Saddy 1982

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    1/23

    Third World Quarterly

    OPEC Capital Surplus Funds and Third World Indebtedness: The Recycling StrategyReconsideredAuthor(s): Fehmy SaddyReviewed work(s):Source: Third World Quarterly, Vol. 4, No. 4 (Oct., 1982), pp. 736-757

    Published by: Taylor & Francis, Ltd.Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3991109.

    Accessed: 23/12/2012 09:26

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at.http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

    .JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of

    content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms

    of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    .

    Taylor & Francis, Ltd.and Third World Quarterlyare collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and

    extend access to Third World Quarterly.

    http://www.jstor.org

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=taylorfrancishttp://www.jstor.org/stable/3991109?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/3991109?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=taylorfrancis
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    2/23

    FEHMY

    SADDY

    O P E a p i t a

    S u r p u

    u n

    a n d

    h i r d

    W o r l d Indebtedness

    t h

    re y l ing

    s t r a t e g y

    reconsidered

    Introduction

    The first

    rhetorical

    round

    of the New

    International

    Economic Order

    NIEO)

    came

    to an end

    at the Cancutn

    Summit

    Conference

    last October. An

    agreement

    was

    reached

    to pursue 'global

    negotiations'

    at the United Nations.

    Whether the new

    forum will

    open

    up

    better

    prospects

    or

    merely

    offer itself as a

    launching pad

    for

    the

    second

    round

    of

    rhetoric and

    recriminations

    remains

    to be

    seen.

    The

    Eleventh

    Special Session

    of

    the UN

    General

    Assembly,

    held in August

    1980, considered

    a

    New International

    Strategy

    (NIS)

    for the

    Third

    Development

    Decade in which

    the

    objectives

    of the first two

    decades were

    affirmed

    more

    vigorously.

    But

    optimism

    does not seem warranted and only little hope exists that better results will be

    attained.

    The

    United

    States'

    misapprehension

    about what

    it

    considers

    to be the

    demand

    of

    developing

    countries

    for a

    global

    economic welfare

    system

    financed

    by

    the industrialised

    ountries

    casts

    doubt

    on

    its

    willingness

    o be

    more

    forthcoming

    n

    future

    negotiations.

    Moreover,

    the

    developing

    countries are

    in

    a much weaker

    position

    now

    than

    they

    were

    in

    the

    1970s,

    and conflicts

    of interest

    among

    them

    have

    been drawn

    more

    sharply.

    Therefore,

    while

    negotiations

    on

    trade,

    energy,

    raw materials,

    development

    finance and monetary

    issues will be pursued at the

    United

    Nations,

    innovative

    thinking

    and

    a search for

    solutions must

    continue

    outside the

    North-South

    framework.

    Ironically, one of the major problems that developing countries have come to

    face

    during

    the

    past

    decade

    finds its

    origin

    -

    and

    to a

    large

    extent its solution

    -

    within

    the South

    itself. It

    concerns the

    tremendous

    transfers

    of

    financial

    assets

    from the

    oil-importing to

    the oil-exporting

    countries over

    a

    short

    period

    of time.

    The

    quadrupling

    of the

    prices

    of

    oil

    in

    1973-4

    and

    the

    doublingof these prices

    again

    in 1978-9

    resulted in current

    account deficits

    for all

    oil-importing

    countries,

    but

    their effect

    was hardest

    on

    the

    less

    developed

    countries

    (LDCs).

    In

    response

    to

    these

    increases,

    the industrialised

    countries

    (ICs)

    have,

    adopted

    deflationary

    policies

    that

    resulted

    in

    reversing

    their

    negative

    current

    accounts.

    However,

    these

    policies

    failed

    to curb

    inflation

    and instead

    produced

    stagflation, unemployment

    Author'sNote:

    This research

    was

    conducted

    in

    the Fall semester of 1981

    at The School of International

    Service,

    The American University,

    where

    he was

    Visiting

    International

    ResearchAffiliate. He would

    like to

    thank Calvin

    De

    Pass,

    John

    W Tuthill and Howard

    M

    Wachtel for

    theircomments on an earlier

    draft of

    this

    paper.

    October

    1982 Volume

    4 No.

    4

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    3/23

    OPEC CAPITAL SURPLUS

    FUNDS AND THIRD WORLD INDEBTEDNESS

    and reducedgrowth.These effects were n turnpassedonto theoil-importingLDCs

    which had benefited from

    economic liberalisation in the 1960s and increased

    exports

    to the ICs. The combined

    effects of increased oil

    prices,

    substantial

    reduction of their

    exports,

    depressed market prices for their raw materials and

    manufactured products and

    increased costs of their imports, due to inflation,

    reducedtheir terms of trade. The

    only alternative left for themin order to maintain

    their

    economies was to rely on borrowing from the

    international capital markets.

    Thus, the

    problem of Third World indebtedness was born.

    In

    addition, the OPEC countries pursued investment and

    trade policies that

    have benefited the ICs and adversely

    affected the oil-importingLDCs. The bulk of

    the oil revenues were spent on purchases from the ICs to finance the development

    programmes

    of

    the

    oil-exporters.

    The few

    oil-exporting

    countries that were left

    with some

    capital surpluses preferred to invest them in the

    ICs as well. Although

    substantial aid and 'soft' loans were

    extended to the oil-importing LDCs through

    multilateral institutions and by

    bilateral

    arrangements,

    the gap left by the

    reduction of their

    terms of trade and soaring oil bills

    could only be filled by

    increased indebtedness.

    This

    paper

    will focus

    first

    on

    the indebtednessproblem of

    oil-importing LDCs,

    which is

    bound to worsen further in the future if the

    policies

    of both the oil-

    exporters and the ICs continue their

    present

    course.

    Second, it will review the

    argumentsin regardto theirresponsibilityfor ThirdWorld indebtedness. Third, it

    will discuss the

    investmentpolicies

    of

    the

    capital surplus

    oil-exporters and

    assess

    their effects.

    Fourth, it will present

    some

    arguments

    in

    favour of increased

    investments

    in the

    oil-importing LDCs.

    Finally,

    it

    will conclude with a brief note

    on

    proposals

    that have

    been advanced

    on

    the

    problem

    of

    recycling

    and

    investment.

    The

    IndebtednessProblem

    Indebtedness is not new to

    developing

    countries. Debt-financed

    development has

    been pursued

    by many countries,

    both

    developing

    and

    industrialised.

    The United

    States reliedon imported capital to financeits infrastructureand build its industry

    in

    the

    18th

    Century. Alexander

    Hamilton

    spoke

    in

    defence

    of

    foreign

    investments

    which increased

    the wealth

    of

    nations.2

    Of

    the

    developing

    countries,

    Brazil

    floated

    its

    first

    'Eurobond'

    on

    the

    London market

    n

    1824and was followed

    by

    other

    Latin

    American

    countries.3

    However,

    nothing resembling

    the scale of

    borrowing

    that

    took

    place

    in

    recent

    years

    has

    ever

    occurred

    before.

    The

    magnitude

    of

    borrowing

    and the

    constraints

    it

    has

    placed

    on the economies

    of

    oil-importing

    LDCs threaten

    a

    serious

    crisis

    n

    international

    inancial

    obligations

    with adverse effects

    on

    the

    world

    economy.

    1

    John

    A Matheison,

    'North-SouthImbalances',Bulletin

    ofAtomic

    Scientists,

    38

    (1)

    January 1982,

    p 1.

    2

    As recounted

    by

    Edwin

    in his introduction

    to James

    A

    Gathings,

    International

    La,"and American

    Treatment

    of Alien Enemy

    Property, Washington,

    DC: American

    Council

    on Public

    Affairs,

    1940,

    p

    vii.

    I

    Jeff Frieden,

    'Third

    World Indebted

    Industrialisation:

    International

    Finance

    and State

    Capitalism

    in Mexico,

    Brazil,

    Algeria

    and South

    Korea',

    International

    Organisation

    35

    (3)

    Summer

    198

    1,

    p

    410.

    737

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    4/23

    THIRD

    WORLD

    QUARTERLY

    The seriousness of the indebtedness problem has been recognised by

    multilateral development

    agencies, many

    governments

    and concerned analysts,

    with

    varying

    degrees

    of

    alarm. While

    the

    countries

    of

    the

    Organisation

    of

    Economic

    Cooperation and

    Development (OECD)

    view it with 'neither

    complacency nor

    undue

    alarm',4 he World Bank is

    carefulnot to pass

    a uniform

    judgment

    on

    all

    borrowing countries.5Others,

    however,

    are more

    alarmist. Some

    believe

    that

    developing countries

    cannot escape

    the

    prospect of default and that

    the

    recycling mechanism

    that was used

    in

    the

    1

    970s

    is

    no

    longer

    adequate.6Others

    have likened

    the

    indebtedness

    problem to aticking

    internationaltime-bomb which

    will

    require 'concerted

    attention and action' in

    order to

    be defused.7 Former

    Presidentof the World Bank RobertMcNamara has declared that 'over the next

    five

    to six years, the deficits more

    and

    more

    are

    going to

    be concentrated in the

    developing countries ... these current account

    deficits cannot be

    sustained

    indefinitely by external

    financing.8

    Structureof

    Indebtedness

    The indebtedness

    problem

    accelerated after the

    first increase

    of OPEC oil

    prices

    in

    1973-4, and continues its

    upwardmovement.9

    The

    question

    whether the oil price

    increases were the

    primary reason for the

    increased

    indebtedness of the oil-

    importing LDCs will

    be discussed below.

