19
- WP/16/52 Singapore’s Export Elasticities: A Disaggregated Look into the Role of Global Value Chains and Economic Complexity By Elif Arbatli and Gee Hee Hong

Singapore's Export Elasticities: A Disaggregated Look into the Role

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

-

WP/16/52

Singapore’s Export Elasticities: A Disaggregated Look into the Role of Global Value Chains and Economic Complexity

By Elif Arbatli and Gee Hee Hong

© 2016 International Monetary Fund WP/16/52

IMF Working Paper

Asia and Pacific Department

Singapore’s Export Elasticities: A Disaggregated Look into the Role of Global Value Chains and Economic Complexity

Prepared by Elif Arbatli and Gee Hee Hong1

Authorized for distribution by Alex Mourmouras

March 2016

Abstract

Singapore is one of the world’s most open economies, with the size of its trade reaching about 350 percent of its GDP. With the rise of highly diversified cross-border production networks, Singapore has come to play an integral role in the global supply chain with heavy reliance on foreign contents in its exports and production. It has also successfully moved up the value chain, exporting goods with high sophistication and economic complexity. Against this backdrop, in this paper, using disaggregate industry/product level trade data, we revisit Singapore’s export elasticities and find that growing participation in global production chains and rising export complexity are important determinants.

JEL Classification Numbers: D57, F10, F14, F31

Keywords: Trade elasticities, trade structure, global supply chain, economic complexity

Authors’ E-Mail Addresses: [email protected]; [email protected]

1 We are grateful to Swarnali Ahmed, Max Appendino, Varapat Chensavasdijai, Nan Li, Alex Mourmouras, Edward Robinson, Rachel van Elkan and our colleagues in the Asia and Pacific Department (APD) for very helpful comments and suggestions and to Jingzhou Meng for excellent research assistance.

IMF Working Papers describe research in progress by the author(s) and are published to elicit comments and to encourage debate. The views expressed in IMF Working Papers are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or IMF management.

Contents PageAbstract ......................................................................................................................................2 I. Introduction ............................................................................................................................4 II. Structure and Role of Singapore’s External Trade ................................................................6

A. External Trade and Economic Structure. ..........................................................................6 B. Composition of Trade. ......................................................................................................8 C. Economic Complexity. .....................................................................................................9

III. Export Elasticities ................................................................................................................9IV. Results................................................................................................................................11V. Conclusions .........................................................................................................................16

Tables Table 1a. Export Elasticities ....................................................................................................11 Table 1b. Export Elasticities ....................................................................................................11 Table 2. Effect of Domestic Value-added Share on Export Elasticities ..................................14 Table 3. Effect of Economic Complexity on Export Elasticities .............................................15 Table 4. Effect of Economic Complexity on Export Elasticities for Major Product Groups ..16 Table 5. Effect of Domestic Value-added Share and Economic Complexity on Export Elasticities ................................................................................................................................16

Figures

Figure 1 . Exports as Percent of Total Output by Industry ........................................................7 Figure 2 . Share of Value-added by Primary Inputs ..................................................................7 Figure 3 . Import Intensity and Export Orientation of Sectors ..................................................7 Figure 4 . Share of Employee Compensation and Export Orientation .............................................7 Figure 5 . Value-added Share of Exports for Different Industries .............................................8 Figure 6 . Value-added Share of Exports for Different Industries .............................................8 Figure 7 . Value-added Share of Exports for Different Industries .............................................8 Figure 8 . Index of Economic Complexity–Selected Countries ................................................9 Figure 9 . Distribution of Economic Complexity by Export Products ......................................9 Figure 10. Distribution of Export Elasticities ..........................................................................12 Figure 11. Distribution of Price and Income Elasticities within Category HS 84 ...................13 Figure 12. Distribution of Price and Income Elasticities within Category HS 85 ...................13 Figure 13. Distribution of Domestic Value-added Share of Exports by Product ....................14 Figure 14. Distribution of Complexity Index within Individual Product Groups....................15

REFERENCES ........................................................................................................................18 

I. INTRODUCTION

Singapore is one of the world’s most open economies, with the size of its trade (exports plus imports) reaching about 350 percent of its GDP. This reflects Singapore’s role as a trading port and an oil and gas hub and its participation in regional supply chains, which has over time let to a significant increase in trade in intermediate goods. With the rise of highly diversified cross-border production, Singapore now plays an integral role in the regional and global supply chain with heavy reliance on foreign contents in its exports and production. Singapore has also successfully moved up the value chain, exporting products with ever increasing sophistication and complexity.2

Against this backdrop, this paper revisits the size and determinants of Singapore’s export elasticities in light of growing trade in intermediate inputs and goods of growing complexity. The size of these elasticities are important for understanding the role of the exchange rate, competitiveness and external demand in the determination of output and trade balance. Export elasticities are also critical to understand the transmission of the exchange rate based monetary policy in Singapore. The Monetary Authority of Singapore (MAS) uses the nominal effective exchange rate as its monetary policy instrument given the relative importance of the exchange rate in the context of a very open economy. Exchange rate changes can affect profits and trade volumes differently, depending upon the price pass-through to import and export prices and the price elasticity of exports and imports. While fully recognizing the importance of the first channel – exchange rate pass-through to export prices -, in this paper, we focus on the price elasticity of exports.

