79
Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director, Regulated Energy Division Michigan Public Service Commission

Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Tariff Development IIIDeveloping a Rate Design

Energy Regulatory Partnership ProgramAbuja Nigeria

July 14-18 2008

Ikechukwu N Nwabueze PhDDirector Regulated Energy Division

Michigan Public Service Commission

Fair and Just Rates

Late 19th Century concern over the growing economic power of certain corporations that were affected with the public interest Suspect behavior fell into four groupsndash Prices were ldquotoo highrdquo reflecting monopoly powerndash Prices were ldquotoo lowrdquo (implying predatory pricing

which discouraged economic entry)ndash Prices that were ldquotoo highrdquo for some but ldquotoo lowrdquo for

others (involving ldquounduerdquo discrimination andor subsidies for some markets)

ndash Prices that were ldquounstablerdquo (making it difficult for producers and consumers to plan ahead)

2 of 79

Todayrsquos Pricing Issues

bull Few issues today are fundamentally different from those at the turn of the century This is due in part to the early recognition of the fundamental characteristics of a natural monopoly (Farrer 1902)ndash Capital intensive (having significant fixed costs or scale

economies)ndash Necessity (essential to the community)ndash Nonstorable (yet subject to fluctuating demands)ndash Produced in particularly favored locations (yielding rents)ndash Involve direct connections with customers

bull The unregulated monopolist has the power to set prices that are not in the public interest

3 of 79

Goals of Rate Designbull Equity (ldquofairnessrdquo) goals

ndash Be just and reasonable (fair to various groups)ndash Be subsidy free

bull No group or service charged less than its incremental cost or more than its stand alone cost (ie the utility receives a positive rate of return from each group or service but not a monopolistic profit)

4 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

bull Efficiency Goalsndash Give correct signals to consumers and to the

utility (ie Price = Marginal Cost) bull Promote efficient use of resources and efficient

planning by the utility

ndash Allow for efficient competitive entry bull Prevent predatory pricing price squeezes

uneconomic bypass and cross-subsidization of competitive services by monopoly services

5 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

bull Social goals may includendash Promoting universal servicendash Promoting conservation (eg inverted rate

structure) or at least discouraging wasteful use of a utility service

ndash Promoting environmental protectionndash Promoting economic development and full

employmentndash Assisting seniorlow income consumers

6 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)bull Operational Goals

ndash Be sufficient to allow the utility to collect its legitimate costs (ie allowed capital and operating costs)

ndash Be relatively stable from period to period bull Avoid rate shock

ndash Promote revenue stability for the utilityndash Be understandable and administratively feasiblendash Avoid undue discrimination across rate classes or

servicesndash Apportion costs fairly

7 of 79

Additional Commentsbull It is often difficult mdash or impossible mdash to

achieve all these goals at oncebull Almost all real-world rate designs are

compromisesbull Certain goals may be conflicting

ndash Rates that are efficient may not be considered fairbull Efficiency involves maximizing total net economic valuebull Fairness involves distribution of net economic value

among customers and the utilityndash Rates that promote energy conservation may not

be efficient or considered fair

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

8 of 79

Allocation of Revenue Requirementsto Various Classes of Service

bull Group customers into rate classesbull Rate classifications should produce

homogeneous groups based upon characteristics of each groupbull Residentialbull Commercial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Industrial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Retail Open Access ndash ROA

9 of 79

Rate Structures

bull The existing rate structures for the various rate classes is the best source of information to assist in selecting rate structuresbull Evaluate the performance of current structure

bull Do rates provide revenue stabilitybull Do rates provide for recovery of revenue

requirements for that class of servicebull Are the rates perceived to be fair by the

customers

10 of 79

The Traditional Ratemaking Process

Revenue

Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

11 of 79

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 2: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Fair and Just Rates

Late 19th Century concern over the growing economic power of certain corporations that were affected with the public interest Suspect behavior fell into four groupsndash Prices were ldquotoo highrdquo reflecting monopoly powerndash Prices were ldquotoo lowrdquo (implying predatory pricing

which discouraged economic entry)ndash Prices that were ldquotoo highrdquo for some but ldquotoo lowrdquo for

others (involving ldquounduerdquo discrimination andor subsidies for some markets)

ndash Prices that were ldquounstablerdquo (making it difficult for producers and consumers to plan ahead)

2 of 79

Todayrsquos Pricing Issues

bull Few issues today are fundamentally different from those at the turn of the century This is due in part to the early recognition of the fundamental characteristics of a natural monopoly (Farrer 1902)ndash Capital intensive (having significant fixed costs or scale

economies)ndash Necessity (essential to the community)ndash Nonstorable (yet subject to fluctuating demands)ndash Produced in particularly favored locations (yielding rents)ndash Involve direct connections with customers

bull The unregulated monopolist has the power to set prices that are not in the public interest

3 of 79

Goals of Rate Designbull Equity (ldquofairnessrdquo) goals

ndash Be just and reasonable (fair to various groups)ndash Be subsidy free

bull No group or service charged less than its incremental cost or more than its stand alone cost (ie the utility receives a positive rate of return from each group or service but not a monopolistic profit)

4 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

bull Efficiency Goalsndash Give correct signals to consumers and to the

utility (ie Price = Marginal Cost) bull Promote efficient use of resources and efficient

planning by the utility

ndash Allow for efficient competitive entry bull Prevent predatory pricing price squeezes

uneconomic bypass and cross-subsidization of competitive services by monopoly services