    Nevertheless,

    these

    countries

    were

    forced to supplement their deficits by external borrowings which have come to

    take new forms. The

    main

    features

    of the

    new

    borrowings departed from familiar

    'External Debt

    Statistics for

    Developing

    Countries: Latest

    Trends', Organisation

    for

    Economic

    Cooperation and

    Development,

    Development

    Cooperation

    Directorate,

    September 1981, p 3.

    Wor/dDevelopmentReport 1981,

    Chapter

    5.

    The World

    Bank:

    Washington,

    DC, 1981.

    6

    Chandra S

    Hardy, 'Adjustment

    to Global

    Payments

    Imbalances:

    a

    tripartite

    solution',

    Working

    Paper

    No.

    5,

    Overseas

    Development

    Council, Washington,

    DC,

    September 1981, p

    2.

    Mathieson,

    op cit, p

    1.

    8

    Hobart

    Rowen,

    'The

    Third World Still Has A Friend in

    Robert

    McNamara',

    International

    nvestor,

    September

    1981, p 156.

    The indebtedness problem and the role of multinational banks in 'recycling'the surplusfunds to the

    Third World are the

    subject

    of an

    ever-widening

    literature.

    See,

    for

    example, Harold

    Van

    B

    Clevelandand

    W

    H

    Bruce

    Brittain,

    Are

    the LDCs in Over

    TheirHeads?',

    ForeignAffairs 55

    (3) July

    1977 pp 732-50;

    Cheryl Payer, 'Third World

    Debt

    Problems:

    The

    New

    Wave

    of Defaults',

    Monthly

    Review 28

    (4) September

    1976

    pp 1-19;

    Karin

    Lissakers,

    'International

    Debt,

    The

    Banks and US

    Foreign Policy', a staff

    paper prepared

    for

    the Subcommittee on

    Foreign

    Economic

    Relations, US

    Senate,

    Washington, DC,

    US/GPO, 1977;

    Jonathan

    David

    Aronson

    (ed),

    Debt

    and the

    Less

    Developed

    Countries, Boulder, Colo.:

    Westview

    Press,

    1979;

    Laurence G

    Franco

    and

    Marilyn

    J

    Seiber

    (eds),

    Developing

    Countries

    Debt,

    New York:

    Pergamon

    Press,

    1979;

    David

    Beck,

    'Commercial

    Bank

    Lending

    to the

    Developing

    Countries', Federal Reserve

    Bank

    of New

    York

    Quarterly

    Review1

    2)

    Summer

    1967, pp 1-8;

    Howard

    M

    Wachtel, The Nelw

    Gnomes:

    multinational

    banks in the Third

    World,Pamphlet

    No. 4,

    Washington, DC:

    Transnational

    Institute, 1977,

    and 'A

    Decade of

    International

    Debt',

    Theoryand

    Society

    9

    (3) May

    1980pp504-18;

    Paul

    Watson,Debtand

    the

    Developing Countries:

    newproblems

    and

    newtsactors,

    Washington, DC:

    Overseas

    Development

    Council, Paper 26, NIEO Series, 1978;Miguel Wionczek (ed), LDC External Debt and the World

    Economy, Mexico

    City: El

    Colegio

    de

    Mexico, 1978; Special

    Issue

    on 'International

    Indebtedness

    and

    World Economic

    Stagnation', World

    Development

    7 (2)

    February 1979 pp

    91-224; and

    International

    Monetary Fund, 'External

    Indebtedness of

    Developing

    Countries', Occasional

    Paper

    No. 3,

    May 1981.

    738

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    5/23

    OPEC CAPITAL SURPLUS FUNDS AND THIRD WORLD INDEBTEDNESS

    patterns that they had taken in earlier years thus substantially affecting the

    capacity of

    oil-importing LDCs to service their debts.

    The World

    Development Report 1981 shows that the total debt of oil-importing

    LDCs increased

    from $86.6 billion in 1971 to an estimated $524 billion in 1981

    (Table 1). The rate of borrowing increased from 16 per cent per year in 1971to 24

    per cent

    in

    1975, the year following the first oil price increases. It registered a

    further increase

    of

    27

    per cent per year

    in

    1978, but since 1980 has stabilised at 15

    per cent.'0

    A marked shift in

    the source of borrowing has taken place over the past decade.

    While the Official Development Assistance of the OECD countries more than

    doubledbetween 1971 and 1978 (by increasing from $24.7 billion to $61.0 billion),

    borrowing from

    OECD's capital markets increased by more than twelve-fold

    (from $16.1 billion to $209 billion

    -

    excluding export credits). Borrowing from

    international

    organisations, such as the WorldBank, InternationalMonetaryFund

    (IMF),

    and

    regional

    development

    banks increased sixfold

    (from $10.0 billion to $65

    billion).

    OPEC

    countriesemergedas

    an

    importantsource of lending by extending

    credits

    from

    less

    than half a

    billion in 1971

    to

    $23

    billion in

    1981.

    Another

    feature of the indebtedness

    of the

    oil-importing LDCs is the declining

    percentage

    of

    borrowing at

    concessional

    rates

    and the

    increasing percentage

    of

    borrowing

    at

    rates

    prevailing

    on the

    international

    capital markets.

    While

    fixed

    interest rates charged on concessional loans increased from 4.2 per cent in 1972 to

    6.2

    per

    cent in

    1981, the floating

    interest

    rate"I

    harged

    on

    the expanding loans

    in

    the

    capital

    market increased

    from

    7.9

    per

    cent to

    18.0

    per

    cent

    during

    the

    same

    period (Table 2).

    The burden that

    developing countries

    face in

    servicing their debts is shown in

    Table

    3.

    The

    total debt service in 1971 amounted

    to

    one-eighth ($10.9 billion out

    of

    ?86.6

    billion);

    in

    1981

    the

    percentage

    increased to

    just

    under one-fifth

    ($111.7

    billion

    out of

    $524.0 billion).

    The debt service

    on

    bilateral

    and

    multilateral

    Official

    Development

    Assistance has remained

    low

    ($5.9

    billion

    out of $118.0 billion).

    However,

    the debt service

    on

    commercial loans and

    export credits increased

    from

    their lowest levels in 1971($8.5 billion out of $47.4 billion - or less than one-fifth),

    to their

    highest

    levels

    in

    1981

    ($100.8

    billion

    out

    of

    $368.0

    billion

    -

    or

    almost

    one-

    third).

    These

    statistics, however, may

    be

    misleading

    because

    they

    do not

    distinguish

    between

    developing

    countries

    at

    different

    stages

    of

    development.

    Table

    4

    shows

    that the bulk

    of

    the

    debts were accumulated

    by

    79 Middle

    Income

    Countries

    (MICs)

    and a

    group

    of 11

    Newly

    Industrialised

    Countries

    (NICs).

    Both

    groups

    accounted

    for

    $341

    billion

    of the total

    debt in 1981. Thirteen OPEC

    countries

    accounted

    for

    $94

    billion,

    while the

    remaining

    55

    Low Income Countries

    (LICs)

    10

    The

    increased

    rate

    of

    borrowing

    in

    1978 was

    due to

    temporary

    decline in

    the

    rate of interest, and

    the

    purpose

    of borrowing

    was to

    pay prematurely

    earlierdebts which had been accumulated at higher

    rates.

    World

    DevelopmentReport

    1981, p

    59.

    11;Floating

    interest rate

    is

    expressed

    as a

    margin

    above the

    London

    Interbank

    Offered

    Rate (LIBOR),

    called the spread,

    which includesallowances

    for

    risk, commission,

    etc. The

    spread

    is

    normally

    0.5

    per

    cent, but it

    has gone up

    occasionally

    to 2.0

    per cent,

    as in

    the case of recent

    borrowings

    by Brazil.

    739

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    6/23

    THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY

    accounted for $89 billion. But it is also significantthat the higher the income level

    and the largerthe debt of a country the harder its debt service.

