22
International Journal of Politics, Culture and Society, Vol. 13, No. 3, 2000 I. Political Economies and Transformations of Capitalism Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the Twentieth Century* Gary Herrigel The notion that there is a unitary trajectory associated with capitalist industrialization is identified with many of the great theorizers of economic development in the twentieth century: Schumpeter, Veblen, Trotsky, Lux- emburg, Keynes, Rostow, Gerschenkron, Chandler, Galbraith, and Schon- field. Each of these thinkers, while differing amongst themselves on a broad array of issues of theory, shared in common the view that there was an epochally specific social system of capitalism, founded on private property and free markets for labor power. In its early phases, this system operated according to a very specific logic of task- and product-specialization, guided by rational market exchange, that led to increases in the scale of production. This dynamic yielded a process of centralization and concentration in the organizational and property forms governing the social division of labor which, as the system matured, ultimately led to the displacement of market rationality by a rationality of hierarchy and bureaucracy. Naturally, these unitary theorists of capitalism held that different societies would experience this common process in different ways, owing to the contingencies of timing and the greater and lesser tractability of tradition. But that there was one process and that it had a single and determinable directionality was never doubted. Indeed, it was taken to be one of the great discoveries of modern economic science. This unitary view of capitalism and its trajectory of development was also a core part of classical social theory as it emerged in the first fifty years of the twentieth century—in particular in the work of Weber, Polanyi, Parsons, Aron, Bell and the neo-Marxian tradition of critical social theory represented most notably by Horkheimer, Marcuse, Pollock and Neumann. *A review essay of Harry F. Dahms Transformations of Capitalism: Economy. Society, and the State in the Twentieth Century. Main Trends in the World Series. New York: New York University Press, 1999. 405 © 2000 Human Sciences Press. Inc.

Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

International Journal of Politics, Culture and Society, Vol. 13, No. 3, 2000

I. Political Economies and Transformations of Capitalism

Social Theory and the Transformation ofCapitalism in the Twentieth Century*Gary Herrigel

The notion that there is a unitary trajectory associated with capitalistindustrialization is identified with many of the great theorizers of economicdevelopment in the twentieth century: Schumpeter, Veblen, Trotsky, Lux-emburg, Keynes, Rostow, Gerschenkron, Chandler, Galbraith, and Schon-field. Each of these thinkers, while differing amongst themselves on a broadarray of issues of theory, shared in common the view that there was anepochally specific social system of capitalism, founded on private propertyand free markets for labor power. In its early phases, this system operatedaccording to a very specific logic of task- and product-specialization, guidedby rational market exchange, that led to increases in the scale of production.This dynamic yielded a process of centralization and concentration in theorganizational and property forms governing the social division of laborwhich, as the system matured, ultimately led to the displacement of marketrationality by a rationality of hierarchy and bureaucracy. Naturally, theseunitary theorists of capitalism held that different societies would experiencethis common process in different ways, owing to the contingencies of timingand the greater and lesser tractability of tradition. But that there was oneprocess and that it had a single and determinable directionality was neverdoubted. Indeed, it was taken to be one of the great discoveries of moderneconomic science.

This unitary view of capitalism and its trajectory of development wasalso a core part of classical social theory as it emerged in the first fifty yearsof the twentieth century—in particular in the work of Weber, Polanyi,Parsons, Aron, Bell and the neo-Marxian tradition of critical social theoryrepresented most notably by Horkheimer, Marcuse, Pollock and Neumann.

*A review essay of Harry F. Dahms Transformations of Capitalism: Economy. Society, andthe State in the Twentieth Century. Main Trends in the World Series. New York: New YorkUniversity Press, 1999.

405

© 2000 Human Sciences Press. Inc.

Page 2: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

406 Herrigel

These theorists examined the broader social, political and cultural conse-quences of capitalism's movement from market to bureaucratic rationalitythat the unitary political economists described. In particular, they focusedon the way in which that development conditioned (and was conditionedby) the organization of social and political power, itself increasingly bureau-cratic, in modern societies. Further, their work linked this analysis of bu-reaucratic organization and control to the development of (increasinglytruncated) subjective senses of individual and collective possibility in mod-ern life. As with their counterparts in political economy, these thinkerswere sensitive to national difference stemming from contingencies in timingand tradition. But, despite their many substantive and theoretical differ-ences, none disputed that "modern capitalism" [or "industrial society"] wasa unitary historical form that profoundly shaped the way that all societiesgrappled with modernity.

The theoretical achievements of the above traditions—which are inpart excerpted, collected and summarized in the new reader Transforma-tions of Capitalism: Economy, Society, and the State in the Twentieth Centuryedited by the social theorist Harry Dahms1 have been formidable. Indeed,as Dahms's extensive introduction notes, they have produced the contempo-rary disciplines of sociology and political economy and have constructedextremely powerful understandings of contemporary reality in industrialdemocracies. To the first group of political economists, we owe core para-digms for understanding innovation, combined, uneven and late develop-ment, corporate organization in the firm, the joint stock enterprise andstate led macroeconomic governance. To the social theorists, we owe acritical appreciation of the affinity between the acquisitiveness, instrumen-talism and individuality of capitalist commodity production and the formal,hierarchical and instrumentally rational forms of bureaucratic organizationand hierarchical control that historically accompany them in political andsocial realms.

I have no intention in what follows of denying the validity or signifi-cance of the theoretical accomplishments of the classic twentieth centurytraditions that the Dahms volume celebrates. I will, however, argue thatthey are not as generally helpful or broadly relevant for analyzing andconstructing explanations of the developmental experience of industrialsocieties in the twentieth century as they, or Dahms, maintain. The generaland unitary theoretical ambition that defines the tradition results in a self-blinding dynamic in which theorists are unable to recognize the highlyparticular character and context dependence of what they take to be generaldevelopmental dynamics in industrial societies. Indeed, in my view, thisunitary tradition's linear and homogenizing conception of capitalist devel-opment has led to a profound underestimation of a wide array of perfectly

Page 3: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

Social Theory and Capitalism in the Twentieth Century 407

viable forms of organization, control, struggle and governance that havebeen constitutive of the various developmental experiences of industrialsocieties throughout the twentieth century. The unitary tradition's failureto appreciate alternative forms of organization is a great limitation. Atbest, it creates a sense of false necessity in the interpretive orientationof the theorist. At worst, it shackles the transformative imagination insocial theory.2

