Regional Economist - October 2009

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    1/24

    Its Big, but Its Not Great

    The

    Man-Cessionof 2008-09

    The Regional

    Economist

    A Quarterly Reviewof Business andEconomic Conditions

    Vol. 17, No. 4

    October 2009

    The Federal reserve Bank oF sT. louis

    C e n T r a l t o a m e r i C a s e C n m yTm

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    2/24

    3 P r n t M g

    10 More Freedom,

    Less Terrorism

    By Craig P. Aubuchon, Subhayu

    Bandyopadhyay and Javed Younas

    Te root causes o terrorism might

    not be poverty and lack o educa-

    tion, as many believe. Rather, the

    lack o civil liberties, political rights

    and the rule o law might be more

    infuential.

    12 Cap and Trade:

    Economics and Politics

    By Cletus C. Coughlin

    and Lesli S. Ott

    Te anti-pollution program in

    Congress contains desirable

    economic eatures. But a key

    componentan auction process

    covering all permits or carbon

    emissionsdoes not seem to be

    politically viable.

    c o n t n t

    The Man-Cession of 2008-2009By Howard J. Wall

    Tat men are losing jobs at a much aster rate than women duringthis recession isnt a surprise. Te pattern is typical. And its not

    just the men in the hard hats who are out o a jobmen in almost

    all categories o work are being aected disproportionately.

    4

    The Regional Economistis published

    quaely by he reseah ad Publi

    ais depames he Fedeal

    reseve Bak . Luis. addesses

    he aial, ieaial ad eial

    emi issues he day, paiulaly

    as hey apply saes i he ihh

    Fedeal reseve isi. Views

    expessed ae eessaily hse he . Luis Fed he Fedeal

    reseve ysem.

    Please die yu mmes

    ubhayu Badypadhyay a 314-

    444-7425 by e-mail a subhayu.

    [email protected].. Yu a

    als wie him a he addess belw.

    ubmissi a lee he edi

    ives us he ih ps i u web

    sie ad/ publish i i The Regional

    Economistuless he wie saes

    hewise. We eseve he ih edi

    lees laiy ad leh.

    Director of Research

    chisphe J. Walle

    Senior Policy Adviser

    rbe H. rashe

    Deputy Director of Research

    cleus c. cuhliDirector of Public Affairs

    rbe J. hek

    Editor

    ubhayu Badypadhyay

    Managing Editor

    l ambski

    Art Director

    Ji Williams

    ile-py subsipis ae ee.

    t subsibe, e-mail al.a.musse

    @sls.b. si up via www.

    sluised./publiais. Yu a

    als wie The Regional Economist,

    Publi ais ofe, Fedeal reseve

    Bak . Luis, Bx 442, . Luis,

    Mo 63166.

    The Eighth Federal Reserve Districtiludes all kasas, ease

    Missui, suhe lliis ad diaa,

    wese Keuky ad teessee, ad

    he Mississippi. the ihh isi

    fes ae i Lile rk, Luisville,

    Memphis ad . Luis.

    The Regional

    EconomistOCTOE 2009 | VoL. 17, no. 4

    14 Hosings Great Fall:

    Avoiding a epeat

    By William Emmons

    Te simplest way to avoid another

    devastating housing crash and

    oreclosure crisis probably is to

    reduce household borrowing and,

    then, to keep it low.

    16 c o M M n t Y P r o F L

    Alton, Ill.

    By Susan C. omson

    Tis city on the Mississippi River

    north o St. Louis has accepted

    that its industrial heyday is over.

    Civic leaders hope that their

    ambitious eorts to redevelop

    the riverront will bring back

    some o the glory.

    19 t r c t o V r V W

    Tax Collections Decline

    By omas A. Garrett

    In general, the recession is tak-

    ing its toll on the collection o

    sales tax, personal income tax

    and corporate income tax in

    the seven states o the Eighth

    Federal Reserve District.

    21 B o o K r V W

    In Fed We Trst

    By Kevin L. Kliesen

    A Fed economist reviews In Fe

    We Trust:Ben Bernankes War

    on the Great Panic, the new bo

    by David Wessel, a columnist

    e Wall Street Journal.

    22 cono MY t gL nc

    23 r r c H ng

    cv illustti by gg gvs/www.mucmpg.cm

    2 The Regional Economist | October 2009

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    3/24

    mortgage insurance premiums were not

    deductible until 2007. Te homeownership

    rate increased rom 63.8 percent in early 1994

    to 68 percent in 2002.

    Over the ollowing three years, the rate

    increased to 69.2 percent, in the heart o the

    housing boom. Over this period, subprime

    lending took o and additional mortgage

    products were introduced and became

    popular. Tese included zero down-paymentloans, interest-only adjustable-rate mortgages

    (ARMs) and payment-option ARMs. Te last

    loan type allowed borrowers fexible monthly

    repayment strategies, including ull amorti-

    zation o principal with either zero or even

    negative amortization.

    Te bottom soon ell out. Since the end o

    2006, nationwide home prices have allen by as

    much as 30 percent. Te homeownership rate

    has been steadily declining, too, since then.

    Trough the second quarter o 2009, it was

    down 1.5 percentage points, to 67.4 percent.Tis decline refects a rebalancing: Just as we

    saw the homeownership rate increase by a lit-

    tle over one percentage point as new mortgage

    products were introduced, we now see those

    buyers exiting the market as that equity disap-

    pears. Assuming they could just renance

    later, they ound themselves unable to make

    payments as prices tanked. Additionally,

    as Carlos recently discussed in the St. Louis

    Feds National Economic Trends publication,

    James llard, Peside ad co

    Fedeal reseve Bak . Luis

    he housing crisis has been central to ourcurrent recession. An economist at theFederal Reserve Bank o St. Louis, Carlos

    Garriga, has devoted much o his research to

    understanding the intricacies o mortgage

    markets and loan choices.

    What insight might his research bring to

    the current environment? o begin, he has

    examined the evolution o homeownership

    rates and their connection with mortgage

    market innovations. For about a quarter o

    a century, the homeownership rate hovered

    around 64 percent. In 1966, it was at 63.5

    percent. wenty-seven years later, in 1993, it

    had barely budged to 63.8 percent. However,

    over the past 15 years, a signicant change

    occurred, largely the result o government

    policy and innovations in mortgage markets.

    Politicians pushed to increase the home-

    ownership rate on the premise that home-

    owners are more likely to maintain their

    property than a renter would. And, o course,almost every version o the American dream

    includes a house with a white picket ence.

    In the early 1990s, the Federal Housing

    Administration (FHA) started to oer mort-

    gage products with low down payments. Prior

    to this, most mortgage lenders required a 20

    percent down payment on all new loans. Te

    rationale or the down payment was to ensure

    that the home had enough equity to ward o

    oreclosure i home prices were to all sub-

    stantially. o qualiy or a low down payment,

    homeowners had to buy lenders mortgageinsurance or private mortgage insurance.

    In the late 1990s, conventional lending

    became more sophisticated. o avoid mort-

    gage insurance, lenders oered a second loan

    (at a higher interest rate) or a portion o the

    remaining loan amount. Te advantage o

    the combo, or piggyback, loan was that bor-

    rowers could increase their leverage at a lower

    cost since mortgage interest payments could

    be deducted on their income tax, whereas

    Is the ate of Homeownership Nearing a ottom?

    P r n t M g

    renancing denials started to increase well

    beore the peak o the housing boom, suggest-

    ing that lenders were uncomortable with the

    values being assessed to homes.1

    Tese borrowers obtained nancing

    through risky tools. I all borrowers who

    could obtain nancing through standard

    nancing options (i.e., not zero down-

    payment loans, interest-only loans, etc.) had

    already entered the homeownership arena,they would have already been captured

    within the 2002 rate o 68 percent.

    Te homeownership rate is now down

    below the 2002 level; it has remained at

    roughly 67.5 percent or three quarters

    (Q4 2008 through Q2 2009). Although ur-

    ther data are needed, this suggests the decline

    might now have bottomed out, provided the

    economic environment doesnt pull down

    otherwise well-positioned homeowners.

    A natural question is to wonder whether

    the severity o the price decline will orceadditional homeowners out. During the 27

    years that the homeownership rate hovered

    around 64 percent, there were many price

    fuctuations and yet no change in the owner-

    ship rate. Te dierence is that virtually no

    homebuyer was highly leveraged; almost all

    buyers had already paid at least 20 percent

    o the purchase price o their home. Hence,

    even as prices ell, homeowners were able to

    ride out the storm.

