimal- given the utility function at their disposal - then in

order to overcome these situations states build institutional settings in which

pareto-optimal results can be eventually achieved.However, creating institutions is

costly and risky for states since they are not certain of the future gains of

cooperation (Keohane 1984).

If creating new organizations is always costly and risky, then an alternative is

institutional maintenance which entails costs over the years that are generally lower

than those involved in creating new institutions. Only severe newcircumstances,

such as shifts in the distribution of power or the appearance of cooperation

problems, are likely to alter the original cost/benefit relationship of institutional

maintenance. Yet if the marginal costs of maintaining an existing institution

outweigh the costs of creating an entirely new set of: norms, rules, and procedures;

states will choose to sustain existing arrangements rather than abandon them. In

sum, for institutionalist theory the hypothesis of institutional variation and change

are related to transaction costs and distributional consequences perpetrated by

states actions (Keohane 1984,Wallander 2000).

Reform is never easy in institutional settings. The consequences of adopting

Page 5: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

5

new rules are often hard to predict,even if actors could modifyrules easily they may

hesitate due to uncertainty (Hall 2010). If change is going to negatively affect gains,

players may prefer the status quo, despite the necessity of change. Since institutions

are impregnated by tensions because they inevitably raise resources, considerations

and distributional effects,then changingthe rules means choosing between losers

and winners in a scenario of uncertainty. If organizationsare costly to construct and

modify, and those who design them are often risk-averse, we cannot expect

institutions to change smoothly in response to structural variables. Therefore, sunk

costs and risk-aversion behavior account for institutional inertia(Keohane and

Martin, 2003).

Nevertheless, change occurs under a few conditions. The literature shows

three reasons for change: external shocks, inefficient outcomes and internal

coordination problems(Barnett and Coleman 2005; Aoki 2007; Greif and Laitin

2004; Ostrom 2005; Kingston and Caballero 2009, Stein 1983).First, institutions can

be changed by exogenous shocks that shift the internal equilibrium between

members. When a shift in balance of power allows rising states to question the

status quo, thensome members start to perceive the cost/benefit relationship of the

current equilibrium as negative and, consequently, start demanding internal

changes. Second, inefficient outcomes can also prompt change; for example,

thelowefficiency of policiesbystatus quo institutions are taken in consideration not

only by countries directly affected by these policies, but also by countries that

designed them, whether they are dominant or rising powers.However, the

incapacity of rising powers to modify inefficient policiesdue to excessive control of

traditional powersover the decision making process can create incentives for these

countries to push for reforms where their policies views can become

predominant.Thirdly, endogenous changes are usually related to iteratedgames

within the institution that affects some of the members negatively. Unsatisfied

members start to perceive that status quo rules are not as favoring as before and

that dominant powers repeatedly reap the benefits.This represents a coordination

problem that forces unsatisfied members to callfor internal reform.

Exogenous shocks are indeed necessary for change, but the lack of internal

Page 6: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

6

reforming iskey to our argument. We aim to understand what happens if internal

reforms are non-existent despite mounting exogenous shocks, policies inefficiency,

and internal coordination problems.How will unsatisfied states react to situations in

which the absence of internal change impedes them to obtain gains from

cooperation?The literature shows that internal reforming can happen either by

removing the existing rules and introducing new ones or by introducing new ones

on the top of the existing rules (Mahoney and Thelen 2010).Ifneither of these

processes is taking place, or if reforms are perceived by new rising powers as

dramatically slow, the gap between unsatisfied countries perception and status quo

institutions performanceincreases over the years, creating powerful incentives for

new institutional making.

We argue that if existinginstitutions do not change in a way that favors rising

powers, these countries may eventually become unsatisfied to a point of

cooperation breakdown. Such situations tend to wind down the costs of creating a

new institution, outweighing the costs of status quo maintenance. When creating a

new organization becomes less expensive than institutional maintenance

unsatisfied states would seek for alternatives. These alternatives can be either

exiting currentinstitutions - a risky strategy that very few countries would be able

or willing to incur - or creating a more favorable parallel organization. In sum, we

argue that if (1) the relative costs of potential alternative strategies is lower than

pushing for internal reforms, and the (2) internal governance problems represent

insuperable obstacles to cooperation and future gains, it is likely that unsatisfied

and capable states will seek for a different equilibrium in other institutional settings

without defecting from the current ones.

Additionally, institutional inertia aggravates distributional problems in the

international system, especially for rising powers. Dominant powers are responsible

for the provision of public goods in an international system without sanctioning,

andas a result, they design institutions that produce the form of order they prefer.

Other actors may prefer different institutions, exacerbating distributional problems

(Morrow 1994);however, dominant powers can include the interests of rising

power through a process of reforming that contemplates gains for the new comers,

Page 7: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

7

if the inclusion is non-existent,the perception of rising powers reveals cooperation

as more beneficial to dominant powers. Furthermore, the inefficiency of policies

designed by institutions in which rising powers have less influencealso

reinforcesthe perception of dissatisfaction, so unsatisfied actors preferring for

alternative solutions is a byproduct of iterated problems of cooperation within the

dominant institutions.

Then again, institutional inertia does not respond alone to new institutional

making,exogenous shocks have a key role as well. As environmental changes

associated with financial crisis empowers new countries and reduces the capacity of

dominant powers to control the decision-making process, unsatisfied countries

startto increase the internal pressure for change. As a result, balance of power

changes and market failures are also responsible for creating opportunities for new

institutional making. For instance, market failures have increased in the last

financial crisis and status quo institutions were not capable of solving the situation

alone. With a financial system almost collapsing it was clear that the

currentorganizations were insufficient and flawed to deal with this enormous

task.Hence, exogenous shocks have the capacity of changing the power equilibrium

that keep developing and developed countries together within certain institutions,

but it is the internal decisions for change or inertia that prompts or not new

institutional making.