ALTERNATIVE NON-UNITARY TRADITIONS

The first point to be made is that the unitary tradition represented inthe Dahms volume has always been only one voice among many competingones in the collective effort to comprehend the industrial transformationsof society in the modern age. Even as it was emerging in the nineteenthcentury (in the writings of Marxian and classical economists and Darwiniansocial theorists), the unitary conception of capitalism's trajectory was op-posed by (among others): catholic corporatist thinkers who believed in afragmented social order of organic and customary communities of vocationand belief;3 pragmatic conservatives in the Burkean tradition who believedin the piecemeal, uneven, locally reflective and gradual nature of socialevolution;4 nationalist economists such as Friedrich List who denied thatthere was a common logic in industrialization and insisted on (nationallyempowering) local economic peculiarity;5 and, finally, anarchist and mutual-ist writers, such as Proudhon and Kropotkin who believed that the centraliz-ing and concentrating vision of the Marxian and classical economists satpoorly with the numerous and demonstrable ways in which human beingsflourished and created in decentralized, local and smaller scale productiveenvironments.6 In the twentieth century, especially on the left, oppositionto the unitary view of capitalism has been found in the experimentalistinclinations of pragmatic philosophers and social critics such as John Dewey,who believed in the radically historically specific, contingent, provisionaland imminently revisable character of organization and practice in modernlife.7 Opposition also came from pluralist writers who viewed tendenciestoward centralization and bureaucracy as one form of modern control andgovernance among many alternatives, including, not least, the extremelystrong and attractive experiments in modern societies in group and associa-tional governance.8

Though this debate has never been settled entirely in favor of one sideor the other, in recent decades the unitary traditions have come under verysignificant attack—empirically, theoretically and politically—from a broadarray of practical and academic locations. The catalyst for the critiques has

Page 4: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

408 Herrigel

been the massive transformations in the organization of industrial produc-tion, in corporate organization and in state finance and services that havebeen occurring in industrial societies all over the world. These transforma-tions are awkwardly explained by the unitary traditions, not only becausedifferent companies, regions and national governments are responding tosimilar pressures in very different institutional, political and strategic ways.The unitary narratives are also being rendered problematic, theoretically,because their core explanatory mechanisms are being falsified in practice.9For example, industrial production in a broad array of manufacturing indus-tries is being spread out away from a central firm location and distributedacross a wide array of independent property holders in the social divisionof labor.10 In other words, instead of the unitary logic of concentration andcentralization of capital, we see increasingly—in many different ways!!—spatial decentralization in production and a decoupling of the developmentof the division of labor from property. This picture is then further compli-cated when one views the organization of work within production in suchcontexts. Here the unitary strategy of separating conception from executionis in many factories being abandoned for forms of organization—multifunctional teams, simultaneous engineering—that self-consciouslyseek to reintegrate conception and execution in the interest of flexibilityand manufacturing quality."

These attacks in the empirical world by real agents on bureaucraticcontrol and hierarchy, finally, are not confined to business enterprise. Statebureaucracies are also being leveled through efforts to make organizationaldecision making more efficient, to unburden responsibility from centers ofauthority and to enhance the flexibility of organizations by locating decisionmaking authority closer to the origin of the problem (i.e., by reintegratingpolicy conception and execution).12 Moreover, in the same process of de-bureaucratization, functional specialization and the division of authoritybetween government and citizens is frequently being replaced by multifunc-tional community and government groups in which decisional authority isshared by the disparate members of the group and decision making capacityis exercised through discussion among the members of the group.13 Hereagain, instead of unitary instrumentalism, hierarchical control and atomiza-tion, regulatory governments are in this way introducing practical reflectionand explicit ideas of mutual dependence into policy making.

By pointing to these examples (and there are many others), contempo-rary critics of the unitary tradition in economic history,14 economic sociol-ogy,15 economic geography,16 evolutionary economics,17 political science,18

and social theory19 have not, for the most part, intended to suggest thatthe unitary conception of capitalism's trajectory is utterly wrong or indeed,being replaced by an alternative one. Everyone admits some historical

Page 5: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

Social Theory and Capitalism in the Twentieth Century 409

significance, under the proper conditions, for the forms of organization andcontrol identified by the unitary tradition. Moreover those critics writingon the contemporary period acknowledge that it is still possible, in partialagreement with the later essays in Dahms's volume (e.g., by Bluestone andHarrison, Zysman and Cohen, Kolko, Stallings and Streeck et al.) to findexamples in the world that seemingly correspond to the unitary expecta-tions: hierarchy, bureaucracy, and Taylorism still exist and are being repro-duced in all advanced industrial societies. The criticisms, however, arenot about suggesting an alternative trajectory or an alternative holisticconception of capitalism. Rather, they are about moving away from theidea that there needs to be a unitary trajectory at all and developing atheoretical language that makes it possible to account for what appears tobe enduring developmental, and organizational heterogeneity in industrialsocieties, polities and economies.

Seen in this light, it is striking that Dahms has chosen to celebrate theunitary position in a volume that is supposed to chronicle voices on thetransformation of capitalism in the twentieth century. No critics of theunitary conception are included and, to the extent that their arguments areaddressed (largely in passing in the editor's introduction and epilog), it isonly to dismiss them as superficial interpretations of economic changethat miss "deeper," "underlying" "dominant" and "more fundamental"features of capitalist continuity and development. This is an odd move,given the very profound tension between the developmental expectationsgenerated by the explanatory mechanisms in the unitary view and thevariety of observed forms of "non-unitary" organization and control un-earthed by the alternative critical tradition. How can this one sided repre-sentational strategy be explained? I think it comes from the self blindinglogic of the unitary conception of capitalism itself: When confronted withempirical evidence that is in tension with the trajectory of organization andcontrol predicted by the coherence of the unitary notion of capitalism, theimpulse is to make that evidence into something exogenous to fundamentalprocess e.g., intractable tradition or organizational forms that have to dowith the lack of synchrony in the unfolding of the deeper unitary logic. Iwill elaborate on this point below, but before doing so it is important toturn to the more detailed picture of twentieth century capitalism that theunitary Dahms volume presents.

THE UNITARY VIEW OF CAPITALISM IN THETWENTIETH CENTURY

Dahms's portrait of twentieth century capitalism has two framing largeclaims. The first is that the twentieth century saw the triumph of bureau-

Page 6: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

410 Herrigel

cracy, in the form of the corporation and the welfare state, in capitalistsociety. By this he means that the principles of hierarchical organizationand control replaced the market as the dominant mode of governance forcapitalism and that they pervade contemporary political and industrialexperience: "Focusing on structural shifts in advanced political economies,this volume brings to light the fundamental trends that operate "below"the surface of economic activity, conveying the central importance of orga-nization and control . . . [T]hese trends constitute crucial aspects of eco-nomic decision-making processes in bureaucratic capitalism" (page 7). Inthe twentieth century, control is hierarchical and organization bureaucraticfor Dahms. The second claim is that the United States is the historicalembodiment or realization of bureaucratic capitalism as a pure type. "Sincethe late nineteenth century," Dahms writes, "the United States may wellhave been the most capitalistic society" (page 9). The trends toward perva-sive bureaucratization in the economy and the polity "manifested them-selves more distinctly and clearly" in the U.S. than elsewhere (page 9).

Using these two framing arguments, Dahms arranges his unitary theo-rists to construct the following narrative about the emergence and evolutionof twentieth century bureaucratic capitalism. Guided by a pervasive capital-ist instrumental rationality and calculation, hierarchical and bureaucraticprinciples in the form of the industrial corporation (Chandler) triumphedcompletely over all traditionalist non-capitalist/non-bureaucratic opposi-tion in the early twentieth century United States economy. These hierarchi-cal and bureaucratic principles were extended and consolidated throughthe spread of joint stock enterprise and the increasing separation of owner-ship and control (Veblen, Berle & Means). The absolute hegemony ofthese principles of control and organization in the broader society as awhole was consolidated at mid century with the growth of the bureaucraticwelfare state, military industrial complex and American dominated interna-tional monetary and trade apparatus of the post war Golden Age (Keynes,Schumpeter, Polanyi, Kindleberger, Adams, Galbraith, Aron, Jordan). Forthe Europeans and Japanese during this period, Dahms writes, "the conceptas well as the reality of capitalism [was] tempered to a greater extent thanin the United States by political, social and cultural factors and preconceivednotions that imposed limits on the importance of the economy and its rolein the society" (page 9).

