32

rta III. General Equilibrium

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Intermediate Microeconomics (22014)

Part III. General Equilibrium

Instructor: Marc Teignier-Baqué

First Semester, 2011

Page 2: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Welfare

Outline Part III. General Equilibrium

1. Pure Exchange Economy (Varian, Ch 31)

1.1 Edgeworth Box1.2 The Core1.3 Competitive Equilibrium1.4 Welfare Theorems1.5 Walras' Law

2. Production (Varian, Ch 32)

3. Welfare (Varian, Ch 33)

Page 3: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Welfare

Topic 6. General Equilibrium

I Up until now, partial equilibrium analysis:

I markets for goods analyzed in isolation, ignoring e�ect ofother prices on the market equilibrium;

I demand and supply functions of own price alone.

I In general, however, demand and supply in several marketsinteract to determine equilibrium prices of all goods.

I Substitutes and complements.I People's income a�ected by goods sold.

I In top 6, general equilibrium analysis: all markets clear

simultaneously.

I Considerations of Pareto e�ciency and also of welfare distributionand "social preferences."

Page 4: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

PURE EXCHANGE ECONOMY (Varian, Ch 31)I Since very complex problem, simpli�cations adopted:

I Only competitive markets studied, so that consumers andproducers take prices as given.

I Situations with, at most, two goods and two consumers.I First, pure exchange economy : �xed endowments, no

description of resources conversion to consumables.I Afterwards, production introduced into the model.

I Pure exchange economy:

I Two consumers, A and B, two goods, 1 and 2.I Endowments of goods 1 and 2:

ωA =

(ωA

1 ,ωA

2

), ω

B =(

ωB

1 ,ωB2

).

I Given a price vector (p1,p2), consumers choose their favoritea�ordable allocation (as in topic 1):

p1xA

1 +p2xA

2 ≤ p1ωA

1 +p2ωA

2

p1xB

1 +p2xB

2 ≤ p1ωB

1 +p2ωB

2

I Prices must be such that allocations chosen are feasible:

xA

1 +xB

1 ≤ ωA

1 +ωB

1 , xA2 +xB

2 ≤ ωA

2 +ωB

2

Page 5: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

Edgeworth Box

I Edgeworth box is diagram showing all possible

allocations of the available quantities of goods 1 and 2

between the two consumers.

I The dimensions of the box are the quantities availableof the goods.

I The allocations depicted are the feasible allocations.

BA22

Height = 

22

Width = BA Width =  11

Page 6: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

Endowment allocation

I The endowment allocation is the before-trade

allocation:

Oω1

BOB

A ω2B

ω2A ω2

EndowmentllωAB

+

allocationω2ω2B

OA

A Bω1

A

ω ω1 1A B+

Page 7: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

Feasible reallocationsI Which reallocation will consumers choose?

I Feasible.I Pareto-improving over the endowment allocation.

I An allocation is feasible if and only if

xA1 + xB1 ≤ ωA1 +ω

B1

xA2 + xB2 ≤ ωA2 +ω

B2

I All points in the box, including the boundary, represent

feasible allocations of the combined endowments:

OxB

1OB

Aω2A

xB2

B+

xA2

ω2B

OA

x2

xA1

ω ω1 1A B+

Page 8: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

Pareto-improving allocations

I An allocation is Pareto-improving over the endowment

allocation if it improves the welfare of a consumer

without reducing the welfare of another.

I Preferences of consumers A and B:

xA2

Preferences consumer A

2A

1A xA

1OA

1 1

Preferences of consumer B1

BBx1

Preferences of consumer BOB

1

B2B

Bx22

Page 9: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

Pareto-improving allocations

I An allocation is Pareto-improving over the endowment

allocation if it improves the welfare of a consumer

without reducing the welfare of another.

1B

OB

A B2A

O

2B

1AOA

Set of Pareto‐improving allocations

I Since each consumer can refuse to trade, the only

possible outcomes from exchange are Pareto-improving

allocations.

Page 10: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

Contract curve

I An allocation is Pareto-optimal if the only way one

consumer's welfare can be increased is to decrease the

welfare of the other consumer.

I The set of all Pareto-optimal allocations is called

contract curve.

Pareto‐optimal allocations are marked by     .Convex indifference curves are tangent at     .    

1B

OB

A B2A

O

2B

1AOA

Th t tThe contract curve

Page 11: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

The Core

I The core is the set of all Pareto-optimal allocations

that are welfare-improving for both consumers relative

to their own endowments.

1B

OB

A B2A

O

2B

1AOA

The Core: Pareto‐optimal ptrades not blocked by A or B.

I Rational trade should achieve a core allocation.

Page 12: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

Trade in competitive marketsI Speci�c core alloation achieved depends upon the

manner in which trade is conducted.

I In perfectly competitive markets, each consumer is a

price-taker trying to maximize her own utility given

(p1,p2) and her own endowment:

AxA2 Consumer A optimization

A A A Ap x p x p pA A A A1 1 2 2 1 1 2 2

Ax*2

2A

A

2

1A

xA1OA Ax*

1 1

I Similarly for consumer B.