5 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

bull Social goals may includendash Promoting universal servicendash Promoting conservation (eg inverted rate

structure) or at least discouraging wasteful use of a utility service

ndash Promoting environmental protectionndash Promoting economic development and full

employmentndash Assisting seniorlow income consumers

6 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)bull Operational Goals

ndash Be sufficient to allow the utility to collect its legitimate costs (ie allowed capital and operating costs)

ndash Be relatively stable from period to period bull Avoid rate shock

ndash Promote revenue stability for the utilityndash Be understandable and administratively feasiblendash Avoid undue discrimination across rate classes or

servicesndash Apportion costs fairly

7 of 79

Additional Commentsbull It is often difficult mdash or impossible mdash to

achieve all these goals at oncebull Almost all real-world rate designs are

compromisesbull Certain goals may be conflicting

ndash Rates that are efficient may not be considered fairbull Efficiency involves maximizing total net economic valuebull Fairness involves distribution of net economic value

among customers and the utilityndash Rates that promote energy conservation may not

be efficient or considered fair

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

8 of 79

Allocation of Revenue Requirementsto Various Classes of Service

bull Group customers into rate classesbull Rate classifications should produce

homogeneous groups based upon characteristics of each groupbull Residentialbull Commercial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Industrial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Retail Open Access ndash ROA

9 of 79

Rate Structures

bull The existing rate structures for the various rate classes is the best source of information to assist in selecting rate structuresbull Evaluate the performance of current structure

bull Do rates provide revenue stabilitybull Do rates provide for recovery of revenue

requirements for that class of servicebull Are the rates perceived to be fair by the

customers

10 of 79

The Traditional Ratemaking Process

Revenue

Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

11 of 79

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 3: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Todayrsquos Pricing Issues

bull Few issues today are fundamentally different from those at the turn of the century This is due in part to the early recognition of the fundamental characteristics of a natural monopoly (Farrer 1902)ndash Capital intensive (having significant fixed costs or scale

economies)ndash Necessity (essential to the community)ndash Nonstorable (yet subject to fluctuating demands)ndash Produced in particularly favored locations (yielding rents)ndash Involve direct connections with customers

bull The unregulated monopolist has the power to set prices that are not in the public interest

3 of 79

Goals of Rate Designbull Equity (ldquofairnessrdquo) goals

ndash Be just and reasonable (fair to various groups)ndash Be subsidy free

bull No group or service charged less than its incremental cost or more than its stand alone cost (ie the utility receives a positive rate of return from each group or service but not a monopolistic profit)

4 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

bull Efficiency Goalsndash Give correct signals to consumers and to the

utility (ie Price = Marginal Cost) bull Promote efficient use of resources and efficient

planning by the utility

ndash Allow for efficient competitive entry bull Prevent predatory pricing price squeezes

uneconomic bypass and cross-subsidization of competitive services by monopoly services

5 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

bull Social goals may includendash Promoting universal servicendash Promoting conservation (eg inverted rate

structure) or at least discouraging wasteful use of a utility service

ndash Promoting environmental protectionndash Promoting economic development and full

employmentndash Assisting seniorlow income consumers

6 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)bull Operational Goals

ndash Be sufficient to allow the utility to collect its legitimate costs (ie allowed capital and operating costs)

ndash Be relatively stable from period to period bull Avoid rate shock

ndash Promote revenue stability for the utilityndash Be understandable and administratively feasiblendash Avoid undue discrimination across rate classes or

servicesndash Apportion costs fairly

7 of 79

Additional Commentsbull It is often difficult mdash or impossible mdash to

achieve all these goals at oncebull Almost all real-world rate designs are

compromisesbull Certain goals may be conflicting

ndash Rates that are efficient may not be considered fairbull Efficiency involves maximizing total net economic valuebull Fairness involves distribution of net economic value

among customers and the utilityndash Rates that promote energy conservation may not

be efficient or considered fair

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

8 of 79

Allocation of Revenue Requirementsto Various Classes of Service

bull Group customers into rate classesbull Rate classifications should produce

homogeneous groups based upon characteristics of each groupbull Residentialbull Commercial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Industrial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Retail Open Access ndash ROA

9 of 79

Rate Structures

bull The existing rate structures for the various rate classes is the best source of information to assist in selecting rate structuresbull Evaluate the performance of current structure

bull Do rates provide revenue stabilitybull Do rates provide for recovery of revenue

requirements for that class of servicebull Are the rates perceived to be fair by the

customers

10 of 79

The Traditional Ratemaking Process

Revenue

Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

11 of 79

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 4: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Goals of Rate Designbull Equity (ldquofairnessrdquo) goals

ndash Be just and reasonable (fair to various groups)ndash Be subsidy free

bull No group or service charged less than its incremental cost or more than its stand alone cost (ie the utility receives a positive rate of return from each group or service but not a monopolistic profit)

4 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

bull Efficiency Goalsndash Give correct signals to consumers and to the

utility (ie Price = Marginal Cost) bull Promote efficient use of resources and efficient

planning by the utility

ndash Allow for efficient competitive entry bull Prevent predatory pricing price squeezes

uneconomic bypass and cross-subsidization of competitive services by monopoly services