The novelty of our empirical approach is that we explore the size of Singapore’s export elasticities at the disaggregated industry/product level, using the mean group estimator (MG) of Pesaran and Smith (1995) and fixed-effects regressions. This allows us to consider the heterogeneity across different products and explore how product complexity and position in

2 The economic complexity of a country’s export product used in the paper follows Hidalgo and Hausmann (2009). The notion of economic complexity is related to the number of countries that export the product and the diversity of those countries’ exports. If a product is produced by a small number of countries and if those countries have a diverse export product mix, the economic complexity of the product is measured to be higher. See section II.B for further details.

5

global value chains, or foreign value added in exports affect elasticities3. Product and industry level heterogeneity are important in the context of the ongoing structural change in Singapore’s economy and the tilt of exports towards more sophisticated products, which allows Singaporean firms to capture a higher share of value added.

Our work contributes to recent theoretical and empirical studies that focus on the role of global value chains (GVCs) in global trade. The complex input-output linkages of the intermediate goods and output crossing borders multiple times motivate a new interpretation of the trade elasticities on several dimensions.4 The fragmentation of production in global trade, points to the need to distinguish between gross versus value-added (net of imported inputs) trade data in estimating trade elasticities (Johnson and Noguera (2012a, 2012 b, 2014), Bems and Johnson (2015)). For instance, IMF (2015) empirically assesses the effect of real effective exchange rate changes on exports and imports distinguishing between GVC and non-GVC-related trade. They find that participation in GVCs and a country’s position in GVCs (upstream versus downstream position), are important determinants of the size of trade elasticities.

Furthermore, as countries become more deeply integrated in global production chains, they demand more foreign value-added to use in their production and exports. This aspect is particularly relevant in understanding the trade elasticities of Singapore. In fact, Singapore is a country with one of the highest share of foreign value-added contents in its exports—40 percent in 2011 (OECD, Trade in Value-Added Data)—on par with countries such as Hong Kong and Taiwan, Province of China. Studies have found that as backward participation increases, exchange rate pass-through and trade elasticities decline (Koopman et al. (2010)). For instance, in a partial equilibrium simulation Riad et. al. (2012) find that a downstream position in GVCs, or a higher share of imported foreign inputs in exports, cushions the impact of relative price changes on exports and imports. This is due to the foreign content in a downstream country’s exports, which mitigates the impact of exchange rate changes, given that an appreciation lowers exports but it also implies cheaper imports. Similar findings were reported for Belgium (Amiti et al. (2014)), Switzerland (Fauceglia et al. (2014)) and the US (Powers and Riker (2013)). Cheng et al. (2015) find that this effect is large, so much so that that a real appreciation (depreciation) could increase (decrease) the GVC-related exports for countries with high foreign-value added contents in their exports.

This study provides additional evidence, using Singapore and the heterogeneity of its export products as a case study, on how integration in GVCs affects trade elasticities. Consistent with IMF (2015), we find that at the product level, more upstream export products with a higher domestic value-added share tend to be more price elastic. As highlighted in IMF (2015), this

3 We use position in GVCs and foreign value added in exports interchangeably in the paper.

4 A recent work by Ahmed, Appendino and Ruta (2015) assess the implications of GVC participation on the price elasticities of trade. They find that the rise of GVC participation explains on average 40 percent of the fall in the price elasticity from 1996–2012.

could reflect the dampened impact of exchange rate adjustments on downstream exports due to their high import content. We also explore whether the complexity of export products has an effect on price and demand elasticities. We find that economic complexity is related to export price elasticities: higher economic complexity is associated with lower price elasticity of exports. This is intuitive given the potentially higher market power enjoyed by producers of highly sophisticated products. This relationship is stronger within certain product segments such as pharmaceuticals.5 The next section of this paper provides an overview of the structure and composition of Singapore’s external trade. The consequent sections discuss the empirical strategy for estimating trade elasticities and results.

II. STRUCTURE AND ROLE OF SINGAPORE’S EXTERNAL TRADE

A. External Trade and Economic Structure. Singapore is a highly export oriented economy. Although net exports have declined from 30.8 percent of GDP before the global financial crisis to 24.4 percent of GDP in2014, they are still one of the highest in the world. The export orientation of Singapore’s economy can also be seen at the industry level. For instance, about 70 percent of all industries which produce 67 percent of Singapore’s total output are export-oriented (Figure 1).6 Singapore’s output and exports are also highly dependent on imports. Most industries have a significant import input share, with the most import-intensive sector being the petroleum products industry (Figure 2). There is also a clear relationship between export orientation and import intensity at the industry level that becomes more significant for industries with an export share of output more than fifty percent (Figure 3). Looking at the relationship between export orientation and the share of labor compensation in value added, there also seems to be a negative relationship, with more export-oriented sectors having a lower labor share in value-added (Figure 4).

