9
TEACHING TOOLS: TEACHING METHODS IN UNDERGRADUATE ECONOMICS WILLIAM E. BECKER and MICHAEL WATTS* Lectures have long been the dominant pedagogical approach in undergraduate eco- nomics courses, but they are certainly no longer the exclusive approach. Much 4 the recent soul-searching in the discipline, dealing with the desirable characteristics 4 economics programs and their graduates, has largely ignored the issue of promoting the use of innovative and more active forms of teaching and learning. We reuiew a considerable literature on new teaching approaches, developed by economists over the past twenty-five years, and argue that this should also be a part of the current debate about curriculum and training r+ms for the profession. I. INTRODUCTION In 1970 Nobel Laureate George Stigler argued that ”economics belongs in everyone’s education once we have learned how to teach it.” But because the logic of economics is not easy to learn or teach, he concluded that ”Economics is not yet ready to be made a part of the basic curriculum of all educated men” [p. 801. We now have new models for teaching economics. In fact, as in other areas of economics, we have competing models, with new approaches being offered to sup- plement extensively, if not replace entirely, the lecture pedagogy used nearly exclu- sively by economists at the time Stigler’s comments were published. Yet in major Commission and Committee reports and daily conversations held in faculty lounges around the world, alternatives to the lecture approach, in which the teacher often serves as a preacher and students as passive receptacles into which great thoughts and wisdom are poured, still . * Professors of Economics at Indiana University and Purdue University, respectively. Becker is the Ed- itor and Watts the Associate Editor for the Instruction Section of the Journal 4 Economic Education. appear to be either unknown or tacitly dismissed as unworkable. In this journal, for example, McCloskey [1992] tells of an exchange between George Stigler and Milton Friedman. Friedman argued that while individuals pursue their self-interest they are often ignorant and require education to see that something they thought was in their per- sonal or national interest was not-e.g., tariffs and quotas. Stigler called Friedman a preacher. He argued that people find their own self-interest with or without education, and that no amount of preach- ing or lecturing about economics would change that self-interest. In the “Report of the Commission on Graduate Education in Economics” by Krueger et al. [19911, considerableattention was given to bringing “real-world issues into the classroom.” But the Commission’s assumed instructional mode was still the lecture: It is our impression that most Ph.D. programs devote little or no attention to teaching or encouraging the devel- opment of expository sk &....We suspect the lack of emphasis on communication in most Ph.D. programs reflects partly the scarcity of teaching time, partly Economic Inquiry (ISSN 0095-2583) Vol. XXXIII, October 1995,692-700 692 @Western Economic Association International

TEACHING TOOLS: TEACHING METHODS IN UNDERGRADUATE ECONOMICS

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

TEACHING TOOLS: TEACHING METHODS IN UNDERGRADUATE ECONOMICS

WILLIAM E. BECKER and MICHAEL WATTS*

Lectures have long been the dominant pedagogical approach in undergraduate eco- nomics courses, but they are certainly no longer the exclusive approach. Much 4 the recent soul-searching in the discipline, dealing with the desirable characteristics 4 economics programs and their graduates, has largely ignored the issue of promoting the use o f innovative and more active forms of teaching and learning. We reuiew a considerable literature on new teaching approaches, developed by economists over the past twenty-five years, and argue that this should also be a part o f the current debate about curriculum and training r+ms for the profession.

I. INTRODUCTION

In 1970 Nobel Laureate George Stigler argued that ”economics belongs in everyone’s education once we have learned how to teach it.” But because the logic of economics is not easy to learn or teach, he concluded that ”Economics is not yet ready to be made a part of the basic curriculum of all educated men” [p. 801. We now have new models for teaching economics. In fact, as in other areas of economics, we have competing models, with new approaches being offered to sup- plement extensively, if not replace entirely, the lecture pedagogy used nearly exclu- sively by economists at the time Stigler’s comments were published. Yet in major Commission and Committee reports and daily conversations held in faculty lounges around the world, alternatives to the lecture approach, in which the teacher often serves as a preacher and students as passive receptacles into which great thoughts and wisdom are poured, still

. * Professors of Economics at Indiana University and Purdue University, respectively. Becker is the Ed- itor and Watts the Associate Editor for the Instruction Section of the Journal 4 Economic Education.

appear to be either unknown or tacitly dismissed as unworkable.