5 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

bull Social goals may includendash Promoting universal servicendash Promoting conservation (eg inverted rate

structure) or at least discouraging wasteful use of a utility service

ndash Promoting environmental protectionndash Promoting economic development and full

employmentndash Assisting seniorlow income consumers

6 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)bull Operational Goals

ndash Be sufficient to allow the utility to collect its legitimate costs (ie allowed capital and operating costs)

ndash Be relatively stable from period to period bull Avoid rate shock

ndash Promote revenue stability for the utilityndash Be understandable and administratively feasiblendash Avoid undue discrimination across rate classes or

servicesndash Apportion costs fairly

7 of 79

Additional Commentsbull It is often difficult mdash or impossible mdash to

achieve all these goals at oncebull Almost all real-world rate designs are

compromisesbull Certain goals may be conflicting

ndash Rates that are efficient may not be considered fairbull Efficiency involves maximizing total net economic valuebull Fairness involves distribution of net economic value

among customers and the utilityndash Rates that promote energy conservation may not

be efficient or considered fair

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

8 of 79

Allocation of Revenue Requirementsto Various Classes of Service

bull Group customers into rate classesbull Rate classifications should produce

homogeneous groups based upon characteristics of each groupbull Residentialbull Commercial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Industrial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Retail Open Access ndash ROA

9 of 79

Rate Structures

bull The existing rate structures for the various rate classes is the best source of information to assist in selecting rate structuresbull Evaluate the performance of current structure

bull Do rates provide revenue stabilitybull Do rates provide for recovery of revenue

requirements for that class of servicebull Are the rates perceived to be fair by the

customers

10 of 79

The Traditional Ratemaking Process

Revenue

Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

11 of 79

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 5: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

bull Efficiency Goalsndash Give correct signals to consumers and to the

utility (ie Price = Marginal Cost) bull Promote efficient use of resources and efficient

planning by the utility

ndash Allow for efficient competitive entry bull Prevent predatory pricing price squeezes

uneconomic bypass and cross-subsidization of competitive services by monopoly services

5 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

bull Social goals may includendash Promoting universal servicendash Promoting conservation (eg inverted rate

structure) or at least discouraging wasteful use of a utility service

ndash Promoting environmental protectionndash Promoting economic development and full

employmentndash Assisting seniorlow income consumers

6 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)bull Operational Goals

ndash Be sufficient to allow the utility to collect its legitimate costs (ie allowed capital and operating costs)

ndash Be relatively stable from period to period bull Avoid rate shock

ndash Promote revenue stability for the utilityndash Be understandable and administratively feasiblendash Avoid undue discrimination across rate classes or

servicesndash Apportion costs fairly

7 of 79

Additional Commentsbull It is often difficult mdash or impossible mdash to

achieve all these goals at oncebull Almost all real-world rate designs are

compromisesbull Certain goals may be conflicting

ndash Rates that are efficient may not be considered fairbull Efficiency involves maximizing total net economic valuebull Fairness involves distribution of net economic value

among customers and the utilityndash Rates that promote energy conservation may not

be efficient or considered fair

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

8 of 79

Allocation of Revenue Requirementsto Various Classes of Service

bull Group customers into rate classesbull Rate classifications should produce

homogeneous groups based upon characteristics of each groupbull Residentialbull Commercial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Industrial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Retail Open Access ndash ROA

9 of 79

Rate Structures

bull The existing rate structures for the various rate classes is the best source of information to assist in selecting rate structuresbull Evaluate the performance of current structure

bull Do rates provide revenue stabilitybull Do rates provide for recovery of revenue

requirements for that class of servicebull Are the rates perceived to be fair by the

customers

10 of 79

The Traditional Ratemaking Process

Revenue

Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

11 of 79

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 6: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

bull Social goals may includendash Promoting universal servicendash Promoting conservation (eg inverted rate

structure) or at least discouraging wasteful use of a utility service

ndash Promoting environmental protectionndash Promoting economic development and full

employmentndash Assisting seniorlow income consumers

6 of 79

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)bull Operational Goals

ndash Be sufficient to allow the utility to collect its legitimate costs (ie allowed capital and operating costs)

ndash Be relatively stable from period to period bull Avoid rate shock

ndash Promote revenue stability for the utilityndash Be understandable and administratively feasiblendash Avoid undue discrimination across rate classes or

servicesndash Apportion costs fairly

7 of 79

Additional Commentsbull It is often difficult mdash or impossible mdash to

achieve all these goals at oncebull Almost all real-world rate designs are

compromisesbull Certain goals may be conflicting

ndash Rates that are efficient may not be considered fairbull Efficiency involves maximizing total net economic valuebull Fairness involves distribution of net economic value

among customers and the utilityndash Rates that promote energy conservation may not

be efficient or considered fair

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

8 of 79

Allocation of Revenue Requirementsto Various Classes of Service

bull Group customers into rate classesbull Rate classifications should produce

homogeneous groups based upon characteristics of each groupbull Residentialbull Commercial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Industrial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Retail Open Access ndash ROA

9 of 79

Rate Structures

bull The existing rate structures for the various rate classes is the best source of information to assist in selecting rate structuresbull Evaluate the performance of current structure

bull Do rates provide revenue stabilitybull Do rates provide for recovery of revenue

requirements for that class of servicebull Are the rates perceived to be fair by the

customers

10 of 79

The Traditional Ratemaking Process

Revenue

Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

11 of 79

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 7: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)bull Operational Goals

ndash Be sufficient to allow the utility to collect its legitimate costs (ie allowed capital and operating costs)

ndash Be relatively stable from period to period bull Avoid rate shock

ndash Promote revenue stability for the utilityndash Be understandable and administratively feasiblendash Avoid undue discrimination across rate classes or

servicesndash Apportion costs fairly

7 of 79

Additional Commentsbull It is often difficult mdash or impossible mdash to

achieve all these goals at oncebull Almost all real-world rate designs are

compromisesbull Certain goals may be conflicting

ndash Rates that are efficient may not be considered fairbull Efficiency involves maximizing total net economic valuebull Fairness involves distribution of net economic value

among customers and the utilityndash Rates that promote energy conservation may not

be efficient or considered fair

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

8 of 79

Allocation of Revenue Requirementsto Various Classes of Service

bull Group customers into rate classesbull Rate classifications should produce

homogeneous groups based upon characteristics of each groupbull Residentialbull Commercial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Industrial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Retail Open Access ndash ROA