According to Dahms, the dominance of hierarchical control and bu-reaucratic organization became even stronger and more pervasive (andmore reactionary) in the United States with the deep crisis of the 1970sand eighties. This capitalist crisis was accompanied by the collapse of theBretton Woods system (Block), and initiated the decimation of the orga-nized labor movement (Bluestone & Harrison, Kolko), and attacks on the

Page 7: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

Social Theory and Capitalism in the Twentieth Century 411

welfare state (Offe, Bensman & Vidich). Out of the crisis, bureaucraticcapitalism in the U.S. emerged in the 1990s even stronger with the globalgrowth of the massively controlling and bureaucratic multinational (Gilpin),supported by the huge unchecked power of finance capital (Fligstein, Hel-leiner). Despite the neo-liberal ideology that accompanied the reactionagainst the welfare state and the labor movement, bureaucracy was actuallyexpanding (not retreating) in the state realm as well, as states increasinglysought to circumvent the market and foster innovation and technologicaldevelopment in their economies (Zysman and Cohen). Naturally, owingto differences in tradition and timing of the crisis, major capitalist powersmanifested the dominance of bureaucracy in their economies and politiesin different ways (Stallings & Streeck).

Dahms freely acknowledges that the authors he has assembled toconstruct this narrative do not all agree on theoretical first principles or inall of the details of the transformation of capitalism in the twentieth century(although he does not acknowledge that they all adhere to the unitarynotion of capitalism). He believes, legitimately, that despite this pluralism,it is nonetheless "possible to arrive at an intelligible narrative of the trans-formations of capitalism in the twentieth century" with this assemblage ofthinkers (page 24). This, in turn, gives him hope that it will one day bepossible to arrive at a grand and massive theoretical synthesis that willenable us to grasp contemporary capitalism as a unitary whole. He writes:"This collection ought to be understood as an attempt to prepare the kindof comprehensive perspective without which we cannot hope to addresseffectively any issues pertaining to capitalism in general. . . This is, afterall, the promise of modern times: that we can move beyond the narrowdefinitions of 'reality' (whether political, economic, ideological, religious, ortheoretical), to arrive at a better sense of the whole by means of unimpededintellectual and practical exchange" (page 26). Dahms believes that movingtoward the construction of a general, holistic conception of unitary capital-ism will make it more likely for societies to be able to solve the problemsthat such a capitalism generates.

AN ALTERNATIVE PERSPECTIVE

From my point of view, which is frankly sympathetic to the opponentsof the unitary conception, this is both a highly flawed portrait of twentiethcentury capitalism and a chimerical theoretical hope. The alternative non-unitary tradition objects to both of the core framing themes of Dahms'twentieth century: It does not construct the United States as the embodi-ment of a pure capitalist type, nor does it view hierarchical bureaucracy

Page 8: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

412 Herrigel

as the dominant form of organization and control in the century. Further,the alternative tradition takes the ambition to achieve unity and wholenessas an obstacle to the invention of solutions to problems generated in contem-porary historical contexts rather than as a necessary step toward suchsolutions. The character of the alternative position can best be grasped bylooking first at core theoretical differences between the alternative theoristsand the unitary theorists. Once these have been specified, it will also bepossible to show how the alternative tradition reconceives the activity ofsocial criticism and facilitates practical problem solving capacity. Finally,it will be possible to show how the problem of the development of industrialsocieties in the twentieth century can be framed very differently.

DIFFERENCES IN THEORY

The core difference in theory, from which all others follow, betweenthe unitary conceptions of capitalism and contemporary critics concernsthe way in which each tradition understands the historical specificity of theprocesses and institutions being observed. For the unitary tradition, historyhas a linear directionality in which the human condition either becomesbetter and better or in which tensions between forms of human potentialand given possibilities become increasingly acute.20 The line of unitaryhistory is marked by an ordered and hierarchical sequence of epochs offundamentally different but internally unitary and systematically integratedforms of social, economic and political order (agrarian empires, feudalism,capitalism, etc.), each of which themselves contain linearly arranged sub-stages of development (competitive capitalism, bureaucratic or corporatecapitalism, globalization, etc.). Historical specificity within this tradition,then, involves placing ideas, events, processes and institutions within thiselaborate linear and hierarchical structure. Naturally, social reality is ex-tremely heterogeneous, but the normative hierarchy and the ideal types(and sub-types) of historical systems make it possible to separate progres-sive from reactionary (or backward or irrelevant) phenomenon at any pointin time.

In unitary theory, moreover, the causal analytic and the normativedimensions of theory depend on and reinforce one another: Without a lineof progressive development, and a systematically interconnected matrix ofideal typical relations and processes that produce it, the specific normativeends of the theory would have no general, transhistorical authority. Theywould just be one normative position among many in a given present. Onthe other side, without the authority of a norm of progress, the analyticalprocedures of unitary theory would have no grounds for separating so

Page 9: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

Social Theory and Capitalism in the Twentieth Century 413

decisively progressive from reactionary or backward dimensions of hetero-geneous reality—especially if the "backward" elements tended to repro-duce themselves over time. This very modern union of universal normswith rational analytic concepts is notably resistant to empirical disconfirma-tion, not least because inconvenient pieces of data can be dismissed assuperficial or out of step with the "underlying" forces of development. Toan outsider, who does not accept the unitary theory's coupling of universalnorm and systematic theory, this resistance to evidence appears as a kindof blindness. Their normative confidence blinds them both to the possibilityof alternative trajectories and to the particularity of their own analyticaland normative claims.21

The alternative tradition, on the other hand, denies that history hasany inherent directionality or trajectory at all. Human potential is takento be effectively limitless, and as a consequence indescribable as a whole.Without a conception of the whole, however, it is not possible to constructa general normative ordering of progress with transhistorical validity, asthe unitary tradition does. For the contemporary alternative tradition, allnorms and practical understandings of individual and collective possibilityare local and historically specific.22

This difference from the unitary tradition has consequences in threeareas: 1.) for the way in which this alternative tradition conceives of social,political and economic order and the role of choice and action in the waythat an order changes; 2.) for the way it relates the past to the present; and3.) for the understanding it has for the critical role of social theory. Eachof these areas further distinguish the alternative tradition of social theoryfrom the unitary.

