23
Robust measures of intergenerational poverty transmission for Europe: the role of education * Luna Bellani § University of Konstanz Michela Bia LISER This Version: June 2015 (This draft compiled: June 8, 2015) Preliminary version. Please do not quote without permission Abstract This paper examines the causal channels through which growing up poor affects the individual’s economic outcomes as an adult. We contribute to the growing literature on intergenerational transmission, on the one end providing a quantitative measurement of the causal effects of poverty in childhood, applying a potential outcome approach to this question and implementing a series of robustness checks. On the other end, analyzing the impact of the interplay between growing up in poverty and individual human capital accumulation on the children outcomes later in life. The analysis is based on the module on intergenerational transmission of 2011 of the EU-SILC data, where retrospective questions about parental characteristics (such as education, age, occupation) were asked. We find that even after controlling for possible unobserved confounders, e.g. child ability, being poor in childhood significantly decreases the level of income in adulthood, increasing the average probability of being poor. Moreover, our results reveal a significant role of human capital accumulation in this intergenerational transmission. Keywords: poverty, intergenerational transmission, potential outcome, dynamic treatment effects, education JEL classification codes: D31, I32, J62 * This work has been supported by the second Network for the analysis of EU-SILC (Net-SILC2), funded by Eurostat. The European Commission bears no responsibility for the analyses and conclusions, which are solely those of the authors. In addition, Bellani acknowledges financial support from an AFR grant (PDR 2011-1) from the Luxembourg Fonds National de la Recherche cofunded under the Marie Curie Actions of the European Commission (FP7-COFUND). Usual disclaimers apply. § E-mail:[email protected] E-mail:[email protected] 1

Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

Robust measures of intergenerational poverty transmission

for Europe: the role of education∗

Luna Bellani§

University of Konstanz

Michela Bia‡

LISER

This Version: June 2015

(This draft compiled: June 8, 2015)

Preliminary version. Please do not quote without permission

Abstract

This paper examines the causal channels through which growing up poor affects the individual’s economic

outcomes as an adult. We contribute to the growing literature on intergenerational transmission, on the one

end providing a quantitative measurement of the causal effects of poverty in childhood, applying a potential

outcome approach to this question and implementing a series of robustness checks. On the other end, analyzing

the impact of the interplay between growing up in poverty and individual human capital accumulation on the

children outcomes later in life. The analysis is based on the module on intergenerational transmission of 2011

of the EU-SILC data, where retrospective questions about parental characteristics (such as education, age,

occupation) were asked. We find that even after controlling for possible unobserved confounders, e.g. child

ability, being poor in childhood significantly decreases the level of income in adulthood, increasing the average

probability of being poor. Moreover, our results reveal a significant role of human capital accumulation in this

intergenerational transmission.

Keywords: poverty, intergenerational transmission, potential outcome, dynamic treatment effects, education

JEL classification codes: D31, I32, J62

∗This work has been supported by the second Network for the analysis of EU-SILC (Net-SILC2), funded by Eurostat.The European Commission bears no responsibility for the analyses and conclusions, which are solely those of the authors.In addition, Bellani acknowledges financial support from an AFR grant (PDR 2011-1) from the Luxembourg Fonds Nationalde la Recherche cofunded under the Marie Curie Actions of the European Commission (FP7-COFUND). Usual disclaimersapply.§E-mail:[email protected]‡E-mail:[email protected]

1

Page 2: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

1 Introduction

The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of

active research and a major policy concern in many developed as well as developing countries.

The economic literature on intergenerational transmission focused typically on the estimates of the

intergenerational elasticity in income or earnings of parents and their offspring. In the United States,

the first studies on this topic revealed the elasticity coefficients of children’ earnings with respect to

parent’s earnings to be of around 0.2 (Behrman and Taubman, 1985; Becker and Tomes, 1986). More

recently Chadwick and Solon (2002) estimate elasticities in the range 0.35 to 0.49 for family income,

and Altonji and Dunn (2000) in the range 0.35 to 0.41, for hourly wages. A substantial literature

followed, estimating this mobility for many other countries, focusing on Europe in particular, among

others for Scandinavian Countries (Bjorklund and Jantti, 1997), for Britain (Blanden et al., 2007), for

France (Lefranc and Trannoy, 2005) and OECD (2010) for European OECD countries.

Many of these estimates are based on predicted fathers’ earnings, rather than the actual ones, using

fathers’ characteristics (father’s education and occupation in Bjorklund and Jantti (1997); only educa-

tional levels in Grawe (2004); different levels of education, occupational groups and age in Lefranc and

Trannoy (2005); detailed occupation sectors in Leigh (2007)).

The general message coming form these contributions suggests that the United States and the United

Kingdom have higher rates of intergenerational persistence than other countries, while the Scandinavian

countries have the lowest, with respect to the other countries instead the ordering varies.

Fewer studies have instead been focusing on poverty persistence across generations (see among oth-

ers Ermisch et al. (2004); Mayer (1997); Shea (2000); Acemoglu and Pischke (2001)). These papers

find significant impact of parental income or parental financial difficulties on children human capital

accumulation and later labor market outcomes, in the range of 5% decrease in education given parental

joblessness for Britain, and a 1.4 percentage point increase in the probability of attending college for

an increase of income of 10% for the United States.

Blanden et al. (2007) analyze in detail the association between childhood family income and later adult

earnings, among sons, exploring the role of education, ability, non-cognitive skills and labor market

experience in generating intergenerational persistence in the UK. They do so by decomposing the es-

timated mobility coefficient conditional on those mediating variables. They show that inequalities in

achievements at age 16 and in post-compulsory education by family background are extremely impor-

tant in determining the level of intergenerational mobility. In particular they find a dominant role of

education in generating persistence. Cognitive and non-cognitive skills both work indirectly through

2

Page 3: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

influencing the level of education obtained, with the cognitive variables accounting for 20% of inter-

generational persistence and non-cognitive variables accounting for 10%.