    Therefore, there

    seems to be little comfort in the fact that because the ability of the

    MICs and

    NICs to expand their exports is better than the LICs, they can afford

    to service

    their debts."2Considering the present policies of the industrialised

    and OPEC

    countries,

    further deterioration

    of

    the

    terms

    of trade of oil-importing LDCs is

    expected to reduce their ability to service their debts.

    Allocation of Responsibility

    Since 1973 it has become customary to distinguish between the

    oil-exporting

    countries as a sub-categoryof the Third World and single out the capital-surplus

    oil-exporters

    as a

    separate category

    not

    included

    among developing countries.

    I3

    In

    delineating these categories

    the

    implication

    is

    that oil pricing and investment

    allocation policies

    affect

    the

    health

    of the

    world

    economy. This implication

    is

    sometimes

    misplaced because

    none

    of

    these

    policies operates outside the domain

    of

    the economies

    of the ICs. The increased

    indebtedness of oil-importing LDCs

    and the measures

    required

    to correct

    the

    financial

    imbalances

    are,

    to a

    large

    extent,

    the

    result

    of decisions made in the

    ICs.

    Arguments

    of

    Industrialised

    Countries

    The ICs have argued that the quadrupling of oil prices by OPEC countries in

    1973-4 produced

    the first 'shock'

    to the world

    economy and

    must

    account

    for the

    spiral

    of

    inflation that

    ensued. The economic

    consequences

    of the

    sudden

    oil

    price increases

    left

    a deep impact

    on the

    oil-importing

    LDCs in

    particular.

    In

    1974

    the ICs suffered a current account deficit

    of

    $11.6 billion,

    while one

    year

    earlier they had realised a $19.3

    billion

    surplus.

    The

    oil-importing

    LDCs

    increased their

    current account deficits

    from

    $11.5

    billion in

    1973 to

    $36.9

    billion

    in 1974

    (Table 5).

    On the

    opposite

    end

    of

    the

    scale the

    OPEC

    countries increased

    their

    current

    account

    surpluses

    from

    $6.6

    billion in

    1973

    to

    $67.8

    billion

    in

    1974.

    The

    immediate

    effect

    of

    the

    quadrupling

    of the oil

    prices was an increase in the

    inflation rate in the ICs which soared to double-digit heights in 1974 and 1975.

    The ICs

    have also pointed

    out

    that every time

    the

    price of oil rises by $1 a barrel

    the

    oil-importing

    LDCs

    have

    to

    find

    nearly $2

    billion

    more to

    pay

    for their oil

    imports.

    The indirect

    effects are even worse since

    'higher

    oil

    prices

    mean slower

    growth

    in

    the

    industrialised

    world which

    buys

    two-thirds of

    all

    LDCs'

    exports.

    So

    the non-oil

    LDCs

    have been

    unable to fill

    the

    hole

    which

    dearer oil has

    punched

    in

    their

    current

    accounts.'4

    The

    ICs

    have

    further

    argued

    that

    the

    high

    rate of inflation

    they experienced prior

    to

    the oil

    price increases, together

    with

    the

    slump

    in

    the

    prices

    of raw materials

    of

    the

    oil-importing

    LDCs,

    could

    not

    have

    resulted

    in

    such

    large

    current

    account

    deficits had

    the

    oil

    prices remained

    12

    'External

    Debt Statistics. ..

    ', op

    cit.

    p

    4.

    '3 The oil-exporting

    developing countries comprise

    20 countries.

    The

    capital-surplus oil exporters

    number

    six and

    are not counted

    as

    developing countries.

    World

    DevelopmentReport 1981, viii.

    14

    'Rich

    Banks

    and

    Poor Countries',

    The

    Economist,

    (London)

    3

    November

    1979, p 92.

    740

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    7/23

    OPEC CAPITAL SURPLUS

    FUNDS AND THIRD WORLD

    INDEBTEDNESS

    relatively stable. These arguments are compelling and are widely accepted

    except, of course, by the OPEC countries.

    Arguments of OPEC Countries

    While recognising the adverse effects that higher oil prices have had on both the

    ICs

    and

    the

    LDCs, OPEC countries

    like to

    cite their own statistics. They have

    argued

    that the oil

    prices

    were

    kept unrealistically

    low

    by the major oil companies

    for many years and, at times, they were even reduced.'5 For example, a recent

    OECD study revealed that, in 1970, Saudi Arabia was selling its oil for $1.30 a

    barrel, which represented a decline

    of

    50 per cent in real terms of its value in

    1950.16

    In spite of the slight increase in the prices of oil in 1970 the (real) value of

    the

    oil

    revenues decreased between

    1970

    and

    1973 due to inflation

    in

    the

    ICs

    and

    the

    devaluation

    of

    the

    US dollar in

    1972.

    In

    addition the sharp increase in the

    prices of food and manufactured products more than offset the increase in oil

    prices.'7 The oil-importing

    LDCs

    suffered from the deterioration of their terms

    of

    trade

    with

    the

    ICs in

    equal

    measure with the

    increase

    in

    the prices of oil. Table

    5 shows that their termsof tradedeclined by 8.0 per cent in 1974 and again by 9.5

    per cent

    in 1975.

    This

    decrease affected

    their current

    accounts,

    which went from a

    deficit of

    $36.9

    billion

    in

    1974

    to a

    deficit

    of

    $45.9

    billion in

    1975.

    The blame

    must

    be shared by

    both the ICs

    and

    OPEC countries

    together.

    The oil-exporting countries have also arguedthat no serious harm was actually

    done

    to

    the

    majority

    of the

    oil-importing

    LDCs since

    they

    were more

    than

    compensated

    for their increased

    oil bills. The

    Organisation

    of

    Arab Petroleum

    Exporting Countries (OAPEC) published

    a

    report

    in which

    it provided

    the

    following

    calculation:'8

    out of

    1,050

    million tons

    of oil

    imported by developing

    countries between 1974 and

    1976,

    563 million

    tons,

    or

    53

    per cent,

    were

    re-

    exported

    in the form of either crude

    oil or

    refined

    products. The remaining 487

    million tons were

    the LDCs' net

    imports.

    Of

    this,

    five

    countries (Argentina,

    Brazil, India,

    South Korea and

    Taiwan) imported

    more than

    50 per

    cent. The

    report contends that

    these countries have

    strong

    and

    diversified economies,

    and

    that they were among the countries which succeeded in maintaining high growth

    rates

    in

    spite

    of the

    oil

    price

    increases.

    In

    addition, during

    this

    period (1974-6)

    OPEC countries committed

    $18.5

    billion

    in

    aid to the LDCs. This

    amounted

    to

    66.1

    per

    cent of

    the total

    $28

    billion

    these

    countries accumulated as current

    account deficits.

    If the five countries mentioned above were

    excluded

    from

    the

    15

    Loring Allen,

    'OPEC Speaks

    Out:

    an interview

    with

    Ali

    M

    Jaida',

    WorldReview,,March

    1979, p 42.

    16

    Cited

    by Hardy, op. cit.

    p 14.

    17

    The prices of

    food and

    services

    from

    the OECD countries

    have

    increased to

    such a level that OPEC

    countries'

    imports

    reached $79.3

    billion

    in

    1978,

    something they

    could afford

    to pay and

    even realise

    some

    current

    account surpluses. Oil-importing

    LDCs were in no position to do so. Petroleum

    Intelligence

    Service, 10 July 1979,

    p

    1.

    'Report on the

    Relationship

    Between

    the

    Financial

    Aid of OPEC

    Countries and the

    Financial

    Burdens

    of the

    Developing

    Countries Resulting

    from the Correction of Oil Prices Since 1973',

    OAPEC

    Bulletin,

    October 1979, pp

    15-25 (in Arabic).

    741

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    8/23

    THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY

    calculation of the oil import-aid ratio, thepercentageof OPEC aid commitments

    to

    the rest

    of the

    LDCs would

    be

    134.4

    per

    cent.

    The Muted Controversy

    Statistics

    can be

    creative;

    but

    they

    can

    also

    be

    deceptive. However,

    the

    glaring

    reality remains that Third World indebtedness was

    the

    making

    of

    both the

    ICs

    and

    OPEC countries.

    The

    deflationary policies

    that

    the OECD countries

    have

    pursued

    since

    1974 resulted

    in some

    improvements

    in their current accounts

    but

    have also retarded their economic recovery.

    These

    improvements were

    accom-

    plished by increasing

    their

    exports

    to

    OPEC

    countries

    and

    decreasing

    their

    imports from the oil-importing LDCs. A large part of the burden of adjustment,

    therefore,

    was

    shouldered

    by

    the

    latter,

    which

    benefited neither from

    the

    expanded

    markets of

    OPEC

    countries

    nor from their

    accumulated

    capital-

    surpluses. These surpluses

    were

    concentrated

    in

    the

    Western banking system

    which lent them

    to

    the

    LDCs

    at

    high

    interest

    rates,

    thus further

    affecting

    their

    economic imbalances.