    Examining homeownership rates is one

    small but interesting piece o the puzzle.Government policy helped buoy the home-

    ownership rate to historic highs, and risky

    lending practices pushed it even higher.

    ime will tell where the new equilibrium

    rate will settle, but signs point to a near end

    in the decline.

    aual quesi is

    wde whehe he seveiy

    he pie delie will e

    addiial hmewes u.

    1 Garriga, Carlos. Lending Standards in Mortgage Mar-

    kets. National Economic Trends, May 2009, p. 1. See

    http://research.stlouised.org/publications/net/20090501

    /cover.pd.

    The Regional Economist | www.stloisfed.org 3

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    4/24

    r c o n

    4 The Regional Economist | October 2009

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    5/24

    By Howard J. Wall

    The

    of 2008-09Its Big, but Its Not Great

    Between the ourth quarter o 2007, when thecurrent recession began, and the rst quarter o2009, men bore 78 percent o the job losses. Overthe same period, the unemployment rate or menrose rom 4.9 percent to 8.9 percent, while the rateor women rose by only hal as much, rom 4.7 per-cent to 7.2 percent. As reported by economist MarkPerry o the University o Michigan-Flint in his blog

    Carpe Diem, this gap in unemployment rates hasno precedent during the post-war period. In lighto the disproportionate employment eects o therecession on men, some commentators in the pressand elsewhere have labeled the current recessiona man-cession or even the Great Man-Cession.

    The Regional Economist | www.stloisfed.org 5

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    6/24

    Te dominant explanation or this

    phenomenon is that it ollows rom the

    severity o the recession across industries.

    According to Christina Ho Sommers o

    the American Enterprise Institute, Men are

    bearing the brunt o the current economic

    crisis because they predominate in manu-

    acturing and construction, the hardest-hit

    sectors. Women, on the other hand, are

    a majority in recession-resistant elds such

    as education and health care. Harvard

    economist Greg Mankiw echoes this in

    his blog, conjecturing that a large part o

    the explanation is the sectoral mix o this

    particular downturn in economic activity,

    including a signicant slump in residential

    construction.

    The Great Man-Cession

    or Just a Normal One?

    Despite the sudden interest in the phe-nomenon, the relative eects o the reces-

    sion on men and women are not the least bit

    unusual. At least since the 1969 recession,

    men have borne the brunt o job losses dur-

    ing recessions, and, compared with previ-

    ous recessions, men have actually borne a

    smallerproportion o job losses in the cur-

    rent recession. Between 1969 and 1991, male

    employment ell by an average o 3.1 percent

    during the ve recessions experienced dur-

    ing the period. Female employment, on the

    other hand, actually tended to rise by anaverage o 0.3 percent during recessions.1

    Women have a much larger presence in the

    work orce now than between 1969 and 1991;

    so, a more-relevant comparison is to the

    2001 recession. For that recession, employ-

    ment peaked in the rst quarter o 2001 and

    bottomed out in the third quarter o 2003,

    with a total loss o a little more than 2.6 mil-

    lion jobs. Men accounted or 78 percent o

    those job losses, just as they have during the

    current recession. So, in terms o job losses,

    the current recession has hit men in roughlythe same proportion as did the previous

    recession, but by a much smaller proportion

    than during earlier recessions.

    Still, according to unemployment rates,

    the gap between men and women is higher

    than it has ever been. It is a bit o a mystery

    as to why the gap in unemployment rates

    shows much more o a man-cession than is

    indicated by jobs numbers, but unemploy-

    ment rates indicate much more than simply

    changes in employment status. Te rates

    refect not only the net number o people

    who lose their jobs, but also the net num-

    ber o people who are in the labor orce

    either already employed or looking or a

    job. During this recession, the male labor

    orce has been shrinking as the number

    o unemployed men has been rising. Te

    emale labor orce, in contrast, is actually

    larger than it was when the recession began,

    accounting or much o the increase in the

    gap between the male and emale unemploy-

    ment rates.

    In sum, the proper perspective on the

    current recession is that its eect on the

    employment o men relative to women

    is very similar to the eects o the 2001

    recession and much milder compared with

    earlier downturns. Although this perspec-

    tive debunks the notion o this recession

    being an especially bad one or men relativeto women, the act remains that recessions

    hit male employment much harder than

    emale employment. otal employment

    has allen by 3.1 percent between the ourth

    quarter o 2007 and the rst quarter o 2009

    while male and emale employment ell by

    4.8 percent and 1.4 percent, respectively.

    Put another way, men lost jobs at 3.4 t imes

    the rate at which women did. Despite what

    has been presumed, however, or the current

    recession, this is not necessarily due to the

    dierent mixes o industries in which menand women tend to be employed.

    The Role of Industry Mix

    Its easy to see the reasons or supposing

    that the disproportionate job losses or

    men are due to the disparate impacts o the

    recession on the goods-producing sector, in

    which 77 percent o employees in the ourth

    quarter o 2007 were men. Te two hardest-

    hit industries have been construction and

    manuacturing, which lost 12.7 percent

    and 9 percent o their jobs, respectively,between the ourth quarter o 2007 and the

    rst quarter o 2009. Tese two industries

    also happened to have had two o the three

    highest shares o male employment. At the

    other end o the spectrum, two o the three

    industries that saw positive job growth over

    the periodthe government sector as well

    as the education and health services sec-

    torare among the three with the lowest

    shares o male employees. As illustrated by

    Th 2009 csson has hit the construction

    industry especially hard. By August, employment in

    the construction industry had fallen by 19 percent

    during the recession. In the picture above, workers

    pave a portion of Route 101 in Exeter, N.H.

    /uts/cbis

    6 The Regional Economist | October 2009

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    7/24

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    8/24

    disproportionately on women. Whereas

    men comprised 58 percent o initial employ-

    ment in the inormation service industry,

    they accounted or only 49 percent o thejob losses. Tis industry is relatively small,

    however, making up only about 2 percent o

    total employment. In the nancial services

    industry, the job losses ell almost propor-

    tionally, with women seeing 61 percent o

    the job losses while starting the recession

    with 59 percent o the jobs.

    The Demographics of the Man-Cession

    Because men tended to have been aected

    disproportionately across all industries,

    whether goods-producing or service-pro-ducing, the story behind the man-cession

    cannot be about industry mix alone.

    Clearly, then, the man-cession phenomenon

    is not a story about the goods-producing

    industries but refects something much

    broader about the economy and how rms

    respond to downturns by deciding which

    workers they will let go and which they will

    hire. As we have seen, employment losses

    are not elt the same by men and women

    within the same industry, and, in act, reces-

    sions have widely varying eects acrossdemographic groups. Perhaps the male/

    emale dierences within these categories

    can shed some light on the man-cession

    phenomenon.

    Up to this point, all o the data have come

    rom payroll employment series produced

    by the Bureau o Labor Statistics (BLS) and

    which are derived rom a monthly survey o

    150,000 or so employers around the country.

    Tese data, however, are not broken down

    4

    2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    12

    14

    16

    %C

    HANGEINEMPLOYMENT,

    Q4.2

    007TOQ1.2

    009

    SOURCE: Bureau of Labor Statistics

    NOTE: The number above or below the bars is the ratio of the change in men's employment to the change in women's employment.

    Men Women

    Married Single White Black Other Ages

    16-19

    Ages

    20-24

    Ages

    25-34

    Ages

    35-44

    Ages

    45-54

    Ages

    55+

    8.9 2.4 3.5 4.5 2.7 1.1 5.5 4.1 1.6 24.1

    0.9

    The Man-Cession Across Demographic Grops

    fiure 2 by demographic categories other than sex;

    so, a dierent data source is needed. Fortu-

    nately, the bureau also surveys households

    on a monthly basis and categorizes the

    responses by demographic categories. Te

    employment measures rom the payroll and

    household surveys are not the same in that

    they cover dierent types o employment.

    For example, payroll employment does not

    include arm employment or sel-employ-

    ment. Although the two employment

    measures do not coincide perectly, they do

    capture the same broad patterns in male/

    emale employment. In act, by ortunate

    coincidence, the household survey indicates

    the same 78/22 split in the male/emale

    employment losses that arise rom the

    payroll employment data and each o its two

    major components, the goods-producing

    and service-producing sectors.