Social, Economic, and Political Order and the Role of Choice:

Because it rejects the notion of a transhistorical normative anchor bywhich local constellations of human potential can be ordered (as progressiveor backward etc.) the alternative tradition also rejects the analytical strategyof constructing an overarching, abstract, interconnected model of social,economic and political order—such as "bureaucratic capitalism." Instead,this non-unitary tradition approaches the analysis of a given moment ofheterogeneous social life with the expectation that it will have order andnot be chaotic, but that it will also be full of multiple possibilities forindividual and collective' enhancement as well as multiple forms of con-straint. Transformation and liberation is continually occurring within thevarious particular realms of a given social order while being blocked orconstrained in others. Any particular historical social order will likely be

Page 10: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

414 Herrigel

governed by multiple principles of order, contain an array of organizationalforms and be subject to numerous and competing forms of control. More-over, in most cases, the governing, organizing and controlling principles andtheir relation to one another will be either contested, ambiguous or both.

Conceiving of the social order in this way tends to cede structureless causal or shaping power and give strategic agency, deliberation andcreativity more importance in the process of social transformation than istypical of the unitary tradition. Contestation and ambiguity in the realmsof control and organization creates the possibility for agents to reshape thecontext in which their interactions are ordered. This possibility for effectiveagency is enhanced by the absence of a privileged global position fromwhich all of the possibilities and constraints can be identified: local playerswill see possibilities and constraints that are not apparent to others, creatingcongenital uncertainty in systems and the possibility for unforeseeableoccurrences. Struggle, conflict and deliberation among different perspec-tives and locations, as well as surprise, play crucial roles in the constructionof organizational forms and governance mechanisms that come to constitutea given social economic and political order.

Different theorists in the alternative tradition describe this non-unitaryconception of social, economic and political order in different ways. Geof-frey Hodgson, for example, has suggested that non-unitary evolutionarytheories are governed by what he calls the "impurity principle," by whichhe means that "there must always be a coexistent plurality of modes ofproduction, so that the social formation as a whole has the requisite struc-tural variety to cope with change."23 Hodgson and the evolutionary econo-mists, however, place less emphasis on creative agency than other theoristswithin the alternative tradition. Jonathan Zeitlin, for example, denies thatthere really are coherent modes of production that interpenetrate, in reality.Instead, he suggests that reflexive agents draw distinctions, in thought,between modes of production—in his parlance, epochs—that facilitate thecreation of hybrid forms of organization in practice. In his view the

The interpenetration of strategies and practices within industries and national econo-mies at any one time resulting from actors' efforts to hedge their organizationaland technological bets about future changes in the environment casts inevitabledoubt on the possibility of drawing sharp distinctions between epochs or periodssuch as the "age of Fordism" or the "era of flexibility." From this vantage point, itseems more useful to distinguish historical epochs according to changing orientationstowards the ideas of political and economic regarded as normal or paradigmaticthan to divide history into periods where social life was in fact thoroughly organizedaccording to one or another master principle. This notion of changing orientationstowards paradigmatic or normal ideas faithfully conveys both a sense of changingconstraints on historical actors and that of continuing scope for localized strategicchoice insofar as ideas of normality tend to magnify and thus to increase theimportance of dominant conceptions without reflecting or constraining anythinglike the totality of behaviour they purportedly characterize.24

Page 11: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

Social Theory and Capitalism in the Twentieth Century 415

On either of the alternative views, however, the result is that atany given time, the social political and economic order is understoodto be composed of highly contingent constellations of institutional andideological compromises and provisional solutions to common problems.They are newly created admixtures of possibility and constraint forgedout of problems and struggles that antecedent admixtures fostered.Specific forms of institutional organization and conceptions of authorityand control as well as whole complexes of them at the level of largesocieties will, on this alternative view, never achieve the kind of tightinterconnected coherence and power that they are given within unitarytheories. Non-unitary theory holds as unrealistic, overly simplistic oreven implausible notions of organization and control such as a formallyrational bureaucracy or a social order dominated through and throughby instrumental rationality. The normative hierarchy that encouragessuch a way of conceiving social order and its component institutions isabsent in non-unitary theory. In the unitary conception, social ordersfollow lines of development; in the alternative non-unitary conception,social orders transform themselves from what they were through thecreative local strategies of reflexive agents.

Relation Between the Present and the Past

Conceiving of the social, political and economic order as a highlycontingent congery of possibility and constraint, characterized by the contin-uous, unpredictable local lifting of constraint, realization of possibility and(inevitably) creation of new constraint has consequences for the way thatthe relationship between the past and the present are thought of in thealternative theories of industrial transformation. In the unitary tradition,where history moves along a path, the past is in all positive practical sensesuseless. The present has moved beyond the organizational forms, technolo-gies, and mechanisms of the past to more "developed" forms. The past isuseful only in an analytical sense, as a way of identifying the specificity ofthe present along the development path. The only practical role that thepast plays in the present is an obstructive and polluting one in the form of"tradition." Advocates of outmoded and backward modes of practice andorganization can use structural power to disrupt the forward march ofunitary progress. But over time, such traditions tend to give way to theacid of unitary capitalist progress. The present literally destroys the pastin unitary theories.

In the alternative tradition, where there is no path toward a beyond,merely contingent constellations of possibilities and constraints on human

Page 12: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

416 Herrigel

potential, the past can be extremely useful in a practical sense. It canserve as a reservoir of information involving past institutional experiments,viable but abandoned organizational forms, technologies, productionarrangements, forgotten possibilities for human improvement, and soforth, from which those in the present can learn. Thus, the alternativepresent is understood as a congery of problems and possibilities forliberation, while alternative history is viewed as a reservoir of ideas,beliefs, practices, understandings, organizational forms, and so forth thatcan be drawn on in the effort to solve problems, lift constraints andmake liberation possible.25 In the alternative theoretical frame, traditionis understood in an utterly different way than it is in the unitary tradition:Not as a barrier to change, but as contingently ordered congeries ofthought and/or practice from the past that continues to have value inthe present and that can be applied, abandoned, ignored or deconstructedas a whole or piecemeal by problem solving actors in the present. Thealternative tradition rejects the unitary view of tradition as a barrier tochange and social, economic or political transformation.

Alternative Critical Theory

Understanding the social political and economic order as a heterodoxconstellation of contingently related social arrangements (possibilities andconstraints), and the past as a reservoir of information that can have practi-cal value for problem solving in the present, makes for a very differentconception of the role of social theory and of "critical" analysis. In theunitary tradition, "critical theory" set itself the task of using reason (prop-erly understood) to identify ways in which the structure of the social order—capitalism—systematically stifled or repressed the realization of a veryparticular transhistorical conception of human potential. In the alternativeview, critical analysis tries to point to ways in which active and presentpossibilities for the development of human capacity might be realized,either through the elimination of constraint or through the identificationof possibility. The social theorist can also be publicly useful by marshallingknowledge of the organization of other contexts, both in the present andin the past, that not only identify possibility, but that can contribute to realproblem-solving and transformation in the social order. Naturally therewill be normative and analytical disagreements among analysts as to thecharacter of problems and on the possibility and desirability of their solu-tion. There is no transhistorical norm that makes it possible to order theimportance of social problems or prioritize them. Such ordering must bedone through local and historically specific debate, collective argument,

Page 13: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

Social Theory and Capitalism in the Twentieth Century 417

struggle and experimentation. The alternative tradition expects the evolu-tion and transformation of the social world to be driven by politics andstruggle and for all outcomes to be provisional and subject to revision.