Institutionalist arguments are built using counterfactuals. Our two key

variables are exogenous shocks and endogenous reform. Applying these variable to

the case of Bretton-Woods/BRICS Bank we argue that if exogenous shocks had

never existed, and internal reforms were still demanded by unsatisfied countries, it

would be unlikely that new institutional making would have happen. The status quo

institutions would continue to be the sole responsible for dealing with financial

governance in the international system due to the incapacity of developing

countries to create new organizations since their power did not raise accordingly.

On the other hand, if exogenous shocks had been followed by internal reforms or if

internal problems had never existed, it would be unlikely that Bretton-Woods

institutions would face the birth of a rival organization. The internal reforming

Page 8: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

8

process would include the interests of rising powers and securethem gains from

future cooperation.

We claimthat only the sum of powerful exogenous shocks and internal

governance problems dramatically decreasedthe costs of new institutional making.

If exogenous shocks are a necessary condition, the lack of institutional reform is a

sufficient conditionfor the creation of a new institution. The separated existence of

internal problems and exogenous shocks wouldhardly promote new organizations

in the financial area. This is the reason why the creation of global financial

institutions is such a rare event.

As we said before, creating new institutions is costly and risky. These general

factors reinforce the status quo bias of institutional choice. All other things being

equal, using the current institutionis the most commonly pursued strategy by any

country, selection among institutional alternatives the next most common, and

change and creation least common (Jupille and Snidal 2006). However, the financial

area is one of the few areas in international relations where there are almost no

institutional alternatives for rising powers. The regional banks are geographically

closed out to new global powers. If rising powers suffer serious macroeconomic or

developmental problems, there are only a handful of institutional choices available.

We show that exogenous shocks and institutional inertia only exacerbate the

necessity of institutional making.

One possible consequence of new institutional making is

unsatisfiedcountries pushing harder for internal reforms at Bretton-Woods

institutions after the inception of a new organization.BRICS countries do not aspire

for a new world order that competes with the status quoreshaping it is their overall

strategy (Abdenur, Esteves and Gama 2014). More importantly, the existence of an

institutional alternative empowers their claim for internal reforms at status quo

institutions because it creates margin of maneuver in the case of rejection. It is likely

thatthe decline in prestige and legitimacy of Bretton-Woods institutions following

the creation of BRICS Bank will put dominant powers in a position of reestablishing

the status quo by advancing reforms that had been denied before.

Based on this discussion, we suggest that the creation of the BRICS Bank has

Page 9: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

9

followedthe causal pathway below:

1. Redistribution of economic power in the international system, favoring

BRICS countries.

2. A financial crisis boosting the claim of rising powers for reforms in favorable

terms.

3. Status quo policies perceived by rising powers as inefficient.

4. Internal reforms of current institutions evolving slowly or inexistent due to

excessive control of traditional powers over the decision-making process.

5. New institutional making to overcome lack of reforms of status quo

institutions.

6. The existence of a new financial institution boosts even further the claims of

rising powers to deeper reforms of status quo institutions.

Decision-tree for BRICS countries

Cooperate?

Page 10: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

10

No Yes Unilateralism Use institution? No Yes Bilateralism Reform institution? No Yes Defect? Positive institutionalized cooperation

No Yes Create new institution?Unilateralism or bilateralism No Yes Negative institutionalized cooperation New institutional making

2.The exogenous and endogenous forces operating at the Bretton-

Woods institutions:

Exogenous shocks are the starting point of our argument. Powerful external

shocks triggered unsatisfied countries to seek for internal reforms within the IMF

and the World Bank, and more recently to look for institutional alternatives. These

shocks are related to two main factors: the 2008 global economic crisis and the

recent economic performance of BRICS countries.

Analysts and observers have predicted a relative decline in American power

and a return to a multipolar world economy1. The common scenario emerging is one

of decreased U.S. power and increased power for newly emerging powers. Whether

1World Bank Global Development Horizons 2011 Multipolarity: The New Global Economy.

Page 11: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

11

it is just a cycle and or a steady trend is something yet to be determined.However,

the real question is what emerging economies will de facto emerge and what will be

their responsibilities in the global system.A group that is becoming the most

prominent to fulfill these needs is the BRICS countries.

In 2003 the investment firm Goldman Sachs issued a research report that

coined an acronym: the “BRICs economies,” or Brazil, Russia, India, and China. At the

time of writing, the four large emerging economies collectively represented around

15 percent of the gross national product (GNP) of the six major advanced industrial

economies: the United States, Japan, Germany, France, Britain and Italy. However,

the prediction showed that BRICs would become in 30 years the world’s main

“engine of new demand growth and spending power”2.From a group of emerging

economies put together by Goldman Sachs, they went on to become one of the few

economies during the economic recession that had showed positive results.The

literature talks about “power shifts” from developed countries, mainly the G-7, to

BRICs countries over the next decades (Armijo 2007, Armijo and Roberts 2014,

Brustchand Pappa 2013, Cheng et al 2007, Griffith-Jones 2014, Abdenur, Esteves

and Gama 2014, Ban and Blyth 2013).

The economic crisis of 2008 only exacerbated the performance gap between

the G-7 and BRICS. The collapse of US financial services firm Lehman Brothers in

September 2008 brought the crisis, exposing vulnerabilities across the financial

sector. The first wave of effects spread across countries that had opened up their

financial systems to global banking. Countries like Portugal, Iceland, Spain, Italy,

Ukraine started to go into economic turmoil. The second wave hit developing

countries. At first glance BRICs countries economies stood still. After years of rapid

growth the 2008 financial crisis seemed to be the last moment of BRICs economic

success. However, as the events passed BRICS economies were performing better

than G-7 economies in several indicators (Woods 2010, Gaddy and Ickes 2010). So it

is fair to say that the 2008 financial crisis speeded up the rising of BRICS countries

in the economic area.

2O’Neill, Wilson and Purushothaman, Dreaming with the BRICS: the path to 2050. Goldman Sachs Report 2003.