As we have already argued in a previous contribution (Bellani and Bia, 2015), although those studies

agree that growing up in a poor family raises the probability of falling below the poverty threshold in

adulthood, the key contentious question for policy here is whether this association is truly causal in the

sense that poverty in childhood per se influences later outcomes or whether it is driven by other factors

correlated with both childhood poverty and later outcomes, such as parenting styles, family structure,

neighborhood influences, genetic transmissions, etc. Moreover, as suggested also by Blanden et al.

(2007), it is relevant for policy to examine a plausible causal channel through which being born poor

affects the individual’s economic and social status as an adult. In this paper we thus not only provide a

series of robustness checks on the impact of growing up in poverty that is provided in Bellani and Bia

(2015), but we also analyze this process, introducing individual human capital as intermediate variable.

Our analysis is based on the module on intergenerational transmission of 2011 of the EU-SILC data,

where retrospective questions about parental characteristics (such as education, age, occupation) were

asked. We find that even after controlling for possible unobserved confounders, e.g. child ability,

being poor in childhood significantly decreases the level of income in adulthood, increasing the average

probability of being poor. Moreover, our results reveal a significant role of human capital accumulation

in this intergenerational transmission.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 introduces the estimation strategy and in

Section 3 the data used through the whole paper are described. In Section 4 we analyze both the average

and the distributional impact of growing up poor, while in Section 5 we focus on a possible channel of

this impact, analyzing the role of attaining higher education. Section 6 concludes.

2 Estimation strategy

Experiencing financial difficulties growing up is not the only determinant of outcomes later in life,

because of the complexity of the process, different statistical techniques have been used, each of which

relies on a different set of assumptions, as reviewed in our previous contribution on the topic (Bellani

and Bia, 2015).

In this paper we follow the framework of Potential Outcomes approach for causal inference (Rubin,

1974, 1978), which considers a randomized experiment where (a) subjects are randomly selected from

the target population; (b) a binary treatment is randomly allocated to the subjects; (c) there are no

hidden versions of the treatment and there is no interference between units (Stable Unit Treatment

3

Page 4: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

Value Assumption - SUTVA) as the golden standard for estimating causal effects. In observational

studies, the existence of other difficulties in addition to the critical problem of non-random treatment

assignment implies that additional assumptions have to be made in order to estimate the causal effects

of the treatment.

In our study, the critical problem of non-random treatment assignment (assumption (b) above) implies

that additional assumptions have to be made in order to estimate the causal effects of the treatment.

An important identifying assumption is the selection on observables (unconfoundedness) (Rosenbaum

and Rubin, 1983). For a review of the statistical and econometric work focusing on estimating average

treatment effects under this assumption, see Imbens (2004)).)

Let us consider a set of N individuals, and denote each of them by subscript i: i = 1, . . . , N . Let Ti

indicate whether a child was growing up in a poor household, Ti = 1 (treated), or not, Ti = 0 (control).

For each individual, we observe a vector of pre-treatment variables, Xi and the value of the outcome

variable associated with the treatment, Yi(1) for being a poor child, Yi(0) for not being a poor child.

The central assumption of our approach is that the “assignment to treatment” is unconfounded given

the set of observable variables: Yi(0), Yi(1) ⊥ Ti|Xi.. Let p(X) be the probability of growing in a

poor household given covariates: p(X) = Pr(T = 1|X = x) = E[T |X = x]. Rosenbaum and Rubin

(1983) show that if the potential outcome Yi(0) is independent of treatment assignment conditional on

X, it is also independent conditional on p(X). Following Rosenbaum and Rubin (1983), we adjust

for the propensity score, that is, treatment and potential outcomes are independent also conditional on

p(X): Yi(0), Yi(1) ⊥ Ti|p(X), thus removing all biases associated with differences in the covariates.

For a given propensity score, exposure to treatment can be considered as random and thus poor and

non poor children should be on average observationally identical. Therefore, we apply a propensity

score matching method to select a control group of non-treated individuals (in this case non poor as

a child) who are very similar to treated individuals conditional on a set of observable characteristics

(parental characteristics, family composition, and other features fixed in childhood, such as the number

of siblings or birth order) (unconfoundedness). The matched samples of poor and non-poor children

will then be used to assess impacts on adulthood outcomes, primarily equivalent income and probability

of being poor.

Formally, given the population of units i, if we know the propensity score p(Xi), then the average effect

of being poor on the population (ATE) is estimated as follows:

τ = E[Y1i − Y0i] = E[E[Y1i − Y0i|p(Xi)]] = E[E[Y1i|Ti = 1, p(Xi)]]− E[E[Y0i|Ti = 0, p(Xi)]]

and the average effect of being poor on those exposed to poverty (ATT) as follows:

τt = E[Y1i − Y0i|Ti = 1] = Ep(Xi)|Ti=1[E[Y1i − Y0i|Ti = 1, p(Xi)]] =

4

Page 5: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

Ep(Xi)|Ti=1[E[Y1i|Ti = 1, p(Xi)]]− Ep(Xi)|Ti=1[E[Y0i|Ti = 0, p(Xi)]]

Finally in Section 5, we introduce a dynamic treatment approach based on sequential conditional-

independence assumptions to assess if there is any impact of growing up in poverty on children out-

comes later in life after controlling for individual human capital. Statistical analyses concerning the role

of an intermediate variable between a particular treatment and an outcome are important for understand-

ing issues concerning mechanism. Several ways to conceptualize the mediatory role of an intermediate

variable in the treatment - outcome relationship have been proposed in the causal inference literature

(Joffe et al., 2007).