    Figure 2 illustrates the dierences acrossdemographic groups and between men

    and women within each group. For every

    demographic group except or those aged 55

    and above, ewer were employed in the rst

    quarter o 2009 than in the ourth quarter

    o 2007, and men ared worse than women

    within every group. Tere were, however,

    signicant dierences in the impact o the

    recession across the groups and on men

    relative to women. Note that the demo-

    graphic groups overlap a great deal; so, the

    explanations or the dierences across themalso oen overlap. Further, across groups,

    employment changes over the period refect

    not only the eects o the recession but also

    ongoing trends in the tendency to partici-

    pate in the labor market.2

    Married men and women saw smaller job

    losses than did their single counterparts.

    Moreover, the eect o the recession on the

    employment o married men was almost

    nine times that on married women, whereas

    the eect or single men was 2.4 times

    that or single women. In part, the actthat married women are the least likely

    subgroup to see employment losses can

    be explained by what has been called the

    added-worker eect. 3

    According to this eect, some married

    women enter the labor orce during reces-

    sions ollowing their husbands job losses.

    Te added-worker eect can account or

    some o the increase in the emale labor

    orce during the recession.

    the evidee ha sme-

    hi else is i is ha

    me have bee hi disp-

    piaely i alms evey

    idusy; ha is, wihi aidusy, me have eded

    lse jbs a a hihe ae

    ha have wme.

    8 The Regional Economist | October 2009

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    9/24

    E N D N O T E S

    1 See Goodman, Antczak and Freeman.

    2 A recent paper by DiCecio et al. reviews the

    trends in labor orce participation, separating

    out the changes due to trends rom the changes

    due to economic conditions.3 See, or example, Stephens. DeRiviere has

    estimated the size o a related eect called the

    pin-money hypothesis .

    R E F E R E N C E S

    DeRiviere, Linda. Have We Come a Long Way?

    Using the Survey o Labour and Income

    Dynamics to Revisit the Pin Money Teory.

    Journal of Socio-Economics,Vol. 37, No. 6,

    December 2008, pp. 2340-67.

    DiCecio, Riccardo; Engemann, Kristie M.;

    Owyang, Michael .; and Wheeler, Christo-

    pher H. Changi ng rends in the Labor Force

    A Survey. Federal Reserve Bank o St. Louis

    Review, Vol. 90, No. 1, January/February 2008

    pp. 47-62.

    Goodman, William; Antczak, Stephen; and Free-

    man, Laura. Women and Jobs in Recessions:

    1969-92. Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 116,

    No. 7, July 1993, pp. 26-35.

    Ho Sommers, Christ ina. No Country or Burl

    Men. e Weekly Standard, Vol. 14, Issue 39,

    June 29-July 6, 2009, pp. 22-24.

    Stephens Jr., Melvin. Worker Displacement

    and the Added Worker Eect. Journal of

    Labor Economics, Vol. 20, No. 3, July 2002,

    pp. 504-37.

    Another explanation or the dierence

    between married and single people is that

    married people are more likely to have

    children and are, thereore, more likely to

    take a new job at lower pay aer they lose

    their old job. Also, much o the dierences

    according to marital status are refections

    o other demographic dierences that

    make them more likely to be aected by a

    recession: Compared with married people,

    single people tend to be younger and,

    thereore, have less work experience and

    lower education levels.

    Te dierences across racial categories are

    intertwined with dierences in other cat-

    egories. Black men, who have less education

    on average than black women or whites, saw

    the largest decrease in employment. Black

    women, on the other hand, have seen the

    smallest reduction in employment o any o

    the six sex-race categories. Underlying thesedierences is the long-term trend o women,

    especially black women, becoming more

    likely to be employed.

    Figure 2 also illustrates the changes in

    employment across age groups, or which

    there are signicant dierences across

    groups and between sexes within each

    group. eenagers, or example, have seen

    the biggest decrease in employment during

    the recession, but there was little dierence

    between the percentage decreases or male

    and emale teenagers. In contrast, or thenext lowest age group, those aged 20 to 24

    years, men saw about a 9 percent decrease

    in employment, which was 5.5 times the

    decrease or women. Very large dierences

    between men and women were also seen

    or ages 25-34 and 45-54. Partly refecting

    the ongoing trend o increasing employ-

    ment, the number o employed people aged

    55 and above rose by more than 3 percent

    during the period. Tis increase might also

    be due to the eects o delayed retirements

    in the wake o dramatic decreases in sav-ings and investments or retirement.

    Te nal demographic category is edu-

    cational attainment, or which there were

    dramatic dierences in male and emale

    employment changes during the recession.

    For every category, men ared worse than

    women (Figure 3). Much o these dier-

    ences refect the industry-mix eects: Men

    without a high school diploma, or example,

    would make up a signicant proportion o

    2

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    12

    14

    Men Women

    %C

    HANGEINEMPLOY

    MENTQ4.2

    007TOQ1.2

    009

    No HighSchool

    Diploma

    High SchoolDiploma

    SomeCollege

    AssociateDegree

    BachelorsDegree or

    Higher

    The Man-Cession y Edcation Level

    fiure 3

    men in the construction and manuactur-

    ing industries, whereas women with associ-

    ate and bachelors degrees would make up

    a large portion o the education and healthindustries. Nevertheless, given the dier-

    ences in education levels between the sexes

    within other demographic categories, such as

    race and age, education level is probably an

    important part o the man-cession story.

    So, Whats It All About?

    Te rst thing to take away rom this

    blizzard o data is that the so-called Great

    Man-cession o 2008-09 is nothing unusual

    when compared with the previous reces-

    sion. Even so, a greater than three-to-oneemployment impact on men relative to

    women is still large relative to the nearly

    equal representation o the sexes in the work

    orce. Tis certainly has something to do

    with the dierences in the industries or

    which men and women are in the majority,

    as there is a strong tendency or industries

    with large shares o men to have been hit

    hardest by the downturn. Tese dierences,

    however, are only part o the story, which

    must be completed by examining the some-

    times large dierences in the educationaland demographic characteristics o men

    and women. Te dierences in employment

    changes between men and women within

    these groups are usually larger than those

    across industries.

    Howard J. Wall is an economist at the FederalReserve Bank of St. Louis. For more on his work,see http://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/wall.

    Read more about economist

    Howard Walls research into

    recent U.S. recessions. Hisreport, e Eects of Reces-

    sions across Demographic

    Groups, looks at employ-

    ment o U.S. workers or this

    recession and others going

    back to 1972. Wall presents a

    range o demographic cat-

    egoriessex, marital status,

    race, age and education. o

    read the report, go to www.

    stlouised.org/publications/

    RecessionDemographics/.

    Report Goes In-Depth

    On Recessions

    The Regional Economist | www.stloisfed.org 9

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    10/24

    Each year, the U.S. State Departmentpublishes Country Reports on Terror-ism, which highlights current strategies,

    outcomes and casualties rom U.S. counter-

    terrorism eorts. Te 2008 report high-

    lights the growing trend in terrorist attacks

    abroad, including the September attackagainst the U.S. Embassy in Yemen that

    kil led 18 people. Te continued incidence

    o terrorism prompts us to consider its root

    causes. It is popular to single out poverty or

    lack o education as major actors.1 Recent

    economic literature, however, points more

    toward civil liberties, political rights and the

    rule o law as ar greater actors.

    Measring Terrorism:

    What Conts and How Mch?

    Measuring the incidence and type o ter-rorism is controversial. First, it is important

    to distinguish between domestic and trans-

    national terrorism. Te latter is generally

    considered any event that involves citizens

    or territories o more than one country,

    while the ormer is a local act carried out by

    citizens o the target country. (Te attack

    in New York City on 9/11 is a prominent

    example o transnational terrorism, where

    oreign citizens carried out the attack. Te

    bombing by imothy McVeigh in Okla-

    homa City in April 1995 is an example odomestic terrorism.) It is also important to

    consider whether the number o incidents

    or the magnitude o events is more impor-

    tant. Tis is brought out very clearly in the

    accompanying graphs reproduced rom the

    work o economists Graham Bird, S. Brock

    Blomberg and Gregory Hess.2 While Figure 1

    shows a drop-o in the number o terrorist

    incidents, Figure 2 shows a rise in the num-

    ber o deaths per incident over time. Tis

    demonstrates that terrorists are using more

    lethal methods and weapons.