In this journal, for example, McCloskey [1992] tells of an exchange between George Stigler and Milton Friedman. Friedman argued that while individuals pursue their self-interest they are often ignorant and require education to see that something they thought was in their per- sonal or national interest was not-e.g., tariffs and quotas. Stigler called Friedman a preacher. He argued that people find their own self-interest with or without education, and that no amount of preach- ing or lecturing about economics would change that self-interest.

In the “Report of the Commission on Graduate Education in Economics” by Krueger et al. [19911, considerable attention was given to bringing “real-world issues into the classroom.” But the Commission’s assumed instructional mode was still the lecture:

It is our impression that most Ph.D. programs devote little or no attention to teaching or encouraging the devel- opment of expository sk &....We suspect the lack of emphasis on communication in most Ph.D. programs reflects partly the scarcity of teaching time, partly

Economic Inquiry (ISSN 0095-2583) Vol. XXXIII, October 1995,692-700

692

@Western Economic Association International

BECKER & WATTS: TEACHING UNDERGRADUATE ECONOMICS 693

instructors’ lack of confidence in their ability to teach communications skills, and partly a judgment that the ap- propriate style of professional commu- nication is something students can figure out for themselves by watching their teachers. [p. 10491

The report of the Committee on College Faculty by Kasper et al. 119911, represent- ing the nation’s premiere liberal arts col- leges, emphasized the need for breadth in content coverage in economists’ graduate training, but did not even mention the need for breadth in instructional methods, or training in those areas.

Despite these btentional or uninten- tional slights, in literature from the past twenty-five years we found that many economists have spent a great deal of time developing and applying new teaching methods to actively engage students in the learning process. In what follows we sum- marize those alternative approaches to make it easier for others to consider and access these articles on innovative instruc- tional methods in economics.

II. CLASSROOM GAMES, SIMULATIONS, AND LABORATORIES

Although Edward Chamberlin and oth- ers working in the area of imperfect com- petition were developing artificial mar- kets in the classroom as early as the 1940s, Joseph and Saunders I19701 were perhaps the first economists to publish an exten- sive account on how to use such games to teach basic economic concepts. The ap- proach soon proved to be quite popular, at least with the developers of these activ- ities. The National Council on Economic Education (then known as the Joint Coun- cil on Economic Education) published the first edition of its Guide to Games and Simulations for Teaching Economics in 1971, written by Lewis and Wentworth, with references to some ninety different activi- ties and publications.

In recent years commercially published games and simulations in economics have continued to appear, often featuring main-

frame econometric models or microcom- puter programs written specifically as a classroom simulation. Examples of such activities include Blackburn and Case 119851; Gold, Pray, and Dennis [19841; and Lumsden and Scott t19951. Yoho and Walstad t19901 recently published a re- view article on microcomputer software for principles courses.

Perhaps more novel are the articles that have been published to explain the peda- gogical advantages of a particular game or simulation in teaching a certain economic idea or concept, or in overcoming gaps in student understanding that stubbornly persist after traditional textbook and lec- ture treatments. For example, Sulock El9901 described two games used to teach the free-rider problem, voting paradoxes, and the Coase Theorem. Hester [1991] developed an extensive simulation of a commercial banking system for use in large-lecture money and banking courses at the University of Wisconsin. Hemenway, Moore, and Whitney [1987] describe an oligopoly/cartel game that can be played in one class period, even by students who have no prior knowledge of oligopoly theory. Halstead [1989] devel- oped a short simulation of central plan- ning processes and problems. Yoho [1989] reviewed classroom exercises featuring the Fairmodel, which replicate different periods of recent U.S. economic history, involve students in sessions of economic forecasting, and simulate the effects of alternative macroeconomic stabilization policies.