5 Other studies have looked at the role of supply constraints in affecting trade elasticities. See Tulin and Raissi (2015) and Anand et al. (2015) for an application to India and South Africa respectively. 6 Industries are classified as export-oriented when exports constituted more than 50 percent of final output. The calculations are based on Singapore’s 2010 Input-Output Tables.

7

Figure1. Exports as Percent of Total Output by Industry (percent)

Figure2. Share of Value-added by Primary Inputs (share)

Figure3. Import Intensity and Export Orientation of Sectors (share)

Figure4. Share of Employee Compensation and Export Orientation (share)

Most export industries in Singapore have a relatively low value-added share of exports (i.e. large import content), but there is some heterogeneity across sectors (Figure 5). Unsurprisingly, petroleum products sector stands out in terms of its low value-added content, reflecting the high value of imported crude oil relative to the refining and processing that takes place in Singapore. Sectors with relatively high value added are mainly services sectors, which is also intuitive. However, there are some service sectors such as water transport that have a low value-added share, reflecting the reliance of the sector on imported petroleum products as input.

0102030405060708090

100

Pharm

ace

utica

ls an

d b

iolo

gica

l pro

du

ctsA

ircraft a

nd

rela

ted

mach

inery

Ele

ctron tu

bes a

nd

ele

ctron

ic disp

lay …

Po

rt op

era

tion se

rvices

Perfu

mes, co

smetics a

nd

rela

ted

…Je

we

llery a

nd

rela

ted

article

sD

ata

stora

ge

Sup

po

rting

service

s to w

ate

r transp

ort

Ind

ustria

l chem

icals a

nd

gase

sN

on-in

sula

ted

cab

le p

rod

ucts

Carg

o h

and

ling

and

oth

er …

Meta

lwo

rkin

g (e

xcep

t treatm

en

t and

…R

ub

be

r pro

ducts

Head

office

s and

bu

siness …

Land

transp

ort e

quip

ment

Meta

l pre

cision

com

po

nen

tsSug

ar, ch

oco

late

an

d re

late

d p

rod

ucts

Ware

ho

usin

g a

nd

stora

ge

No

n-life

insu

rance

and

pe

nsio

n fu

nd

sIn

du

strial d

esig

nC

on

sum

er e

lectro

nics

Oils a

nd

fats

Tre

atm

en

t and

coatin

g o

f meta

lsO

ther m

eta

l pro

ducts

Freig

ht la

nd

tran

spo

rtC

on

sulta

ncy se

rvices (in

clud

ing

ma

rket …

Po

stal a

nd

courie

r service

sBu

ildin

g a

nd

rep

airin

g o

f ship

s and

bo

ats

Dairy p

rod

ucts

Prin

ting

and

rep

rod

uctio

n o

f reco

rded

…Exh

ibitio

ns, co

nve

ntio

ns a

nd

oth

er e

vents

Waste

colle

ction, tre

atm

ent, d

ispo

sal …

Oth

er m

an

ufa

cturin

gC

offe

e a

nd

tea

Ag

ricultu

re (e

xcep

t nurse

ry pro

ducts)

Aq

uariu

m fish

Do

me

stic ap

plia

nce

sEm

plo

yment a

nd

lab

our co

ntra

cting

Fun

d m

anag

em

en

tSup

po

rting

service

s to a

ir transp

ort

Oth

er fo

od

pro

ducts

Te

leco

mm

un

icatio

ns

Alco

ho

lic drin

ks a

nd

tob

acco

pro

ducts

No

n-m

eta

llic min

era

l pro

ducts

Co

mp

ute

r pro

gra

mm

ing

, consu

ltan

cy …O

ther p

rofe

ssiona

l, scientific a

nd

…Liftin

g a

nd

han

dlin

g m

ach

ine

ryS

tructu

ral m

eta

l pro

ducts

Life in

sura

nce

Cle

anin

g a

nd

lan

dsca

pe

ma

inte

nan

ce …

Re

search

and

de

velo

pm

en

tW

ate

r and

sew

era

ge

Livesto

ckFo

od

pre

para

tion

sFu

rnitu

re (e

xcep

t of sto

ne)