A NON-UNITARY ACCOUNT OF THE TWENTIETH CENTURY

In light of these theoretical differences between the unitary traditionand the alternative tradition, it is easy to see how the latter tradition mightpresent a different narrative of the industrial experience in the twentiethcentury. In fact, writers in the non-unitary tradition present a host of differ-ent narratives of the experience of industrial development in the twentiethcentury.26 I do not intend to outline all the narrative variants. Instead, Iwill highlight how they collectively reject the main empirical claims of theunitary narrative, in particular the two most central claims in the unitaryaccount as represented by Dahms: that twentieth century industrial societyhas been dominated by hierarchy and bureaucratic organization and that theexperience of the United States corresponds to the most pure capitalist type.

Bureaucracy: Whatever it is, it's not the Whole Picture, Only Part of it

A major critique of the unitary idea of bureaucratic domination asa system of control based on hierarchy and instrumental or means/endsrationality comes from organization theory and empirical studies of bureau-cracy itself. Most studies show organizations of the sort that the unitarythinkers theorize rarely exist in such a unitary form in reality.27 Moreover,Hans Joas, after summarizing a vast array of empirical objections to theview that bureaucracy dominates modern organizations, notes that

there are equally numerous objections to the notion that the most rational formof organization is one with a hierarchical command structure. Arguments whichhave been brought forward to refute the reality and viability of the command-hierarchy model include reference to the specialized expert knowledge of subordi-nates, to their independent interaction with the outside world, to the stimulationof their ability to learn, to horizontal cooperation and to the need to encourageautonomous action.28

Each of those capacities in subordinate locations within a hierarchy,Joas emphasizes, significantly diffuses and refracts the capacity of those atthe top of a hierarchy to achieve or implement their ends. The degree ofcontrol in bureaucracy is thus, as an empirical matter, considerably lesspowerful than is represented in unitary views of the corporation or ofstate agencies. The alternative tradition is therefore highly skeptical ofarguments, especially from the unitary left, that attribute tremendous coher-

Page 14: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

418 Herrigel

ence and power to bureaucratic or corporate capital as an actor.29 Thereis little evidence that such coherent actors exist. So, before the questionof the degree to which bureaucracy was or was not a "dominant" form ofcontrol and organization in the twentieth century is even posed, the non-unitary tradition casts doubt upon the idea that bureaucratic organizationand hierarchical control ever existed in any actual form reminiscent of theway they are described in the abstract unitary conception.

Non-unitary theorists have provided other forms of counter evidenceto the claim that the twentieth century was a bureaucratically dominatedcentury as well. Business historians and historical political economists, forexample, have done a lot of historical work showing that forms of industrialproduction that did not take place within large vertically integrated corpora-tions existed all over the industrial world throughout the twentieth century.30

To take only the work on the United States, Philip Scranton has shownthat small and medium sized producers in machinery, textiles, furnitureand jewelry making and other sectors, in a broad array of industrial regions,prospered in the US economy in the period between the end of the nine-teenth century when the Chandlerian industrial corporation first emergedand World War II, when Scranton's narrative stops.31 The historical eco-nomic sociologists, Schwartz and Fish, have done extensive research onearly twentieth century Detroit showing that during the period of theinvention of "Fordism" and the creation of the multidivisional enterpriseby the Ford Motor Company and General Motors, the region was denselypopulated by small and medium sized supplier firms upon whom the largerassemblers were symbiotically related and dependent.32 Gerald Berk, anhistorical political economist, has extensively documented how even innational anti-trust law and industrial regulation the power of large corpora-tions was by no means completely determining of state policy in the firstpart of the twentieth century in the U.S. Indeed, much of the regulatorydiscussion was preoccupied with the proper way to govern highly specializedsmall- and medium-sized firm-dominated industries.33

Claims of bureaucratic dominance in the post-War period have alsobeen radically relativized. Critics of the unitary view emerged already in the1950s, sixties, and seventies among labor market economists and sociologistswho pointed out that the growth of large scale production did not lead toa unitary process of concentration and centralization. Rather, they pointedout that mass production growth seemed to be accompanied by the develop-ment of a "dual labor market" for less skilled labor and a "secondarysector" of smaller firms acting both as suppliers and competitors of largefirms during boom times.34 Not only that, others pointed out that the growthof the large mass production firm tended also to cultivate the developmentof sectors of craft production based specialists in capital goods who supplied

Page 15: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

Social Theory and Capitalism in the Twentieth Century 419

mass producers with production technology. These sectors were, on thewhole, dominated by small- and medium-sized—often family-owned firms.35

Finally, in the 1980s and 1990s, as producers of all sizes began to seekgreater flexibility in production, numerous scholars in political economy,economic geography and economic sociology (as discussed earlier in thisessay) pointed to both a growing vibrancy of small and medium sized firmproduction in many sectors and breathtaking efforts on the part of formerlylarge vertically integrated producers to dis-integrate their production andextend their sub-contracting ties. This literature, moreover, placed greatemphasis on the significant regional variation of institutions, strategies andgovernance structures within the U.S. that these trends revealed.36 Givenall of this historical evidence, it seems prudent to claim that even wherecorporate bureaucracy did exist in the twentieth century U.S. economy, itwas never a general phenomenon, but rather always a particular facet ofthe U.S. experience, coexisting (and colliding) with alternative forms oforganization, control and regional peculiarity.

Another way in which non-unitary theory has attempted to relativizethe significance of bureaucracy within the modern economy has been toindicate that hierarchy is only one of a wide array of empirically identifiableand theoretically coherent forms of governance in contemporary industrialeconomies. To chose only one argument from an array of competing onesamong non-unitary schools of thought, this point is developed well in therecent book by Michael Storper and Robert Salais, Worlds of Production:The Action Frameworks of the Economy.37 Storper and Salais thoroughlydeconstruct the core categories of unitary economic analysis—individualself-interested action, markets, hierarchies, preferences, growth—as wellas its core dualisms and constitutive distinctions—structure and action,state and market, economic and non-economic behavior—such that ratherthan acting as points of theoretical departure, those categories are under-stood as conditioned outcomes of prior cognitive and behavioral processes.Ultimately they suggest that there are four quite distinct possible worldsof production in the contemporary world economy, governed by differentframeworks of action, different kinds of rationality, different institutions,different standards of profitability, different ways of dealing with labor anddifferent propensities to innovation. The four worlds, the InterpersonalWorld, Market World, Intellectual World and Industrial World are idealtypes, but the authors show that they are found in various interpenetratedcombinations in actual practice ("real worlds") in all contemporary ad-vanced economies.38 The point to be emphasized here is that in the Storper/Salais typology the bureaucratic organization and hierarchical control thatthe Dahms volume regards as dominant in twentieth century capitalism isconfined by Storper and Salais to the Industrial World. In their view then,

Page 16: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

420 Herrigel

in a conceptual sense, bureaucratic governance is only one of four possiblecontemporary forms of organization and control in the economy. And,further, this ideal form, they show, is actually nowhere realized in its pureform in historical and actual practice.