Page 13: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

Trade in competitive markets

I At equilibrium prices p1 and p2, both consumers

maximize their own utility and both markets clear:

xA1 + xB1 = ωA1 +ω

B1

xA2 + xB2 = ωA2 +ω

B2

Budget constraint for consumer B

B1 OB

Bx*1

Bx*2

Ax*2

A2

O

B2

A1OA Ax*

1

Equilibrium allocationBudget constraint for consumer A

Equilibrium allocation

Page 14: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

First fundamental theorem of welfare economics

Theorem

Given that consumers' preferences are well-behaved, trading

in perfectly competitive markets implements a Pareto-optimal

allocation of the economy's endowment.

I Note: Indi�erence curves are tangent, which implies that

the equilibrium allocation is Pareto optimal.

Page 15: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

Second fundamental theorem of welfare economics

Theorem

Given that consumers' preferences are well-behaved, for any

Pareto-optimal allocation, there are prices and an allocation

of the total endowment that makes the Pareto-optimal

allocation implementable by trading in competitive markets.

I In other words, any Pareto-optimal allocation can be

achieved by trading in competitive markets provided

that endowments are �rst appropriately rearranged.

Pareto‐optimal allocation        cannot be implemented by competitive tradingimplemented by competitive trading from initial endowment        but it can beimplemented by competitive trading from l d

OB

alternative endowment      .

OOA

Page 16: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

Walras' Law

Theorem

If consumer's preferences are �well-behaved�, so that for any

positive prices (p1,p2) consumers spend all their budget, the

summed market value of excess demands is zero. This is

Walras' Law.

p1xA1 +p2x

A2 = p1ω

A1 +p2ω

A2

p1xB1 +p2x

B2 = p1ω

B1 +p2ω

B2

p1

(xA1 + xB1 −ω

A1 −ω

B1

)+p2

(xA2 + xB2 −ω

A2 −ω

B2

)= 0

Page 17: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Edgeworth Box

The Core

Competitiveequilibrium

Welfare theorems

Walras' Law

Production

Welfare

Implications of Walras' Law

I One implication of Walras' Law for a two-commodity

exchange economy is that if one market is in equilibrium

then the other market must also be in equilibrium.

p1

(xA1 + xB1 −ω

A1 −ω

B1

)+p2

(xA2 + xB2 −ω

A2 −ω

B2

)= 0

⇒ If xA1 + xB1 = ωA1 +ω

B1 , then xA2 + xB2 = ωA

2 +ωB2 .

I Another implication of Walras' Law for a two-commodity

exchange economy is that an excess supply in one

market implies an excess demand in the other market.

p1

(xA1 + xB1 −ω

A1 −ω

B1

)+p2

(xA2 + xB2 −ω

A2 −ω

B2

)= 0

⇒ If xA1 + xB1 < ωA1 +ω

B1 , then xA2 + xB2 > ωA

2 +ωB2 .

Page 18: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Robinson CrusoeEconomy

CompetitiveEquilibrium

Welfare Theorems

Welfare

Outline Part III. General Equilibrium

1. Pure Exchange Economy (Varian, Ch 31)

2. Production (Varian, Ch 32)

2.1 Robinson Crusoe economy2.2 Competitive equilibrium2.3 Welfare theorems

3. Welfare (Varian, Ch 33)

Page 19: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Robinson CrusoeEconomy

CompetitiveEquilibrium

Welfare Theorems

Welfare

PRODUCTION (Varian, Ch 32)I Add input and output markets, �rms' technologies.I Robinson Crusoe's Economy:

I One agent: Robinson Crusoe.I Endowment: a �xed quantity of time.I Decision: use time for labor (production of coconuts) orleisure.

I Technology: coconuts are obtained from labor according

to the production function C = f (L).

Coconuts

Production function

Feasible productionl

Labor (hours)240

plans

Page 20: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Robinson CrusoeEconomy

CompetitiveEquilibrium

Welfare Theorems

Welfare

Robinson Crusoe's preferencesI Indi�erence curves in the leisure-coconut diagram:

coconut is a good, leisure is a good:

Coconuts

More preferred

Leisure (hours)240

I Indi�erence curves in the labor-coconuts diagram:

coconut is a good, labor is a bad.

CoconutsMore preferred

Labor (hours)0 24

Page 21: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Robinson CrusoeEconomy

CompetitiveEquilibrium

Welfare Theorems

Welfare

Robinson Crusoe's choice

I Robinson chooses time allocation and, as a result, his

consumption of coconuts:

Coconuts

MRS = MPL

Production functionC*

Output

Labor (hours)240 L*Labor Leisure

t

Leisure (hours)24 0

Page 22: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Robinson CrusoeEconomy

CompetitiveEquilibrium

Welfare Theorems

Welfare

Competitive equilibrium in the Robinson economy

I Robinson esquizofrenia:

I We �rst consider Robinson as a pro�t-maximizing

�rm, who takes prices as given and decides how muchhours to hire and how much to produce.