    Poverty and Terrorism

    A study by economists Alan Krueger

    and Jitka Maleckova considers the infu-

    ence o poverty and education on terrorism.Surprisingly, they nd no evidence that

    reducing poverty or improving education

    would meaningully reduce international

    terrorism.3 Te authors reached their

    conclusion based on evidence rom three

    sources: Hezbollah militant activities in the

    Gaza/West Bank region rom 1998 to 2000,

    individual proles rom members o Israeli

    Jewish extremists in the late 1970s and rom

    a cross-country analysis using data rom the

    U.S. State Department. Interestingly, the

    authors ound that within the context o theWest Bank/Palestinian confict, individu-

    als who engaged in terrorism were better

    educated and economically more auent

    than the average citizen. Tis apparently

    paradoxical result may be better understood

    when one realizes that individuals incomes

    may correlate with their abilities. o suc-

    ceed in terrorist attacks in a heavily guarded

    environment (like Israel), one needs a

    relatively high degree o skill and ability.

    Tereore, it is natural or leaders o the ter-

    rorist groups to choose more-able volunteersso that a planned attack is more likely to be

    successul.

    Another study, by Krueger and economist

    David Laitin, analyzes the characteristics

    o nations rom which terrorism originates

    and o target nations.4 Tey considered

    incidents o terrorism where the target and

    source nations o terrorism were distinct.

    Tey ound that source nations o terror-

    ism were more likely to suer rom a lack

    o civil liberties and that economic condi-

    tions (as captured by GDP per capita) in

    these nations had no statistically signicant

    relationship with terrorism.5 On the other

    hand, they nd that nations with high GDP

    per capita were more likely to be targets o

    terrorism. A 2006 paper by Harvard econo-mist Alberto Abadie also ound that the risk

    o terrorism was not signicantly higher or

    poorer nations once one accounted or other

    country-specic characteristics such as the

    level o political reedom.6

    Te study by Bird and his co-authors

    comes to a dierent conclusion. Tey ound

    that net exporters o terrorism were poorer

    nations, while terrorist targets (eectively,

    the importers o terrorism) were rich.

    Based on this observation, they suggest that

    economic actors, among others, do have arole in explaining both the origin and the

    location o terrorist acts.

    The ole of Political and Civil ights

    Te aorementioned study by Abadie

    ocuses on the role that political reedom

    plays in spurring terrorism.7 By studying

    dierent nations, he nds that the incidence

    o terrorism is highest in nations with

    intermediate levels o political reedom.

    Highly democratic and also highly auto-

    cratic regimes both tend to experienceless terrorism.

    A recent working paper by St. Louis

    Federal Reserve economist Subhayu Ban-

    dyopadhyay and co-author Javed Younas

    explores the link between terrorism and

    political and civil rights in developing

    nations, using a sample o 125 countries.

    Disaggregating the data between domestic

    and transnational terrorism, they ound that

    it was only domestic terrorism that was

    Increasing Political FreedomMay Be Key To Reducing Threats

    t r r o r M

    By Craig P. Aubuchon, Subhayu Bandyopadhyay and Javed Younas

    bi b

    10 The Regional Economist | October 2009

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    11/24

    E N DN O T E S

    1 For example, Chapter 5.7 o the 2008 Country

    Reportson Terrorism states the implicit

    assumption that poverty can lead to terrorism:

    High unemployment and underemployment

    oen a result o slow economic growth, are

    among the most critical issues in predomi-

    nantly Muslim countries.2 See Bird et al.3 See Krueger and Maleckova (2003).4

    See Krueger and Laitin (2007).5 Admittedly, many nations are both sources

    and targets o terrorism; the ocus o this

    study, however, was on transnational inci-

    dents where the sources and targets diered.6 See Abadie.7 A common measure o political and civil rights

    comes rom Freedom House, a nonprot, non-

    partisa n organization. Freedom House denes

    civil liberties as the protection o undamental

    individual rights against coercion and interer-

    ence by the state; political rights include the

    right to participate in the political process and

    having reedom o speech. On a scale o 1 to 7,

    Freedom House measures a countrys level

    o political and civil rights separately, with 1

    being ree and 7 being not ree, or a combined

    score o 14. For example, in 2005 the UnitedStates scored a 1 in both political and civil

    liberties; Sudan scored a 7 on both accounts.

    Examples o countries in-between include

    Argentina (2 and 2), Taila nd (3 and 3), and

    Aghanista n (5 and 5).8 Chapter 5 o the RAND MIP publication,

    More Freedom, Less error? Liberal ization

    and Political Violence in the Arab World

    presents a detailed look at the political climat

    and terrorist activity in Saudi Arabia rom

    1990 to the present.

    R E F E R E NC E S

    Abadie, Alberto. 2006. Poverty, Political Free-

    dom, and the Roots o errorism. American

    Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings,

    2006, Vol. 96, No. 2, pp. 5056.Bandyopadhyay, Subhayu; Younas, Javed. Does

    Democracy Reduce errorism in Developing

    Nations? Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

    Working Paper 2009-023A. Available at: http://

    research.stlouised.org/wp/2009/2009-023.pd.

    Bird, Graham; Blomberg, S. Brock; and Hess,

    Gregory D. Internat ional errorism: Causes

    Consequences and Cures. e World

    Economy, 2008, Vol. 31, No. 2, pp. 255-74.

    Kaye, Dalia Dassa; Wehrey, Frederic; Grant,

    Audra K; and Stahl, Dale. More Freedom, Les

    Terror? Liberalizat ion and Political Violence

    in the Arab World. RAND Corp.: Santa

    Monica, Cal. 2008. See www.rand.org/pubs/

    monographs/MG772/.

    Krueger, Alan B; Laitin, David D. Kto Kogo?:

    A Cross-Country Study o the Origins andargets o errorism. NBER Working Paper,

    2007. See www.krueger.princeton.edu/ter-

    rorism4.pd

    Krueger, Alan B; Maleckova, Jitka. Education,

    Poverty and errorism: Is Tere a Causal

    Connection? Journal of Economic Perspec-

    tive, 2003, Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 119-44.

    RAND-MIP errorism Incidents Database, 2007

    See www.rand.org/ise/projects/terrorism-

    database/.

    U.S. Department o State. Country Reports on

    Terrorism 2008. See www.state.gov/s/ct/rls/

    crt/2008/index.htm.

    related to the level o political and civil

    rights. Along the lines o Abadie, they

    ound that a transition rom autocracy todemocracy might be associated with an

    initial increase in terrorism.

    Tese studies suggest that nations may

    need to be patient on the path to democracy.

    Giving more political rights to citizens may

    not immediately reduce terrorism in that

    country. An interesting example was the

    2003 terrorist attacks against Saudi civilians

    by an Al Qaida aliate, which occurred

    against the backdrop o political reorm,

    including the announcement o municipal

    council elections in October 2003.8

    Conterterrorism Policy:

    A Comprehensive Approach

    Because o the highly emotional and

    traumatizing impact o terrorism, it is

    important to take a measured and thought-

    ul look at counterterrorism policy. While

    still in its early stages, research suggests that

    economic status or lack o education may

    not be the most important actors spurring

    terrorism. Te evidence suggests a closer

    relationship with the lack o political or civil

    liberties in origin nations, perhaps becauserustrations with existing regimes make

    people more readily rely on violence. Tese

    ndings suggest a multipronged approach

    to counterterrorism policy; military power

    as well as economic assistance may help the

    source nations o terrorism to achieve eec-

    tive reorm. All the studies suggest that, in

    the long run, political reorms that coner

    rule o law, civil liberties and political rights

    to developing nations will be the best way to

    reduce incidents o global terror.

    Subhayu Bandyopadhyay is an economist atthe Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Craig P.Aubuchon is a research associate at the Bank.Javed Younas is assistant professor of economicsat the American University of Sharjah, UnitedArab Emirates. For more on Bandyopadhyayswork, see http://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/bandyopadhyay.