All of these examples have been presented simply to point out thatthere are very many sound empirical, conceptual and theoretical argumentsagainst the view, represented by the thinkers in the Dahms volume, thathierarchical bureaucracy was/is the dominant form of organization andcontrol in industrial societies during the twentieth century. Surely the ele-ments of bureaucratic capitalist order noted by Dahms and his authors—hierarchy, the separation of ownership and control, financial pressure onmanagement, etc.—were/are dimensions of the twentieth century experi-ence. But, to call them dominant or to argue that they shaped (or continueto shape) the development of whole national industrial orders, even in theUnited States, is to be blind to the wide variety of alternative forms oforder and strategies for transformation that characterize the experience ofdevelopment in advanced industrial countries in the twentieth century.

THE UNITED STATES AMONG A VARIETY OF CAPITALISMS

The examples of alternative, non-bureaucratic forms of developmentwithin the United States during the twentieth century may also serve aspieces of evidence for why the alternative tradition does not regard theUnited States as the practical embodiment of a pure model of capitalism.There are simply too many contending, competing, regionally dispersedand contradictory forms of governance and development within the U.S.economy to be able to represent the whole economy in a unitary way—muchless as somehow dominated by the corporate bureaucratic form or financecapitalism. The U.S. is a congery of many forms of capitalism.

For the non-unitary tradition, this is no surprise, for it is highly skepticalof the very idea of a single or pure type of capitalism. Indeed, conceivingof social, economic and political order as a historically specific congery ofpractices and institutions, leads the alternative tradition to be very fasci-nated with and preoccupied by the whole problem of variety among indus-trial societies. In the non-unitary tradition, the other industrialized countriesare not viewed as lesser variants of the U.S. case. Rather, they are viewedin the same way the U.S. is: as distinctive, nationally bounded, congeriesof organization and control, compose by reflexive actors confronted bysimilar but not identical world market pressures, and capable of drawingon different historical resources. When the comparative process of industri-alization is viewed in this way, interesting questions then become: How

Page 17: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

Social Theory and Capitalism in the Twentieth Century 421

well do these systems compete against one another at any one point intime? What are the relative transformational possibilities and constraintsthat each face in the context of a new global dynamic of exchange andcompetition? European and Japanese (and all other) industrialisms aredifferent and, from a U.S. perspective, are competitors, but also possibleexemplars for alternative practice, and sources of inspiration for thosegrappling with local problems and/or seeking change. Such reflective andcompetitive engagements among varieties of industrial society are what inthe end drive global change, not any underlying unitary logic of capitalism.

Dahms and the unitary tradition hang a lot of their argument forviewing the U.S. as a pure type on the importance of traditional beliefsand institutions in economies outside the U.S. acting as a barrier to industrialdevelopment. But a considerable body of alternative empirical work existsshowing that so-called traditional elements in industrializing countries haveeither been irrelevant to the adoption of new forms of industrial technology,organization and mechanisms of control, or they have actually contributedto highly innovative new forms that result in highly competitive new ar-rangements. An example of the irrelevance of tradition to the industrializa-tion process is the Japanese encounter with Taylorism in the twentiethcentury.39 In his recent book on the subject, William Tsutsui writes: "Scien-tific Management was smoothly aligned with Japanese conceptions of tradi-tion".40 More specifically: "Taylorite doctrines . . . were rooted in 'tradi-tion' and almost effortlessly recast as 'Japanese-style management' whenthey were imported and applied in Japan. In the end, extensive cross-fertilization by American ideas and a broad parallelism with Western prac-tice, rather than culturally specific and autonomous course of development,characterized the Japanese experience with Scientific Management."41 Tra-dition in this case, was an accommodating interlocutor for the new formof organization; not a force of opposition. An example of how traditioncan contribute actively to the construction of new and highly competitivearrangements is the German system of workplace codetermination. Thissystem, which enforces dialogue between labor and capital inside of plants,was forged during the American occupation of Germany out of a set ofcompromises between social catholic, socialist, bourgeois conservative, andliberal American ideas about property and the proper limitation of its socialpower.42 The system has been widely praised for its flexibility and positivecontribution to German manufacturing success.43

CONCLUSION

It would be possible to go marshalling empirical example after empiri-cal example to show how overdrawn or incorrect the claims of the unitary

Page 18: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

422 Herrigel

tradition of social theory are. But I think the point has been made. Incommitting itself to a single, abstract, tightly interconnected and linearconception of capitalism and its development, the unitary traditions insocial theory and political economy have blinded themselves to the greatvariety of social, political and economic organization that have consistentlyreproduced themselves in advanced industrial societies throughout thetwentieth century. Their preoccupation with corporate and bureaucraticpower, in particular, causes them to vastly overestimate its coherence andultimately its significance in social life. It is, moreover, worth it to pointout that this preoccupation with a particular form of power in social organi-zation has, in its critical and left variants, produced a form of social theoryprimarily concerned with constraints on the capacity of human beings toextend and develop their potential. The critical and reflective capacity toidentify transformative possibilities in social organization, in other words,has been undermined by the false necessity invested in the constraints ofbureaucratic power.

The alternative non-unitary tradition, on the other hand, is concernedwith identifying practical possibilities for human improvement in social life.For this tradition, the extent of bureaucratic and corporate power in sociallife is an empirical question, unconnected to a set of commitments tothe nature and trajectory of capitalism. In an effort to unearth as manypossibilities for transformation as possible, the tradition has preoccupieditself with identifying the broad variety of organizational forms and mecha-nisms of control that contemporary industrial societies are producing. Forthe alternative tradition, the critical project is to try to learn from thisvariety and to communicate this learning in the interests of the practicallifting of constraint and the enhancement of human possibility.

ENDNOTES

1. Harry F. Dahms TRANSFORMATIONS OF CAPITALISM: ECONOMY, SOCIETY,AND THE STATE IN THE TWENTIETH CENTURY (Main Trends in the WorldSeries) (New York: NYU Press, 1999).

2. On false necessity in social theory, see Roberto Unger, False Necessity, (New York:Cambridge University Press, 1987).

3. Birke, A. (1971). Bischof Ketteler und der deutsche Liberalismus. Mainz, Griinewald.4. Uday Mehta, (1999) Liberalism and Empire. A Study in Nineteenth Century British Liberal

Thought, (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).5. Friedrich List, (1904), The National System of Political Economy, English edition, (Lon-

don: Longman).6. K. Steven Vincent, (1984) Pierre-Joseph Proudhon and the Rise of French Republican

Socialism, (Oxford: Oxford University Press).7. John Dewey, 1927, The Public and its Problems, (Athens: Ohio University Press, 1954);

id. (1931), Individualism. Old and New, (London: George Allen & Unwin); id. 1939,Freedom and Culture, (New York: GP Putnam's Sons).

Page 19: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

Social Theory and Capitalism in the Twentieth Century 423

8. Paul Hirst, (1989) The Pluralist Theory of the State: selected writings of GDH Cole, JNFiggis and HJ Laski, (London: Routledge); Mary Parker Follett, 1926, The New State.Group Organization and the Solution of Popular Government, (New York: Longmans,Green & Co.) and David P. Mandell, "The Promise of Pluralism: Pragmatism, Pluralismand Civil Society," Ph.D. dissertation, Department of Political Science, University ofChicago (March 1999).