I Then, we consider Robinson as a utility-maximizing

consumer who gets the �rm pro�ts and decides hishours of work and his consumption of coconuts.

I Let p be the coconuts price and w the wage rate.

I Use coconuts as the numeraire good; i.e. price of acoconut = 1.

Page 23: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Robinson CrusoeEconomy

CompetitiveEquilibrium

Welfare Theorems

Welfare

Robinson as a �rmI Optimization problem of the �rm: given w , choose labor

demand and coconut supply to maximize pro�ts:

maxL

π = C −wL= f (L)−wL ⇒ MP (L∗) = w

I Labor demanded: L∗, output supplied: C ∗ = f (L∗).

I Graphically, �rm demands L such that production

function tangent to isopro�t line:

Coconuts

w = MPL * * * C wLIsoprofit line:

Production functionC* *

Labor (hours)24L*0

Page 24: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Robinson CrusoeEconomy

CompetitiveEquilibrium

Welfare Theorems

Welfare

Robinson as consumerI Optimization problem of the consumer: choose labor

supply and coconut demand to maximize utility subject

to the budget constraint:

maxC ,L

U (C ,L) s.t. C = π∗+wL ⇒ ∂U (C ,L)/∂L

∂U (C ,L)/∂C= w

I Labor supplies: L∗, coconuts demanded: C ∗.

I Graphically, consumer chooses C and L such that the

indi�erence curve is tangent to the budget constraint:

Coconuts

C wL *Budget constraint:MRS = w

*

C wL * .C*

Labor (hours)240 L*

Page 25: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Robinson CrusoeEconomy

CompetitiveEquilibrium

Welfare Theorems

Welfare

Market equilibrium

I In equilibrium, wage rate must be such that

quantity labor demanded = quantity labor supplied

(quantity output supplied = quantity output demanded)

CoconutsMRS = w = MPL

C* *

Labor (hours)24L*0

Page 26: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Robinson CrusoeEconomy

CompetitiveEquilibrium

Welfare Theorems

Welfare

First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics

Theorem

If consumers' preferences are convex and there are no

externalities in consumption or production, a competitive

market equilibrium is Pareto e�cient.

I Pareto e�ciency: MRS =MP :I Competitive equilibrium achieves Pareto e�ciency: w isthe common slope of the ispro�t line and the budgetconstraint.

CoconutsMRS = MPMRS MP

Labor (hours)240

Page 27: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Robinson CrusoeEconomy

CompetitiveEquilibrium

Welfare Theorems

Welfare

Second Fundamental Theorem of WelfareEconomics

Theorem

If consumers' preferences are convex, �rms' technologies are

convex, and there are no externalities in consumption or

production any Pareto e�cient economic state can be

achieved as a competitive market equilibrium.

Page 28: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Robinson CrusoeEconomy

CompetitiveEquilibrium

Welfare Theorems

Welfare

Non-convex technologies

I The First Welfare Theorems still holds if �rms have

non-convex technologies since it does not rely upon

�rms' technologies being convex.

I The Second Welfare Theorem does not hold if �rms

have non-convex technologies.

MRS MP f i i ilib iCoconuts

MRS = MPL If competitive equilibrium exists, the common slope is the relative wage rate wth t i l t th P tthat implements the Pareto efficient plan by decentralized pricing.

Labor (hours)240

Coconuts

MRS = MPL. This Pareto optimal allocation cannot be implemented by a competitive equilibrium.

Labor (hours)240

Page 29: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Welfare

Outline Part III. General Equilibrium

1. Pure Exchange Economy (Varian, Ch 31

2. Production (Varian, Ch 32)

3. Welfare (Varian, Ch 33)

Page 30: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Welfare

WELFARE (Varian, Ch 33)

I Social choice: Di�erent economic states will be

preferred by di�erent individuals. How can individual

preferences be �aggregated� into a social preference

over all possible economic states?

I Fairness: Some Pareto e�cient allocations are �unfair�

(for example, one consumer eats everything). Under

what conditions, competitive markets guarantee that a

fair allocation is achieved?

Page 31: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Welfare

Social welfare functions

Let ui (x) be individual i's utility from overall allocation x.

I Utilitarian social welfare function:

W =n

∑i=1

ui (x)

I Weighted-sum social welfare function:

W =n

∑i=1

aiui (x) , ai > 0

I Minimax welfare function:

W =min{u1 (x) ,u2 (x) , ....,un (x)}

Page 32: rta III. General Equilibrium

Part III. GeneralEquilibrium

Exchange

Production

Welfare

Fair allocations

I An allocation is fair if it is

I Pareto e�cientI envy free (no agent prefers the allocation of otheragents to their own).

I If every agent's endowment is identical, then trading in

competitive markets results in a fair allocation (may not

be true for non-competitive markets).