Saving and Consumption Function

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    1/29

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    2/29

    Aggregate Expenditure and Equilibrium

    National OutputAggregate expenditure (AE)

    total amount that all economic agents want or plan tospend on domestic goods and services.

    the planned spending of households,

    firms,

    government, and

    foreigners.

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    3/29

    Aggregate ExpenditureAE = C + I + G + (X-M)

    consumption (C),

    investment (I), government spending (G), and

    exports less imports (X-M).

    Note thatAE is not the same as GDP.

    AErepresentsplannedspending

    GDP represents actualspending or output.

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    4/29

    Aggregate Expenditure (AE) and National

    Output (Y)AE and Y are not necessarily equal:

    Firms formulate their production plans with an estimateof the quantities that people want to buy.

    A mistake on their part will cause production to exceedor fall below the amounts that people want to buy.

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    5/29

    What if AE and Y are not equal? If AE < Y

    people want to buy less than what has beenproduced so firms will accumulate inventories.

    firms will reduce production

    If AE >Y What people want to buy is greater than actual

    production so inventories will decline. firms will increase production

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    6/29

    Equilibrium National IncomeAE = Y

    Can be depicted by the intersection between the

    AE schedule and the 45 degree line

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    7/29

    The 450

    line The 45-degree line is a tool that assists us in

    identifying the economy's equilibrium position.

    Property: every point along this line depicts asituation wherein the value of the variable on thehorizontal axis (in this case actual output, (Y) is equalto its counterpart on the vertical axis (AE).

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    8/29

    0100

    100

    450 line

    450

    200

    200

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    9/29

    45

    E0AE20

    AE

    0 20

    Output, income (in pesos)

    Aggregateexpen

    diture

    (inpesos)

    Y

    Y*

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    10/29

    Equilibrium Income (Y*)WhenAEis equal to Y

    there is no reason for firms to adjust production.

    this suggests that the economy is in equilibrium.

    Equilibrium requires the equality betweenincome and aggregate expenditure. That is,

    Y = AE.

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    11/29

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    12/29

    45

    AE0E0

    E1

    AE1

    20

    30

    AE

    0 20 30Y

    Output, income (in thousands)

    Aggregateexpen

    diture

    (inpesos)

    Y0 Y1

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    13/29

    Consumption and Income Keynes (1936) suggested that consumption spending

    (C) tends to increase with income.

    In other words, households with higher incomes tend tospend more.

    There is a positive relationship between consumptionspending and income

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    14/29

    TABLE 9.1. Consumption and income (in Rs-thousands).

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

    Income Consumption Change In

    income

    Change in

    consumption

    Mpc

    (Y) (C) (Y) (C) (C/Y)

    0 200 _

    200 350 200 150 0.75

    400 500 200 150 0.75

    600 650 200 150 0.75

    800 800 200 150 0.751,000 950 200 150 0.75

    1,200 1,100 200 150 0.75

    1,400 1,250 200 150 0.75

    1,600 1,400 200 150 0.75

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    15/29

    Consumption and income Higher levels of income correspond to higher levels of

    consumption spending

    When income is equal to zero, consumption spending is

    equal to 200.

    Consumption spending and income are equal at each otherwhen income = 800. When income is less than 800, consumption is higher than income.

    When income is greater than 800, consumption less than income

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    16/29

    0

    450200

    Consum

    ptionSpending

    (inp

    esos)

    Output, Income (in thousands)

    400

    600

    800

    1000

    800 1200 1600

    400

    1200

    1400

    1600

    C

    Y

    THE CONSUMPTION SCHEDULE

    Y

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    17/29

    Consumption and Income Observations from values above:

    (a) autonomous consumption spending-

    component of consumption spending that doesnot depend on income

    - equal to 200 in example

    (b) marginal propensity to consume (mpc) -shows the increase in consumption spending for aone peso increase in income;

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    18/29

    Marginal Propensity to Consume MPC or the marginal propensity to consume represents the change

    in consumption spending that arises from a one rupee change inincome.

    Value of MPCis between 0 and 1.

    MPC=0.75 means that a one peso increase in income leads to a 75-

    centavo increase in consumption spending.

    Cmpc

    Y

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    19/29

    Marginal propensity to consume In example above,

    C = 150 for Y = 200. Hence,

    1500.75

    200

    CMPC

    Y

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    20/29

    Consumption Function Consumption Function:

    C = c + mpc.Y

    C = 200 + 0.75Y

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    21/29

    Savings and Income Sum of consumption spending and savings (S) must

    equal income. In symbols,Y = C + S.

    Subtracting C from both sides of this equation leads toS = Y - C.

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    22/29

    (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) MPS

    Y C S Y C S S

    Y

    0 200 -200 - - - -

    200 350 -150 200 150 50 0.25

    400 500 -100 200 150 50 0.25

    600 650 -50 200 150 50 0.25

    800 800 0 200 150 50 0.25

    1000 950 50 200 150 50 0.251200 1000 100 200 150 50 0.25

    1400 1200 150 200 150 50 0.25

    1600 1400 200 200 150 50 0.25

    Relationship bet. Income and Savings

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    23/29

    E0

    S

    I

    -200

    1000

    800 1,200 1,600

    Income (in Rs.-thousands

    Y

    Y*

    (B)

    S, I

    (A)

    E0

    Fig 9.5

    C+I = AE

    C

    0 400 800 1,200 1,600Y

    45

    AE

    300

    200

    Y*

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    24/29

    Savings and income Savings - that component of income that is not

    allocated to consumption.S = Y C

    How is savings linked to income?

    YS.

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    25/29

    Savings and Income Marginal propensity to save (MPS) is the

    increase in savings for a one Rs.increase in

    income; In the example above, S = 50 for Y = 200.

    Implies that

    500.25

    200

    SMPSY

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    26/29

    Savings function Note: MPC+MPS = 1

    Savings schedule listing of values of savings at eachlevels of income

    Savings function in equation form

    S = -200 + .25Y

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    27/29

    Relationship between mpc and mpc

    1

    Y C S

    Y C S

    Y C S

    Y Y Y

    mpc mps

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    28/29

    S

    -200

    -50

    150

    0

    400 800 1,200 1,600

    Income (in thousands

    Savings

    (inpesos)

    Y

    S F9.4

    Propensity to Save

  • 7/28/2019 Saving and Consumption Function

    29/29

    Table 9.3 Consumption, Investment and Equilibrium Income.

    Y C S I AE

    400 500 -100 100 600

    600 650 -50 100 750

    800 800 0 100 900

    1,000 950 50 100 1,050

    1,200 1,100 100 100 1,200

    1,400 1,250 150 100 1,350