9. For a systematic critical discussion of additional unitary economic explanatory mecha-nisms that I do not mention in my list that follows, see G. Dosi, C. Freeman, and S.Fabiani, "The process of economic development: Introducing some stylized facts andtheories on technologies, firms and institutions" in Industrial and Corporate Change,Volume 3, Number 1, 1994, pages 1-46.

10. For a general description of these new systems, see Charles Sabel, "Learning by Monitor-ing" in Neil Smelser and Richard Swedberg, eds., The Handbook of Economic Sociology,(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994) pages 137-165; for a wide range of casestudies of such systems in the automobile industry, see Robert Boyer. Elsie Charron,Ulrich Jurgens and Steven Tolliday, eds. Between Imitation and Innovation: The transferand hybridization of productive models in the international automobile industry, (Oxford:Oxford University Press, 1998); Thomas A. Kochan, Russell D. Lansbury, and John PaulMacDuffie (eds.), After Lean Production: Evolving Employment Practices in the WorldAuto Industry (Ithaca, NY: ILR Press, 1997); John Paul MacDuffle and Susan Helper,"Creating Lean Suppliers: Diffusing Lean Production through the Supply Chain" inCalifornia Management Review. Vol. 39, No. 4, Summer 1997, pages 118-151.

11. For German examples, see Michael Schumann, "New Concepts of Production and Produc-tivity" in Economic and Industrial Democracy, 1998, vol. 19: 17-32; Michael Schumann,"The German Automobile industry in Transition" in The Economic and Labour RelationsReview, 1998: 221-247; Michael Schumann, "The Development of Industrial Labour-New Inconsistencies" lecture to Arbetslivsinstitutet in Stockholm, May 1998; MichaelSchumann and Detlef Gerst, "Innovative Arbeitspolitik—Ein Fallbeispiel. Gruppenar-beit in der Mercedes Benz AG" in Zeitschrift fttr Arbeits- u. Organisationspsychologie(1997) 41 (N.F. 15) 3: pages 143-156; for US examples, John Paul MacDuffie, "TheRoad to 'Root Cause': Shop Floor Problem-Solving at Three Auto Assembly Plants" inManagement Science, Vol. 43, No. 4, April 1997 pages 479-502.

12. See Philip Cooke and Kevin Morgan, The Associational Economy, (Oxford: OxfordUniversity Press, 1998) Michael Storper, The Regional World, (New York: GuilfordPress, 1998).

13. see Archon Fung, "Street Level Democracy; A Theory of Popular Pragmatic Deliberationand Its Practice in Chicago School Reform and Community Policing, 1988-1997," Ph.D.dissertation, Department of Political Science, Massachusetts Institute of Technology,February 1999; Ulrich Mueckenberger, "Zivilgesellschaft und Politische Theorie. Bezugzum Ansatz Eurexcter/Zeiten und Qualitat der Stadt" ms, Hamburg; Michael C. Dorfand Charles F. Sabel, 'A Constitution of Democratic Experimentalism', Columbia LawReview 98, 2 (1998).

14. Charles Sabel & Jonathan Zeitlin, World of Possibilities. Flexibility and mass production inwestern industrialization, (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1997); Philip Scran ton,Endless Novelty: Specialty Production and American Industrialization, 3865-1925(Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1997), esp. ch. 13, Rudolf Boch,, "Zunfttraditionund friihe Gewerkschaftsbewegung. Ein Beitrag zu einer beginnenden Diskussion milbesonderer Berucksichtigung des Handwerks im Verlagssystem," Prekitre Selbstiindigkeit,Zur Standortbestimmung vom Handwerk, Hausindustrie und Kleingewerbe im Industriali-sierungsprozess, ed. Ulrich Wegenroth. (Stuttgart: Franz Steiner, 1989) Rudolf Boch, DieEntgrenzung der Industrie. Zur Industrialisierungsdebatte im rheinischen Wirtschaftsbilrg-ertum, 1814-1857, (Gottingen: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht, 1991); Boch, Rudolph, Hand-werker Sozialisten gegen die Fabrikgesellschaft, (Gottingen: Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht,1985).

15. Grannovetter, Mark, "Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embed-dedness," American Journal of Sociology 91.3 (1985): 481-510; Walter W. Powell and

Page 20: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

424 Herrigel

Paul J. DiMaggio, eds., The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, (Chicago:University of Chicago Press, 1990).

16. Michael Storper and Allen Scott, eds. Pathways to Industrialization and Regional Develop-ment, (London: Routledge, 1992), Michael Storper and Robert Salais, Worlds of Produc-tion. Collective Action and the Economic Identities of Nations and Regions, (CambridgeMA: Harvard University Press, 1997), Allen Scott, New Industrial Spaces: Flexible Produc-tion and Regional Economic Development in the USA and Western Europe. (London:Pion, 1988); Anna Lee Saxenian, Regional Advantage, (Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer-sity Press, 1991); Cooke & Morgan, The Associational Economy.

17. G. Dosi, R Nelson, G. Silverberg and L. Soete, eds., Technical Change and EconomicTheory, (London: Pinter, 1988); Geoffrey Hodgson, Economics and Evolution. BringingLife back into Economics, (Cambridge: Polity, 1993).

18. Gerald Berk, Alternative Tracks, (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1993);Victoria Hattam, Labor Visions and State Power, (Princeton: Princeton University Press,1992); Richard Locke, Remaking the Italian Economy, (Ithaca, NY: Cornell UnversityPress, 1995).

19. Dorf & Sabel, "A Constitution of Democratic Experimentalism;" Unger, False Necessity,Hans Joas, The Creativity of Action, (Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1996).

20. The tradition is divided in what it thinks: those closer to classical economics believe theformer while those closer to Marxism believe the latter.

21. For a very thorough elaboration of this critique, see Unger's, False Necessity.22. A good example of the position elaborated at this level of theory is John Dewey, Recon-

struction in Philosophy, (Boston: Beacon Press, 1957) and The Public and its Problems(Athens: Ohio University Press, 1954). Contemporary elaborations, from slightly differentperspectives within the alternative tradition, are Geoffrey Hodgson, Economics andEvolution, and Unger, False Necessity. Also on the very broad understanding of "local"and "historically specific" within pragmatism, see Eric MacGilvray, "The Task BeforeUs: Pragmatism and The Narratives of Liberal Democracy," Ph.D. dissertation, Depart-ment of Political Science, University of Chicago, December 1999.

23. Geoffrey Hodgson, "Varieties of capitalism and varieties of economic theory" in Reviewof international political economy, Vol. 3, No. 3, Autumn 1996, pages 380-433, quote page403; This principle is also extensively discussed in Hodgson, The Democratic Economy:A New Look at Planning, Markets and Power, (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1984), esp.pp. 85-109.