Pa

ssen

ge

r land

transp

ort (in

clud

ing

…A

ccom

mo

datio

nH

ealth

service

sSp

ecia

lised

constru

ction se

rvices

Oth

er p

erso

na

l service

sSp

orts

Ed

uca

tion

So

cial se

rvices

Do

mestic se

rvices

p

Sources: SingStat, Singapore 2010 Input-Output Tables

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

Petro

leum

pro

ducts

No

n-in

sula

ted

cab

le p

rod

ucts

Pub

lishin

gPetro

chem

icals a

nd

petro

chem

ical …

Wate

r transp

ort

Co

mp

ute

rs and

perip

hera

l eq

uip

ment

Ele

ctrical w

ires, ca

ble

s and

lightin

g …

Prin

ted

circuit b

oard

sSem

icond

ucto

r rela

ted

eq

uip

ment

Pap

er a

nd

pap

er p

rod

ucts

Oth

er m

eta

l pro

ducts

Meta

lwo

rkin

g (e

xcep

t treatm

ent a

nd

…D

airy p

rod

ucts

Cla

y, cem

ent, co

ncre

te a

nd

ston

e …

Ele

ctricityPain

ts and

rela

ted

pro

ducts

Air tra

nsp

ort

Ele

ctrical in

dustria

l ap

para

tus

Ad

ditive

sA

ircraft a

nd

rela

ted

mach

inery

Data

stora

ge

Scie

ntific, p

ho

tog

rap

hic a

nd

op

tical …

Rep

air o

f road

transp

ort e

quip

ment

Foo

twear a

nd

leath

er p

rod

ucts

Do

mestic a

pp

liance

sExh

ibitio

ns, co

nve

ntio

ns a

nd

oth

er e

vents

Stru

ctura

l meta

l pro

ducts

Med

ia e

nte

rtain

ment

Rep

air o

f com

pute

rs, perso

na

l an

d …

Furn

iture

(exce

pt o

f stone)

Lifting

and

hand

ling

mach

inery

Waste

colle

ction, tre

atm

ent, d

ispo

sal …

Life in

sura

nce

Civil e

ng

ineerin

g w

ork

sBuild

ing

and

rep

airin

g o

f ship

s and

bo

ats

Foo

d a

nd

beve

rag

e se

rvices

Gla

ss and

gla

ss pro

ducts

Aq

uariu

m fish

Build

ing

constru

ction

Tre

atm

ent a

nd

coatin

g o

f meta

lsTra

vel a

gencie

s, tour o

pera

tors a

nd

…C

om

pute

r pro

gra

mm

ing

, consu

ltancy …

Prin

ting

and

rep

rod

uctio

n o

f reco

rded

…O

ther p

rofe

ssional, scie

ntific a

nd

…O

ther a

uxilia

ry financia

l and

insu

ran

ce …

Head

office

s and

busin

ess …

Office

ad

min

istrative

and

sup

po

rt …N

urse

ry pro

ducts

Rese

arch

and

deve

lop

ment

Marin

e e

ng

ines a

nd

ship

parts

Muse

um

s, park

s, arts a

nd

ente

rtain

ment

Oth

er p

erso

nal se

rvices

Cle

anin

g a

nd

land

scap

e m

ain

tenance

…A

ccom

mo

datio

nM

em

ber o

rganisa

tions

Ware

ho

usin

g a

nd

stora

ge

Ag

ricultu

re (e

xcep

t nu

rsery p

rod

ucts)

Secu

rity service

sPo

rt op

era

tion se

rvices

Acco

untin

g, a

ud

iting

and

tax …

Sup

po

rting

service

s to a

ir transp

ort

Sup

po

rting

service

s to la

nd

transp

ort

Ed

uca

tion

Do

mestic se

rvices

Imports Compensation of Employees Operating Surplus

Sources: SingStat, Singapore 2010 Input-Output Tables

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2

Imp

ort

Req

uir

em

en

t

Share of Exports

( )

Sources: SingStat, Singapore 2010 Input-Output Tables

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2

Valu

e-ad

ded

sh

are

of

Co

mp

. of

Emp

loye

es

Share of ExportsSources: SingStat, Singapore 2010 Input-Output Tables

Singapore’s exports of computers and electrical products also have relatively low value-added shares, reflecting Singapore’s upstream position in global value chains. B. Composition of Trade. Singapore’s exports have been dominated by the machinery and mechanical appliances, electrical machinery and equipment and mineral fuels and oils sectors (Figure 6). Over time, the share of organic chemicals, pharmaceuticals, plastics and measuring and checking, precision, medical or surgical instruments sectors have also increased. Important changes have taken place over time in the share of individual products under machinery and mechanical appliances and electrical machinery. For instance the share of computers in Singapore’s gross goods exports declined from 14.1 percent in2000 to 2.4 percent in2013. Integrated circuits gained significant share in the1990 s, reached about20 percent of total goods exports in the early2000 s, and have remained an important export product since then. On the other hand, the export shares of radio receivers, monitors and projectors and related parts have declined since the1990 s. The composition of imports closely follows that of exports (Figure 7). Singapore’s input-output tables confirm that a large share of imports is intermediate goods mainly imported by export-oriented sectors.