Bartlett and King 119901 described far more extensive, department-wide experi- ences in setting up a computer laboratory for use in several different undergraduate economics courses at Denison University, under funding provided by the National Science Foundation. Some simulations are used in this laboratory, but there is also a concentrated effort to have students “gather their own data or use existing data bases to contribute to their own learning.

694 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

Students confront real problems, make de- cisions, and suggest policy actions in the laboratory” [p. 1861.

111. EXPERIMENTAL ECONOMICS

As Vernon Smith has noted 11981,369- 701, much of the earliest work in the young field of experimental economics was in- spired both by Chamberlain’s games on imperfect competition and as a way to introduce or partially replace traditional lectures on supply and demand in princi- ples courses. The experimental framework usually lends a different cast to these classroom exercises than is seen in tradi- tional games and simulations, to be sure; but largely because of the direct linkages to ongoing research programs, experimen- tal economics appears to be a fertile new source of pedagogical innovations. In fact, the Fall 1993 issue of the Journal of Eco- nomic Education is devoted entirely to a collection of articles describing new class- room games and simulations developed out of the experimental economics frame- work.

Williams and Walker [1993] describe a computerized application of experimental economics developed at Indiana Univer- sity, in which students first act as monop- olists facing an uncertain demand curve, then as producers who must allocate an endowment of productive resources be- tween a private good and a public good, and finally as traders in a market for a financial asset that yields an uncertain return over a long time horizon. Class- room experiments developed by Leuthold I19931 at the University of Illinois and Brock [1991] at the U.S. Air Force Acad- emy demonstrate the free-rider problem; and a trading activity developed by Wil- liams [1993] at Guilford College has stu- dents experience the effects of diverse skills, aptitudes, effort, and initial resource endowments in determining patterns of wealth distribution.

The April 1993 issue of Economic Inquiry features an article by Daniel Levy and

Mark Bergen that describes a multi- product barter trading experiment, which has been used successfully at the Univer- sity of Minnesota, the University of Cali- fornia-Irvine, Pepperdine University, the University of Chicago, and Union College. The experiment demonstrates the role and functions of money, for example by using ice cubes to show the desirability of a currency being made out of substances that are durable and stable.

After reviewing twelve articles on the classroom use of experimental economics, Fels [ 19931 offered an interesting summary and critique of these classroom activities:

It was natural that those doing exper- imental research would use experiments in their teaching and hold workshops to spread the word about their method. They have the skills to do it without excessive work, and there are spillovers in both directions .... The question now is what, if anything, do their accom- plishments ... have to contribute to other economics teachers.

In particular, Fels asked if the experi- mental economists had overcome the high start-up costs of giving up the lecture method in order to make greater pedagog- ical use of experiments and related class- room activities, and whether they offered evidence that students learned more by doing so, or responded more favorably to these instructional methods. He con- cluded that “the cost has been reduced to manageable proportions for some experi- ments but not others,” and that ”NO seri- ous attempt ... has been made to evaluate any of them” [p. 3651.

To further reduce start-up costs for economists who want to begin using ex- perimental economics in their teaching, since 1985 the National Science Founda- tion has funded summer training pro- grams at the Economic Science Library at the University of Arizona. The classroom activities featured in this program are briefly described in an article by Wells [1991].

BECKER & WATTS TEACHING UNDERGRADUATE ECONOMICS 695

IV. WRITING ASSIGNMENTS IN ECONOMICS COURSES

One of the latest instructional reform movements appearing on many of the nation’s campuses and in many different subject areas is usually described as “Writ- ing Across the Curriculum.” This ap- proach promotes the development of bet- ter student writing skills in the various content-area courses, not just in first-year English composition classes.

Many economists are clearly sympa- thetic to these goals and methods, and some have written brief articles about their experiences in these programs. Four such articles appeared in a recent issue of the Journal qf Economic Education. In the first, Hansen [19931 describes eight writ- ing assignments-initially rather short and simple, but leading up to much more extensive projects-which he incorpo- rated into a labor economics course taught at the University of Wisconsin. Davidson and Gumnior [19931 describe class projects involving both an economist and a writing specialist as instructors in an international macroeconomics policy course at Indiana University. Cohen and Spencer [19931 re- port on a similar joint effort involving an economist and writing specialist in a his- tory of economic thought course taught at York University. Abdalla 119931 required undergraduate students in international or development economics courses at Illi- nois State University to prepare a series of reports on economic conditions and poli- cies in some nation, and later to expand the reports into more substantial term papers.