We consider dynamic matching models that extend the static Neyman-Robin model based on selec-

tion on observable (see Gill and Robins (2001) and Lok (2008), and for application to economics

Fitzenberger et al. (2008) and Lechner and Miquel (2010)). In particular we consider a discrete-time

finite-horizon model. Under the assumption that the actual treatment assignment S is sequentially ran-

domized (SR), we can sequentially identify the causal effects of treatment and construct the distribution

of the potential outcomes Y (s) for any treatment sequence s in the support of S. Moreover, the no-

anticipation condition (NA) ensures that potential outcomes for a treatment sequence s equal actual

(under treatment T0) outcomes up to time t− 1 for agents with treatment history st−1 up to time t− 1.

Formally, Y t−1(s) = Y t−1 on the set {St−1 = st−1}.

Consider a two-period version of the model in which agents take either treatment (1) or control (0)

in each period. Then, S(1) and S(2) have values in S = {0, 1}. The potential outcomes in period t

are Y (t, (0, 0)), Y (t, (0, 1)), Y (t, (1, 0)) and Y (t, (1, 1)). For example, Y (2, (0, 0)) is the outcome in

period 2 in the case that the agent is assigned to the control group in each of the two periods.

In a nutshell, in this paper we consider two treatments (poverty, education) and two periods. In period

1, a member of the population can be observed in exactly one of two treatments (Poor, Non poor). In

period 2, she faces the subsequent treatment (Tertiary Education), thus she participates in one of four

treatment sequences (0, 0), (1, 0), (0, 1), (1, 1), depending on what happened in period 1.

Therefore, a comparison of causal effects of T (growing up in poverty) on Y (children outcomes later

in life) for individual now matched also on the value of the intermediary outcome (tertiary education in

our specific case) provides information on the extent to which a causal effect of growing up in poverty

on later outcomes occurs together with a causal effect of growing up poor on the intermediate outcome

human capital status.

5

Page 6: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

3 Data

The analysis is based on data from the the European Union Statistics on Income and Living Conditions

(EU-SILC), which provides comparable, cross-sectional and longitudinal multidimensional data on in-

come, poverty, social exclusion and living conditions in the European Union.1 For the specific purpose

of this project we will use the module on intergenerational transmission of 2011, where retrospective

questions about parental characteristics (such as education, age, occupation) referring to the period in

which the interviewee was a young teenager (between the age of 14 and 16) were asked to each house-

hold member aged over 24 and less than 66. We treat missing data as an additional category, keeping

cases that would otherwise be dropped. “This is particularly appropriate when the unobserved value

simply does not exist. For instance, individual may have questions on mother’s and father’s education,

but the father or mother was unknown or never part of the family”.(Allison, 2001)

We further restrict our sample to the individual in working age between 35 to 55 to maintain a degree

of homogeneity in the period of the life cycle in which the outcomes of interests are measured.

More in details, our treatment variable is constructed based on the financial situation of the household

(vary bad or bad), while the variables we used as pre-treatment are the country of residence and of

birth, the gender, the year and quarter of birth, the n. of adults in the household, n. of persons in the

household in work, number of siblings, family composition, year and country of birth, highest level of

education, main activity, main occupation and citizenship of the father and of the mother and tenancy

status.

The outcome in adulthood that we are interested in are the log of the equivalized income,2 and the

probability of being poor (defined as having an equivalized income lower than 60% of the median in

his/her country in that year).

As already mentioned at the end of Section 2, as intermediate outcome that are after treatment and have

an impact on the final outcome of interest we are analyzing the probability of having a post-secondary

education.

The descriptive statistics and the T-test on the means of the variables used in the following analysis can

be found in the Appendix A.3

1Refer to chapter 2 in Atkinson and Marlier (2015) for a description of this database.2We use equivalized disposable income that is the total income of a household, after tax and other deductions, that is

available for spending or saving, divided by the number of household members converted into equalized adults; householdmembers are equalized using the so-called modified OECD equivalence scale.

3We are aware that individuals may suffer from retrospective recollection bias. The retrospective technique has beenextensively applied in studies of intergenerational occupational mobility (Atkinson et al., 1983). In this specific case, webelieve that the type of question asked is less affected by this problem compared, for example, with a direct question on thelevel of income in the household.

6

Page 7: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

4 Results

4.1 Propensity score based methods

A preliminary analysis of these data can be found in Bellani and Bia (2015), where a propensity score

base method has been applied for both 2005 and 2011 data. Here, as in there, we firstly estimate

by means of probit model, each individual’s propensity score, i.e. his/her probability to be poor in

childhood given the observed characteristics introduced in the previous section.4

As already explained in Section 2, the propensity score is a balancing score (Rosenbaum and Rubin,

1983), that is, within strata with the same value of p(X) the probability that T ={0, 1} (being poor or

not) does not depend on the value of X. This balancing property, combined with the unconfoundedness

assumption, implies that, for a given propensity score, exposure to a treatment status is random and

therefore treated and control units should be on average “similar” conditional on observables character-

istics. As a result, to be effective, propensity score based methods should balance characteristics across

treatment groups. The extent to which this has been achieved can be explored by comparing balance in

the pre-treatment covariates before and after adjusting for the estimated propensity score (PS). Figures

1 provides the standardized bias (in percentage) for unmatched and matched units,5 showing a huge

improvement in the balancing property when adjusting for the PS, with a bias always around 0.