9 of 79

Rate Structures

bull The existing rate structures for the various rate classes is the best source of information to assist in selecting rate structuresbull Evaluate the performance of current structure

bull Do rates provide revenue stabilitybull Do rates provide for recovery of revenue

requirements for that class of servicebull Are the rates perceived to be fair by the

customers

10 of 79

The Traditional Ratemaking Process

Revenue

Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

11 of 79

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 8: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Additional Commentsbull It is often difficult mdash or impossible mdash to

achieve all these goals at oncebull Almost all real-world rate designs are

compromisesbull Certain goals may be conflicting

ndash Rates that are efficient may not be considered fairbull Efficiency involves maximizing total net economic valuebull Fairness involves distribution of net economic value

among customers and the utilityndash Rates that promote energy conservation may not

be efficient or considered fair

Goals of Rate Design (Continued)

8 of 79

Allocation of Revenue Requirementsto Various Classes of Service

bull Group customers into rate classesbull Rate classifications should produce

homogeneous groups based upon characteristics of each groupbull Residentialbull Commercial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Industrial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Retail Open Access ndash ROA

9 of 79

Rate Structures

bull The existing rate structures for the various rate classes is the best source of information to assist in selecting rate structuresbull Evaluate the performance of current structure

bull Do rates provide revenue stabilitybull Do rates provide for recovery of revenue

requirements for that class of servicebull Are the rates perceived to be fair by the

customers

10 of 79

The Traditional Ratemaking Process

Revenue

Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

11 of 79

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 9: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Allocation of Revenue Requirementsto Various Classes of Service

bull Group customers into rate classesbull Rate classifications should produce

homogeneous groups based upon characteristics of each groupbull Residentialbull Commercial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Industrial ndash Secondary and Primarybull Retail Open Access ndash ROA

9 of 79

Rate Structures

bull The existing rate structures for the various rate classes is the best source of information to assist in selecting rate structuresbull Evaluate the performance of current structure

bull Do rates provide revenue stabilitybull Do rates provide for recovery of revenue

requirements for that class of servicebull Are the rates perceived to be fair by the

customers

10 of 79

The Traditional Ratemaking Process

Revenue

Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

11 of 79

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 10: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Rate Structures

bull The existing rate structures for the various rate classes is the best source of information to assist in selecting rate structuresbull Evaluate the performance of current structure

bull Do rates provide revenue stabilitybull Do rates provide for recovery of revenue

requirements for that class of servicebull Are the rates perceived to be fair by the

customers

10 of 79

The Traditional Ratemaking Process

Revenue

Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

11 of 79

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 11: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

The Traditional Ratemaking Process

Revenue

Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

11 of 79

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 12: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Steps in Traditional Ratemaking

bull Three basic stepsndash Determination of revenue requirements (cost

assessment) for a test yearndash Allocation of costs to customers based on

usage patternndash Rate design to recover costs through rates

and chargesbull Considerable discretion is involved in all three

steps

12 of 79

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 13: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

What Stakeholders Want from the Ratemaking Process

bull Utilities a reasonable return on investment (compensatory and non-confiscatory) to ensure financial viability protection from ruinous competition

bull Customers Nondiscriminatory service at fair reasonable and affordable rates protection from monopoly abuse (captive customers)

bull RegulatorsSociety Utility services that promote the public interest including price signals that encourage efficient use of resources and promote other social goals

13 of 79

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 14: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Ratemaking Process

bullCost allocation determines how many dollars to collect from various classes or services

bullRate design determines how to collect dollars from various customer groups and services

bullLike cost allocation rate design is as much art as science ndash more ldquosausage makingrdquo

14 of 79

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 15: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Designing Sound Tariff Structures

Pricing principles provide a foundation for rate design and sound tariff structures

bull Fairness to both the regulated utility and the ratepayers

bull Avoidance of unjust or undue discrimination between rate classes or customers

15 of 79

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 16: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Design Rates to Provide for Recoveryof Revenue Requirements

bull General Attributes of a Sound Rate Structurebull Effectiveness in yielding total revenue requirementsbull Revenue and rate stability and predictabilitybull Fairness and avoidance of undue discrimination among

the different rate classesbull Political and public policy issues eg subsidiesbull Simplicity understandability and public acceptabilitybull Practicability metering and billing constraints

16 of 79

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 17: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Objectives in Setting Rates

bull Protect the ratepayerrsquos interest by assuring safe reliable and reasonably priced services

bull Fairly apportioning cost among customersbull Protect the shareholderrsquos interest by allowing the

utility a reasonable opportunity to earn a fair rate of return on its investment

17 of 79

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 18: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Rate Structure v Rate Levels

bull Regulators must approve both the rate structure and rate levelsbull The term rate structure refers to how the prices are designed The

rate structure may reflect various attributes For example- Number of rate levels (eg declining block or constant rate per kWh)- Customer classes (industrial commercial government residential)- Time of day (peak v off-peak)- Capacity (kilowatt)

bull The term rate level refers to the price per unit sold (eg 5 cents per kWh or $1050 per kW)