    The symbiotic relationship that developed between the oil exporters and the

    ICs in the second part of the 1970s may explain the muted controversy over who

    caused the indebtedness of the oil-importing LDCs. In fact, the second 'shock'

    that OPEC delivered to the

    world

    economy

    in

    1979 was anticipated and did not

    raise the cries that werevoiced after the first oil priceincreases in 1973.A number

    of

    factors may explain

    this

    restrained

    reaction.

    First,

    the

    steady

    decline

    in the

    value

    of

    oil in

    real terms was

    bound to

    make

    price adjustments a necessity.

    The

    realvalue

    of

    oil declined by one-third between

    1974 and

    1978,

    and

    OPEC countries' current account

    surpluses decreased

    from

    $67.8

    billion to

    $5.0

    billion

    during

    the same

    period. Meanwhile,

    the

    prices

    of

    goods imported by

    OPEC countries

    soared,

    thus

    increasing

    the cost of their

    development programmes.

    The ICs failed to heed

    OPEC countries' calls

    for

    taking

    effective measures

    to control

    inflation,

    which

    was eroding the value

    of

    their oil

    capital surpluses (Table 5).

    Second, the price of oil in the parallel ('spot') market was increasing rapidly in

    relation to the

    price

    of contracted

    oil. The

    increase was

    necessary to bring OPEC

    oil

    prices

    to that

    level,

    which was also

    the

    level

    at which oil

    produced by

    industrialised countries (UK, Norway and Canada) and other developing

    countries

    (Mexico)

    was

    sold.

    In

    addition,

    the

    increase in the

    prices of oil could

    stimulate

    interests in

    developing alternative sources of energy.

    Third,

    the

    balance of trade of

    the ICs with OPEC

    countries registered signifi-

    cant

    improvements

    in the

    preceding years.

    This

    experience demonstrated that

    there

    was

    no

    reason to

    be

    alarmed at OPEC's

    increased revenues. Most of the

    revenues have been spent

    on

    purchases of goods and services from the ICs and

    the remaining surpluses have been invested there. Besides, any increases in oil

    prices could,

    as

    in

    the past,

    be

    offset by increasing the prices of exports.

    Fourth,

    OPEC

    countries, particularly the capital surplus oil exporters have

    displayed

    a sense of

    responsibility in cooperating with international lending

    742

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    9/23

    OPEC CAPITAL SURPLUS FUNDS

    AND THIRD WORLD

    INDEBTEDNESS

    instititutions.'9 They have also responded positively to the ICs' needs and

    recommendations

    ncludingmaking

    larger

    contributions o

    developing

    countries.20

    The

    muted

    reaction

    to the

    secondoil price

    'shock',

    however, has

    resolved

    noneof

    the

    problemsthat

    have

    afflicted heworld

    economy since

    1973.In

    fact, it

    has

    allowed

    the

    policies

    pursued by

    the ICs to

    continue. More

    than

    two years

    have

    already

    passed since the

    second 'shock'

    was

    administered, and no

    substantive

    changes of

    policy

    have been

    taken

    by the

    ICs

    to alleviate the

    problemsof

    inflation,

    slackening

    growth

    and

    unemployment.

    However,

    this

    muted

    reaction

    may

    no longer

    be

    possible,

    considering

    the

    prospects for

    growth

    and

    development

    in a world

    characterised

    more and

    more by

    interdependence. As it

    was put

    recently by

    Jacques de Larosiere, IMF Executive Director, 'the increase in international

    economic

    interdependence

    has

    brought with

    it a new

    element

    of

    vulnerability.

    Countries

    expanding trading

    and

    other

    economic

    links

    have

    become

    increasingly

    exposed

    to

    external

    economic

    and financial

    developments

    that are

    beyond their

    control'.21

    Although

    developing countries

    are more

    dependent on

    international

    trade

    for their

    growth

    than

    the

    ICs,

    their

    reduced level

    of

    trade

    and

    slackening

    economies will

    have an

    increasingly

    important

    impact

    on the

    prospects for

    economic

    recovery in

    the

    industrialised countries.

    Therefore,

    the

    relationship

    between the ICs

    and OPEC

    countries,

    to the

    exclusion of

    the

    developingworld,

    will

    not

    serve the

    interests of

    both

    in

    the

    long

    run.

    OPEC's

    diversification of

    trade and

    investment to the developing countries is a matter of necessity, not choice.

    Investment

    of

    Capital

    Surpluses

    It

    is

    difficult

    to

    estimate the amount of the

    capital-surplus oil funds

    with

    any

    measures

    of

    accuracy.

    Measured

    by

    the

    currentaccount

    surpluses

    of

    Saudi Arabia.

    Kuwait,

    Libya,

    Iraq, Qatar

    and

    the

    United

    Arab

    Emirates

    (UAE) between 1973

    and

    1980,

    the

    capital-surplus

    oil

    funds are

    estimated

    at

    some

    $350

    billion. But

    they

    could

    be twice that

    level.22Others

    estimate

    they

    will

    reach

    $500

    billion

    by

    1982.23

    9 In spite of the increased ndebtedness

    of

    oil-importing

    LDCs,

    aid

    from

    the ICsas

    a percentage of their

    Gross National Products (GNPs) declined from 0.30 per cent in 1974 to 0.22 per cent in 1977. This

    was well

    below

    the

    recommended

    target

    of 0.7

    per

    cent for

    the

    UN

    Second Development

    Decade. By

    comparison, OPEC

    members

    committed

    8.2

    per

    cent of

    their GNPs

    in

    aid

    in

    1974, the first

    yearafter

    the oil price

    ncreases;

    see

    Organisation

    forEconomic

    Cooperation

    and

    Development,

    Development

    Assistance

    Directorate,

    Flow

    ofResourcesfrom OPECMembers

    toDevelopingCountries,

    Document

    No. DD. 403, 6 December

    1975,

    Table

    2, p

    8.

    The

    estimated

    figures of

    Official

    Development

    Assistance of

    OECD

    countries

    in

    1980 is

    $26.6 billion,

    or

    0.37

    per cent of their

    GNPs; for

    OAPEC

    countries they

    are

    $6.798

    billion,

    or 2.34

    per

    cent.

    WorldDevelopmentReport

    981,

    Table

    16, Official

    Development

    Assistance

    from

    OECD

    andOPEC

    Members, pp

    164-5.See

    also 'Arab

    Institutions for

    Development

    Aid Have

    Rapidly Expanded

    Their

    Activities',IMFSurvey,

    5

    Februaryl979,p 37;and

    'Arab Monetary Fund

    Loan

    Operations

    Begin

    With

    Payments

    Assistance for

    Five

    Members', IMF

    Survey,

    20

    August

    1979, pp

    249-50.

    20

    OPEC countries received

    praise

    by

    the new

    president

    ofthe

    World

    Bank,

    A

    W

    Clausen.Address

    o the

    Board of

    Governors,

    World

    Bank,

    Washington, DC,

    29

    September

    1981.

    21

    EconomicCooper-ationndWorldStability, InternationalMonetaryFund,

    Washington, DC, August

    198 1, p 9.

    22

    Hardy,

    op.

    cit.

    p

    18.

    23

    'Morgan

    Guarantee

    Warnson

    Massive

    OPEC

    Revenues',InternationalHerald

    Tribune

    10

    December

    1979, p

    1.

    743

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    10/23

    THIRD

    WORLD

    QUARTERLY

    'Secrecytheorists,'however, contend that thesurpluses are much larger, but their

    accurate

    figures are known only to

    thecapital-surplus

    countries andsome

    Western

    governments,particularly the

    United States.24

    The

    capital surpluses

    are

    the

    result

    of

    over-production of oil. Under normal

    conditions it

    is in

    the interests

    of the oil

    exporters

    to

    produce

    only enough

    to

    meet

    the

    requirements of their

    development. For

    example,

    SaudiArabia's

    development

    requirements

    can

    be

    met by

    producing only

    4.5 million

    barrels

    of oil

    per day. Yet, it

    producesmore than

    twice as much. The reason

    it

    produces morethan it

    needs is to

    help

    -

    together

    with other oil

    exporters

    -

    meet

    the

    world demand for oil.

    Any

    cutback

    in

    production will result in

    driving

    the

    price

    of oil even

    higher

    which will

    further worsen prospects for the world economy. The oil producers themselves

    would

    suffer

    the

    consequences

    as

    well,

    because

    inflation

    spurred by

    oil

    price

    increases would drive

    up

    the

    prices

    of

    imported

    goods and reducethe value of their

    capital surpluses.25

    If

    the obligation to

    maintain

    current evels of oil

    production

    -andconsequently

    the accumulation of

    large capital surpluses

    -

    is

    inescapable,

    then

    they

    must find

    ways

    to

    protect

    their

    surplusesagainst

    inflation and

    currencydevaluation.