Page 12: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

12

Yet, exogenous pressures do not account entirely for the BRICS Bank

creation. As we said before, while exogenous shocks are obviously important, they

are not a sufficient condition to our argument. Endogenous problems are the

necessary condition for new institutional making. In this sense, the IMF and World

Bank reforms can be considered one of the most challenging and intricatedisputes in

the international governance structure. Changing quotas systems entails clear losers

and winners. If China’s quotas are increased from the current 3.81% to 6% (2008

proposal) somecountries will have their quotas necessarily decreased by a

comparable margin. This is not clear in other institutional settings. For example, if

Brazil gains a permanent seat at the UN Security Council, France or the United

Kingdom will not necessarily loose power, or at least they will not be certain by how

much exactly they are losing it. Quota is a fixed number that makes changes more

complicate and defeats clearer.

Reforms at the IMF and the World Bank quota system have different timings

and implications, but they have been historically connected. Yet, while reforming the

IMF can be considered the cornerstone of the international financial governance,

reforming the World Bank receives less attention both from the academia and the

media. Actually, changes at the IMF quotas will almost automatically promote

changes at the World Bank since they are usually approved together at

theIMF/World Bank Annual Meetings. An analysis of literature on the IMF and

World Bank reforms will show that countries dispute quotas shares more fiercely at

the IMF than the World Bank. So the IMF dispute represents the true quest for

financial power in the international system3.

The history of IMF/World Bank quota systemreform is long and

controversial. Since their foundation quotas had been changed to accommodate just

a handful of rising countries, such as Japan and Saudi Arabia, leaving behind several

important candidates (Boughton2001, De Vries 1986). Theoretically, every country

should have a quota share somewhat related to the size of its GDP. However, after a

3The literature on IMF/World Bank reforms is vast. See Buira 2002 and 2003, Bird and Rowlands 2006, Bryant 2008, Truman 2014, Woods 2000 and 2010, Vestergaard2011, Vestergaard and Wade 2012 and 2014, Virmani2012.

Page 13: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

13

couple decades a series of developing countries became seriously underrepresented

despite their GDP advances. For example, China currently holds 3.81% of the

shares;a number calculated when China had half of today’s GDP. In 2010, the

proposal of quotas adjustment recommends that China quotas should be increased

to 6.07%, a number still below its GDP in 2014.As we will see below, this proposal is

still pending. Currently, the US holds 16,75% of the voting shares, the five biggest

European economies (Germany, France, UK, Italy, and Spain) hold 19,18%, and

BRICS only 11,03%, bearing in mind that BRICS represent nowadays 25,5% of

world’s GDP while Europe only 15,31%.

More recently, two rounds of reforms took placeat the Annual Meetings.

First, in Singapore March 2006 it was agreed that the most underrepresented

countries were to be given an immediate increase in their quotas(China, Korea,

Mexico and Turkey). Four other reforms were endorsed in March 2008 and

constitute the second round of reforms. These were: a new quota formula4; a second

round of ad hoc quota increases based on the new formula; a increase of basic

votes5;and an increase in the representation of African Countries on the Executive

Board (Woods 2010).

In April 2008, the IMF’s Board of Governors announced ‘far-reaching

reforms’ aimed at rebuilding its ‘credibility and legitimacy’. The reforms taken

together have had an overall shift of 5.4% of voting power in the IMF including

increases in quota shares for Korea (+106%), Singapore (+63%), Turkey (+51%),

China (+50%), India (+40%), Brazil (+40%) and Mexico (+40%). Some

industrialized countries were prepared to forgo a part of the quota increase for

which they were eligible, including Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Luxembourg and

the United States (Woods 2010). In the midst of an enormous economic crisis G-7

countries implemented none of these changes and nothing went into effect.

In 2009G20 leaders agreed to reform the governance of the IMF and the

World Bank once again. They committed themselves to push for a shift of at least

4The formula determines a country’s economic size thereby its voting power and access to resources in the IMF. 5Minimum votes share for every country.

Page 14: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

14

5% of voting power from developed to developing countries in the IMF and at least

3% in the World Bank. These proposals were sent to the respective Executive

Boards. In Seoul 2010 the executive boards of both organizations agreed to even

greater changes than the G20 leaders called for. They also agreed that countries’

share of world GDP should be the primary criterion for countries’ share of

votes(Vestergaard and Wade 2014).

The 2010 Seoul package of IMF quota and governance reforms had three

major elements: (1) Doubling IMF quotas, with a corresponding reduction in the

size of commitments to the New Arrangements to Borrow (NAB) for some countries,

mainly the United States, and a reallocation of quota and voting shares in the IMF,

especially towards developing countries. (2) An amendment to provide an all-

elected executive board6. (3) An understanding that the “advanced” European

countries would reduce their representation on the 24-person executive board from

the current eight or nine seats by two seats7.

More importantly, changes in quotas shares proposed in the package meant

decreasing participation of countries like the USA (-0,28%), United Kingdom and

France (-0,27), Germany (-0,50%) and Japan (-0,10%), while countries like China

would increase their shares by 2.26% and Brazil by 0,5%. In the years following the

2010 announcements, however, changes have been much more modest, and some

are even going in the opposite direction. In both organizations developed countries

have increasedtheir voting power relative to GDP. The current voting shares (early

2014) of developing countries are significantly lower than what was agreed in 2010

- 3.11% lower in the Bank, and 2.54% lower in the Fund (Truman 2014,

Vestergaardand Wade 2014).

For Vestergaard and Wade (2014), the notion of relative country economic

weight is at the core of the stalemate. The default position for most countries

6Currently, the five IMF members with the largest quotas are entitled to appoint an executive director: the United States, Japan, Germany, France, and the United Kingdom. Nineteen persons are elected every two years to fill the remaining seats. The voting power of China, Russia, and Saudi Arabia is sufficient to allow each of those countries to elect their own executive directors. The remaining 16 seats are formally contested, but the outcome is normally pre-negotiated (TRUMAN 2014). 7See G-20 Summit Seoul Declaration, October 2010, Paragraph 5.

Page 15: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

15

remains ‘share of world GDP’, mainly because of its simplicity. But the Europeans

insist that integration with the world economy must have great weight in the

formula, along with GDP. Europeans insist they are underrepresented, not

overrepresented – an assertion which provokes much scoffing from other

participants, including the BRICS.