Figure 5. Value-added Share of Exports for Different Industries (share)

Figure 6. Composition of Singapore’s Gross Goods Exports by Major Product Groups (percent)

Figure 7. Composition of Singapore’s Gross Goods Imports by Major Product Groups (percent)

00.10.20.30.40.50.60.70.80.9

1

Petroleum products

Non-insulated cable products

PublishingPetrochem

icals and petrochemical products

Water transport

Computers and peripheral equipm

entElectrical w

ires, cables and lighting equipment

Printed circuit boardsSem

iconductor related equipment

Paper and paper productsO

ther metal products

Metalw

orking (except treatment and coating of …

Dairy products

Clay, cement, concrete and stone products

ElectricityPaints and related productsAir transportElectrical industrial apparatusAdditivesAircraft and related m

achineryD

ata storageScientific, photographic and optical productsRepair of road transport equipm

entFootw

ear and leather productsD

omestic appliances

Exhibitions, conventions and other events Structural m

etal productsM

edia entertainment

Repair of computers, personal and household …

Furniture (except of stone)Lifting and handling m

achineryW

aste collection, treatment, disposal and m

aterial …Life insuranceCivil engineering w

orksBuilding and repairing of ships and boatsFood and beverage servicesG

lass and glass productsAquarium

fishBuilding constructionTreatm

ent and coating of metals

Travel agencies, tour operators and reservation …Com

puter programm

ing, consultancy and …Printing and reproduction of recorded m

ediaO

ther professional, scientific and technical servicesO

ther auxiliary financial and insurance servicesH

ead offices and business representative officesO

ffice administrative and support services

Nursery products

Research and development

Marine engines and ship parts

Museum

s, parks, arts and entertainment

Other personal services

Cleaning and landscape maintenance services

Accomm

odationM

ember organisations

Warehousing and storage

Agriculture (except nursery products)Security servicesPort operation servicesAccounting, auditing and tax consultancy servicesSupporting services to air transportSupporting services to land transportEducation

( )

Sources: Singapore Input-Output Tables 2010

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013

mineral fuelsmachinery and mechanical applianceselectrical machineryorganic chemicalsplasticsmeasuring and checking, precision, medical or surgical instrumentsPharmaceuticals

p

Sources: UN Comtrade Database and IMF staff calculations.

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 2013

mineral fuelsmachinery and mechanical applianceselectrical machineryorganic chemicalsplasticsmeasuring and checking, precision, medical or surgical instrumentsvehiclesprecious stones, pearls, jewelry

p

Sources: UN Comtrade Database and IMF staff calculations.

9

C. Economic Complexity. The notion of complexity of goods and services, originally described in Hidalgo and Hausmann (2009), is helpful in capturing the diversity and sophistication of a country’s exports. Product complexity is captured by the fewness of the number of countries that export the product and the diversity of those countries’ exports. If a product is produced by a small number of countries and if those countries have a diverse export product mix, the economic complexity of the product is measured to be higher. Economic complexity of Singapore is among the highest in the world and has increased steadily up until the mid-2000s, but has remained relatively flat since then (Figure 8). Although Singapore’s export products have a high level of average complexity, there is significant variation across its export products (Figure 9).

Figure 9. Distribution of Economic Complexity by Export Products

III. EXPORT ELASTICITIES

We estimate trade elasticities for export volumes using data from the UN Comtrade Database for about 1180 individual products for the 1989 –2013 period. We estimate the following specifications for export volumes using the Mean Group estimator of Pesaran and Smith (1995), allowing for product-specific fixed effects and price and demand elasticities.

exp , c , β rp , γ y , e ,

Figure 8. Index of Economic Complexity–Selected Countries (level)

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

5

-5 0 5 10pci_value

Distribution of Economic Complexity (all categories)

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998 2001 2004 2007 2010

South Korea United States

Japan China

Germany Singapore

Sources: Hausmann et. al (2011) The Atlas of Economic Complexity. Puritan Press. Cambridge MA.

Where exp , is the export volume for individual products at the level of 6-digit HS codes. The relative price variable is calculated as Singapore’s export price divided by the average global import price of the same product that year. Each 6-digit price is calculated by dividing the total trade value (in USD) by total quantity7.8 Foreign demand (y , ) is calculated as a weighted average of demand by Singapore’s trading partners, whereby the weights are based on the share of Singapore’s exports to different trading partners at the HS 2-digit product group level. Trading partners’ demand is estimated by total imports of the country in U.S. dollars, divided by the U.S. GDP Deflator. All variables enter in log form. In the second stage of our analysis, we explore how different product or industry characteristics affect export elasticities using interaction terms with relative price and demand variables and a fixed-effects panel regression model.

exp , c , βrp , γy , δ IV , ∗ rp , θ IV , ∗ y , e , We explore two factors: 1) value-added in exports and the global supply chains and 2) economic complexity, through interaction terms with relative price and demand variables (IV , ). To explore the role of domestic value added we link sector-specific information on the domestic value content of Singapore’s exports from input-output tables to different export products, allowing us to have a product-specific measure of the domestic value-added content.910 The economic complexity index described earlier is available for individual products at the HS 4-digit level for1995 –2012. We use this data to match Singapore’s export products with economic complexity.11