Although these authors all report that they and their students were generally pleased with the results of these writing assignments, both in terms of the amount of economics learned and improvements in students’ writing skills, Fels’s com- ments about the papers on experimental economics apply just as well here. Teach- ers with special interests and skills in writing are most likely to undertake and

support this kind of classroom project, and more likely to successfully “sell” the approach to their students. Articles report- ing their experiences with this approach can help to reduce start-up costs and un- certainty facing other instructors who are considering using such an approach; but in many of the more extensive projects (such as those involving “outside” writing specialists) those are still very serious con- cerns. And while there is some anecdotal and student-course-evaluation data lend- ing support to the use of such extensive writing projects, there has been no formal evaluation of gains in student learning under these programs, especially as com- pared to student learning and interest in traditional lecture classes, or across large samples of students and instructors.

V. ECONOMICS IN LITERATURE AND DRAMA

If assignments in economics courses can be used to develop good writing skills and, arguably, improve students’ learning and interest in economics at the same time, perhaps it is not surprising that it has also been claimed that good reading-in the form of literature and drama-can also be used to help students learn more econom- ics, and motivate them to do so. Watts and Smith [1989] provide a list of seventy-five literary passages, written by over forty different authors, dealing with economic concepts and issues. They also review a surprisingly extensive group of academic articles and books dealing with the some- times complementary but often uneasy relationship between the literary and eco- nomic ways of thinking.

Many economists have used literary allusions and epigrams in their articles and textbooks, and under George Stigler’s editorship the Journal of Political Economy began printing a literary excerpt dealing with economics on the back cover of each journal issue. None of this has led, as yet, to a full-blown course or teaching method in undergraduate economics, but the

696 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

seeds for such programs are now avail- able.

VI. THE NOBEL LECTURES AS A TEACHING TOOL

The first Nobel prize in economics was awarded in 1969. Each year, the recipient’s speech (or the recipients’ speeches, if there are multiple winners) is published in Le Prix Nobel and widely reprinted in eco- nomics journals. Since the immediate au- dience for these speeches is made up of many noneconomists, the speeches tend to be nontechnical and suitable for use in undergraduate courses. In fact, reviewing the first twenty-six lectures, delivered from 1969 to 1988, Zahka [19901 concluded that fifteen of the lectures were “readily adaptable to upper-level undergraduate economics courses and honors programs” while the remaining eleven were “espe- cially geared to graduate school students, who are more skilled in econometrics’’ [p. 3971.

VII. TEACHING ECONOMICS WITH THE POPULAR AND BUSINESS PRESS

Turning to more prosaic forms of read- ing and writing, economics has been front- page news on a regular basis through most of this century, and seems to command a larger percentage of the typical daily newspaper’s front page with each passing decade. This has led economists such as Kelley [1983] to offer suggestions on how media reports can be used to help moti- vate and teach economics, and to an article by Marks 119881 offering specific ques- tions and assignments to use in having students deal with the economic concepts presented in a highly controversial article published in The New Republic.

On the other hand, Kennedy [1992] asked not what the press could do for economics, but what economics should be doing to help students better understand articles in the press. He found that five macroeconomic concepts are regularly and prominently featured in business sec- tions of leading national papers, but not

emphasized in macroeconomics text- books. Accordingly, he called for more classroom and textbook coverage on: (1) the discouraged/encouraged worker hypotheses and paradoxical changes in unemployment statistics, (2) the role of inventory levels in macro forecasts of the national economy, (3) effects of money supply growth on the bond market, (4) the effects of inflation in foreign exchange markets, and (5) the effects of interna- tional differences in nominal interest rates on foreign exchange rates.