However, criticism to the Seoul package didnot come from Europeans alone.

Since all of these changes were subject to ratification in local legislatives, the most

important challenge came not from Europeans parliaments, who would most likely

loose power with the package, but from the US Congress. Within both the House and

the Senate criticism of the 2010 package reform loomed large and it came in several

shapes. From lending too much to Europeans during the crisis to the apparent

decline of US power in the Executive Board (Truman 2014).

Blocking the Seoul package in the last couple years had interesting

consequences. The US share of the world economy has declined from 23% in 1980

to 19% in 2010. Yet they have chosen to hold 15% of the quota shares and continue

to remain below their share of the World economy, although it is enough votes to

use veto power. The Euro area plus UK's share of the World economy has declined

from 25% of total in 1980 to about 18% in 2010, while their quota share is still

27.5% (2009). For Virmani (2012) there is another very important fact that is often

obscured, sometimes deliberately in the debates. The financial contribution of the

"Rest of the World", including BRICS countries, has increased by 10% from 33.8% in

the 1980s to 43.4% in the 2000s.That is, the traditional power not only still holds on

to their quotas share, but they are also decreasing their financial contribution to the

organizations.

In short, these circumstances only reinforce the idea that Europe, Japan and

the US have full control of quotas reforms. Even when developed countries agree on

some changes, whether it is at the Annual Meetings or at a G20 Meeting, their local

legislatives block further reforms. Moreover, Europeans insist in a loose

interpretation of the GDP weight in the quotas calculus. It is quite obvious that

traditional powers still have an overwhelming control over the decision-making

Page 16: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

16

process. This impressive grip over the rules of the game has been labeled as “the art

of power maintenance” (Wade2013).

Other things being equal, the more institutionalized the organizations - and

the IMF and the World Bank are probably the most institutionalized financial IOs in

the world - the more they are to persist in the face of environmental change. Europe

and US having de facto veto power makes reforms almost impossible to accomplish,

especially if they mean decreasing their relative power8 . The initial power

distribution during the formation of Bretton-Woodsinstitutions has created super-

majority rules that solidifies the initial uneven power in a way that makes almost

impossible for developing countries to foster deep reforms despite the new power

distribution in the international system. This makes the Bretton Woods institutions

almost impenetrable from either exogenous shocks or internal transformation when

comes to power redistribution. But it also means that the costs of institution

maintenance for developing countries are increasing while their vote shares

decreasing.

The excessive control of traditional powers over the decision-making process

is not the only negative aspect affecting developing countries.The inefficiency of

their economic policies is another important factor. The debate on the consequences

of IMF conditionality programs and World Bank development projects is

controversial910, but the literature shows that IMF’s conditionality programs are

more negative than beneficial to countries that request them (Dreher 2009).

Vreeland finds that IMF programs reduce economic growth in the short run, without

producing any compensating long-term benefits. Further, IMF programs lower

wages, redistributing income to the owners of capital (Vreeland2003,

Przeworskiand Vreeland 2000). And since IMF policies are very

8The literature showing the US and G-7 influence on the decision-making process of the IMF and the World Bank is long: Dreher, Sturm and Vreeland 2009a and 2009b, Kaja and Werker 2009, Thacker 1999,Gould 2003, Oatley and Yackee 2004, and Stone 2002. 9The literature on the conditionality is vast. It seams to be the most controversial subject of the IMF and to a lesser extent to the World Bank. Important works on this subject are Williamson 1983, Bird 1995, Vreeland 2003 and 2007,Przeworskiand Vreeland 2000, Gould 2003a and 2003b,Polak 1991, Babb and Buria 2004, and Dreher 2009. 10On the discussions of World Bank’s development projects see Guimarães 2012 and Weaver 2008.

Page 17: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

17

comprehensive,influencing a variety of economic and social policies, World Bank’s

developmental programs are also affected by its inefficiency, despite World Bank’s

effort to improve programs ownership11 (Weaver 2008).

Indeed, the fact that such policies are inefficient affects not only BRICS

countries, but also all members and institutions credibility. However, BRICS

countries are dealing with a decision-making process in which their input has a

minor effect.As a matter of fact, BRICS countries usually feel left out when comes to

design such policies, especially at the IMF. There are two additional reasons for

BRICS to feel excluded: Senior Management and bureaucracies composition. The

literature shows that G-7 countries control the selection process of Senior

Management candidates, as well as the selection of bureaucrats in both institutions,

particularly at the IMF (Guimarães 2012, Babb 2003, Babb and Buria 2004, Birdsall

2002). The directors and economists hired by these institutions are responsible for

designing and implementing such policies. If the G-7 controls how these employees

are selected, it is less likely that BRICS countries will have leverage to decide. Biased

employees tend to favor G-7 views to the detriment of BRICS countries.

Our argument, therefore, is that endogenous causes of new institutional

making are the sum of (1)policy design control, and (2) decision-making control by

G-7 countries. Facing a situation in which influencing the results is very limited,

BRICS countries started to perceive these institutions as not only biased towards G-

7 countries, but also expensive to maintain in the long run. The shadow of the future

for cooperation, as put it by Keohane and Axelrod (1986), seemednegative, allowing

them to look for institutional alternatives.

3. The Empirical Patterns of the BRICS Bank creation:

The BRICS Bank formation is twofold: the simultaneous creation of the CRA

(Contingent Reserve Arrangement) and the NDB (New Development Bank). The CRA

is a stabilization fund of US$ 100 billion in reserves shared by the respective central

11 Policy ownership means that the recipient is responsible not only for the implementation, but also for the program design.