18 of 79

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 19: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Pricing Attributes

Dr James C Bonbright in his book ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961) which is often quoted by rate design witnesses provides a list of eight traditional rate-making or pricing attributesndash Simplicity and public acceptabilityndash Freedom from controversyndash Revenue sufficiencyndash Revenue stabilityndash Stability of ratesndash Fairness in apportionment of total costsndash Avoidance of undue rate discriminationndash Encouragement of efficiency

19 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 20: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Simplicity and Public Acceptability

bull The costs associated with regulatory hearings on rate structures will be reduced if policies can be easily understood by the affected parties

bull Consumersrsquo information processing costs should be included in the derivation of efficient prices

bull Why do consumers prefer flat-rate telephone service

20 of 79

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 21: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Simplicity and Public Acceptability (Continued)

bull ATampTrsquos vice-president EJ Hall conjectured in 1898 that although customers could understand paying a flat fee for unlimited use of the local network or no connection charge and a usage charge for each call they were confused by the combination of paying an entry and usage fee

ldquoThe claim that [a two-part tariff] is easy for the customer to understand and would therefore be popular is not justified by history nor will it stand logical analysis No compound proposition [ie two-part tariff] can be as easily understood as can either one of the simple ones from which it is composedrdquo

bull Simple rate structures may conflict with other pricing objectives (eg efficiency)

21 of 79

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 22: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Freedom from Controversy

bull Hard to modify an existing rate structure or rate levels in a manner that is free from controversy

bull In order to minimize the level of controversy regulatory commissions will often phase in the change

bull Controversy can also be reduced if a well accepted pricing or costing methodology can be used to explain the need for the change in rates

22 of 79

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 23: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Revenue Sufficiency

bull In 1930s and 1940s the view came to be held that the right policy was to make public utility prices everywhere equal to marginal cost even where marginal cost was less than average cost and a government subsidy was required to maintain production

bull This policy proposal had serious weaknesses It did not take into account the benefit of a subsequent market test whether consumers were willing to pay the total cost it ignored the probable effects on the administrative structure it involved a redistribution of income in favor of consumers of products produced in conditions of decreasing costs it failed to take into account the misallocation of resources resulting from the additional taxation necessitated by the subsidies

bull But if prices are not to equal marginal cost the question of what the structure of rates should be needs to be examined

23 of 79

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 24: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Revenue Stability

bull Concern is not so much revenue stability as it is net revenue (revenue ndash cost)

bull When comparing alternative rate structures regulators must examine how rates customer responses and production costs interact to yield net revenue stability

24 of 79

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 25: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Stability of Rates

bull Stability allows consumers to plan ahead Alcoa for example needs to know the long-term cost of purchasing electricity before it decides where to build a new smelter

bull But if costs are changing and rates are inflexible there can be shortages or excess supply

bull To avoid imposing hardships on particular customers regulators will tend to prefer a gradual transition to new rates

25 of 79

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 26: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Fairness in the Apportionment of Costs

bull Bonbright discussed fairness in terms of apportionment of total costs When you move away from rate base regulation and towards price caps the discussion evolves to a debate over the apportionment of costs (eg common costs)

bull Can the winners compensate the losing group when a new rate structure is adopted If they could then an economist might contend that the change should be implemented even if no compensation is paid

26 of 79

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 27: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Fairness in Ratemaking

bull An inherent tension exists between equity v efficiencybull Sometimes cost differences are ignored (eg old and

new customers)bull Values and perceptions of equity vary from place to

place and evolve over timebull Regulation considers whether rates are ldquojust and

reasonablerdquobull In practice rate design can be a mix of art science and

politics

27 of 79

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 28: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Avoidance of Undue Rate Discrimination

bull Price discrimination exists where the mark-up above marginal cost is greater in percentage terms of product A than product B

bull Price discrimination is often seen as welfare enhancing Telephone and airline pricing

bull Regulatory and anti-trust concern that a vertically integrated firm will foreclose competition in the downstream market

28 of 79

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 29: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Encouragement of Efficiency

bull Technical efficiency requires that the least-resource-consuming production processes be used to produce a given level of output

bull Allocative efficiency requires that the economically correct level (and mix) of output be chosen from among the technically efficient outputs

bull Innovative efficiency depends on how well firms perform the intertemporal tasks of cost reduction and new product development

29 of 79

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 30: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

A Feedback Loop

Revenue Requirement

CostAllocation

Rate Design(prices)

CustomerBehavior

30 of 79

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 31: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Rate Design

bull There are a wide variety of rate structures to choose from ndash flat rates step rates declining block rates demand rates

bull Michigan employs a three step structurebull Customer Charge ndash Fixed monthly chargebull Delivery or Distribution Charge ndash Energy (and Demand for

some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) charge on each unit of sale

bull Power Supply Charge ndash Energy charge (and Demand for some Commercial amp all Industrial rates) on each unit of sale

bull Additional surcharges are sometimes used to recover specific cost items such as Power Supply Cost Recovery (fuel and purchased power expenses under PA 304 Nuclear Decommissioning or expanded security at power plants

31 of 79

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 32: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Unbundling

bull Michigan uses tariffs broken down by delivery and power supply charges on customersrsquo bills so that customers can shop for the power supply portion of their service from an alternate energy supplier

bull Transmission is included in production as it is now billed

as component of power supply just as purchased power

bull Customer costs are recovered along with distribution costs under delivery charges