Actually, the national media has a pro- nounced effect on much of the work econ- omists do, including their undergraduate teaching. For example, the reason so many departments and textbooks teach the prin- ciples of macroeconomics before microe- conomics is that macroeconomic concepts and issues are more frequently discussed in the daily media, and therefore innately more interesting to a larger number of students. This instructional pattern was first popularized by Samuelson’s path- breaking principles textbook in 1948, but that has been somewhat reversed in the past two decades, with many newer text- books and a large number of departments adopting a “micro-first” strategy in order to stress microeconomic concepts as key building blocks for many macroeconomic concepts and issues. The debate over the most effective order is still a lively one, however, and Alan Blinder [1991] for one sees the issue potentially coming down to a

- fundamental^ trade-off:

Suppose teaching micro first is sounder but macroeconomics brings in the crowds. Then putting micro first would mean that fewer students would be get- ting a slightly better education. Teachers of economics believe that some exposure to economics is good for students. So which is better: giving more students less, or giving fewer students more? The answer is not obvious ... [p. 2531

Wood [19851 argued that the full poten- tial of using media reports in economics classes cannot be realized because too

BECKER & WATTS TEACHING UNDERGRADUATE ECONOMICS 697

many editors and reporters do not know economics, resulting in stories that are flawed with errors and important omis- sions. Cochran and Brown [19891 see jour- nalistic mistakes and inexact use of eco- nomic terms more in terms of an opportu- nity to show students the important dif- ferences between economic and journalis- tic analysis, but they too realize the inher- ent difficulty instructors face in trying to catch and correct all of the errant journal- istic passages in classes where students are expected to read financial newspapers or magazines throughout the semester.

A recent study by Becker, Walstad, and Watts [1994] finds empirical support for the argument that economists and journal- ists approach economic topics and issues quite differently. The authors compared survey responses by economists, joumal- ists (including members of the Society of American Business Editors and Writers), and teachers, using items dealing with a wide range of economics issues that were originally developed by Alston, Kearl, and Vaughn [1992]. It turned out that the gen- eral samples of economists and economic educators held very similar opinions on these items; and that the journalists, high school economics teachers, and other high school social studies teachers held very similar opinions; but the economists and economic educators had very different opinions from those expressed by the jour- nalists and high school teachers. This has important implications for teachers of un- dergraduate economics courses, in terms of the knowledge and attitudes entering students are likely to hold on a variety of contemporary economic issues, whether or not they have taken a high school course on economics.

VIII. CASE STUDIES IN UNDERGRADUATE ECONOMICS CLASSES

The case method has long been a favor- ite teaching method in MBA programs at Harvard and other leading universities. Economists at Harvard and at the Pew

Case Study Center at Georgetown Univer- sity have developed a number of cases that may be purchased and used in upper division undergraduate courses. One full- blown textbook in macroeconomics by Ruckstad [1992], featuring several exten- sive case studies, was developed out of the Harvard programs. This particular text- book is succeeding in the marketplace (at least to the extent of reaching a third edition), and other books of cases dealing with topics usually taught in upper divi- sion undergraduate and graduate courses are starting to appear from other sources, such as Schumann, Rogers, and Reitzes 119921. At the introductory level, however, while there have been occasional attempts to develop a case-study textbook-most recently by Fels, Buckles, and Johnson [19791, so far as we have been able to determine-such efforts have not yet met with success in the marketplace, probably because of instructor reluctance to use the case method with students who have such limited backgrounds in economics.

Carlson and Schodt [19951 have also argued that ”one obstacle to the more widespread adoption of case teaching in economics, apart from a simple lack of information, appears to be that, in [the] minds of many economists, any shift from the traditional lecture format involves an inevitable sacrifice of theoretical rigor.” However, after attending a training ses- sion on the case method at Harvard and using the method in their own undergrad- uate and master’s levels classes, Carlson and Schodt claim that

Case method teaching, while no panacea for all that may ail contemporary in- struction in economics, ...p rovide(s) a means for the active engagement of students with their learning, for having them do economics, and, ultimately, for their learning how to think like econ- omists.