    In

    over-

    producing

    the oil exporters 'are

    depleting a

    non-renewableasset and

    exchanging

    an

    asset

    (oil)

    which

    is

    appreciating

    in value

    for

    financial assets which are

    depreciating

    in

    value.'26

    Any

    investment

    strategy,

    therefore,

    must

    be

    at least as

    profitable as if the oil had been kept underground.This goal, however, has been

    elusive in

    spite

    of

    the

    tremendous

    increases

    in

    the

    prices of

    oil

    since

    1973.

    The Harvest of the

    1970s

    The

    recycling

    strategies that the

    capital-surplus oil exporters

    pursued in the 1970s

    focused

    on

    the

    industrialised countries. There

    was,

    and

    still is, a

    general belief that

    only

    the Western

    economies have the

    width and

    depth

    to

    absorb

    their surpluses.

    There are other

    considerations, but they are less

    important than

    the basicpremise

    of

    the Western

    markets' viability.27Evenafter

    the

    developmentof a

    sophisticated

    banking

    system

    in

    the

    capital-surplus

    countries

    they

    have not

    ventured on any

    significant scale outside the industrialised economies. It will be worthwhile,

    therefore,

    to

    look

    briefly at the results of these

    investments

    since the recycling

    mechanism was initiated. What

    gains

    and losses

    have

    accruedby this

    mechanism

    24

    'Saudi-American Finances

    -

    That

    Secret

    Agreement:

    final

    confirmation

    and

    assessment of its

    long

    term

    importance',

    International

    Currency

    Reviewt12

    (1) 1980,pp

    7-24.

    25

    There are

    other

    reasons for the

    over-production

    of

    oil,

    which are

    political

    and

    economic. For

    example, theability of Saudi

    Arabia to

    increase

    tsproduction

    from

    8.5 to

    11.5million

    barrelsof oil a

    day

    alleviated the

    shortages

    in the world oil market that

    developed

    after

    the

    Iranian

    Revolution and

    impeded other OPEC members from

    raising

    the

    price

    of

    their oil.

    This

    capability is translated nto

    political

    power. In

    addition,

    Saudi Arabia fears

    that

    substantial increases

    of

    oil prices

    would

    accelerate the process

    of

    developing

    alternative sources of

    energy by

    the ICs and

    ultimately

    result in

    depressing the prices of oil.

    26

    Hardy, op.

    cit.

    p

    3.

    27

    These considerations

    are discussed at

    length

    in

    Fehmy Saddy and

    Antun Harik,

    'Investment of

    Surplus

    Oil Funds in the Third

    World:

    Latin

    America',

    Arab-Latin

    American

    Relations:

    Energy,

    Trade and Investment,

    Fehmy Saddy,

    (ed).,

    New

    Brunswick,

    N.J.:

    Transaction Books,

    1982.

    744

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    11/23

    OPEC

    CAPITAL SURPLUS

    FUNDS

    AND THIRD WORLD

    INDEBTEDNESS

    to the capital-surplus oil exporters,the industrialisedcountries and thedeveloping

    world?

    1.

    Capital-Surplus Oil

    Exporters

    Table 6 shows

    that the

    investablesurpluses

    varied from$59

    billion in 1974

    to $20

    billion

    in

    1977.

    Therewas a net

    deficit

    of$7 billion in 1978

    whensome oil

    producers

    had to

    draw on

    their deposits or

    borrowto pay for

    theirexpanded

    purchases. The

    investable

    surpluses rose

    to, $68

    billion in

    1979

    and again to

    $73

    billion in 1980.

    Most

    of the capital

    surpluses were

    invested in

    short-term bank

    deposits and

    securities in the

    Euromarket or in long-term

    US

    Treasury bills and

    UK securities.

    In addition, other investmentswereplaced in the stock marketsand in realestate.

    The rate of

    returnon

    these investments

    rangedbetween

    zeroand-3.4

    percent per

    year during the

    1972-9period.28The

    reasons for

    this

    negative return appear

    to be

    inflation and

    the

    depreciation

    of

    the US

    dollar in

    which oil

    payments are

    made.

    These reasons

    are

    explained by one economic

    analyst as

    follows:

    The

    annual increase in

    Eurodollar deposit rates

    between 1972 and

    1979 was 10.8 per

    cent, compared with the annual

    average

    ncrease n

    import

    prices

    of 14.2

    per cent, and

    in OECD

    domestic prices of 10.5

    per cent...

    In

    addition to a low or

    negative

    yield,

    it

    appears

    that

    the

    purchasing

    power

    of

    OPEC's

    dollar assets

    has also

    eroded because

    of

    the

    decline

    in

    the real

    effective

    exchange

    rate

    of

    the US

    dollar against

    the

    current-

    effective

    exchange

    rate of the US dollar

    against

    the

    currencies of 15 other

    major

    countries.29

    2. The Industrialised

    Countries

    The

    Eurodollar markets attracted most of the

    investable

    surpluses because of

    higher interest

    rates,

    minimum

    restrictions,

    and

    easy

    access to the

    surpluses

    when

    needed.

    The

    Euromarkets

    expanded

    in

    the 1970s with

    increased

    involvement

    of

    US

    banks.

    The

    purpose

    of this involvement was to

    help

    absorb or

    'recycle'

    the

    capital

    surpluses.

    The

    expansion

    of US

    banking

    overseas,

    particularly

    in

    developing

    countries,

    helped

    to

    connect the Euromarket with these

    countries,

    as

    lending

    to

    them became

    the cornerstone of the petro-dollar 'recycling' strategy.30In 1965, only 11

    American banks had branches

    in

    other countries.

    The number

    reached 125 banks

    in

    1975,

    with 732 branches

    operating

    in

    59

    countries.

    Wachtel

    reports that

    'taking

    just the

    20 largest

    US banks

    (which

    account for

    82

    per

    cent of the

    total number of

    foreign

    branches and 92

    per

    cent of total

    foreign

    assets), foreign

    assets account

    for

    about 35

    per

    cent

    of

    their total

    assets.'3'

    Some of

    the

    largest

    US

    banks even have

    more than

    50

    per

    cent

    of

    their assets

    in

    overseas

    branches.

    One

    indication

    of the

    profitability

    of'recycling'

    for US

    multinational banks

    is

    to

    compare

    the

    earnings

    from

    their

    overseas

    operations

    with their

    earnings

    at home.

    28

    Much

    of this discussion

    relies

    on

    Hardy op.

    cit.

    pp

    18-19.

    29

    ibid.

    3

    Much of the statistical data and

    evaluation

    thatfollow are drawn

    from HowardMWachtel,TheNew

    Gnomes:multinationalbanks

    in the

    Third

    World, Pamphlet

    No.

    4), Washington,

    DC: Transnational

    Institute, 1977.

    31

    ibid,

    p 8.

    745

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    12/23

    THIRD WORLD QUARTERLY

    By 1976, the external assets of the eight largest US banks32 accounted for 45 per

    cent of

    their

    total

    assets, compared with

    16

    per

    cent

    for

    all US banks. International

    earnings accounted

    for 95

    per

    cent

    of

    the increase in their

    total

    earnings during

    the

    1970-75 period.33 Wachtel

    composes

    the

    following profile

    of

    US

    banking

    operations,

    drawn from such authoritative sources

    as TheNew York

    Times

    and the

    investment

    house Salomon Brothers:

    A

    substantial portion of the total

    earnings

    of the

    12

    largest

    US

    banks come

    from

    earnings

    on loans

    made outside

    of the

    United States.

    In

    1975,

    63

    per

    cent of

    total

    income for these

    12

    largest banks originated

    in

    their

    foreign

    branches,up

    from 23

    per

    cent

    in

    1971 and 43

    per

    cent in 1974. For several

    of

    these

    large banks, nearly

    all

    of

    their

    earnings

    in

    1975 was derived

    from

    foreign

    branch

    activity. For

    example,

    Chase

    Manhattan

    received an astounding 82 per cent

    of its 1975

    earnings from foreign

    activities; First National Bank of

    Chicago,

    63

    per cent; and First

    National

    Bank of

    Boston, 80 per cent. Salomon

    Brothers, an investment house

    which employed

    William

    Simon before he became Secretary of the

    Treasury under Nixon and Ford,

    recently reported that

    the 'growth

    in

    international

    earnings has accounted for 95 per

    cent of

    the total earnings increase'

    in

    the

    largest banks since

    1970. The dynamic

    growing sector

    of

    banking activities had

    definitely shifted from the

    United States

    during

    this

    period.