Another important requirement for identification is given by the common support, as shown in figure 2,

which ensures that for each treated unit there are control units with the same observables. In the matched

sample, the comparison of baseline covariates may be complemented by comparing the distribution of

the estimated PS between treated and controls. The common area of support serves as a first evaluation

4For the results of this first step of the estimation strategy please refer to table 25.3 in Bellani and Bia (2015) and therelative comments.

5The reduction of bias due to matching is computed as:

BR = 100(1− BM

B0)

whereBM

is the standardized bias after matching

BM =100(xMC − xMT )√

S2MC

+S2MT

2

andB0

is the standardized bias before matching

B0 =100(x0C − x0T )√

S20C

+S20T

2

,

where subscript M denotes after matching, 0 denotes before matching.

7

Page 8: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

Figure 1: Balancing property

Figure 2: Common support

of whether covariates means included in the PS model are similar between the two groups (Ho et al.,

2007). We con notice here that, as expected given the topic of interest, children with a probability of

being poor higher than 0.7 cannot be included in our study as it is not possible to find children with

these levels of pre-treatment variables belonging to both groups. This results n giving us a sort of lower

bound for the real effect which could be sensibly be considered even higher if this part of the population

was included.

8

Page 9: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

We implement the propensity score procedure applying a single nearest-neighbor matching to remove

bias associated with differences in covariates and estimate the effects of being poor on adulthood out-

come, primarily equivalent income and probability of being poor later in life.

Table 1: Propensity Score Matching

(1) (2) (3)Main Outputs Intermediate Outputs

Income Poverty Education

ATE -0.02 0.03 -0.06(0.007) (0.006) (0.008)

ATT -0.04 0.04 -0.04(0.006) (0.006) (0.006)

N. 133647 133818 132789

Results are presented in table 1. The results on income show a substantial decrease in the equivalized

income in adulthood due to exposure to poverty in childhood. This decrease is on average close to 3

percentage points.

With respect to our intermediate outcome of interest, our results show an average of 5% decrease in the

probability of reaching a higher level of education for the children experiencing financial difficulties

while growing up.

This significant decrease in the probability of getting higher education could be considered as a cause

of the strongly significant difference in income in adulthood between these two groups of children. In

the last part of the paper (section 5) we address this research question in more details.

4.2 Robustness checks

4.2.1 Combining Matching and Regression: Doubly-Robust Estimation

In this section we combine both matching on the propensity score and regression, doing a doubly-robust

estimation. By doing the matching we trim from the data all the observations that are not “similar” in

their probability of belonging to any of the treatment groups, with respect to the pre-treatment observ-

ables. In practice, we eliminate units that are not on common support, including in our sample only the

control cases that are on average “identical” to the treatment cases and discarding the remaining data.

In our analysis the psmatch2 Stata package6 gives us the information we need via the weights. We know

which individuals we should discard and which should be counted more than once7. Hence, over the

matched units, we run a regression with all the same covariates used in the propensity score estimation.

6See Leuven and Sianesi (2003) for more details on the package.7More detailed results are available upon request from the authors.

9

Page 10: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

The marginal effect of the treatment is our doubly-robust estimate of the average treatment effect, as

reported in table 2.8 The average treatment effect estimate, relative to each outcome considered in our

study, is overall very close to the findings derived from the ATT and ATE estimation when using the PS

based technique, with slightly different results only for income and education at the population level.

Table 2: Doubly-Robust Estimation

(1) (2) (3)Main Outputs Intermediate Outputs

Income Poverty Education

ATE -0.03 0.03 -0.04(0.002) (0.003) (0.004)

ATT -0.03 0.04 -0.04(0.003) (0.004) (0.004)

N. 133647 133818 132782

4.2.2 Sensitivity analysis for poverty risk

One of the central assumptions of our analysis is that being poor in childhood can be considered as ran-

dom, given a set of precedent covariates X and thus the outcome of non-poor children can be used to

estimate the counterfactual outcome of the poor children if they were not experiencing poverty in child-

hood. The plausibility of this assumption heavily relies on the quality and amount of information con-

tained inX .9 The validity of this assumption is not directly testable, since the data are completely unin-

formative about the distribution of the potential outcomes, but its credibility can be supported/rejected

by additional sensitivity analysis. Our analysis would be in fact biased if we were to believe that even

conditional on all the covariates we can observe (parental education and occupation, family situation,

child own age, sex, year and country of birth and number of siblings, etc.), being poor in childhood

would be linked to some unobserved parental genetic ability which would not only influence the proba-

bility of the parents of falling into poverty (being treated) but also the child potential outcome as a result

of the genetic transmission of ability. In this setting, it is assumed that the conditional independence

assumption holds given X and the unobserved variable A: Yi(0) ⊥ Ti|Xi, Ai10 and knowing A would

be sufficient to consistently estimate the ATT: E[Y0i |Ti = 1, Xi, Ai] = E[Y0i |Ti = 0, Xi, Ai].

In order to asses the credibility of our assumption, we follow the approach suggested by Ichino et al.

8 The results presented in this table are the average marginal effect of the treatment variable, given by the OLS coefficientestimation for the continuous variable log of Income, and the average of the marginal effects calculated from the probitestimates for the probability of being poor in adulthood and to attain tertiary education.

9Refer to Section2 for a more detailed description of the assumptions made.10If the average treatment effect of interest is the ATT, the CIA assumption is then reduced to: Yi(0) ⊥ Ti|Xi, where, within

each cell defined by X , treatment assignment is random, and the outcome of controls are used to estimate the counterfactualoutcome of treated in case of no treatment.