Page 18: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

18

banks whose main goal is to provide emergency resources during balance of

payment crisis of any of its members. Indeed, the CRA is a coordinated central bank

fundset up to provide mutual liquidity during crisis. The contribution of China for

the CRA is around US$ 40 billon,while Brazil, India, and Russia contribute around

US$ 18 billon each, and South Africa close to US$ 10 billion. It is agreed that China

contribution will never exceed 50% of the fund. The CRA is still far from IMF’s in

terms of lending capacity. Before the 2008 economic crisis the IMF lending capacity

was around US$ 250 billion. In 2014 is reaching US$ 1 trillion.In turn, the NDB aims

to finance investment in infrastructure in BRICS and other emerging economies.

Based on a diagnostic that sources for infrastructure are very limited and their

needs on this area tremendous, BRICS countries decided to make the case for a

major step in investment in infrastructurethat will foster economic growth. The

initial NDB’s fund is about US$ 50 billion, having each member depositing US$ 10

billion per year. The current World Bank lending capacity per year is US$ 50 billion.

The history of the BRICS Bank starts in 2009 during the first BRIC Summit in

Yekaterinburg, Russia. Although the official joint statement is broad and superficial

there is an important paragraph showing BRIC countries (South Africa was not yet a

member) unsatisfied with the reforms at Bretton-Woods institutions:

“We are committed to advance the reform of international financial institutions, so as to reflect

changes in the world economy. The emerging and developing economies must have greater voice and

representation in international financial institutions, and their heads and senior leadership should be

appointed through an open, transparent, and merit-based selection process”12.

At the same time,BRIC countries were involved in dealing with the effects of

the 2008 financial crisis and the G-20 seemed to be the best forum to tackle the

issue.Although it was not central to the agenda, the reform of the IMF/World

Bankappeared at the Summit Declaration in London, April 2009. The G-20 had

committed to implement the 2008 IMF package of quota and voice reforms:

12 See I BRIC Summit, Yekaterinburg Declaration, June 2009, Paragraph 3.

Page 19: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

19

“We commit to implementing the package of IMF quota and voice reforms agreed in April 2008 and call on the IMF to complete the next review of quotas by January 2011 (…) we commit to implementing the World Bank reforms agreed in October 2008. We look forward to further recommendations, at the next meetings, on voice and representation reforms on an accelerated timescale, to be agreed by the 2010 Spring Meetings”13.

In April 2010 during the II BRIC Summit in Brasilia, BRIC countries decided

to stress out more boldly the need for reforms at Bretton-Woods, arguing that they

contributed tremendously to increase the lending capacity of the IMF, especially

China, but the institution had not yet reformed itself:

“We will strive to achieve an ambitious conclusion to the ongoing and long overdue reforms of the Bretton Woods institutions. The IMF and the World Bank urgently need to address their legitimacy deficits. Reforming these institutions’ governance structures requires first and foremost a substantial shift in voting power in favor of emerging market economies and developing countries to bring their participation in decision-making in line with their relative weight in the world economy (…) We do also agree on the need for an open and merit based selection method, irrespective of nationality, for the heading positions of the IMF and the World Bank. Moreover, staff of these institutions needs to better reflect the diversity of their membership (…) The international community must deliver a result worthy of the expectations we all share for these institutions within the agreed timeframe or run the risk of seeing them fade into obsolescence”14.

The coming G-20 meeting in Seoul, Korea must have had effect on BRICS

intentions towards reforming Bretton-Woods. One of the byproducts of that meeting

was going to be the “Seoul package” mentioned above.So in April 2011 in Sanya,

China the BRICS Summit Declaration does not mention a single time the reforms.

They only stress the need for G-20 to continue its effort to stabilize the world

economy15. The same effect can be seen at the 2011 G-20 Cannes Declaration where

the reform are not even mentioned16.

In March 2012 BRICS countries met again in New Delhi. By then the quota

reform seemed to be back in agenda. As the Seoul package had received criticism

and developed countries were blocking its approval, BRICS countries restarted their

demand for change showing concern at the slow pace of reforms:

13See G-20 Summit, London Declaration, April 2009, Paragraph 20. 14See II BRIC Summit, Brasilia Declaration, April 2010, Paragraph 11. 15See III BRICS Summit, Sanya Declaration, April 2011, Paragraph 14. 16See G-20 Cannes Declaration, November 2011.

Page 20: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

20

“We are however concerned at the slow pace of quota and governance reforms in the IMF. We see an urgent need to implement, as agreed, the 2010 Governance and Quota Reform before the 2012 IMF/World Bank Annual Meeting, as well as the comprehensive review of the quota formula to better reflect economic weights and enhance the voice and representation of emerging market and developing countries by January 2013, followed by the completion of the next general quota review by January 2014. This dynamic process of reform is necessary to ensure the legitimacy and effectiveness of the Fund. We stress that the ongoing effort to increase the lending capacity of the IMF will only be successful if there is confidence that the entire membership of the institution is truly committed to implement the 2010 Reform faithfully. We will work with the international community to ensure that sufficient resources can be mobilized to the IMF in a timely manner as the Fund continues its transition to improve governance and legitimacy. We reiterate our support for measures to protect the voice and representation of the IMF’s poorest members”17.

In Los Cabos, Mexico G-20 countries pushed again for the reforms. It seems

that BRICS countries had showed their dissatisfaction in the meeting pushing for

stronger words at the final declaration:

“We reaffirm our commitment to implement in full the 2010 Quota and Governance Reform by

the agreed date of the 2012 IMF/World Bank Annual Meetings. These reforms are crucial to enhancing the IMF’s legitimacy, relevance and effectiveness, and will support efforts to further strengthen Fund surveillance and to ensure that the IMF is adequately resourced to play its systemic role. As part of these reforms, we are committed to completing the comprehensive review of the quota formula, to address deficiencies and weaknesses in the current quota formula, by January 2013 and to complete the next general review of quotas by January 2014. We agree that the formula should be simple and transparent, consistent with the multiple roles of quotas, result in calculated shares that are broadly acceptable to the membership, and be feasible to implement based on timely, high quality and widely available data. We reaffirm that the distribution of quotas based on the formula should better reflect the relative weights of IMF members in the world economy, which have changed substantially in view of strong GDP growth in dynamic emerging markets and developing countries”18.