    From 1970-1975credit

    expanded by only 9 per

    cent

    in the United

    States; in

    contrast, international credit grew

    two-and-a-half times as rapidly, about

    30

    per

    cent.

    Earnings

    in

    the

    international

    capital

    market

    expanded

    about

    36 per

    cent

    during

    this same

    period

    while domestic

    earnings

    declined

    by

    9

    per

    cent from

    1970-

    1975, according to the Salomon Brothersreport.34

    3.

    The

    Oil-Importing

    LDCs

    The negative return on

    investments

    of

    surplus

    oil revenues

    and the

    profitability

    of

    international

    banking

    were the result of

    the

    'recycling'

    mechanism. Both

    would have

    been

    justified had

    developing

    countries

    shared in the losses and

    gains.

    Their

    increased indebtedness

    meant,

    in

    fact,

    that

    they

    shared in

    the

    former

    but

    not

    in

    the

    latter,

    unless

    borrowing

    at

    high

    interest rates and

    the creation

    of

    debt-servicing problems

    could be

    considered- successful

    management. But this

    is

    exactly

    how

    it

    has

    been

    perceived.

    The

    intermediation of

    the

    international

    banking system

    has

    received

    praise

    on

    the

    premise

    that it

    prevented

    a

    deeper

    world recession.35 However, such intermediation was carried at a high cost for

    both the

    capital-surplus

    oil

    producers

    and

    the

    oil-importing LDCs.

    The acute

    indebtedness and debt

    servicing

    problems of the latter have come

    to threaten an

    even

    deeper world recession and

    the prospect of wholesale

    defaults for the first

    time

    since the 1930s. Measured

    by these results,

    the forms which the recycling

    strategy has taken could no

    longer be sustained without further

    sacrifices by all

    developing

    countries. In the

    final

    analysis, this

    will defeat the very purpose of

    recycling by

    negatively affecting the

    industrialised as well as the capital-surplus

    countries.

    32

    Citicorp, Bank of

    America,

    Chase

    Manhattan,Manufacturers

    Hanover, Bankers

    Trust,

    Chemical,

    Morgan Guarantee, First Chicago, and Continental

    Illinois.

    33

    Chandra

    S

    Hardy, 'Commercial Bank

    Lending

    to

    Developing Countries:

    supply

    constraints',

    World

    Development

    7

    (2)

    February 1979,

    p

    190.

    3 Wachtel op.

    cit. p

    9.

    3

    WorldDevelopment

    Report 1981, p 50.

    746

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    13/23

    OPEC CAPITAL SURPLUS FUNDS AND THIRD WORLD

    INDEBTEDNESS

    Investment in the Third World

    In concluding the discussion

    on

    external

    financing

    for

    adjustment and growth,

    the World Development Report of 1981 recommends

    improvement in the access

    of

    developing countries

    to stable

    flows of

    non-concessional credits.

    It

    states,

    in

    specific terms, that 'direct placement by the

    oil

    exporters

    in

    developing countries

    must

    be

    encouraged,

    and the

    international financial institutions should play

    a larger role

    in

    intermediation

    -

    directly

    or

    in

    cooperation with the private

    banks.'36

    Direct investments by the capital-surplus oil exporters in the Third World

    must be encouraged because of sound

    economic considerations and not only as a

    matter of concern for the plight of developing countries. The arguments

    presented here emphasise the stability and viability of developing countries.

    Furthermore, a strategy of investment diversification is in the interest of all

    countries because

    of their

    interdependent

    economic

    relations.

    Stability of Developing Countries

    The first concern of investors is political

    stability.

    To

    a large extent, defining

    stability is a matter of perception, even when objective criteria are developed as

    measurements. Paul

    Watson,

    a

    US

    banker,quotes Harry

    C

    Wallich

    of

    the Board

    of

    Governors

    of

    the Federal

    Reserve Board as

    saying:

    Practitionersof the analysisof the economic, inancialand political ituationsof

    the individual ebtor

    country)

    are he firstto

    point

    out

    that

    analysis

    of

    country

    isk

    is

    not

    a

    science. hesitate

    o

    call

    it an

    art;perhaps

    t

    may

    be

    dignified

    withthe term

    'craft'."

    Currently, assessments of the stability of

    developing

    countries are

    produced by

    Western specialists and thus reflect Western

    views

    and perceptions. The missing

    question

    in these assessments

    is:

    stability

    or

    instability

    in

    relation

    to

    which

    countries?

    International

    relations are marked

    by

    various shades of

    friendship

    and

    hostility

    for

    a host

    of reasons. Western investors have

    good

    reason

    to fear the

    expropriation

    of their

    assets

    by developing

    countries. Western involvement in the

    Third World may justify the negative reaction against foreign investments that

    were

    generated

    after

    independence.

    However,

    the

    same does not

    hold

    true for

    investments placed by the capital-surplus

    oil

    exporters

    who

    are themselves

    developing

    countries and

    who share with

    the

    investment-recipient

    countries

    in

    the Third World

    their

    caution

    and

    misapprehensions.

    It is worthwhile to note

    that there

    is no

    precedent

    of

    expropriation

    by

    a

    developing country

    of

    the assets

    of

    another

    developing country. Changes

    of

    government, therefore,

    are

    much less

    of

    a

    political

    risk

    for

    the

    capital-surplus

    countries than for

    Western interests

    with

    a

    questionable

    record

    in the

    Third World.

    In

    any case,

    the

    instability

    of

    developing

    countries is

    often

    exaggerated by

    Western financial circles which have frequentlyused it as a lever in negotiations

    with borrowers.

    In

    spite

    of the claim

    of the

    instability

    of

    developing countries,

    the

    36 ibid.

    3 Debt and The Developing

    Countries: newu roblems and new actors, Washington,

    DC: Overseas

    Development Council, Development Paper 26,

    NIEO Series, April 1978, p 45.

    747

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    14/23

    THIRD

    WORLD QUARTERLY

    Western banking system was able to place some $350 billion in developing

    countries during

    the

    span

    of a few

    years.

    For

    example,

    Brazil

    has been cited

    by

    investors

    as a risk-laden country

    because of its large

    external debt

    which

    amounted

    in 1981 to some $60

    billion. Yet Citicorp's portfolio

    outstanding

    in

    Brazil

    in

    1977

    was

    over $2 billion,

    which amounted to 35 per

    cent of its

    net

    income

    for

    that year.38

    Inspite

    of its

    Jarge

    debt,

    Brazil's

    ability

    to borrow on

    the

    international

    market

    does not seem to have been diminished.

    A further

    evidence

    of the politics

    of risk

    analysis

    is

    provided

    by

    the

    following

    account:

    A year

    ago (1978) some

    bankers stated

    publicly

    that 50 per cent

    of their LDCs

    exposure

    had some form

    of external guarantees.

    Subsequent

    US Federal Reserve

    Board survey (FED) data show that only 6 per cent of the claims on foreigners by

    US

    banks

    carry

    external guarantees

    ...

    Market

    analysts

    feel that

    much of

    what

    banks

    say about

    the risks

    in

    their

    LDC

    portfolios

    is self-serving.39

    Problems

    of Industrialised

    Countries

    The investment

    experiences

    of the capital-surplus

    countries during

    the 1970s

    have

    demonstrated

    that the political

    and economic stability

    of the industrialised

    countries

    is no

    less

    shaky

    than

    that

    of

    developing

    countries.

    On

    the political

    plane, the

    recent US-Iranian

    crisis reveals

    that

    dealing with the

    powerful is a

    mixed blessing,

    to

    say

    the least.

    The extraterritorial

    reach of

    US

    jurisdiction

    by

    which Iranian

    deposits

    in

    branches

    of

    US

    banks overseas were 'frozen'

    make the

    investments

    of capital-surplus

    countries subject

    to political

    considerations.

    Given

    the tenuous

    state of affairs

    between

    the

    United

    States

    and some

    Arab

    oil

    producing

    countries,

    the

    possibility

    of the US

    freezing

    their

    assets,

    whether

    in

    the

    United States

    or

    in

    branches

    of US banks

    overseas,

    cannot

    be discounted

    as a

    political

    risk.

    In

    addition,

    the

    US

    government

    and

    Congress

    have

    been producing

    a

    multiplicity

    of

    legislation

    and

    regulations

    that

    negatively

    affect Arab

    investment and

    trade.40

    These

    political

    risks

    have,

    in

    fact,

    been at work in

    OPEC

    countries' decisions

    to reduce

    their

    deposits

    in

    US

    banks.4'

    On

    the

    economic plane,

    the industrialised

    countries

    continue

    to be unable

    to

    put their house

    in

    order:

    inflation

    still seems

    uncontrollable;

    a

    sluggish

    economy

    is

    characteristic

    of most of

    them;

    and

    social

    upheavals

    resulting from

    unemployment

    and

    stagnation

    are

    on the

    rise.