    Transnational Terrorist Incidents, 1968-2003

    fiure 1

    1968 1973 19881978 1983 1993 1998 2003

    700

    600

    500

    400

    300

    200

    100

    0

    INCIDENTS

    PER

    YEAR

    YEAR

    1968 1973 19881978 1983 1993 1998 2003

    10

    9

    8

    7

    65

    4

    3

    2

    1

    0DEATHS

    PER

    INCIDEN

    T

    EACH

    YEAR

    YEAR

    Deaths Per Transnational Terrorist Incident, 1968-2003

    fiure 2

    suc: graha brd, s. bro boer and greor D. e

    The Regional Economist | www.stloisfed.org 11

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    12/24

    c L M t c H n g

    Increased concentrations o greenhousegases have heightened concern through-out the world about climate change and

    global warming. One maniestation o this

    concern in the United States is refected in

    a market-based approach termed cap and

    trade to regulate carbon dioxide emissions;this is contained in the proposed American

    Clean Energy and Security Act o 2009.1 Tis

    legislation requires a 17 percent reduction in

    emissions o carbon dioxide by 2020 rom

    2005 levels.2 While there are numerous con-

    troversial provisions in this legislation, this

    article ocuses on the economic principles

    underlying the cap-and-trade proposal.3

    Reducing Carbon Emissions Efciently

    Various regulatory approaches exist or

    controlling pollution. A common one iscommand and control. One example in the

    context o carbon emissions is the Corporate

    Average Fuel Eciency (CAFE) standards,

    which mandate minimum feet mileage stan-

    dards or motor vehicles sold in the United

    States. Generally speaking, economists tend

    to preer market-based approaches, such as a

    cap-and-trade program, to other regulatory

    approaches or reducing carbon emissions.

    Various economic reasons exist or preer-

    ring market-based approaches. First, all pol-

    luters ace the same marginal cost o reducingpollution, which is a necessary condition or

    reducing pollution in the most cost-eective

    way. For example, say that a polluter is either

    taxed $15 or each ton o carbon emissions or

    must have a permit that costs $15 per ton o

    carbon emissions. In either case, $15 is the

    price that the polluter must pay to emit one

    ton o additional carbon emissions. Ten,

    each rm must compare this $15 per ton with

    its own cost o reducing carbon emissions.

    As long as the rms incremental costs stay

    less than or equal to $15, then it will reduce

    its emissions; i not, assuming it is protable

    to do so, then the rm will pay the tax or buy

    the permit. (Note that part o a rms adjust-

    ment to the higher price to pollute might

    entail a cut in its production o goods.)Second, incentives are provided so that

    pollution is reduced relatively more by rms

    with relatively lower costs o doing so. In

    other words, i rms must pay $15 per ton

    o carbon emissions, then rms that can

    reduce pollution at relatively lower cost will

    undertake relatively more abatement than

    will higher-cost rms.

    Tird, market-based approaches provide

    incentives or innovative activity that can

    lower the cost o reducing pollution. Sim-

    ply put, rms can increase their prots bynding ways to lower the cost o reducing

    pollution.

    Under a cap-and-trade program, the

    quantity o carbon emissions is capped. Given

    an upper limit on the quantity o carbon

    emissions, market participants will determine

    the price o these emissions. Te supply and

    demand diagram in Figure 1 can be used

    to illustrate the basics o a cap-and-trade

    program. Te horizontal axis measures the

    quantity (Q) o carbon dioxide emissions

    abated, while the vertical axis measuresthe value (benets or costs) per unit (P) o

    carbon abated. Note that by capping emis-

    sions at some level, an abatement quantity

    is set as well. Te marginal benet (MB)

    curve is sloped negatively to refect that

    the additional benet to society o abating

    more carbon declines. Tis marginal benet

    curve refects the social benets o reducing

    pollution. From the perspective o a polluter,

    the (private) benet o abatement is zero.

    Meanwhile, the marginal cost (MC) curve

    is sloped positively to refect the assumption

    o increasing marginal abatement costs. In

    other words, as a rm attempts to abate more

    and more carbon emissions, incremental costs

    to the rm o additional abatement increase.

    Given the curves in Figure 1, the ideal

    quantity o abatement is indicated by Q*.

    Tis quantity o abatement will result in a

    price o carbon emissions o P* per unit. Tis

    ecient outcome refects the act that emis-

    sions abatement should continue until the

    point at which the marginal benets equal

    the marginal costs. Additional abatement

    beyond Q* is inecient because the margina

    costs exceed the marginal benets.

    In the preceding example, the marginalbenet and cost curves were assumed to be

    known with certainty. Tis is highly unlikely

    as it is very dicult to pin down either the

    benets or the costs o reducing carbon emis-

    sions. For example, the benets o reducing

    the atmospheric concentration o carbon

    dioxide rom 380 to 325 parts per million are

    not easily calculated. Not surprisingly, widely

    divergent views are held.4 A more realistic

    assumption is one o uncertainty, which allows

    By Cletus C. Coughlin and Lesli S. Ott

    Regulating Carbon Emissions:The Cap-and-Trade Program

    micl

    P*

    MC

    QQ*

    P

    O (emissions abated)

    MB

    Cap-and-Trade

    gr 1

    12 The Regional Economist | October 2009

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    13/24

    E N DN O T E S

    1

    Te largest active cap-and-trade program or

    greenhouse gases is the European Unions

    Emission rading Scheme. In the United

    States, the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiativ

    has implemented a cap-and-trade program o

    greenhouse gas emissions rom power plants.

    2

    Details on this legislation can be ound

    at: www.govtrack.us/congress/bill.

    xpd?bill=h111-2454.

    3 For a discussion o important design issues,

    see Metcal.4

    See Economist.5

    Tose well-versed in economics wil l recognize

    that the welare loss associated with the cap-

    and-trade program in the present example is

    represented by the triangle ABC.

    6

    Tis allocation is to last until 2030, at which

    time all per mits are to be auctioned.

    R E F E R E NC E S

    Economist. Cap and rade, with Handouts and

    Loopholes. May 23, 2009, pp. 33-34

    Metcal, Gilbert E. Market-based Policy

    Options to Control U.S. Greenhouse Gas

    Emissions. Journal of Economic Perspectives

    Spring 2009, Vol. 23, No. 2, pp. 5-27.

    or ones expectations to dier rom what

    actually occurs. Assume that the expected and

    realized marginal cost curves are identical,

    but that the realized marginal benet exceeds

    the expected marginal benet. In other

    words, the benets o reducing carbon emis-

    sions are higher than originally anticipated.

    In Figure 2, this is represented by a realized

    marginal benet (MBR) curve that lies above

    the expected marginal benet (MBE).

    Under a cap-and-trade program, regula-

    tors, basing their decision on expected costs

    and benets, would require abatement o QQ

    o carbon emissions. In Figure 2, the ideal

    level o abatement is Q*; so, the cap-and-trade

    program would result in too little abate-

    ment because QQ is less than Q*. O course,

    i the realized marginal benet curve was

    at a lower level than the expected marginalbenet curve, too much abatement would

    occur. Te key point in this illustration is

    that, because o uncertainty, the cap-and

    trade program is unlikely to produce an ideal

    outcome all the time.5 Excessive volatility

    in the price o pollution is also a possibility.

    When unintended, large adverse conse-

    quences result, specics o the cap-and-trade

    program will probably need to be modied.

    Unortunately, uncertainty comes into play

    with all regulatory approaches.

    Who Receives the Permits?

    Aer the amount o allowable carbon

    dioxide emissions is determined, decisions

    must be made as to who is allowed to emit

    and how much they are allowed to emit. One

    approach, which is avored by the Obama

    administration, is to have the government

    auction o permits that allow the holder to

    engage in actions that emit carbon. A xed

    number o permits would be auctioned that

    would be purchased by those who placed the

    highest value on them. Subsequently, as time

    passes and circumstances change, those with

    excess permits could sell them to those who

    desired more permits.