32 of 79

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 33: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Unbundling (Continued)bull Unbundled rates are designed to meet the

functionalized power supply and distribution revenue deficiencysufficiency targets derived in the cost of service study by major rate class or sometimes by rate

bull With the restructuring of utility industries customer charges are being unbundled mdash broken down into smaller components ndash Metering billing line maintenance and

transmission may appear separately on the bill with transmission as a usage-sensitive charge

33 of 79

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 34: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

A Point to Consider

bull Utility rates are pricesbull People respond to prices

ndash Prices provide incentives and signals to producers and consumers

bull Rate design will affect behaviorndash Expect a different response to a high customer

charge and low usage charge than to a low customer charge and a high usage charge even if the two are designed to produce equal revenues in the short run (Why)

bull Rate design affects behavior which affects future costs

34 of 79

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 35: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

A Point To Consider (Continued)

ndash Illustrationbull Rate design 1 customer charge = $500

energy charge = 4 centskWhbull Rate design 2 customer charge = $1000

energy charge = 2 centskWhbull The utility expects sales of 250 kWhs or

revenues of $15 no matter which rate design is applied

bull But assuming a price elasticity of -02 one would expect sales to be 20 higher under rate design 2

35 of 79

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 36: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Rate Designs

bull Marginal cost-based rates ndash Definition of MC change in cost due

to change in output represents economic opportunity cost

ndash Favored over fully allocated cost rates by economists

36 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 37: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Multi-part rates ndash Also called nonlinear prices or two-part

tariffsndash Include a fixed customer charge plus a

usage chargendash Relatively high fixed or customer charges

and relatively low usage chargesbull May be efficient but do not promote energy

conservationbull Shift risks away from the utility

37 of 79

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 38: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Rate Designs (continued)

bull Peak-load seasonal real-time or time-of-day rates

ndash Vary by time of day or season of usendash Used for energy services and sometimes

for telephone services

bull Inverted block rates ndash May promote conservation (Why)

38 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 39: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull Demand-side management (DSM) rates

bull Energy efficiency discounts

bull All-electric rates

bull Load-control rates

bull Reliability-based pricingndash Interruptible vs firm power rates

39 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 40: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Rate Designs (Continued)

bull In principle usage charges should recover only usage-sensitive costs

ndash Some fixed charges however are typically recovered through usage charges (particularly for residential and other small customers) bull Exhibited in declining-block rates for

electricity

40 of 79

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 41: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Cost of Service Issues

Allocation of costs to rate classes or specific rates remains one of the biggest issue of controversy in rate proceedings

Various intervening parties to a case employ methods that reduce the costs derived in the cost of service for their particular rate class or specific tariff

An example of this can be seen with the on-going debate of production plant allocation methods High load factor industrial customer groups pursue allocation methods based on demand rather than energy or based on coincident peaks that they are less responsible for

41 of 79

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 42: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate

42 of 79

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 43: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Increasing-block rate

43 of 79

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 44: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Seasonal rate

44 of 79

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 45: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Examples of Rate Designs

Flat Rate per period no usage charge

Uniform Flat Rate per unit

Declining Block Inverted Block

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

$

Q

45 of 79

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 46: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Rate Designs (Continued)

Seasonal or Time of Use

$

Period1

Period2

Q

46 of 79

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 47: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers

bull Bills customers for maximum measured demand (eg the maximum KW demand by a customer for any 15-minute period during the month) and for energy usage

bull Two-part tariff that has a separate demand and energy rate

bull Examplendash $950 per kW of maximum demand per monthndash $0065 per kWh usage in a given billing month

bull Rates can have declining (inverted) block demand andor energy charges

bull Higher load-factor customers pay a lower average price

47 of 79

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 48: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Pricing Philosophies

bull Cost of Service Pricingndash Tends on average to collect more-or-less

equal rates of return from all classes of customers and all services (ldquorate-of-return parityrdquo)

bull Each covers its variable costs and an equal relative contribution to common overhead and capital costs

bull For example if a utilityrsquos overall allowed rate of return is 125 it would earn 125 from each customer class

48 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 49: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing ndash Form of price discrimination

bull Charging different prices for the same service when no equivalent cost difference exists (eg economic development rates)

bull Charging different customers the same price when a significant cost differential exists (eg rural customers charged the same rate as urban customers)

49 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 50: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

bull Value-of-service pricing - continuedndash May consider customers willingness to pay

ability to find alternative suppliers or ability to engage in self supply

50 of 79

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 51: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Pricing Philosophies (Continued)

Commentsbull Non-cost-based pricing methods may not be

sustainable in a competitive environment ndash They may either promote inefficient competition

(eg uneconomic bypass) or thwart efficient competition

bull Rates that do not reflect current cost conditions do not give correct signals to either consumers or producers

51 of 79

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 52: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity

bull The classic conflict in regulation Achieving the correct balance between efficiency and equityndash Rebalancing rates in accordance with

costsndash Offering special rates to customers with

alternative choices

52 of 79

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 53: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Efficiency Goals

bull Economic efficiency as a goal reflects the concerns that are inherent in economic regulation ndash namely a monopolist supplying too little of a service and charging a too high price or engaging in excessive price discriminationndash The economic objective of regulation would be to

maximize total social welfare (total economic efficiency) without regard to who gets the money