The G-20 efforts were in vain. As we mentioned before, by 2013 the US

Congress started to block the Seoul package using a plethora of arguments against it.

The long overdue reform was once more in peril. BRICS countries reacted in March

2013 at their conference in Durham, South Africa. Anticipating the G-20 meeting

that would take place in St. Petersburg later that year, BRICS countries decided to

create two institutions at the same time. According to the Durham Declaration the

decision to create the CRA happened in Los Cabos in 2012 and it was taking shape in

Durham:

17 See IV BRICS Summit, Delhi Declaration, March 2011, Paragraph 9. 18 See G-20 Summit, Los Cabos Declaration, June 2012, Paragraph 33.

Page 21: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

21

“In June 2012, in our meeting in Los Cabos, we tasked our Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors to explore the construction of a financial safety net through the creation of a Contingent Reserve Arrangement (CRA) amongst BRICS countries. They have concluded that the establishment of a self-managed contingent reserve arrangement would have a positive precautionary effect, help BRICS countries forestall short-term liquidity pressures, provide mutual support and further strengthen financial stability. It would also contribute to strengthening the global financial safety net and complement existing international arrangements as an additional line of defense. We are of the view that the establishment of the CRA with an initial size of US$ 100 billion is feasible and desirable subject to internal legal frameworks and appropriate safeguards”19.

In the same meeting BRICS decided to move forward on the preparations to

create a new development bank to finance infrastructure:

“In March 2012 we directed our Finance Ministers to examine the feasibility and viability of

setting up a New Development Bank for mobilizing resources for infrastructure and sustainable development projects in BRICS and other emerging economies and developing countries, to supplement the existing efforts of multilateral and regional financial institutions for global growth and development. Following the report from our Finance Ministers, we are satisfied that the establishment of a New Development Bank is feasible and viable. We have agreed to establish the New Development Bank. The initial contribution to the Bank should be substantial and sufficient for the Bank to be effective in financing infrastructure”20.

The NDB and CRA institutional designs and their lending capabilities would

only take form at the Fortaleza meeting in July 2014.In the preparation or that

meeting, a high Brazilian diplomat and one of the responsible for the negotiations

declared that the creation of new financial institutions were linked to the lack of

reforms in Bretton-Woods:

“BRICS proposals to reform the IMF and the World Bank are not been taking into consideration for well know reasons. In a way, the creation of the CRA and NDB will accomplish this necessity (…). As the bank and the arrangement mirror the World Bank and the IMF, their creation show that BRICS countries do not depend anymore on Bretton-Woods”21.

In July 2014, BRICS officially created two new international institutions.

Firstly, the NDB was born with an initial authorized capital of US$ 100 billion and a

subscribed capital of US$ 50 billion divided equally among its members. Mimicking

the World Bank they also created the Board of Governors, the Executive Board, and

the Senior Management whose first presidents are going to be Russian, Brazilian,

19 See V BRICS Summit, Durham Declaration, March 2013, Paragraph 10. 20See V BRICS Summit, Durham Declaration, March 2013, Paragraph 9. 21 See “Banco dos BRICS é a resposta a falta de mudança no FMI”, Valor Econômico, July 09th 2014.

Page 22: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

22

and Indian respectively. The headquarters of the bank shall be located in Shanghai,

China and a regional office is going t be open in South Africa. In the declaration

BRICS make clear that theory goal is to expand to number of members in the near

future.Secondly, the CRAwas born with a US$ 100 billion provision. The agreement

is a framework for the provision of liquidity through currency swaps in response to

actual or potential short-term balance of payments pressures22. On contrary to the

NDB, the CRA will not expand its membership at a first moment. The idea is to have

an “IMF miniature” for the five countries as an alternative to the IMF in case of

balance of payment crisis, as pointed out by a Brazilian diplomat23.

The decision-making process of the new institution is still under

constructions, but certainly will represent more equally the power of founding

countries. There is some evidence that, in the case of the NDB, each founding

country will have an equal share varying from 10% to 20% of the votes, more than

double of what they currently have at the Bretton Woods Institutions.For important

decisions, such as increasing the capital or new memberships, four out of five votes

(2/3) of funding countries are necessary.The possibility of China becoming too

powerful is taking into consideration to not unbalance to distribution of power

within the institution. The reforms were not forgotten in the declaration. Showing

grave concern on their delay BRICS countries continue to push for changes:

“We remain disappointed and seriously concerned with the current non-implementation of the 2010 International Monetary Fund (IMF) reforms, which negatively impacts on the IMF’s legitimacy, credibility and effectiveness. The IMF reform process is based on high-level commitments, which already strengthened the Fund's resources and must also lead to the modernization of its governance structure so as to better reflect the increasing weight of developing countries in the world economy (…) We reiterate our call on the IMF to develop options to move ahead with its reform process, with a view to ensuring increased voice and representation of developing countries, in case the 2010 reforms are not entered into force by the end of the year. We also call on the membership of the IMF to reach a final agreement on a new quota formula together with the 15th General Review of Quotas so as not to further jeopardize the postponed deadline of January 2015”24.

This chain of events reinforces our argument that the lack of reforms created

the possibility to new institutional making. After repeated delays in implementing

22 See VI BRICS Summit, Fortaleza Declaration, July 2014, Paragraphs 11, 12 and 13. 23 See interview Ambassador Flávio Damico, July 10th 2014. 24See VI BRICS Summit, Fortaleza Declaration, July 2014, Paragraph 18.

Page 23: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

23

reforms, BRICS countries changed the strategy seeking for institutional alternatives.

In this sense, the creation of BRICS Bank represents a concrete example of what has

been called by the literature a “two-pronged approach” in international relations. In

order to overcome stalemates and increase the effectiveness and legitimacy of the

established architecture, the BRICS have two basic options, which are not mutually

exclusive. The first route involves acting within the system: that is, using their

membership in established institutions in order to push for structural reforms. The

second strategy entails the creation of new institutions so as to increase the

pressure for reform of established institutions – or, in certain cases, to bypass them

altogether (Abdenur, Esteves and Gama, 2014).