They also report that their students were very enthusiastic about the use of case studies, based on responses to course eval- uation surveys.

698 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

Velenchik [19951 reports that the case method was particularly successful in mo- tivating students who were not economics majors but taking a policy-oriented under- graduate course in international econom- ics to learn and apply economic theory, and also to enhance their skills in using and presenting quantitative evidence.

IX. COOPERATIVE LEARNING All of the above alternatives to the

standard lecture approach can be incorpo- rated into small group activities in which students work together toward a common goal, and the instructor serves as an ob- server who often provides feedback only after the groups complete various kinds of assignments. For example, in a classroom experiment exercise, student groups might act as firms trying to maximize profits, and the instructor serve as a government agency/overseer. Or, using the Nobel lec- tures, student teams might debate whether common themes, problems, and suggested policy remedies appear over time in various subsets of the lectures, with the instructor serving as a moderator.

For large classes, a simple cooperative exercise called “Think, Pair, Share” re- quires only a few minutes to do, but provides a break in standard lectures that actively involves students and allows in- structors to quickly assess what students know. Students are required to think about a question posed by the instructor; com- pare, discuss, and refine their answers with a neighboring student; and share their responses with the class if their team is called on by the instructor.

Maier and Keenan 119941 describe the ”Think, Pair, Share” activity and the use of other cooperative learning techniques to teach basic economic concepts, such as the supply curve. Citing the general edu- cation literature on cooperative learning, they claim that compared to standard lec- ture methods students working in groups learn more, use higher level reasoning, express more satisfaction with their

classes, are less likely to drop out, and become more tolerant of ethnic and racial differences.

Johnson and Johnson [19911, two of the leading general education authorities on cooperative learning, offer a good survey and comparison of cooperative, competi- tive, and individual learning methods.

There is an inherent free-rider problem in assigning grades in cooperative learn- ing activities. Bartlett [19951 describes an innovative method of avoiding the free riding. Students are given the option of forming groups or not. Then, when an exam or in-class presentation comes due, Bartlett uses a random-number process to choose one member of the group to take the exam or make the presentation, and the grade earned by the student is as- signed to all members of the group. Obvi- ously, this creates incentives for all mem- bers of the group to be sure that they and all of the other members are well prepared for each assignment.

X. CONCLUSIONS

Anecdotal evidence in both collegial discussions and recent books such as Anderson’s Impostors in the TempZe holds that economists, like professors from other disciplines, often express disdain for teaching, and implies that economists are perhaps especially loathe to spend their valuable time developing and experiment- ing with new teaching methods. That point of view is refuted, or at least se- verely strained, by our review of what many economists are actually doing in the classroom, and encouraging other econo- mists to do. This is, of course, also anec- dotal evidence; but there is presently little or no hard evidence available about the amount of time academic economists in different kinds of schools are devoting to their teaching, let alone how well they succeed in raising students’ level of eco- nomic understanding and critical thinking skills.

BECKER & WATTS TEACHING UNDERGRADUATE ECONOMICS 699

Though not supported by findings from formal research, it is tempting to conclude that the variety of teaching methods avail- able for use in undergraduate economics classes is broad enough to offer the means for virtually any instructor to achieve re- spectable teaching ratings, given reason- able amounts of preparation and a modi- cum of sensitivity to student responses in the classroom. Moreover, there is an im- portant place for specialization and com- parative advantage in teaching economics, based on student and instructor differ- ences in preferences and effective learning and teaching styles. Some students and teachers are natural born listeners and lecturers, some are talkers and discussion leaders, and some seem to learn or teach best using group activities that feature ”hands on” demonstrations of economic concepts and relationships.

Great orators should lecture. The rest of us should consider using a variety of teaching methods to actively engage our students and reduce the amount of time we spend lecturing to audiences that are often captive in the short run, but all too willing and able to vote with their feet in the long run, as recent enrollment trends in economics documented by Siegfried and Scott [1994] have shown. Variety in the pace and format of undergraduate classroom instruction-across different class periods and even within a particular class-may well be the missing spice of good teaching and more enthusiastic learning.