    Government sales o the permits would

    generate revenue, which could be returned to

    taxpayers or used or other projects, some o

    which might be directly related to energy and

    climate change issues. Currently, auctioning

    all the permits does not appear to be accept-

    able politically. A House-passed version o

    the American Clean Energy and Security Act

    o 2009 would allow 85 percent o the per-

    mits to be allocated administratively, while

    15 percent would be auctioned.6 Electricity

    distributors would receive the largest share,

    while the rest would be divided among

    energy-intensive manuacturers, carmakers,

    natural-gas distributors, states with renew-

    able energy programs and others. Tiscompromise was viewed as necessary or

    passage. Such an allocation would mean that

    the government would receive little revenue

    because only 15 percent o the permits would

    be auctioned and that the initial allocation

    would probably not go to those who value

    the permits the most. However, this does

    not necessarily mean that the permits would

    not eventually be used by those who value

    them the most. Aer the initial allocation o

    permits, subsequent trading might lead to an

    allocation o the permits to those who valuethem the most. O course, the sellers o the

    permits rather than the ederal government

    would receive the money rom these sales.

    Economics vs. Politics

    Te cap-and-trade legislation illustrates

    the interplay between economics and politics.

    Uncertainty about the benets and costs

    guarantees that any proposal to regulate

    carbon emissions will be controversial. While

    the cap-and-trade program working its way

    through Congress contains desirable economiceatures, the prospects or an auction process

    covering all permits or carbon emissions does

    not seem to be a viable option politically.

    Cletus C. Coughlin is an economist at the Fed-eral Reserve Bank of St. Louis. For more on hiswork, see http://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/coughlin. Lesli S. Ott is a research associate atthe Bank.

    MCB

    C

    A

    Q Q* Q

    MB

    MB

    P

    O Q

    E

    R

    (emissions abated)

    gr 2

    Cap-and-Trade with Benet Uncertainty

    The Regional Economist | www.stloisfed.org 13

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    14/24

    Housings Great Fall:Putting Household BalanceSheets Together Again

    By William Emmons

    Declining U.S. house prices have contrib-uted signicantly to the deepest globalrecession and the most severe nancial crisis

    in many decades.1 At the level o individual

    U.S. households, alling house prices appear

    to be a signicant cause o mortgage deaults.2

    At least 7 million mortgage oreclosures wereinitiated during 2007 and 2008 combined,

    and all indications are that the rate o oreclo-

    sures will remain high or some time.3

    Falling house prices have inficted severe

    damage on many banks and other nancial

    institutions, such as Fannie Mae and Freddie

    Mac, the government-sponsored mortgage

    lenders, because many repossessed houses

    now are worth less than the mortgage debt

    they secure. Likewise, the market values o

    securitized residential mortgages have al len,

    imposing losses on investors around theworld.4 Continuing distress among mil-

    lions o homeowners, together with many

    weakened nancial institutions, may delay

    the economic recovery.

    Why are house-price declines so danger-

    ous and disruptive? Can we prevent this

    rom happening again?

    More Damaging Than Stock Declines

    Perhaps surprisingly, U.S. households

    $4 trillion loss o value since the end o 2006

    on the houses they own is ar less than thedecline in households stock-market wealth

    o $10 trillion that occurred aer mid-2007

    or the $8 trillion loss o stock-market wealth

    that occurred during 2000-02. Yet, many

    economists believe declining house prices

    have been more damaging than either o the

    two recent large stock-market declines.

    Tree eatures o homeownership in the

    U.S. help explain the severe allout rom

    declining house prices. First, unlike stock

    ownership, homeownership is widespread

    among households at most income levels.

    (See able 1.) About two-thirds o ami-

    lies are homeowners, while only about hal

    owned stock directly or indirectly in 2007,

    with most stock-market exposure concen-

    trated at upper income levels.5

    Second, or the vast majority o households,

    the value o their house (i they own one)

    is much larger than their stock portolio (i

    they have one) or any other investment. Te

    median value o a house was about $191,000,

    while the median stock holdings among

    households with a portolio were $35,000,

    both measured beore the recent declines.

    Tird, houses usually are nanced, in part,

    with mortgage debt. (See able 1.) For all

    but the lowest quarter o amily incomes, a

    majority o homeowners have mortgage debt.Leverage, or borrowing to nance an asset

    purchase, causes the owners gains and losses

    on the asset to be magnied.6 Tus, amilies

    are more likely to own houses than stocks;

    or most home-owning amilies, the value o

    their house ar exceeds their stock portolio;

    and housing oen is a leveraged investment.

    Declining house prices, thereore, directly

    aect more amiliesand more signi-

    cantlythan does a alling stock market.

    Why This Time Is Different

    High rates o homeownership and mort-

    gage borrowing are not new developments

    in the U.S. What seems to have made this

    house-price decline so severe is, rst, that

    house prices rose so ar, so astespecially

    in some areas, such as Caliornia, Nevada,

    Arizona and Floridaand then ell hard and

    ast. Second, the amount o mortgage debt

    taken on by millions o households appears,

    in retrospect, to have been excessive. House

    prices, thereore, have declined more than

    at any time since the 1930s precisely when

    many more households were vulnerable to

    the magnied eects o high leverage than

    ever beore.

    Chart 1 shows the ratios o house prices to

    per-capita personal incomes in Florida andMissouri, examples o boom and quiet

    markets, respectively. Average house prices

    in Florida rose much aster aer 2000 than

    incomes, and those prices have allen sharply

    since 2006. Not surprisingly, oreclosure

    rates in Florida have skyrocketed, as shown

    in Chart 2. House-price-to-income ratios

    and oreclosure rates also increased and then

    decreased in Missouri, but by much less.

    Meanwhile, the burden o servicing all

    types o debt averaged across all amilies rose

    rom 10 percent o amily income in 1989 toabout 12.5 percent in 2000 to almost 15 per-

    cent in 2007.7 Tese three years correspond

    to the respective peaks o the past three

    economic expansions, just beore recessions

    began and house-price growth slowed. Its

    clear that a long-term trend toward larger

    debt burdens occurred across the U.S., mak-

    ing many households more vulnerable to

    economic and nancial shocks.

    As most house prices ell aer 2006, mort-

    gaged homeowners equity ell even aster.

    Homeowners overall have lost almost $5 tril-lion o homeowners equity through the rst

    quarter o 2009, even though house values

    ell only about $4 trillion. Te greater decline

    in homeowners equity refects the act that,

    as house prices ell aer 2006, mortgage debt

    continued to rise until recently.8 Considering

    only homeowners with mortgage debt (about

    two-thirds o all homeowners), the average

    loss o homeowners equity is in the neigh-

    borhood o 70 percent, due to the magniying

    F n n c L L t r c Y

    tys mglsDF/www.mu

    14 The Regional Economist | October 2009

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    15/24

    E N DN O T E S

    1 For a discussion o the role o alling house

    prices in the economic downturn and nan-

    cial crisis, see Bernanke.2 See Hatzius.3 See Mortgage Bankers Association.4 See Kohn.5 See Bucks et al. a nd Census Bureau.6 During the early part o this decade, when

    house prices generally were rising, the

    homeowners equity o any household with

    mortgage debt increased aster, on a percent-

    age basis, than the va lue o the house itsel.

    For example, a doubling o the value o a

    $100,000 house on which there is a $50,000

    mortgage results in a tripling o homeown-

    ers equity (rom $50,000 to $150,000). Aer

    house prices began to decline in about 2006,

    the same magnication eect has been work-

    ing in reverse.7 See Bucks et al.8 See Federal Reserve Board.

    R E F E R E NC E S

    Bernan ke, Ben S. Four Questions about the

    Financia l Crisis. Speech presented at More-

    house College, Atlanta, Ga., April 14, 2009.

    See www.ederalreserve.gov/newsevents/

    speech/bernanke20090414a.htm.

    Bucks, Brian K.; Kennickell, Arthur B.; Mach,

    racy L.; and Moore, Kevin B. Changes

    in U.S. Family Finances rom 2004 to 2007:

    Evidence rom the Survey o Consumer

    Finances, Federal Reserve Bulletin, February

    2009. See www.ederalreserve.gov/pubs/

    bulletin/2009/pd/sc09.pd.

    Census Bureau. 2007 American Housing

    Survey. See www.census.gov/hhes/www/

    housing/ahs/ahs.html.

    Federal Reserve Board. Flow of Funds Accounts.

    See www.ederalreserve.gov/releases/z1/

    deault.htm.

    Hatzius, Jan. Beyond Leveraged Losses: Te

    Balance-Sheet Eects o the Home-Price

    Downturn, Brookings Papers on Economic

    Activity, Fall 2008, pp. 195-227. See www.

    brookings.edu/press/Journals/2009/brook-

    ingspapersoneconomicactivityall2008.aspx.