It is important to stress out that BRICS countries will not exit the IMF or the

World Bank. On the contrary, it islikely they will continue to seek for internal

reforms, as the Fortaleza Declaration shows it, but they will the new institutionsas

an additionalargument to push for different type of reforms. That is, they will

probably argue that the slow process of reformonly pushes them to seek for

financial help outside the IMF and World Bank, automatically decreasing their

importance and increasing the centrality of the BRICS Bankin the international

financial system. The demise of Bretton Woods’s institutions is not in question, but

only their relative decline.

4. Conclusions:

The casual pathways lead to the following predictions:

Prediction 1# - if powerful exogenous shocks change the balance of power

within the status quo institutions, unsatisfied countries will seek for internal

Page 24: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

24

reforms (casual pathway 01, 02 and 03).

Prediction 2# - if institutional reform is non-existent because dominant

powers control the decision-making process, unsatisfied countries will seek

for a institutional alternative (casual pathway 04 and 05).

Prediction 3# - if a new institutions is created by the rising powers that

would give them extra power within status quo institutions to push for

reforms (casual pathway 06).

5. References:

Abbott, Kenneth and Snidal, Duncan. (1998).Why States Act through Formal International

Organization. The Journal of Conflict Resolution. Vol. 42, No. 1, pp. 3-32. Abbott, Kenneth and Snidal, Duncan. (2006).Nesting, Overlap and Parallelism: Governance

Schemes for International Production Standards. Memo for Alter-Meunier Princeton Nesting Conference, February 2006. Abdenur, Adriana, Esteves, Paulo and Gama, Carlos.(2014). BRICS and Global Governance: a two-

pronged approach. Papers of the Fifth BRICS Academic Forum Partnership for Development, Integration & Industrials. Aggarwal, Vinod. (1998).Institutional Designs for a Complex World: Bargaining, Linkages, and

Nesting.Cornell: Cornell University Press. Aoki, Masahiko.(2007).Endogenizing institutions and institutional changes.Journal of Institutional Economics. Vol. 3, No. 1, pp. 1-31. Armijo, Leslie. (2007). The BRICS countries as Analytical Category: mirage or insight? Asian Perspective Vol. 31, No. 4, pp. 7-42. Armijo, Leslie and Roberts, Cynthia. (2014). The Emerging Powers and Global Governance: why

BRICS matter. Robert Looney (ed.). Handbook of Emerging Economies. New York: Routledge. Axelrod, Robert and Keohane, Robert. (1985).Achieving Cooperation Under Anarchy.World Politics, Vol. 38, No. 1, pp. 226-254. Babb, Sarah. (2003).The IMF in sociological perspective: a tale of organizational

slippage.Studies in Comparative International Development, v. 38, n. 2, p. 3-27. Babb, Sarah and Buria, Ariel. (2004).Mission creep, mission push and discretion in sociological

perspective: the case of IMF conditionality.G24 Technical Group Meeting, XVIII Paper.

Page 25: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

25

Ban, Cornel and Blyth, Mark. (2013).The BRICs and the WashingtonConsensus: An

introduction.Review of International Political Economy, Vol. 20, No. 2, pp. 241-255. Barnett, Michael and Coleman, Liv. (2005).Designing police: Interpol and the study of change in

international organizations. International Studies Quarterly, v. 49, n. 4, pp. 593-620. Barnett, Michael and Finnemore, Martha. (1999).The politics and pathologies of international

organizations.International Organization, Vol. 53, No. 4, p. 699-732. Bird, Graham. (1995).IMF lending to developing countries: issues and evidence. London: Routledge. Bird, Graham and Rowlands, Dane. (2006).IMF quotas: constructing an IO using inferior building

blocks. Review of International Organization, Vol. 1, No. 2, pp. 153-171. Birdsall, Nancy. (2002).Why it matters who runs the IMF and the World Bank. Washington, DC: Center for Global Development.Working Paper, No. 22. Boughton, James. (2001).The silent revolution: the IMF 1979-1989. Washington, DC:IMF Press. Brutsch, Christian and Papa, Mihaela. (2013). Deconstructing the BRICS: Bargaining Coalition,

Imagined Community, or Geopolitical Fad? The Chinese Journal of International Politics, Vol. 6, pp. 299-327. Bryant, Ralph. (2008). Reform of IMF Quota Shares and Voting Shares: A Missed Opportunity. Washington, DC: Brooking Institution paper. Buira, Ariel.(2002).A new voting structure for the IMF. Washington, DC: Group of 24. Buira, Ariel. (2003).The governance of the IMF. Conceição, P. et al. (ed.). Providingpublic goods: managing globalization. New York: UNDP Press, pp. 225-244. Cheng, Hui, et al. (2007).A future global economy to be built by BRICs.Global Finance Journal, Vol. 18, pp.143-156. Cox, Robert and Jacobson, Harold. (1974).The anatomy of influence: the decision making in

international organizations. New Haven: Yale University Press. De Vries, Margaret.(1986).The IMF in a changing world (1945-1985).Washington, DC: IMF Press. Dreher, Axel. (2009).IMF conditionality: theory and evidence. Public Choice No. 141, pp. 233-267 Dreher, Axel, Sturm, Jan-Egbert and Vreeland, James (2009a).Development aid and international

politics: does membership on the UN Security Council influence World Bank decisions? Journal of Political Economics, No. 88, pp. 1-18. Dreher, Axel, Sturm, Jan-Egbert andVreeland, James. (2009b). Global horse trading: IMF loans for

votes in the UN Security Council.European Economic Review, No. 3, p. 742-757. Gaddy, Clifford and Ickes, Barry.(2010).Russia after the Global Financial Crisis.EurasianGeography and Economics, Vol. 51, No. 3, pp. 281-311. Goldstein, Judith, et al. (2000).Introduction: Legalization and World Politics. International Organization, Vol. 54, No. 3, pp. 385-399.