53 of 79

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 54: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Economic Efficiency

bull Economic efficiency requires correct pricing starting with cost-based rates that reflect the marginal cost of service

ndash Marginal cost can be differentiated by service type or level as well as by time of servicebull Services that differ in quality or reliability

may have different marginal costs

54 of 79

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 55: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Equity

bull Cannot forget the goal of equity or fairness

bull To repeat equity must be balanced against efficiencyndash Equity is subjective and many views of

fairness existndash What is fair to one group may often be

considered unfair to another

55 of 79

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 56: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Price Discrimination Due and Undue

bull The common law like customers pay the same price for the same service

bull The conflict between efficiency and equity is addressed by the undue price discrimination testndash Not all price discrimination is goodndash Not all price discrimination is evilndash Only undue price discrimination is illegal

56 of 79

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 57: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Price Discrimination (Continued)

bull Price differentials that reflect differences in the cost of providing service is not price discrimination

ndash Price differences can be related to different services being provided

bull Different reliability or voltage levels

bull Different load or usage patterns

ndash Such price differences cannot be considered discriminatory from an economic perspective

57 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 58: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate

bull Reduce surplus capacityimprove utilization of existing capacity

ndash Examples include daynight and weekend differentials in long-distance pricing promotional rates for industrial customers

bull Accommodate competitive forces (may be necessary for a utility to compete in certain markets)

bull Encourage economic development (must get the blessing of regulators)

58 of 79

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 59: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)

bull Boost profits through increased sales to price-elastic customers ndash Special contracts ndash Economic development rates

bull Meet a social goalndash Lifeline ratesndash Businessresidential differentials in local

telephone accessndash Universal service support for high-cost

areas59 of 79

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 60: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Permissible Discrimination

bull Ramsey pricing (prices based on customersrsquo elasticities) maximizes social welfare (given a revenue-requirement constraint) and may be the most extreme form of permissible price discrimination

bull Price discrimination is often found to be permissible if authorized or directed by a state public utility commission ndash State action doctrine or legislation ndash The discrimination serves some public

interest such as economic development or capacity (cogeneration) deferral

60 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 61: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

bull Discriminatory prices must fall within the ldquozone of reasonablenessrdquo

bull At the high end of the zone rates can not be exorbitant or unconscionablendash Rates cannot be or exceed what an

unregulated monopolist would charge ndash Rates cannot be above the ldquostand-alonerdquo

cost of the service (eg the cost of self-supply)

61 of 79

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 62: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness

(Continued)bull At the low end of the zone rates cannot be so low

as to be predatory ndash Rates cannot be below incremental costndash Pricing below incremental cost may constitute anti-

competitive behaviorbull Courts are reluctant however to make a finding of

predatory behavior unless recoupment is possible

ndash Pricing below incremental cost implies that the service or customer is receiving a cross-subsidy from other services or customers ndash ie the utility is collecting a negative rate of return from the service or customer 62 of 79

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 63: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Tariffs (Time-of-Use Rates Rates to Encourage Targeted Energy

Usage Stand-by Tariffs)

63 of 79

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 64: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Time-of-Use Tariffs

Rates are designed to increase existing on-peak to off-peak rate differentials Shifting loads to off peak periods lowers peak demand and can reduce the need for additional generation capacity

Section 1252 of the Energy Policy Act of 2005 Public Law 109-58 requires each state regulatory authority to decide whether certain electric utilities under its jurisdiction should implement time-based rate schedules in accordance with 16 USC 2621(d)(14)

64 of 79

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 65: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Energy Policy Act of 2005

Sec 2621 Consideration and determination respecting certain

ratemaking standards

(1) Cost of service

(2) Declining block rates

(3) Time-of-day rates

(4) Seasonal rates

(5) Interruptible rates

(14)(b) (i-iv) Time-based metering and communications 65 of 79

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 66: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Standby Tariffs

Standby backup and maintenance tariffs allow customers with their own generation the availability to purchase power from the utility during times of need when their own sources of power are not operating

Parallel generation presents issues of cost recovery for metering distribution and transmission plant that may only be used part of the year along with how much to bill for actual energy purchased from the utility or sold back to the utility

Ideally tariffs should reflect appropriate costs for standby capacity in the utilityrsquos generation plant or purchased power contracts

66 of 79

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 67: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Attributing Costs to Different Categories of Customers Based on How Those Customers Cause Costs to be

Incurred (Customer Classes Categorization)

Customers are grouped together for rate design purposes based on like cost causation attributes (such as usage patterns load factor etc) into classes similar to the following

Residential - Single family1048678- Alternative Residence Nonresidential - Industrial such as manufacturing or automotive production - Commercial such as stores and offices - Wholesale (usually non-jurisdictional) - Irrigation and Farming - Public authorities such as Lighting and Pumping

67 of 79

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 68: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Calculating Costs of Individual Types of Service Based on the Costs Each Service Requires the Utility to Expend

Specific costs that are required to be expended for a particular customerrsquos needs are calculated to allow proper rate design to generate revenue to fully recover the expenditure

An example would be inclusion of a higher rate for Delivery Charges to recover additional costs of time-of-day metering under rates requiring time-of-day metering

The reverse is also true that for tariffs that allow utilities to reduce costs such as interruptible rates cost savings are passed on in the form of reduced rates to the customer who agrees to non-firm service

68 of 79

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 69: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer

Classbull Customer Charge

ndash Covers basic fixed cost of serving a customer (eg cost of customer hook-up)

bull Meter reading billing etc bull Charge for basic facilities used to provide service

bull Capacity or Demand Chargendash Covers cost imposed on the system by the userrsquos

maximum load or usagendash Usually excluded for residential service

bull Usage Chargendash Covers incremental cost of each unit of service

69 of 79

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 70: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Separating Costs Between Regulated and Non-Regulated Operations of a Utility