    Kliesen, Kevin. Survey Says Families Are

    Digging Deeper into Debt. Federal Reserve

    Bank o St. Louis e Regional Economist.

    Vol. 14, No. 3, July 2006, pp. 12-13. See www.

    stlouised.org/publications/re/2006/c/pages/

    debt.cm.

    Kohn, Donald L. Comments on Financia l

    Intermediation and the Post-Crisis Financial

    System by Hyun S. Shin et al., at the Eighth

    Annual Bank or International Settle-

    ments Conerence, Financial System and

    Macroeconomic Resilience: Revisited, in

    Basel, Switzerla nd, June 25, 2009. S ee www.

    ederalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/

    kohn20090710a.htm.

    Mortgage Bankers Association. National Delin-

    quency Survey o May 28, 2009. See www.

    mortgagebankers.org/ResearchandForecasts

    ProductsandSurveys/NationalDelinquency-

    Survey.htm.

    eects o leverage. O course, many home-

    owners have deaulted on their mortgages

    already and, unortunately, many more arelikely to do soparticularly i house prices

    continue to all and the unemployment rate

    rises urther.

    Lessons Learned

    One clear lesson rom the housing crash

    and oreclosure crisis is that house prices

    can all sharply, even on a nationwide basis.

    Remarkably, it had become almost an article o

    aith earlier in this decade among many mort-

    gage lenders and borrowers that house prices

    would not all signicantly, even in overheatedmarkets. It was assumed that most homeown-

    ers simply would wait to sell their houses until

    demand recovered, rather than dumping their

    properties into a alling market. As it turned

    out, deaults increased sharply in 2006 and

    2007. Banks and other owners o oreclosed

    properties did sell a large number o houses,

    even in alling markets. Tis unleashed a

    downward spiral o house prices which, in

    turn, contributed to more deaults.

    Fa or nddanoe aeor

    n 2007

    er of faen h aeor

    (on)

    f hh, nerof fae haare hoeoner

    (on)

    f hh, nerof fae hahae oraede (on)

    peren of faen h noe

    aeor ha arehoeoner (%)

    peren of hoe-onn faen h noeaeor h

    orae de (%)

    le han $20,000 23.2 10.1 3.4 43.7 33.9

    $20,000 o $39,999 27.6 16.1 8.1 58.5 50.4

    $40,000 o $79,999 31.3 23.6 16.7 75.3 70.9

    $80,000 or ore 28.2 25.8 20.6 91.3 79.9

    Totl popultionof fmilies

    110.4 75.6 48.9 68.5 64.6

    suc: 2007 eran on sre, brea of he cen.

    Tab 1

    Homeownership and Mortgage Borrowing By Family Income Category

    charT 1

    Ratio of House Prices to Per-CapitaPersonal Income

    90 95 00 05 10

    180

    160

    140

    120

    100

    80

    Florida Missouri

    A V E R A G E L E V E L IN 1 9 9 1 E Q U A L S 1 0 0

    sucs: Federa on Fnane en and brea ofono na. Qarer daa hroh Q1 2009.

    charT 2

    Mortgage Foreclosure Rate

    90 95 00 05 10

    12

    10

    8

    6

    4

    2

    0

    Florida Missouri

    % OF 1ST-LIEN MORTGAGES ENTERING FORECLOSURE (ANNUAL RATE)

    sucs: morae baner oaon. Qarer daahroh Q1 2009.

    Another key lesson is that mortgage bor-

    rowing can be excessive. Rather than ocus-

    ing merely on the aordability o the initialmonthly payments a household must make, it

    clearly is necessary to plan or any increases

    that could occur and to build in a margin o

    saety or unexpected nancial stresses, such

    as unemployment or unexpected medical or

    other expenses.

    Te simplest way to avoid another devas-

    tating housing crash and oreclosure crisis

    probably is to reduce and maintain much

    lower levels o household leverage. Not only

    might less mortgage borrowing make house-

    holds better able to withstand any uturehouse-price declines or any other nancial

    shocks that might occur, but it also might

    reduce the chance o house prices again ris-

    ing to unsustainable levels.

    William Emmons is an economist at the Fed-eral Reserve Bank of St. Louis. For more on hiswork, see www.stlouisfed.org/banking/pdf/SPA/Emmons_vitae.pdf.

    The Regional Economist | www.stloisfed.org 15

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    16/24

    hrough the 1980s, a railroad bridge,a two-lane highway bridge and a lockand dam, all decrepit with age, dominated

    the riverront at Alton, Ill. Aer the variousagencies in charge slated all three eyesores

    or demolition, the city25 miles north o

    St. Louis and across the Mississippiset to

    work on a master plan to re-create the

    riverront along lines that were more

    image-enhancing.

    In 1991, the plan was done, and the river-

    ront got its rst new attractionthe Alton

    Belle, Illinois rst foating casino.

    Arriving as the city was ast losing its

    longtime industrial base, the boat came

    as a welcome shot o economic adrenalin,bringing the city hundreds o new jobs and

    a wellspring o new revenue rom its local

    shares o state casino taxes. o build on

    those gains, the city imposed its own sepa-

    rate per-person tax on boat customers.

    Although the casino was privately

    nanced, the next big riverront improve-

    menta marinareceived a hand rom

    the city in the orm o $5 million in bonds,

    repayable in part rom marina revenue.

    Since opening in 1996, the acility has been

    expanded three times; nearly 300 boats can

    dock there now.

    Te latest and most ambitious riverrontprojects yet are a $4.4 million amphitheater

    and a $2.5 million pedestrian bridge. Te

    amphitheater, which seats 4,000 under a

    canopy, opened in May with a Miles Davis

    jazz estival, named or one o Altons avor-

    ite sons. Te bridge wil l span the railroad

    tracks and our-lane highway that separate

    the riverront rom Altons downtown; it is

    slated or completion in November.

    Te city nanced the bridge and amphi-

    theater with a combination o tax increment

    nancing (IF) money on hand and $5.5million in IF-backed bonds, all made pos-

    sible by a IF district consisting o the citys

    downtown plus some other commercial and

    industrial properties. Te city earmarks or

    development all real estate taxes collected in

    excess o the amounts in eect when the city

    enacted the district in 1994.

    Te city has used IF money to spruce up

    several downtown blocks with new lights,

    sidewalks and plants. Developers can also

    c o M M n t Y P r o F L

    Alton, Ill. by he umbes

    PPTIN .................... .................... .............. 29,393BR FRE.................. .................... .............. 13,968

    NEPyENT RTE ............................10.3 percent

    PER PIT PERN INE

    adison ount ................... ................... $33,585

    * .. Bureau of the ensus, estimate Jul 1, 2008

    ** HVER (B), June 2009

    *** BE/HVER, 2007

    TOP EMPLOES

    t. nthons Health enter .................... ............... 851

    lton emorial Hospital .................. .................... .. 842

    lton ommunit nit chool District No. 11........ 835

    rgos asino .................... ..................... ............... 549

    merican Water ..................... .................... ............ 530

    RE: elf-reported.

    Includes part-time

    ***

    **

    ***

    Alton Comes to Gripwih dusial elieArticle and photos by Susan C. Thomson

    Te aosy csino rn no on a o of ah a o

    of oor o on rerfron. in 1991, he ano eae

    he r araon ne a aer an a dran oredeeo he reh of he aon he m er.

    get IF grants o $7,500 or each new busi-

    ness or residential unit created in downtown

    buildings, which are up to 150 years old. In

    the past our years, 30 new apartments or

    condos and 10 new oces have resulted. A

    number o new shops and restaurants have

    also opened in an area that ell on hard

    16 The Regional Economist | October 2009

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    17/24

    times aer Alton Square Mall opened on the

    edge o town in 1978 and became the go-to

    local shopping place.

    Te citys investments have turned the

    once run-down downtown and unsightly

    riverront into what Brett Stawar, president

    o the Alton Regional Convention & Visi-

    tors Bureau, describes as a string o pearls

    or tourists.

    Te necklace also includes the 15-year-old

    Clark Bridge, whose swooping yellow cables

    shine in the sun, making a photogenic

    background or the riverront. Te our-

    lane highway bridge was unded by the state

    and ederal governments. Another pearl

    is the new lock and dam, erected two miles

    downstream rom the riverront by the U.S.