REFERENCES

Abdalla, Adil E. A. “A Country Report Project for an International Economics Class.” Journal of Eco- nomic Education, Summer 1993,231-36.

Alston, Richard M., J. R. Kearl, and Michael 8. Vaughn. “Is There a Consensus Among Economists in the 1990s?” American Economic Review, May 1992, 203-09.

Anderson, Martin. Imposters in the Temple: The Decline qf the American University. New York: Simon & Schuster, 1992.

Bartlett, Robin. “A Flip of the Coin-A Roll of the Die: Economic Instruction and Collaborative Learn- ing.” Journal qf Economic Education, Spring 1995,

Bartlett, Robin, and Paul King. ”Teaching Economics as a Laboratory Science.” Journal of Economic Ed- ucation, Spring 1990, 181-93.

Becker, William, William B. Walstad, and Michael Watts. “A Comparison of the Views of Econo- mists, Economic Educators, Teachers and Jour- nalists on Economic Issues,” in A n International Perspective on Economic Education, edited by Wil- liam B. Walstad. Boston: Kluwer Academic Pub- lishers, 1994, 65-87.

Blackburn, Anthonv 1.. and Karl E. Case. Fairmodel Stu-

131-39.

dent Manual.’Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1985.

Blinder, Alan S. “Research in Economic Education and the Teaching of Economics.” Journal of Economic Education, Summer 1991, 251-54.

Brock, John R. “A Public Goods Experiment for the Classroom.” Economic Inquiry, April 1991, 395- 401.

Carlson, John, and David Schodt. “Beyond the Lec- ture: Case Teaching and the Learning of Eco- nomic Theory.” Journal of Economic Education, Winter 1995, 17-28.

Cohen, Avi J., and John Spencer. ”Using Writing Across the Curriculum in Economics: Is Taking the Plunge Worth It?” Journal of Economic Educa- tion, Summer 1993, 219-30.

Cochran, John P., and R. Michael Brown. ”What’s Wrong Here?” Economic Inquiry, July 1989, 541- 45.

Davidson, Lawrence S., and Elisabeth C. Gumnior. “Writing to Learn in a Business Economics Class.” Journal of Economic Education, Summer 1993,237-43.

Fels, Rendigs. “This Is What I Do, and I Like It.” Jour- nal of Economic Education, Fall 1993, 365-70.

Fels, Rendigs, Stephen Buckles, and W. L. Johnson. Casebook $Economic Problems and Policies. St. Paul, Minn.: West Publishing, 1979.

Gold, Steven C., Thomas F. Pray, and Terry L. Dennis. Microsim: A Computerized Microeconomic Simula- tion. New York: Macmillan, 1984.

Halstead, Jim. “Sovplan: An In-Class Simulation of Central Planning.” Economic Inquiry, April 1989,

Hansen, W. Lee. “Teaching a Writing Intensive Course in Economics.” Journal of Economic Education, Summer 1993, 213-18.

Hemenway, David, Robert Moore, and James Whitney. “The Oligopoly Game.” Economic Inquiry, Octo- ber 1987, 727-30.

Hester, Donald D. “Instructional Simulation of a Com- mercial Banking System.” Journal of Economic Ed- ucation, Spring 1991, 111-43.

357-61.

700 ECONOMIC INQUIRY

Johnson, David W., and Roger T. Johnson. Learning Together and Alone: Cooperative, Competitive, and Individualistic Learning, 3rd ed. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1991.

Joseph, Myron, and Phillip Saunders. “Playing the Market Game,” in Recent Research in Economics Education, edited by Keith G. Lumsden. Engle- wood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice Hall, 1970,15845.

Kasper, Hirschel, et al. “The Education of Economists: From Undergraduate to Graduate Study.” Journal of Economic Literature, September 1991,1088-107.

Kelley, Allen C. ”The Newspaper Can Be an Effective Teaching Tool.”Journal #Economic Education, Fall 1983,5658.