7 Changes over time and across countries in the units used to measure volumes for a given product could be problematic for our measure of relative export prices. Conducting a scan of the products exported by Singapore (at the 6-digit level) we observe that over time the volume units are broadly fixed. Potential differences across countries are harder to tackle and could add noise to our measure of relative prices. We take comfort in the fact that this measurement error is not likely to be correlated with other economic indicators and hence would not bias our results. 8 In other studies, the relative export price or the real effective exchange rate for individual product groups is estimated by using domestic export price multiplied by the nominal effective exchange rate and divided by the domestic price of the product in trading partners. The ability to match sector specific prices across trading partners has proven to be complicated, depending on the product group and data availability. This measure of relative price has the advantage of being product-specific at a much detailed level of disaggregation and capture Singapore’s export price relative to its competitors. 9 We match industries in Singapore’s input-output tables with the HS 4-digit level product codes that are provided as part of the input-output tables. When there is a match between a certain product code and multiple input-output industry codes, we use a weighted average of the input-output industries with the exports of that industry used as weights. 10 Another important caveat related to these measures of GVC integration is the fact that we use the Input-Output Tables for 2010 only and therefore do not account for potential changes over time in the extent to which a certain product is used in exports and the import content of exports. 11 As mentioned earlier, the complexity index for individual products is available at the HS 4-digit level for 1995–2012, which allows us to match Singapore’s export products with the index of complexity. We assume

(continued…)

11

IV. RESULTS

Baseline results and heterogeneity in export elasticities. Table1 presents estimates of export elasticities for Singapore. The average relative price and demand elasticities of Singapore’s exports are estimated at -0.24 and 0.68 respectively, showing that export volumes are affected by changes in both relative prices and foreign demand. The estimates at the broad product groups show that there is significant variation (Figure 10). The price elasticity varies between 0 and -0.8, while the demand elasticity varies between 0 and 2.5.The distribution of both elasticities is in line with what we would expect. Categories at HS 2-digit level that exhibit low price elasticity (in absolute terms) are the categories that involve sophisticated technology (for instance, man-made staple fibre, vegetable fibre and arms and ammunition). On the other hand, categories that exhibit high price elasticity are more labor-intensive, commodity products such as furniture, beddings, mattresses and live animals. Food related items were among the top 3 categories that show the highest demand elasticity such as miscellaneous edible preparations, beverages and preparation for meat. Some examples of the categories that exhibited low income elasticities are commodity goods, such as cork and woods.

Table1 a. Export Elasticities Table1 b. Export Elasticities

Mean-Group Estimator

Fixed-Effects

VARIABLES log_export_volume log_export_volume

log_relativeprice -0.342*** -0.237*** (0.007) (0.004)

log_foreign_demand 0.602*** 0.680*** (0.015) (0.010)

Constant 2.449*** 1.615*** (0.314) (0.214)

Observations 93,280 93,494 R-squared 0.408

Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Mean-Group Estimator

Machinery, computers

Electrical machinery Telecommunications equip.

VARIABLES log(export volume) log(export volume)

log_relativeprice -0.448*** -0.553*** (0.02) (0.03)

log_foreign_demand 0.297*** 0.661*** (0.06) (0.05)

Constant 5.352*** -0.612 (1.31) (1.00)

Observations 9,881 4,389 R-squared 0.617

Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

that all 6-digit products under the same 4-digit product code have the same complexity. For years that we do not have the product-level economic complexity index we assume that it is the same as the closest available year.

0.1

.2.3

.4

0 .5 1 1.5 2 2.5demand elasticity of exports

Distribution of demand elasticity of exports

0.0

5.1

.15

.2.2

5

-.8 -.6 -.4 -.2 0relative price elasticity

Distribution of relative price elasticity of exports

Figure 10. Distribution of Export Elasticities

Table 1 also shows the estimates for two important export product groups for Singapore: HS 2-digit product category 84, related to machinery, mechanical appliances and computers and HS 2-digit category 85, related to electrical machinery, equipments and telecommunications equipments. Both sectors have higher price elasticity than the average reported in Table 1, but the demand elasticity of machinery and computers sector is lower than the average.12 Within these two sectors, the variance of trade elasticities is also quite substantial. This is relevant given the importance of these two sectors in Singapore’s exports and the fact that broad product group averages can hide important product-level heterogeneity. The following charts show within category 84, the variation of price and income elasticities of 4-digit sub-sectors (Figure 11). The most important 4-digit subsector of category 84 is computers (HS category 8471), which constituted 2.4 percent of Singapore’s total goods exports in 2013 (only third to refined petroleum and integrated circuits). This category shows a low price elasticity of -0.05 and a large income elasticity of 0.7.

12 The Mean Group Estimator (Pesaran and Smith (1995)) assumes cross-sectional independence of error terms. It is possible to relax this assumption by using the common correlated effects mean group (CCEMG) estimator (Pesaran (2006)). Alternatively, one can include trend in each group to estimate the elasticities. Our results based on CCEMG and including trend suggest that the estimates of price and demand elasticities remain reasonably close to the baseline results in Table 1. Export price elasticities for all sectors range from -0.285 to -0.313 with statistical significance. For the two selected sectors, the price elasticity ranges from -0.23 to -0.45 for category 84, while the elasticity ranges from -0.49 to -0.55 for the category 85. The coefficients also look close to the fixed-effect regressions with product category and time fixed effects: for the overall sectors, price elasticity -0.237 with statistical significance. For category 84, the price elasticity using the fixed-effects is -0.487and for category 85, -0.477.