10

Page 11: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

(2008) and assume that the unobserved ability variable A can be expressed as a binary variable taking

value H=high, L=low. In addition, A is assumed to be i.i.d. distributed in the cells represented by

the Cartesian product of the treatment and outcome values. The distribution of the binary confounding

factor A can be fully characterized by the choice of four parameters: pij ≡ Pr(A = 1|T = i, Y =

j) = Pr(A = 1|T = i, Y = j,X) with i, j ∈ 0, 1, which give the probability that A = 1(high) in each

of the four groups defined by the treatment status (poor as a child) and the outcome value (poverty in

adulthood)11. Given arbitrary values of the parameters pij , a value of A is attributed to each individual,

according to her/his belonging to one of the four groups defined by their poverty status in childhood

and adulthood.

The simulated A is then treated as any other observed covariate and is included in the set of matching

variables used to estimate the propensity score and to compute a simulated ATT estimate, derived as an

average of the ATTs over the distribution of A.

We can thus control for the conditional association of A with Y0 and T by measuring how each config-

uration of pij leads to an impact of A on Y0 and T .

In order to do so, we run the sensatt program developed by Nannicini (2007) and estimate a logit

model of Pr(Y = 1|T = 0, A,X) at each iteration, reporting the average odds ratio of A as the

“outcome effect” (Γ) and “selection effect” (∆) of the simulated confounder:

Γ =

Pr(Y=1|T=0,A=1,X)Pr(Y=0|T=0,A=1,X)

Pr(Y=1|T=0,A=0,X)Pr(Y=0|T=0,A=0,X)

,

i.e. the effect of parental ability on the outcome of non-poor children, controlling for the observable

covariates (X),

∆ =

Pr(T=1|A=1,X)Pr(T=0|A=1,X)

Pr(T=1|A=0,X)Pr(T=0|A=0,X)

,

i.e. the effect of parental ability on the probability of experiencing poverty (T=1), controlling for the

observable covariates (X).

In this section, we perform two simulation exercises. In the first one, the pij are set so as to let our

simulated parental abilityAmimic the behavior of parental education variables, as their strong, although

11Note that, in order to perform the simulation, in Nannicini (2007) two assumptions are made: i) binary confounder ii)conditional independence of A given X.

11

Page 12: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

not perfect, positive correlation is well known in the literature (see among others Anger and Heineck

(2010); Bjorklund et al. (2010)).

In the second one, a set of different pij is built in order to capture the characteristics of this potential

confounder that would drive the ATT estimates to zero. (Killer confounder)

In tables 3 and 4 the results of these sensitivity checks are presented. The significance of the impact

is robust to the introduction of the calibrated unobserved ability, although this considerably reduces its

size. These results show that both the outcome and the selection effect need to be very strong (2.2 and

3.9, respectively) in order to kill the ATT, i.e., to explain almost entirely the positive baseline estimate

of the ATT.

Table 3: ATT estimation

Baseline Father’s Educ-Calibrated Mother’s Educ-Calibrated Killer

0.04 0.01 0.02 0.00(0.005) (0.006) (0.007) (0.007)

Table 4: Sensitivity Analysis: pij values and odds ratio

Father’s Educ-Calibrated Mother’s Educ-Calibrated Killer

p11 0.1 0.1 0.5p10 0.2 0.2 0.3p01 0.3 0.2 0.2p00 0.4 0.4 0.1

Outcome Effect 0.49 0.52 2.25Selection Effect 0.31 0.29 3.89

4.3 Distributional effect

Following the results presented in column 1 of Table 1 we know that experiencing financial difficulties

while growing up lead to a decrease of income in adulthood of on average 3%, in this subsection we

are interested in exploring the distributional effect of this impact. In order to do so we present here the

cumulative densities of the distributions of income in adulthood of the children belonging to the treated

and control group together with some measures of inequalities and poverty in both samples.

At first, if we consider the whole sample and compare the distribution of individuals’ income in both

group without controlling for their probability of experiencing poverty in childhood, we can notice that

the distribution of the non-poor children first order stochastic dominates the other, implying thus higher

social welfare in an hypothetical society in which no one experience poverty as a child than one in

which childhood poverty is common (see part (a) and (c) in figure 3). Interestingly, when we control

12

Page 13: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

for the propensity score and we look at the matched sample (see part (b) and (d) in figure 3) this result

no longer holds, suggesting that when we can control for the characteristics which are associated with

experiencing poverty in the first place, the impact of the parental financial difficulties, although being on

average significant, does not clearly predict such a lower welfare achievement. It is worth recall here,

that we excluded from our sample the children with observable characteristics which were leading a

probability of experiencing poverty higher than 70%. This part of the population was clearly notably

decreasing the social welfare when included in the sample of the poor.12 This could also be noticed

from table 5, where we report some measure of inequality and poverty by ”treatment” group in both the

whole (part (a) and (b)) and the matched (part(c) and (d) )sample.

(a) Cumulative density-all sample (b) Cumulative density-matched sample

(c) Generalized Lorenz Curves-all sample (d) Generalized Lorenz Curves-matched sample

Figure 3: Distributional Graphs-Equivalized Income

To conclude this part, we also analyzed the distribution of the highest level of education attained and

we can notice the same patter that we have described for income, driven by the higher average level

12In Appendix B the bottom of the distribution is plotted for both cases, which clearly shows dominance in one case andnot in the other.