    Consider the

    US

    economy,

    the

    strongest

    in the Western world,

    in

    1982. The national debt has

    risen to

    $1,079

    trillion,

    an

    increase

    of

    $94

    billion

    over a

    year

    ago.

    This

    debt 'amounts to $4,694

    for

    every man,

    woman and

    child

    in

    the

    country.'42

    The

    budget

    deficit amounts

    to

    $109

    billion

    which

    imperils

    economic recovery.43

    The unemployment rate

    of 9

    38 Hardy, op.

    cit.

    p 191.

    3

    Ibid., p 193.

    40

    See, in

    particular,

    Public

    Law

    No.

    95-52,

    Title

    11,

    91

    Stat.

    235,

    Export

    Administration

    Amendments

    (1977),

    amending

    50

    USC

    ?

    2401 et

    seq.

    (1970); Henry

    J

    Steiner,

    'International

    Boycotts and

    Domestic Order:AmericaninvolvementintheArab-Israeliconflict', TexasLaiiReview(54)1976, pp

    1355-1410;

    and

    note,

    'US

    Regulation

    of Direct

    Foreign

    Investment:

    current

    developments and the

    Congressional

    response', Virginia

    Journal

    of

    InternationalLaw

    (15) 1975, pp

    611-47.

    41

    'OPEC Nations

    Reduce

    Deposits

    in US

    Banks',

    Net

    York

    Times,

    19

    January

    1982, p

    Dl.

    42

    'Senate Passes

    Bill for

    Debt

    of

    $1 Trillion',

    WashingtonPost,

    30

    September

    1981, p

    1.

    43 'Volker Cautions That Big

    Deficits Imperil Recovery',NewrYork

    Times, 27

    January 1982, p 1.

    748

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    15/23

    OPEC

    CAPITAL

    SURPLUS FUNDS AND THIRD WORLD

    INDEBTEDNESS

    per cent is rising without any indication of government intervention to check it.

    Meanwhile, an ambitious armaments

    programme

    of over ?200 billion is under

    way to be financed

    by diminishing tax collections.

    The economic problems of

    the industrialised countries, however,

    are

    structural and

    not only related to ineffective economic

    policies. As W Arthur

    Lewis has indicated,

    growth in the

    ICs will continue to be low in the

    coming years

    as their economies

    pass througha cyclical decline.

    Recovery will ultimately come

    after structural

    adjustments are made, either by

    more efficient production

    or

    technological

    breakthroughs.44

    Viability of Developing Countries

    In

    spite

    of two oil price 'shocks',

    increased

    ndebtedness, anddeterioration

    intheir

    terms of trade, the developing

    countries were able to

    maintain an averagegrowth

    rate of 2.7 percent throughout

    the 1970s.

    This was

    higher than the average

    growth

    rate of 2.5 per

    cent achieved

    by

    the

    industrialised countries.45

    The growth rate of

    some MICs

    has reached

    higher

    levels than the

    average growth

    rate for

    all

    developing countries.

    The NICs

    in

    East

    Asia

    and

    Latin America

    particularly

    demonstrated

    a strong ability

    to

    withstand the world

    economic

    recession and

    maintained high

    levels

    of

    exports.

    On

    the

    whole,

    outward-looking

    countries in the

    Third World

    werewilling

    to take

    the

    risk of

    heavy

    external

    borrowing to maintain

    theirpace of development, and as a resultthey havefared better than the inward-

    looking countries.46

    These countries

    are

    particularly

    viable

    for

    investment by

    the

    capital-surplus

    oil exporters.

    Direct investment

    would

    help

    them reduce their

    borrowing

    on the international

    capital

    markets

    and allow them to

    manage

    their

    debts moreeffectively.

    The

    injection

    of

    capital

    investment

    in

    these countries would

    stimulate

    further

    growth

    with

    benefits

    for both investors and

    capital

    recipients.

    Conclusion

    The discussion

    of

    indebtedness

    has

    indicated the tremendous

    risks to the world

    economy

    that

    have been

    created

    by

    the financial imbalances

    of

    developing

    countries.

    In

    spite

    of cautious

    optimism

    about

    the

    ability

    of

    developing

    countries

    to

    ward

    off the

    prospects

    of

    default,

    these

    prospects

    cannot be

    ignored.

    The

    indebtedness problem

    is not

    receiving

    the concern it

    requires

    from

    multilateral

    development institutions,

    industrialised

    governments

    and

    capital-surplus

    coun-

    tries,

    and

    no

    concerted

    efforts

    have

    been made to

    bring

    it

    under control.

    The

    investment

    policies

    that the

    capital-surplus

    oil

    exporters

    have

    pursued

    have

    fallen within

    the

    general strategy

    of

    'recycling.'

    Essentially,

    what this

    strategy

    accomplished

    was

    the transformation

    of OPEC's

    surpluses

    into debts to

    developing

    countries

    through

    the

    Western

    banking system,

    which

    reaped

    the

    4

    'The Slowing Down of the Engineof Growth', AmericanEconomicReviewv70), September 1980pp

    555-64.

    4

    Wor dDevelopment

    Report

    1981,

    Table 1-1, Growth

    of GNP

    per person, by region, 1960-90,

    p

    3.

    46

    RalphC Bryant,

    'Notes on

    the Analysisof Capital

    Flows

    to

    DevelopingNations

    and

    the "Recycling"

    Problem',

    World Bank Staff Working

    Paper No. 476, Washington,

    DC, August

    1981.

    749

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    16/23

    THIRD WORLD

    QUARTERLY

    benefits. The economic resultsof this strategyweredisadvantageous to both the

    capital-surplus

    and

    oil-importing

    developing

    LDCs.

    Moreover,

    the

    'recycling'

    strategyhelped to

    deepen

    further the

    dependence

    of

    both on

    the

    ICs.

    It was

    the

    liberal

    'fix'

    of

    the

    early

    1970s that

    provided

    the

    necessary

    logic

    and

    rationale

    for

    the

    recycling

    strategy.

    In its

    simplest

    form it

    meant that

    attention

    must

    be

    given

    to the ICs

    because

    of

    the

    adverse

    effects

    any curtailment

    of

    their

    growth would have on the LDCs. In a

    sense,

    this

    argument

    implies

    that what is

    good for the

    ICs is

    good

    for

    the

    rest of

    the

    world.

    Therefore,

    the

    recycling

    mechanism

    was structured

    for the

    purpose

    of

    helping

    the

    Western

    economies

    recover their

    strength.

    The

    experience

    of the last

    decade

    has

    proven

    the

    recycling

    strategy inadequate. Neither the capital-surplus oil exporters nor the oil-

    importingLDCs

    benefited

    from

    recycling:

    heformer

    byderiving

    negative

    returns

    on

    their

    investments,

    the

    latter

    by

    increasing

    their

    indebtedness to an

    alarming

    level. The benefits that accrued

    to

    the ICs

    were

    substantial.

    However,

    the

    recycling

    strategy

    failed to

    bring

    about

    recovery

    for their

    economies. In

    fact,

    the

    Western

    economies continue

    to face

    serious

    difficulties

    manifested

    in

    persistent

    stagflation,

    unemployment

    and

    declining

    productivity.

    One

    analyst

    has

    commented on

    this

    state of affairs

    by saying

    that

    'controversy

    rages

    both about

    the

    causes of this

    "stagflation"

    and the

    appropriate

    policy

    reaction to

    it.

    Economists'

    views

    about

    macroeconomic

    theory

    and

    policy

    are

    in

    a

    greater

    state of

    disarray han

    at

    any

    time

    in living memory.'47

    In

    spite

    of the structured favouritism in the

    recycling strategy toward

    the

    ICs,

    achievements have been

    meagre.

    The

    developing

    countries, which

    seem to have

    taken

    the

    brunt of

    recycling

    in terms of

    increased

    indebtedness,

    deterioration

    in

    terms

    of

    trade,

    and curtailed

    exports,

    fared better.

    If

    this is

    any indication it is

    that

    they

    are

    more viable

    economically

    and

    are

    better

    candidates for

    future

    growth.

    Investment

    of

    capital surpluses

    in

    these countries is

    at least

    as

    viable as in

    the ICs.

    There

    has been a

    recognition

    of

    the

    limitation

    of

    recycling

    as

    it

    was

    administered

    in the

    1970s. It

    is

    again

    the liberal

    'fixers' who are

    leading

    the

    way. They

    contend

    that

    the

    prospects

    of default in the Third

    World

    would

    pose

    intolerable risks

    to the

    worldeconomy. To ward off such aprospect,some of thecapitalsurplusesmust be

    invested

    directly in

    developing

    countries. The

    Western

    banking system

    has

    reached

    its

    limits in

    terms of its

    ability

    to

    continue

    its

    lending to the

    ThirdWorld.