24. Jonathan Zeitlin, "Productive Alternatives: Flexibility, Governance, and Strategic Choicein Industrial History" To appear in Franco Amatori and Geoffrey Jones (eds.), BusinessHistory Around the World at the End of the Twentieth Century (Cambridge UniversityPress, forthcoming). Further elaboration of this perspective may be found in the introduc-tions to Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities, pages: 4-5, 29-33 and Jonathan Zeitlin and Gary Herrigel, eds., Americanization and Its Limits: Re-working US Technology and Management in Postwar Europe and Japan (Oxford Univer-sity Press, 2000).

25. This poses the problem of how to narrate the relationship between events and organiza-tions in the past to those in the present, an area that is receiving increasing attention inalternative social theory. This will not be addressed in the text, but see the discussionin the introduction to Charles Sabel and Jonathan Zeitlin, eds., World of Possibilities,as well as the literary theoretical work of advocates of more "open" and non deterministicnarrative forms: Gary Saul Morson, Narrative and Freedom, (New Haven: Yale UniversityPress, 1994) and Michael Andre Bernstein, Foregone Conclusions. Against ApocalypticHistory, (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1994).

26. Examples of various non-unitary takes on the industrial experience of the last century:Michael Piore and Charles Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide. Possibilities for Prosperity,(New York: Basic Books, 1984); Michael C. Dorf and Charles F. Sabel, 'A Constitutionof Democratic Experimentalism'; Steven Tolliday and Jonathan Zeitlin (eds.), BetweenFordism and Flexibility: The Automobile Industry and Its Workers (2nd ed., Oxford: Berg,1992; orig. 1986); Mary Nolan, Visions of Modernity, (Oxford: Oxford University Press,

Page 21: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

Social Theory and Capitalism in the Twentieth Century 425

1994); Gary Herrigel, Industrial Constructions. The sources of German industrial power,(New York: Cambridge University Press, 1996); Steven Tolliday and Jonathan Zeitlin,eds.). The Power to Manage? Employers and Industrial Relations in Comparative-Histori-cal Perspective (London: Routledge, 1991); Philip Scranton, Endless Novelty; MichaelSchwartz, 'Markets, Networks, and the Rise of Chrysler in Old Detroit', forthcoming inEnterprise and Society 1 (2000); idem and Andrew Fish, 'Just In Time Inventories in OldDetroit', Business History 40 (1998); Michael A. Cusumano, The Japanese AutomobileIndustry: Technology and Management at Nissan and Toyota (Cambridge, MA: HarvardUniversity Press, 1985); Koichi Shimokawa, 'From the Ford System to the Just-in-TimeProduction System: A Historical Study of International Shifts in Automobile ProductionSystems, their Connection, and their Transformation', Japanese Yearbook on BusinessHistory 10 (1993), 84-105; Steven Tolliday 'The Diffusion and Transformation of Fordism:Britain and Japan Compared', in Robert Boyer et al Between Imitation and Innovationpages 57-95; Michael Storper and Robert Salais, Worlds of Production. Collective Actionand the Economic Identities of Nations and Regions, (Cambridge MA: Harvard UniversityPress, 1997).

27. in addition to the studies in Powell and DiMaggio, The new institutionalism in Organiza-tional analysis; such basic doubts about the unitary rationality of bureaucracy are expressedin classic works of post war sociology: Alvin Gouldner, Patterns of Bureaucracy, (NewYork: Free Press, 1954); and James March and Herbert Simon, Organizations, (NewYork: John Wiley & Sons, 1958).

28. Joas, The Creativity of Action, pages 150-151.29. Dahms invokes a lot of this work to defend his view, set out in his epilog, that bureaucratic

multinationals are extending their tentacles of control deeper into society. Examples hegives are Bennett Harrison, Lean and Mean. The Changing Landscape of CorporatePower in the Age of Flexibility (New York: Guilford Press, 1997; much of this unitaryliterature on Globalization can be found summarized in Manuel Castells, The Rise ofNetwork Society, Vol. I of The Information Age: Economy Society and Culture, (MaidenMass: Blackwell, 1996).

30. For a survey of historical work on other advanced economies, see the article by Zeitlin"Productive Alternatives. . . ."

31. Philip Scranton, Endless Novelty esp. chapter 13.32. Michael Schwartz, 'Markets, Networks, and the Rise of Chrysler in Old Detroit', forthcom-

ing in Enterprise and Society 1 (2000); idem and Andrew Fish, 'Just In Time Inventoriesin Old Detroit', Business History 40 (1998), 48-71.

33. Gerald Berk, "Neither Competition Nor Administration: Brandeis and the Anti-trustReforms of 1914" in Studies in American Political Development, 9,1994, pages 24-59 andidem, "Communities of Competitors: Open Price Associations and the American State,1911-1929" in Social Science History, 20, 3, 1996, pages 375-400. For an overview of USanti trust debate in the 20th century, see Rudolph Peritz, Competition Policy in America,1888-1992, (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1996).

34. see the essays by Michael Piore in Susanne Berger and Michael Piore, Dualism andDiscontinuity in Industrial Society, (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1979).

35. see Gary Herrigel, "Industry as a form of order: A historical comparison of the develop-ment of the machine tool industry in the United States and Germany" in JR Hollingsworth,Wolfgang Streeck and Philippe Schmitter, eds., Governing Capitalist Economies, (Oxford:Oxford University Press, 1986).

36. see Michael Piore and Charles Sabel, The Second Industrial Divide, (New York: BasicBooks, 1984); Allen Scott, New Industrial Spaces; Anna Lee Saxenian, Regional Advan-tage; Michael Storper and Allen Scott, eds. Pathways to Industrialization and Regional De-velopment.

37. (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1997).38. The authors survey the entire advanced industrial world, but present detailed case studies

of interpenetrated "real worlds" in Italy, France and the US. While recognizing that theideal types are not found in ideal form in reality, the various worlds can be illustratedhere with the following examples: The intellectual world emphasizes the kind of dynamic

Page 22: Social Theory and the Transformation of Capitalism in the ... · Social Theory and the Transformation of ... the joint stock enterprise and ... functional specialization and the division

426 Hcrrigel

personal interaction and compulsive networking one observes in dynamic regions such asSilicon Valley; the market world is a world based on largely on exchange and competitionbetween relatively fixed entities, such as are represented in neo-classical textbooks; theIndustrial world is intended to describe the unitary Chandlerian world of hierarchicalmass producers and the interpersonal world is intended to describe the constant circulationand exchanges of skill and market knowledge that one observes in traditional indus-trial districts.

39. William Tsutsui, Manufacturing Ideology: Scientific Management in Twentieth CenturyJapan, (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1998).

40. ibid. p. 239.41. ibid. p. 240.42. see the discussion of the formation of this law from this perspective in my own "American

Occupation, Market Order and Democracy: Reconfiguring the Japanese and GermanSteel industries after World War II" in Jonathan Zeitlin and Gary Herrigel, eds. American-ization and its Limits, pages 340-400, esp. 375-380.

43. for praise, see Kathy Thelen, Union of Parts, (Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press, 1992);Lowell Turner, Democracy at Work, (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1991), DavidSoskice, "Divergent production regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Econo-mies in the 1980s and 1990s" in Herbert Kitschelt, Peter Lange, Gary Marks & JohnStephens, eds.. Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism, (New York: Cam-bridge University Press, 1999) pages 101-133.