13

Figure 11. Distribution of Price and Income Elasticities within Category HS 84

The following two charts reveal the variation of export elasticities for electrical machinery, equipments and telecommunication equipments sector (Figure 12). Integrated circuits (category 8542), which has accounted for20 percent of the SGP’s total goods exports in 2013, shows an income elasticity of 0.89 and a price elasticity of -0.49.

Figure 12. Distribution of Price and Income Elasticities within Category HS 85

Explaining Export Elasticities. In this section we explore the relationship between export elasticities and product/industry characteristics. We first consider the impact of value-added in exports. As discussed earlier, Singapore’s exports typically have high import content. However, there exists substantial heterogeneity in the import intensity, as shown in Figure 13 (at HS 4-digit level), which shows the share of domestic value-added in exports. The higher domestic valued-added or lower import content an exported product has, one can conjecture a higher sensitivity of export volume to changes in relative price.

0.0

5.1

.15

.2.2

5

-1 -.8 -.6 -.4 -.2 0price elasticity of exports

0.1

.2.3

.4

0 .5 1 1.5 2income ealsticity of exports

0.0

5.1

.15

.2.2

5

-1 -.5 0 .5price elasticity of exports

0.1

.2.3

.4

-1 -.5 0 .5 1 1.5income elasticity of exports

Figure 13. Distribution of Domestic Value-added Share of Exports by Product

The regression results reported in Table 2 uses the domestic value-added share of different products, which we obtain by matching products with industry characteristics in Singapore’s input-output tables, as an interaction variable. Consistent with our expectations, the higher is the domestic value-added share of exports, the higher is the absolute value of the price elasticity of exports. The impact of domestic value added share on demand elasticity is negative, indicating that products with higher domestic value added also demonstrate lower demand elasticity.

Table 2. Effect of Domestic Value-added Share on Export Elasticities

VARIABLES log (export volume) log_relativeprice -0.179*** (0.0249) log_foreign_demand 0.262*** (0.0221) log_relativeprice*log_domestic value added -0.0841* (0.0472) log_foreigndemand*log_domestic value added -0.122*** (0.0170) Constant 12.14*** (0.450) Observations 67,059 R-squared 0.404

Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Given the importance of industries with high economic complexity in SGP’s trade, we then assess the relationship between economic complexity and export elasticities. Table 3 below shows estimates of baseline regressions for export volumes, where we interact relative price and demand with the economic complexity index. The estimated coefficients are small, showing a limited impact of economic complexity on elasticities. For instance, based on the estimated coefficient, the difference in terms of export price elasticity between the most and the least complex product is about 0.1. When we look at how complexity is related to trade elasticities within individual product groups, we find a significant and large effect on price

0.0

5.1

.15

0 .2 .4 .6 .8net foreign exchange earnins as a share of exports (HS 4-digit)

15

elasticities. It is important to look at the sensitivity of trade elasticities within individual groups because Singapore’s trade is concentrated in a few major product groups and there is significant product heterogeneity within those product segments (Figure 14). For instance, within the pharmaceuticals groups, price elasticities decline with product complexity, consistent with our priors (Table 4). This relationship is somewhat weaker for the other three product groups. The relationship between complexity and demand elasticities is pretty small within individual product groups.

Table 3. Effect of Economic Complexity on Export Elasticities

VARIABLES log (export volume) log_relativeprice -0.204***

(0.00692) log_foreign_demand 0.193*** (0.0207) log_relativeprice* complexity -0.00811*** (0.00246) log_foreigndemand* complexity -0.00786*** (0.000914) Constant 12.61*** (0.451) Observations 67,059 R-squared 0.403

Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Figure 14. Distribution of Complexity Index within Individual Product Groups

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8

-2 0 2 4 6pci_value

Economic Complexity (Category 84)

0.0

5.1

.15

-2 0 2 4 6pci_value

Economic Complexity (Category 85)

Table 4. Effect of Economic Complexity on Export Elasticities for Major Product Groups

Machinery, computers

Electrical machinery

Telecomm. equip.

Organic chemicals Pharmaceuticals

VARIABLES log(export volume)

log(export volume) log(export volume) log(export volume)

log_relativeprice -0.513*** -0.510*** -0.187*** -0.656*** (0.0122) (0.0196) (0.0167) (0.165) log_foreign_demand -0.933*** 0.169*** 0.639*** 0.0996* (0.136) (0.0595) (0.0195) (0.0573) log_relativeprice* complexity 0.00781** 0.0176** 0.0235*** 0.135** (0.00353) (0.00718) (0.00556) (0.0541) log_foreign_demand* complexity 0.00406** 0.00638** 0.00503*** 0.0420** (0.00171) (0.00280) (0.00187) (0.0171) Constant 32.14*** 10.87*** 2.983*** 10.46*** (3.059) (1.332) (0.420) (0.840) Observations 7,269 3,195 4,502 226 R-squared 0.874 0.918 0.974 0.942

Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Finally, we tried a specification which includes both GVC integration and economic complexity as interaction terms with foreign demand and relative prices. Estimated coefficients for both GVC integration and complexity are similar to the earlier results looking at their impact one at a time. The higher coefficient of GVC integration implies that GVC integration better explains the cross-sectional variation in Singapore’s export elasticities.