13

Page 14: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

Table 5: Equivalized Income Inequality

(a) (b) (c) (d)Not Matched Matched

Non-Poor Poor Non-Poor Poor

Mean 16660 13379 14349 14202Median 13027 10322 10329 8875p90/p10 11.23 11.97 11.11 12.05p75/p25 4.01 3.93 4.12 4.42Gini 0.44 0.44 0.45 0.48Theil Index 0.32 0.33 0.34 0.39Atkinson Index (α = 2) 0.78 0.71 0.62 0.62

of education of the non-poor sample (see Figure 4 part (a) and (b)).13 Once we exclude from the the

sample the extreme cases based on their probability of being poor as children (i.e. the ones who do not

belong to the common support of the propensity score as explained in Section 2), we are again not able

to assess which distribution is better from a social welfare prospective.

(a) Generalized Lorenz Curves-all sample (b) Generalized Lorenz Curves-matched sample

(c) Lorenz Curves-all sample (d) Lorenz Curves

Figure 4: Distributional Graphs-Highest Level of Education

13Around 20% more individual with post secondary education in this group.

14

Page 15: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

5 Results: Poverty in childhood-Education-Poverty in adulthood

As introduced at the end of section 2, in this last part of our analysis we implement a dynamic treatment

approach to our research question in order to uncover the role of human capital accumulation in the

intergenerational poverty transmission.

Table 6 reports the results if we insert education in the set of covariates we use for the matching. The

highest level of education attained is used in the matching procedure as pre-treatment characteristic.

It provides information on how experiencing the (psychological and) physical dimension of poverty

as a child gives less labor market opportunities to young generations via the highest educational level

achieved by the individual. Any progress and advancement at school plays indeed a substantial role

both in terms of intermediate outcome (column 3, Table 1) and control variable (intermediate variable)

to define the causal effect estimation of poverty on labor market outcomes later in life (columns 1 and

2, Table 6). Being poor as a child will more likely translate into an exclusion from tertiary education

and, as a result, more likely into lower income levels as an adult.

Table 6: Propensity Score Matching

(1) (2)Income Poverty

ATE -0.01 0.02(0.008) (0.005)

ATT -0.03 0.02(0.006) (0.007)

N. 130413 130577

Finally, as a robustness check on our measure of human capital accumulation, we present in table 7 the

results using instead of the constructed dummy for post secondary education, the categorical variable

Highest ISCED level of education attained.14

Table 7: Propensity Score Matching

(1) (2) (3)Education Income Poverty

ATE -0.07 -0.01 0.02(0.018) (0.005) (0.006)

ATT -0.12 -0.02 0.02(0.014) (0.005) (0.007)

N. 132789 132620 132789

146 categories: Less than primary education, Primary education, Lower secondary education, Upper secondaryeducation,Post-secondary non -tertiary education, Tertiary education.

15

Page 16: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

6 Concluding remarks

This paper examines the causal channels through which growing up poor affects the individual’s eco-

nomic outcomes as an adult. We provide a quantitative assessment of the causal effect of poverty in

childhood at the European level, performing a series of robustness checks on the potential outcome

approach chosen. Moreover, we analyze the impact of the interplay between growing up in poverty and

individual human capital accumulation on the children outcomes later in life. This analysis reinforce

the need for policies devoted to eliminate the source of these increased risk, reducing child poverty.

Moreover, after having showed that childhood poverty has indeed a relevant detrimental impact on eco-

nomic, and potentially also social and behavioural, outcomes in adulthood, a fundamental question left

to answer to be able to make more effective policy recommendation regards the channels through which

being raised in a poor family affects the individual’s economic and social status as an adult. In order

to do so, as a first step in this direction, this paper provides evidence of the important role that human

capital has in this process.

References

Acemoglu, D. and Pischke, J.-S. (2001). Changes in the wage structure, family income and childrens

education. European Economic Review, 45:890904.

Allison, P. D. (2001). Missing Data. Quantitativa Applications in the Social Sciences, Sage Publica-

tions.

Altonji, J. and Dunn, T. (2000). An intergenerational model of wages, hours, and earnings. Journal of

Human Resources, 35:221–258.

Anger, S. and Heineck, G. (2010). Do smart parents raise smart children? the intergeneretional trans-

mission of cognitive abilities. Journal of Population Economics, 23:1255–1282.

Atkinson, A., Maynard, A., and Trinder, C. (1983). Parents and Children: Incomes in Two Generations.

London: Heinemann.

Atkinson, T. and Marlier, E., editors (2015). Income, work and deprivation in Europe. Eurostat Statis-

tical.

Becker, G. S. and Tomes, N. (1986). Human capital and the rise and fall of families. Journal of Labor

Economics, 4:S1–S39.

16

Page 17: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

Behrman, J. and Taubman, P. (1985). Intergenerational earnings mobility in the united states: Some

estimates and a test of beckers intergenerational endowment model. Review of Economics and Statis-

tics, 67:144–151.

Bellani, L. and Bia, M. (2015). The impact of growing up poor in europe. In Atkinson, T. and Marlier,

E., editors, Income, work and deprivation in Europe. Eurostat Statistical.

Bjorklund, A., Eriksson, K. H., and Jantti, M. (2010). Iq and family background: Are associations

strong or weak? The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 10.

Bjorklund, A. and Jantti, M. (1997). Intergenerational income mobility in sweden compared to the

united states. American Economic Review, 87:1009–1018.

Blanden, J., Gregg, P., and Macmillan, L. (2007). Accounting for intergenerational income persistence:

Noncognitive skills, ability and education. The Economic Journal, 117:C43C60.

Chadwick, L. and Solon, G. (2002). Intergenerational income mobility among daughters. American

Economic Review, 92:335–344.

Ermisch, J., Francesconi, M., and Pevalin, D. J. (2004). Parental partnership and joblessness in child-

hood and their influence on young peoples outcomes. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society,

167:69101.