Page 26: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

26

Gould, Erica. (2003a).When IOs influence each other: has the World Bank expanded Fund

conditionality?Paper presented at the APSA. Gould, Erica. (2003b).Money talks: supplementary financiers and IMF conditionality. International Organization, Vol. 57, No. 3, pp. 551-586. Greif, Avner and Laitin, David.(2004).A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change. American Political Science Review Vol. 98, No. 4, pp. 633-652. Griffith-Jones, Stephany. (2014). BRICS Development Bank: a dream coming true?UNCTAD Discussion Paper, No. 215. Guimarães, Feliciano. (2012). OsBurocratas das OrganizaçõesFinanceirasInternacionais: um

estudocomparado entre FMI e Banco Mundial. Rio de Janeiro: Editora da FGV. Haftel, Yoram and Thompson, Alexander. (2006). The Independence of International

Organizations: concepts and applications. The Journal of Conflict Resolution, Vol. 50, No. 2, pp. 253-275. Hall, Peter.(2010).Historical institutionalism in rationalist and sociological perspective.James Mahoney and Kathleen Thelen.(ed.) Explaining Institutional Change Ambiguity, Agency, and Power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Hawkins, D. et al. (ed.). (2006).Delegation and agency in international organizations.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Jupille, Joseph and Snidal, Duncan. (2006) The Choice of International Institutions: Cooperation,

Alternatives and Strategies.Jupille, Joseph, Walter Mattli and Duncan Snidal, 2013, Institutional Choice and Global Commerce. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Kaja, Ashwin and Werker, Eric.(2009). Corporate misgovernance at the World Bank.Harvard Business School Working Paper, 108. Keohane, Robert. (1984). After hegemony: cooperation and discord in the world

politics.Princeton: Princeton University Press. Keohane, Robert and Martin, Lisa. (1995). The promise of institutionalist theory. International Security, Vol. 20, No. 1, pp. 39-51. Keohane, Robert and Martin, Lisa.(2003). Institutional theory. Elman, Colin and Elman, Mirian. (Ed.).Progress in international relations theory: appraising the field. New York: MIT Press, pp. 71-108. Kingston, Christopher and Caballero, Gonzalo.(2009). Comparing Theories of Institutional

Change.Journal of Institutional Economics. Vol. 5, No. 2, pp. 151-180. Koremenos, Barbara et al. (2001). The Rational Design of International Institutions. International Organization, Vol. 55, No. 4, pp. 761-799. Mahoney, James and Thelen, Kathleen.(2010). A theory of gradual institutional change.Mahoney, James and Thelen, Kathleen. (ed.) Explaining Institutional Change Ambiguity, Agency, and Power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mearsheimer, John. (1995). The False Promise of International Institutions. International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3, pp. 5-49.

Page 27: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

27

Morrow, James. (1994). Modeling the Forms of International Cooperation: distribution versus

information. International Organization, Vol. 48, No. 3, pp. 387-423. Oatley, Thomas and Yackee, Jason. (2004). Political determinants of IMF balance of payments

lending.Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill. Ostrom, Elinor. (2005). Understanding Institutional Diversity. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Polak, Jacques. (1991). The changing nature of IMF conditionality. Essay in InternationalFinance, No. 184. Przeworski, Adam and Vreeland, James. (2000). The effect of the IMF programs on economic

growth. Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 62, No. 2, pp. 385-421. Shanks, Cheryl et al. (1996).Inertia and change in the constellation of IGO’s. International Organization, Vol. 50, No. 4, pp. 593-627. Stein, Arthur (1983). Coordination and collaboration: regimes in an anarchic world. Krasner, Stephen. (Ed.). International regimes. Ithaca: Cornell University Press, pp. 115-140. Stone, Randall. (2002). Lending credibility: the IMF and the post-communist transition. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Swedberg, Richard. (1986).The doctrine of economic neutrality of the IMF and the World

Bank.Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 23, No. 4, pp. 377-390. Sweet, Alec et al.(2001). The Institutionalization of Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Thacker, Strom. (1999). The high politics of IMF lending. World Politics, Vol. 52, No. 1, pp. 38-75. Truman, Edwin.(2014). IMF Reform Is Waiting on the United States. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics, PB 14-9. Van de Graaf, Thijs and Lesage, Dries. (2009). The International Energy Agency after 35 years:

Reform needs and institutional adaptability. Review of International Organization, No. 4, pp. 293-317. Vestergaard, Jakob. (2011). The World Bank and the Emerging Order: adjusting to multipolarity

at the second decimal point. DIIS Report, No. 05. Vestergaard, Jakob and Wade, Robert. (2012). Establishing a new Global Economic Council:

governance reform at the G20, the IMF and the World Bank. Global Policy, Vol. 3, No. 3, pp. 257-269. Vestergaard, Jakob and Wade, Robert. (2014). Out of the woods: Gridlock in the IMF, and the

World Bank puts multilateralism at risk. DIIS Report, No. 06. Virmani, Arvind. (2012). Quota formula reform is about IMF credibility. Mimeo Vreeland, James (2003).The IMF and economic development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Page 28: The Bretton-Woods Institutions and the BRICS Bank: an

28

Vreeland, James. (2007).The International Monetary Fund: politics of conditional lending. New York: Routledge. Wade, Robert. (2013). The Art of Power Maintenance: How Western States Keep the Lead in

Global Organizations. Challenge, vol. 56, no. 1, pp. 5-39. Wallander, Celeste. (2000). Institutional Assets and Adaptability: NATO After the Cold War. International Organization, Vol. 54, No. 4, pp. 705-735. Weaver, Catherine. (2008).Hypocrisy trap: the World Bank and the poverty reform. Princeton:Princeton University Press. Williamson, John.(1983). IMF conditionality. Washington, DC: Institute for InternationalEconomics. Woods, Ngaire. (2000). The challenge of good governance in the IMF and the World Bank

themselves. World Development, Vol. 28, No. 5, pp. 823-841. Woods.Ngaire. (2010). Global Governance after the Financial Crisis: A New Multilateralism or

the Last Gasp of the Great Powers?Global Policy Vol. No. 1.