Table 5. Effect of Domestic Value-added Share and Economic Complexity on Export Elasticities

VARIABLES Log (export_volume) log_relativeprice -0.159*** (0.025) log_foreign_demand 0.268*** (0.031) log_relativeprice*log_domestic value added -0.083* (0.049) log_foreigndemand*log_domestic value added -0.121*** (0.017) log_relativeprice* complexity -0.009*** (0.003) log_foreigndemand* complexity -0.008*** (0.001) Constant 12.107*** (0.656)

Observations 66,904 R-squared 0.409

Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

V. CONCLUSIONS

In this paper we study the role of growing participation in GVCs and of rising complexity in Singapore’s external trade. As emphasized in previous studies, value-added in exports plays an important role in trade elasticities. We find evidence that this is indeed the case for

17

Singapore’s export products using highly disaggregated product-level data. Products that have a higher domestic value-added share also tend to have higher export price elasticities. Economic complexity also matters for the size of Singapore’s export price elasticities, where higher economic complexity is associated with lower price elasticity of exports. Compared to the domestic value-added share, economic complexity seems to matter less in explaining the cross-sectional variation in export elasticities, but economic complexity and export elasticities seem to have a stronger relationship within certain product segments such as the machinery, mechanical appliances and computers as well as the pharmaceuticals. We find that there is important product heterogeneity with respect to export elasticities; both across different product groups but also within individual product groups. This implies that structural changes in the product composition of trade can lead to sizable changes in Singapore’s trade elasticities. Export elasticities are important to understand the transmission of Singapore’s exchange rate-based monetary policy. Our results show that Singapore’s downstream position in GVCs has indeed had a dampening effect on its price elasticities, requiring a higher relative price adjustment to achieve a given volume effect.

REFERENCES

Ahmed, S., M. Appendino and M. Ruta, 2015. Depreciations without Exports? Global Value Chains and the Exchange Rate Elasticity of Exports, Policy Research Working Paper No. WPS 7390, Washington, DC: World Bank Group. Amiti, M. Ol. Itskhoki and J. Konings, 2014. Importers, Exporters, and Exchange Rate Disconnect. American Economic Review, 104 (7), pp.1942 -78. Anand, R., Roberto Perrelli, and Boyang Zhang, 2014, South Africa’s Exports Performance: Any Role for Structural Factors? South Africa: Selected Issues Paper, IMF Country Report No. 14/339. Bems, R. and R. Johnson, 2015. Demand for Value Added and Value-Added Exchange Rates, NBER Working Paper No. 21070. Cheng, K. G. Hong, D. Seneviratne and R. van Elkan, 2016. Rethinking the Exchange Rate Impact on Trade in a World with Global Value Chains, forthcoming IMF Working Paper. Fauceglia, D. A. Lassmann, A. Shingal, and M. Wermelinger, 2014. Backward Participation in Global Value Chains and Exchange Rate Driven Adjustments of Swiss Exports. Study on behalf of the State Secretariat for Economic Affair, SECO International Monetary Fund, 2015, Regional Economic Outlook: Asia and Pacific. Johnson, R. and G. Noguera, 2012 a. Accounting for Intermediates: Production Sharing and Trade in Value Added. Journal of International Economics, 86. Pp.224-236. Johson, R. and G. Noguera, 2012 b. Proximity and Production Fragmentation. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 102(3), pp. 407-411. Johnson, R. and G. Noguera, 2014. A Portrait of Trade in Value Added Over Four Decades. NBER Working Paper Series 18186. Koopman, R. W. Powers, Z. Wang and S. Wei, 2010. Give Credit Where Credit is Due: Tracing Value Added in Global Production Chains, NBER Working Paper No.1 6426, Pesaran, M.H. and R.P. Smith, 1995, “Estimating Long-Run Relationships from Dynamic Heterogeneous Panels,” Journal of Econometrics, 68, 79-113. Powers, W. and David Riker, 2013. Exchange Rate Pass-Through in Global Value Chains: The Effects of Upstream Suppliers. U.S. International Trade Commission, Office of Economics Working Paper Series, No.2 013-02B.

19

Riad, N., L. Errico, C. Henn, C. Saborowski, M. Saito, and J. Turunen, 2012, Changing Patterns of Global Trade, International Monetary Fund. Tulin, V. and Mehdi Raissi, 2015, Price and Income Elasticity of Indian Exports-The Role of Supply-Side Bottlenecks, IMF Working Paper No. 15/161.