Fitzenberger, B., Osikominu, A., and Volter, R. (2008). Get training or wait? long-run employment

effects of training programs for the unemployed in west germany. Annales d’Economie et de Statis-

tique, (91/92):pp. 321–355.

Gill, R. D. and Robins, J. M. (2001). Causal inference for complex longitudinal data: The continuous

case. Ann. Statist., 29(6):1785–1811.

Grawe, N. (2004). Generational Income Mobility in North America and Europe,, chapter Intergenera-

tional mobility for whom? The experience of high and low-earning sons in international perspective.

Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Ho, D., Imai, K., King, G., and Stuart, E. (2007). Matching as nonparametric preprocessing for reducing

model dependence in parametric causal inference. Political Analysis, 15.

Ichino, A., Mealli, F., and Nannicini, T. (2008). From temporary help jobs to permanent employment:

what can we learn from matching estimators and their sensitivity? Journal of Applied Econometrics,

23(3):305–327.

17

Page 18: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

Imbens, G. (2004). Non parametric estimation of average treatment effects under exogeneity: a review.

Review of Economics and Statisitcs, 86:4–29.

Joffe, M., Small, D., and Hsu, C.-Y. (2007). Defining and estimating intervention effects for groups

that will develop an auxiliary outcome. Statistical Science, 22:74–97.

Lechner, M. and Miquel, R. (2010). Identification of the effects of dynamic treatments by sequential

conditional independence assumptions. Empirical Economics, 39(1):111–137.

Lefranc, A. and Trannoy, A. (2005). Intergenerational earnings mobility in france: is france more

mobile than the us? Annales d’Economie et de Statistique, 78:57–78.

Leigh, A. (2007). Intergenerational mobility in australia. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis &

Policy, 7.

Leuven, E. and Sianesi, B. (2003). Psmatch2: Stata module to perform full mahalanobis and propensity

score matching, common support graphing, and covariate imbalance testing. Statistical Software

Components, Boston College Department of Economics.

Lok, J. J. (2008). Statistical modeling of causal effects in continuous time. Ann. Statist., 36(3):1464–

1507.

Mayer, S. E. (1997). What Money Cant Buy. Family Income and Childrens Life Chances. Harvard

University Press, Cambridge MA.

Nannicini, T. (2007). Simulation-based sensitivity analysis for matching estimators. The Stata Journal,

7(3):334–350.

OECD (2010). Economic policy reforms-going for growth. Technical Report chapter 5.

Rosenbaum, P. R. and Rubin, D. B. (1983). The central role of the propensity score in observational

studies for causal effects. Biometrika, 70:41–55.

Rubin, D. (1974). Estimating causal effects of treatments in randomized and nonrandomized studies.

Journal of Education Psychology, 66.

Rubin, D. (1978). Estimating causal effects of treatments in randomized and nonrandomized studies.

Annals of Statistics, 6.

Shea, J. (2000). Does parents money matter? Journal of Public Economics, 77:155–184.

18

Page 19: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

A Descriptive statistics

Table 8: Descriptive Statistics

mean sd min maxquarter of birth 2.45 1.11 1 4year of birth 1965.6 5.95 1956 1976sex 1.52 0.50 1 2n. of adult in hh 2.49 1.21 0 67n. of children in hh 2.39 1.45 0 41n. of person in work 1.84 1.11 0 30year of birth of father 1935.4 9.35 1880 1981year of birth of mother 1938.5 8.86 1841 1988Poor as child 0.13 0.34 0 1Income 4.08 0.42 -0.87 5.14Poor as adult 0.14 0.35 0 1country==AT 0.025 0.16 0 1country==BE 0.023 0.15 0 1country==BG 0.027 0.16 0 1country==CH 0.030 0.17 0 1country==CY 0.018 0.13 0 1country==CZ 0.031 0.17 0 1country==DE 0.049 0.22 0 1country==DK 0.024 0.15 0 1country==EE 0.021 0.14 0 1country==EL 0.024 0.15 0 1country==ES 0.061 0.24 0 1country==FI 0.037 0.19 0 1country==FR 0.043 0.20 0 1country==HR 0.026 0.16 0 1country==HU 0.049 0.22 0 1country==IE 0.017 0.13 0 1country==IS 0.015 0.12 0 1country==IT 0.085 0.28 0 1country==LT 0.021 0.14 0 1country==LU 0.026 0.16 0 1country==LV 0.025 0.16 0 1country==MT 0.017 0.13 0 1country==NL 0.045 0.21 0 1country==NO 0.020 0.14 0 1country==PL 0.057 0.23 0 1country==PT 0.023 0.15 0 1country==RO 0.030 0.17 0 1country==SE 0.026 0.16 0 1country==SI 0.050 0.22 0 1country==SK 0.026 0.16 0 1country==UK 0.029 0.17 0 1country of birth==EU 0.037 0.19 0 1country of birth==LOC 0.90 0.30 0 1country of birth==OTH 0.064 0.24 0 1family composition==Lived with both parents 0.75 0.43 0 1family composition==Lived with single father (single parent family) 0.015 0.12 0 1family composition==Lived with single mother (single parent family) 0.075 0.26 0 1family composition==Lived in another private household, foster -home 0.011 0.10 0 1Observations 179060

19

Page 20: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

Table 9: Descriptive Statistics(cnt.)