Kennedy, Peter. “On Journalists’ Use of Macroeco- nomic Concepts.” Economic Inquiry, January 1992, 194-201.

Krueger, Anne O., et al. “Report of the Commission on Graduate Education in Economics.“ Journal of Economic Literature, September 1991, 1035-53.

Leuthold, Jane H. “A Free Rider Experiment for the Large Class.“ Journal of Economic Education, Fall 1993, 353-63.

Levy, Daniel, and Mark Bergen. “Simulating a Multi- product Barter Exchange Economy.” Economic In- quiry, April 1993,314-21.

Lewis, Darrell R., and Donald R. Wentworth. A Guide to Games and Simulations for Teaching Economics. New York Joint Council on Economic Education, 1971.

Lumsden, Keith G., and Alex Scott. Running the U.S. Economy. New York National Council on Eco- nomic Education, 1995.

Maier, Mark H., and Diane Keenan. “Cooperative Learning in Economics.” Economic Inquiry, April 1994,358-61.

Marks, Stephen V. “Teaching Guide: Abortion Eco- nomics.” Economic Inquiry, January 1988,175-79.

Ruckstad, Michael G. Macroeconomic Decision Making in the World Economy: Text and Cases, 3rd ed. Fort Worth, Tex.: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1992.

Schumann, Laurence, Robert P. Rogers, and James D. Reitzes. Case Studies on the Price Efpcts 4 Hori- zontal Mergers. Washington, D.C.: Federal Trade Commission, 1992.

Siegfried, John J., and Charles C. Scott. “Recent Trends in Undergraduate Economics Degrees.” Journal of Economic Education, Summer 1994, 281-86.

Smith, Vernon “Experimental Economics at Purdue,“ in Essays in Contemporary Fields o f Economics in Honor o f Emanuel T. Weiler, edited by George Horwich and James P. Quirk. West Lafayette, Ind.: Purdue University Press, 1981, 369-73.

Stigler, George J. “The Case, if Any, for Economic Ed- ucation.” Journal of Economic Education, Spring

Sulock, Joseph M. “The Free Rider and Voting Paradox ’Games.”’ Journal of Economic Education, Winter 1990, 65-69.

Velenchik, Ann D. “The Case Method as a Strategy for Teaching Policy Analysis to Undergraduates.” Journal of Economic Education, Winter 1995,29-38.

Walstad, William B., and Michael Watts. ”The Princi- ples of Economics Textbook History and Con- tent,” in The Principles of Economics Course: A Handbook f o r Instructors, edited by Phillip Saunders and William B. Walstad. New York Mc- Graw-Hill, 1990, 141-60.

Watts, Michael, and Robert F. Smith. ”Economics in Literature and Drama.” Journal of Economic Edu- cation, Summer 1989, 291-307.

Wells, Donald A. ”Laboratory Experiments for Under- graduate Instruction in Economics.“ Journal of Economic Education, Summer 1991, 293-300.

Williams, Arlington, and James Walker. “Computer- ized Laboratory Exercises for Microeconomics Education: Thee Applications Motivated by the Methodology of Experimental Economics.” Jour- nal of Economic Education, Fall 1993,291-315.

Williams, Robert B. “Market Exchange and Wealth Distribution: A Classroom Simulation.” Journal of Economic Education, Fall 1993, 325-34.

Wood, William C. ”The Educational Potential of News Coverage of Economics.“ Journal of Economic Ed- ucation, Winter 1985, 27-35.

Yoho, DeVon L. “Fairmodel: Microcomputer Software to Teach Macroeconomic Concepts.” Journal 4 Economic Education, Winter 1989, 107-13.

Yoho, DeVon L., and William B. Walstad. “Microcom- puter Software for Principles of Economics Courses,“ in The Principles o f Economics Course: A Handbook fo r Instructors, edited by Phillip Saunders and William B. Walstad. New York Mc- Graw-Hill, 1990,161-79.

Zahka, William J. “The Nobel Prize Economics Lec- tures as a Teaching Tool.“ Journal 4 Economic Ed- ucation, Fall 1990, 395-401.

1970,77-84.