The cost of service study process also includes determining the ldquojurisdictionalrdquo amount of each base input Jurisdictionalization means separating the costs associated with providing electric service to retail customers which falls under MPSC jurisdiction from those costs associated with providing service at wholesale which is subject to FERC jurisdiction

70 of 79

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 71: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Jurisdictional Total Costs

Non-regulated Costs

Non-jurisdictional Costs

Jurisdictional Costs

Class 1 Class 2Class 3

Total Costs

71 of 79

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 72: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Determining Allowable Costs and Prudent Business Expenses

Part of the audit function in a rate proceeding is to determine if expenses were properly incurred or if a disallowance should be made A disallowance will reduce the necessary revenue requirement

Examples of improperly incurred expenses may be for items such as inappropriate donations and bonus compensation plans excessively high payments made to a parent companyrsquos service division or for non-regulated business expenses that were incorrectly allocated to the regulated utility

72 of 79

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 73: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Marginal Cost Pricing

bull Marginal cost pricing can conflict with certain regulatory objectives

ndash Possible large one-time increase in rates (transition problem)

ndash Revenue reconciliation via the Ramsey-pricing rule would tend to

bull Favor large price-elastic customers and

bull Hurt small price-inelastic customers (namely residential customers)

73 of 79

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 74: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example

bull Commission-approved revenue requirement $100 million

bull Customer-class cost allocationndash Residential $40 millionndash Commercial $35 millionndash Industrial $25 million

74 of 79

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 75: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

An Example (Continued)

ndash Thus the energy charge would have to be set so that the utility collects $28 million

ndash Namely the energy charge would equal $28 million360 million kWhs or 78 cents per kWh

ndash Overall the average price of electricity to residential customers would be 111 cents per kWh ($40 million360 million kWhs)

ndash The customer charge and the energy charge could be set at different values that would allow the utility to collect $40 million from the residential class

75 of 79

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 76: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Real-World Pricing

bull Regulators typically adhere to cost-based pricing (allowing the utility the opportunity to receive an adequate rate of return for its regulated services)

bull Regulators have the authority however to deviate from cost-based pricing in order to achieve certain social objectives ndash and often they do exercise it

ndash Examples Discounted rates to ensure affordability of electricity to low-income households or senior citizens economic development rates

76 of 79

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 77: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

General Factors to remember

bull Regulatory and statutory requirements

bull Economics ndash cost based or not

bull Gradualism ndash previous levels of rates

bull Physical constraints ndash firm or interruptible

bull Revenue stability

77 of 79

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 78: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

Acknowledgements

Thanks to National Association of Regulatory Utility Commissioners (NARUC) Institute of Public Utilities (IPU) National Regulatory Research Institute (NRRI) Detroit Edison and Consumers Energy for use of slides from previous presentations on cost of service and rate design

I want to also acknowledge the use of Dr James C Bonbrightrsquos book on ldquoPrinciples of Public Utility Ratesrdquo (1961)

78 of 79

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79
Page 79: Tariff Development III: Developing a Rate Design Energy Regulatory Partnership Program Abuja, Nigeria July 14-18, 2008 Ikechukwu N. Nwabueze, Ph.D. Director,

79 of 79

Questions

  • Tariff Development III Developing a Rate Design
  • Fair and Just Rates
  • Todayrsquos Pricing Issues
  • Goals of Rate Design
  • Goals of Rate Design (Continued)
  • Slide 6
  • Slide 7
  • Slide 8
  • Slide 9
  • Slide 10
  • The Traditional Ratemaking Process
  • Slide 12
  • Slide 13
  • Slide 14
  • Slide 15
  • Slide 16
  • Slide 18
  • Slide 19
  • Slide 20
  • Slide 21
  • Slide 22
  • Slide 23
  • Slide 24
  • Slide 25
  • Slide 26
  • Slide 27
  • Slide 28
  • Slide 29
  • A Feedback Loop
  • Slide 31
  • Unbundling
  • Unbundling (Continued)
  • A Point to Consider
  • A Point To Consider (Continued)
  • Rate Designs
  • Rate Designs (continued)
  • Slide 38
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Rate Designs (Continued)
  • Slide 41
  • Block Tariffs Decreasing-block rate
  • Increasing-block rate
  • Seasonal rate
  • Examples of Rate Designs
  • Slide 46
  • Illustration of the Hopkinson Demand Rate for Industrial Customers
  • Pricing Philosophies
  • Pricing Philosophies (Continued)
  • Slide 50
  • Slide 51
  • Conflicting Goals Efficiency vs Equity
  • Efficiency Goals
  • Economic Efficiency
  • Equity
  • Price Discrimination Due and Undue
  • Price Discrimination (Continued)
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate
  • Reasons for a Utility to Price Discriminate (Continued)
  • Permissible Discrimination
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness
  • Price Discrimination The Zone of Reasonableness (Continued)
  • Slide 63
  • Slide 64
  • Energy Policy Act of 2005
  • Standby Tariffs
  • Slide 67
  • Slide 68
  • Determining How Costs Will be Recovered From Customers Within Each Customer Class
  • Slide 70
  • Slide 71
  • Slide 72
  • Slide 73
  • From Costs to Regulated Prices A Rate Design Example
  • An Example (Continued)
  • Real-World Pricing
  • Slide 77
  • Slide 78
  • Slide 79