mean sd min maxfather country of birth==country of residence 0.72 0.45 0 1father country of birth==another EU-27 0.059 0.24 0 1father country of birth==Another European 0.017 0.13 0 1father country of birth==outside Europe 0.025 0.16 0 1father citizenship==country of residence 0.72 0.45 0 1father citizenship==another EU-27 0.045 0.21 0 1father citizenship==Another European 0.015 0.12 0 1father citizenship==outside Europe 0.021 0.14 0 1mother country of birth==country of residence 0.74 0.44 0 1mother country of birth==another EU-27 0.062 0.24 0 1mother country of birth==Another European 0.017 0.13 0 1mother country of birth==outside Europe 0.025 0.16 0 1mother citizenship==country of residence 0.74 0.44 0 1mother citizenship==another EU-27 0.046 0.21 0 1mother citizenship==Another European 0.015 0.12 0 1mother citizenship==outside Europe 0.021 0.14 0 1Education father==Less than primary education 0.024 0.15 0 1Education father==Primary education 0.46 0.50 0 1Education father==Lower secondary education 0.21 0.41 0 1Education father==Upper secondary education 0.083 0.28 0 1Education mother==Less than primary education 0.035 0.18 0 1Education mother==Primary education 0.52 0.50 0 1Education mother==Lower secondary education 0.20 0.40 0 1Education mother==Upper secondary education 0.052 0.22 0 1Main activity of father==Employee 0.61 0.49 0 1Main activity of father==Self-employed 0.15 0.36 0 1Main activity of father==Unemployed 0.0049 0.070 0 1Main activity of father==Retired 0.0081 0.090 0 1Main activity of mother==Employee 0.39 0.49 0 1Main activity of mother==Self-employed 0.085 0.28 0 1Main activity of mother==Unemployed 0.0046 0.067 0 1Main activity of mother==Retired 0.0037 0.060 0 1Tenancy status== Owner 0.70 0.46 0 1Tenancy status==Tenant 0.24 0.43 0 1Main occupation father==Armed forces 0.0085 0.092 0 1Main occupation father==Managers 0.042 0.20 0 1Main occupation father==Professionals 0.054 0.23 0 1Main occupation father==Technicians and associate professionals 0.065 0.25 0 1Main occupation father==Clerks 0.033 0.18 0 1Main occupation father==Service and sales workers 0.047 0.21 0 1Main occupation father==Skilled agricultural, forestry and fishery workers 0.099 0.30 0 1Main occupation father==Craft and related trades workers 0.18 0.39 0 1Main occupation father==Plant and machine operators 0.11 0.31 0 1Main occupation father==Elementary occupations 0.085 0.28 0 1Main occupation mother==Armed forces 0.00052 0.023 0 1Main occupation mother==Managers 0.012 0.11 0 1Main occupation mother==Professionals 0.045 0.21 0 1Main occupation mother==Technicians and associate professionals 0.038 0.19 0 1Main occupation mother==Clerks 0.053 0.22 0 1Main occupation mother==Service and sales workers 0.078 0.27 0 1Main occupation mother==Skilled agricultural, forestry and fishery workers 0.069 0.25 0 1Main occupation mother==Craft and related trades workers 0.040 0.20 0 1Main occupation mother==Plant and machine operators 0.028 0.16 0 1Main occupation mother==Elementary occupations 0.092 0.29 0 1Financial situation==don’t know 0.015 0.12 0 1Financial situation==very bad 0.040 0.20 0 1Financial situation==bad 0.089 0.28 0 1Financial situation==Moderately bad 0.17 0.38 0 1Financial situation==moderatley good 0.39 0.49 0 1Financial situation==good 0.25 0.43 0 1Tertiary Education 0.31 0.46 0 1health 0.93 0.25 0 1Observations 179060

20

Page 21: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

Table 10: T-test on the pre-treatment variables means by treatment status

quarter of birth 0.0198∗

(2.13)

year of birth 1.233∗∗∗

(27.00)

sex 0.000970(0.25)

n. of adult in hh -0.146∗∗∗

(-15.74)

n. of children in hh -0.700∗∗∗

(-63.59)

n. of person in work 0.0963∗∗∗

(11.28)

year of birth of father 2.021∗∗∗

(25.80)

year of birth of mother 1.880∗∗∗

(26.51)

country -0.396∗∗∗

(-6.09)

country of birth -0.0260∗∗∗

(-10.75)

family composition -0.314∗∗∗

(-62.79)

Highest ISCED level of education attained by father 0.556∗∗∗

(69.14)

Highest ISCED level of education attained by mother 0.393∗∗∗

(60.93)

Main activity status of father 0.0702∗∗∗

(9.07)

Main activity status of mother -0.415∗∗∗

(-26.84)

countrty of birth of father 0.0411∗∗∗

(6.36)

citizenship of father 0.0730∗∗∗

(11.06)

country of birth of mother -0.0714∗∗∗

(-13.38)

citizenship of mother -0.0451∗∗∗

(-8.09)

Tenancy status -0.150∗∗∗

(-31.82)

Main occupation father 0.263∗∗∗

(10.16)

Main occupation of mother 0.191∗∗∗

(6.64)

Financial situation 2.416∗∗∗

(316.84)t statistics in parentheses∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < 0.01, ∗∗∗ p < 0.001

21

Page 22: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

Table 11: T-test on the post-treatment variables means by treatment status

Income 0.101∗∗∗

(31.24)

Poor as adult -0.0956∗∗∗

(-35.00)

Tertiary Education 0.166∗∗∗

(46.87)t statistics in parentheses∗ p < 0.05, ∗∗ p < 0.01, ∗∗∗ p < 0.001

22

Page 23: Robust measures of intergenerational poverty …The impact of poverty during childhood on individuals economic outcomes later in life is a topic of active research and a major policy

B Cumulative density at the bottom of the distribution.

(a) Without Matching (b) Matched

Figure 5: Cumulative density-2011

23