    Direct investments

    by

    the

    capital-surplusexporters

    in

    developing

    countries

    would

    help the

    latter service their debts

    while

    relegating to

    the former

    a

    larger

    responsibility

    in

    assuming the

    risks.

    However,

    they

    contend that

    the

    largestpart of

    the

    capitalsurpluses

    must be

    invested

    in the

    ICs to

    help them

    'reindustrialise'

    more

    efficiently.48 It

    may

    seem odd to

    argue

    that

    the

    capital

    surpluses of

    some

    developing

    countries

    must

    be

    used

    to

    reindustrialise

    the

    industrialised

    countries

    when

    these

    surpluses

    could be

    used more

    efficiently

    in

    the

    developing

    world. Ifthe

    liberalargumentis adopted, double industrialisationwould havebeencarriedout

    in

    the

    Western countries

    at the

    expense

    ofthe

    developing

    countries,once

    by the use

    47

    ibid.,

    p

    58.

    48

    Hardy,op.

    cit.,

    pSI.

    750

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    17/23

    OPEC CAPITAL

    SURPLUS FUNDS AND

    THIRD

    WORLD

    INDEBTEDNESS

    of their raw materials and again by their capital surpluses.

    Therefore,

    enlightened

    self-interest,

    not

    immediate

    short-term

    benefit, is

    indispensable

    to correct

    the

    present world

    economic

    imbalances

    within a

    framework of

    balanced

    interdependence.49The

    recycling

    strategy

    in the

    1980s

    must make

    the

    developing countries the focus

    of

    its

    attention.

    This

    amounts to

    the

    recognition

    that

    genuine

    interdependence

    is a

    system of

    shared

    risks

    and

    responsibilities.

    It also

    indicates that the

    economic

    viability

    of

    the

    whole

    depends

    on the

    viability

    of

    its

    parts.

    See

    Fehmy

    Saddy,

    'A

    New World

    Economic Order: the limits

    of

    accommodation', Inteinational

    Journal

    34

    (1)

    Winter

    1979,

    pp

    16-38.

    751

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    18/23

    THIRD WORLD

    QUARTERLY

    Q00 ia o

    0

    ClOs \OC

    V.*

    ON

    l

    0 C)

    r-~

    ~~

    ooo~~o

    OCl~

    eqI fn

    tIc

    0 C

    0CC)

    crc

    n

    V

    N

    r*

    o

    -

    oo

    Ct

    ON - - O

    en 00

    00

    0

    ccrcN

    e t i -

    o

    Ic

    t

    _

    mXtmN *

    r * _

    -. --

    - -

    e) f

    o

    W

    ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~

    o00Cl- L

    m X

    00

    eM~~~~~~e

    ON

    -

    ~

    (ccrc0

    O

    0

    4

    eo 1

    c Cx

    e

    vUt

    ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~

    '

    'I *- r

    :

    N

    - - -0 C

    l

    00

    0 0

    0_

    (A

    Q

    ;

    ~~~-z~~~0

    O

    ~ ~ ~ ~ C~ r-

    ?

    'I ON

    0r

    o o o

    t _

    -*

    N o.

    -

    Cl

    .s

    o

    o

    ~r

    m1NO ,..o

    N t

    o i ON

    0.0

    ONcX~J

    w

    N

    Cl

    oc

    \s

    o

    ~o -

    -

    -

    .

    ~~~~0

    eq~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~a

    W

    ?

    :

    Ct

    O

    E-

    - i

    B-t A^ ,

    - j

    C~~~~~ct

    o ?t

    N

    N

    m0

    C)

    _

    752~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~7

    E

    U~~~~~~~~-

    U

    U~~~~~~~~~~.

    C~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C

    0

    0~~~C~EU

    H~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~l

    I

    752~~~~~~~~a

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    19/23

    OPEC

    CAPITAL SURPLUS

    FUNDS

    AND

    THIRD

    WORLD

    INDEBTEDNESS

    v

    *. &

    o

    & o

    6

    o6 6

    C)0C

    o

    rR

    6

    o6

    t

    6

    ON-

    =-~

    i

    0

    0

    CIO tO

    00.

    00

    rNX

    f)

    C

    -

    Cl 0

    ?O

    ^

    U m

    _~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~

    ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~

    ON

    .

    N66

    o ~ N 0 oR

    N O

    C)

    Cn cO

    -

    'No

    C

    O

    ._

    _

    ;~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~

    ci:t:

    3O

    OQ '0 0

    r?

    0

    cO

    CO

    o N

    0a(

    4>1

    s,

    }O;?r

    Oc

    Cf~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ UtC:

    *

    tr) db

    .>

    U O ?

    C 0 Cl

    ? 3

    o

    t

    N t3

    ~~~~~~~~~~o

    ,

    6

    &

  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    20/23

    THIRD WORLD

    QUARTERLY

    00

    00 -

    N O

    :*o o~ o oocr6

    _

    ~

    Q

    OQ

    00

    Cl V( CO

    N

    , r

    _

    ONl

    _,

    _

    N

    -

    * 0

    rn

    00

    00

    r0

    "CNO

    r

    ON

    *o -t Xi ci rm-

    -

    _

    00

    *

    l

    *

    N C Cl ClVN

    Cu~~~~ mN

    o

    m~ ~t ON

    _

    ON

    C0 Cn

    N - 0 C -

    ~~ _

    Cl

    _*

    ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~~~~~~r

    00

    - ~~~~~e -

    S:

    -

    os d- c-i 6t- 0z:)

    _

    CO

    -

    00

    00 " 00

    0

    00 C-

    all

    00~~~~~~~

    _

    _0

    S

    ?-

    ~ s

    Cu~~~~~~~

    0~~~~

    U~~~~~~

    E

    s

    U

    _

    ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ 0 C)

    _

    00 C)

    ~n

    XS >

    r~~~~~

    _ E

    7 05

    0 0

    ,o

    *- m

    oo/ _

    _

    ~ ~

    Cs

    ,

    .O _C

    CM

    ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~

    C

    E

    - su

    ;~~~~~~~~~~~

    ~~~~~~~~CO O)OC O CC

    _~~~~~~~~O

    ._

    ~~

    ~~I4 0~~

    754

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
  • 7/21/2019 Saddy 1982

    21/23

    OPEC

    CAPITAL SURPLUS

    FUNDS

    AND

    THIRD WORLD

    INDEBTEDNESS

    11,

    sv

    S:

    c)t- Cl

    N

    i

    s

    o ,z,

    _

    o

    >

    o

    N

    N~~~-

    C

    Ct

    _~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~"

    b~- Cl

    N \0

    -

    _N

    0

    V) 'I CN

    o

    t C

    Z

    qCl

    00 ON

    ON

    0 0000

    \~00 Cl

    ~.O

    00

    s

    0 t

    oo

    tn

    oo

    N

    Cl

    N

    0 C"i on ern ON Cl

    ,

    -

    -4

    -C

    ONC

    cc'

    cN

    -

    ONt Cl ro 0

    c

    '

    t

    00

    00 00

    "C

    C C 0

    Cl

    N? -'

    N:>o

    -

    -o

    00o N

    N

    tfo

    oo

    'r) 0

    -

    N

    O

    O

    _

    Q

    -

    -~

    -

    }

    N Cl

    -

    00

    O

    -

    -

    ci~ ~ ~ ~~ ~

    ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~O

    0

    X

    X;

    >

    ON

    tI 0

    t

    N

    N Cl N

    -

    0

    ?O \O

    s

    0 ON

    O

    oi-

    O3

    OCl

    NO

    1

    t

    > CrN

    _I

    -= Nc

    2

    N

    ON

    -

    N

    a00

    -

    00

    N

    Cl

    ON tN

    :;~~

    -

    Cl

    _t-

    I

    ,

    =

    :

    >

    -

    ,

    >

    o

    00

    00

    N

    0

    -Cl

    Cl tIN

    0

    N

    -IN

    0

    O0

    N tIN Cl

    00

    0

    -

    CZ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~C

    Na

    -0

    ~N C 00

    ON

    N

    LIN'IN

    0 ON 'Ct 00 Cl

    0

    ON

    tIN 00

    N r'N

    - ~ 6

    &-0

    CZ

    3-

    ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~ ~

    ~~~~~-

    HO

    _

    O

    =

    Ct

    l-

    m00C

    tI

    >N

    9

    0t

    NC

    tI

    00

    O

    IN

    ON

    o

    C) ON

    -"- Cl

    ?tN

    N -0

    ,4

    o

    ?

    _

    R

    ~

    6

    o

    0:

    o

    0

    8

    v

    o

    0

    ;~~~ ?-~ a

    Q

    ^ a.

    755

    This content downloaded on Sun, 23 Dec 2012 09:26:05 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

    http://www.jst