    Army Corps o Engineers. Te complex,

    which includes a river-themed museum,

    logged 61,791 visitors in just the rst six

    months o this year.Te convention and visitors bureau,

    which gets the biggest share o its unding

    rom cuts o the citys taxes on hotels and

    restaurant ood and drink, also promotes

    Altons longtime historic and natural assets.

    Tese include the spot where Lincoln and

    Douglas last debated in 1858, several signi-

    cant Civil War-era sites, three picture-book

    19th-century residential neighborhoods

    on the National Register o Historic Places,

    and scenic river blus where American

    bald eagles come to eed every January andFebruary. Te birds have grown into an

    industry, luring 10,620 tourists to eagle-

    related events this yearmore than double

    the number o two years ago.

    As a measure o tourisms growth, Stawar

    cites the 70,700 room nights Altons three

    hotels sold last year, a 9 percent uptick rom

    2007. He says they were quite oen com-

    pletely booked.

    No count exists o the tourism jobs cre-

    ated, and they are too dispersed or any

    single tourism employer to make the cityslist o top employers, now led by Altons

    two hospitals. Both are expandingAlton

    Memorial Hospital with a $45 million addi-

    tion and St. Anthonys Health Center with

    a $70 million one.

    Health care has been great or the local

    economy, says Philip S. Roggio, the citys

    director o development and housing these

    past 20 years. Health care is generally

    recession-proo.

    Mny emnnts of altons industil eydy ar he n donon and aon he rerfron, he reared

    o e tiF o redeeo hee aan e.

    Alton was a manuacturing town or most

    o the 20th century, but no more. Glass-

    maker Owens-Illinois shut down in 1983,

    Smurt-Stone Container Corp. closed its

    paperboard mill in 1998 and Laclede Steel

    liquidated three years later. From thousands

    at their peaks, the plants were down at theend to hundreds o jobs eachall lost.

    Aer the state o Illinois declared the

    glass companys 153-acre property a brown-

    eld, the city contributed $6 million in

    IF-backed bonds to a private developers

    $18 million cost o cleaning up the site, tear-

    ing down old buildings, installing utilities

    and turning it into a modern business park.

    In 2001, New Jersey-based American Water

    opened a call center in the park, choos-

    ing it or its central U.S. location over ve

    other sites in dierent states. Te center,which operates around the clock serving

    the utility companys customers in 32 states

    and Ontario, has been steadily adding

    employees.

    In 2003, a group o local investors bought

    Lacledes ormer 400-acre site and, on part

    o the parcel, opened Alton Steel Inc., a

    maker o specialty steel bar products.

    Even with the new company and busi-

    ness park, Alton has been le with acres o

    The Regional Economist | www.stloisfed.org 17

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    18/24

    Te bell Mnsion, n 1903, oaed on monareo n on. the anon no a e-non ed and

    reafa.

    amon te sites pomoted o or h onen oon jah p. loejo. e a an aoon her

    ho a an a ro-aer o n 1837.

    Te $4.4 million mpitete oened n ma on he rer-

    fron. in he arond he 15-ear-od car brde, aandar n he s. lo area, han o na ae-

    a den and rh eo ae ran.

    Downtown en red , han n no a ar

    o ax nreen nann. thee o dn had eenanddae for deoon; h tiF nene, deeoer

    rned he no 11 aaren and o ore.

    abandoned, alling-down actory build-

    ings. As with downtown and the riverront,

    the city stands ready to use IF money to

    improve these properties, Roggio says.

    Te city also has its redevelopment

    sights trained on Alton Square Mall, where

    vacancies, declining sales and deerred

    maintenance have taken their toll. o turn

    it around, the city created a special taxing

    district, which added a cent to the malls

    sales tax rate. Te city has pledged up to

    $1.5 million o the extra money to the mallsexas owner or renovations. As those

    proceed, the city is pursuing deals to add a

    12-screen movie theater to the mall and to

    lure a new hotel/conerence center to town.

    I were going to grow tourism, says

    Stawar, we have to have more hotels.

    Downtown and the riverront remain

    works in progress. Downtown is stil l dotted

    with empty buildings, but more IF grant

    applications are pending.

    On the riverront, a foating restaurant

    has been or sale since closing more than ayear ago.

    At the casino, now called the Argosy,

    business is oenough that the boats

    sta is down by about hal rom a decade

    ago, according to the general manager,

    Rich Laudon. He blames the economic

    downturn, competition rom newer casinos

    around the St. Louis metropolitan area and

    a statewide ban on public smoking that

    went into eect Jan. 1, 2008. Nevertheless,

    Altons $5.7 million share o state taxes on

    the boat added up to about 22 percent o

    the citys operating budget last year, and the

    total $414,000 rom the citys separate head

    tax on casino customers went into a und or

    special city projects.

    Meanwhile, on the strength o a $200,000

    grant rom the National Scenic Byways

    Program, plans are aoot or a new river-

    ront attractiona food memorial plaza.

    With a sculpture, ountain and exhibits, it

    will be dedicated to the heroics o Altonscitizens in times o rising Mississippi waters

    Construction could start next year.

    Dale Blachord, president o Liberty Bank

    and an Alton resident or only ve years,

    says that, unlike some locals, he sees more

    o the positives than the negatives about

    the city. Overall, he sees a city that has been

    slowly and successully reinventing itsel

    these past 20 years and, o necessity, contin-

    ues to do so. It takes time, he says.

    Alton Mayor om Hoechst also takes a

    long view, ocused on the uture. Werestill suering rom the old days when the

    industrial jobs were so plentiul, he says.

    Tose jobs are gone, theyre not coming

    back and people have to get used to that

    act.

    Susan C. omson i s a freelancer.

    18 The Regional Economist | October 2009

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    19/24

    t r c t o V r V W

    ecession Takes Tollon Eighth District Tax Collections

    Amidst the current recession, decliningstate tax revenue and an increasingdemand or government servicessuch as

    Medicaid, unemployment insurance and

    various other social programsare putting

    increased pressure on state government

    budgets. State governments estimate a $230billion gap between expected expenditures

    and expected revenue between scal year

    2009 and scal year 2011.1 Tat gure rep-

    resents roughly 12 percent o total annual

    state government revenue (about $1.8 tril-

    lion) or recent years.

    One culprit behind these gaps is the large

    decline in states major sources o tax rev-

    enuepersonal income, corporate income

    and taxable retail sales.2 Revenue rom

    these taxes or scal year 2009 was down

    6.6 percent, 15.2 percent and 3.2 percent,respectively, rom scal year 2008 levels.3

    As with states across the country, tax

    revenue or each o the seven states in the

    Eighth Federal Reserve District is generally

    lower as a result o the current recession.

    able 1 lists state revenue rom the sales tax,

    the personal income tax and the corporate

    income tax, all or scal year 2008 (pre-

    recession) and scal year 2009. In addition,

    the percentage change between the two

    scal years is given. otal state tax revenue

    or the 50 states combined and or the sevenDistrict states combined is also included.

    In our o the seven District states, sales

    tax revenue or scal year 2009 was lower

    than in scal year 2008. Illinois experi-

    enced the largest decrease (7.5 percent),

    ollowed by ennessee (5.5 percent) and

    Missouri (3.7 percent). Sales tax revenue in

    Arkansas increased by 1.1 percent between

    scal year 2008 and scal year 2009. In

    total or the seven states, the percentage

    decline in sales tax revenue (3.8 percent)

    was slightly greater than the decline or all

    50 states (3.2 percent). Te decline in sales

    tax revenue or the seven states was less than

    the decline in personal income tax revenue

    (5.1 percent) and corporate income tax

    revenue (20.3 percent).Personal income tax revenue declined in

    six o the seven District states between scal

    year 2008 and scal year 2009. Illinois and

    ennessee experienced the largest declines

    o 8.8 percent and 30.1 percent, respec-

    tively. It is important to note that ennes-

    sees personal income tax only applies to

    dividend and interest income, not wage

    income (which is the largest component o

    personal income) as in the other six states.

    Tus, a reduction in ennessees much

    smaller personal income tax base yields alarger percentage decrease than an equal

    reduction in other states. Mississippi was

    the only state to experience a positive, albeit

    small, increase in personal income tax rev-

    enue (0.4 percent). As a whole, the decline

    in personal income tax revenue in the seven

    states (5.1 percent) was less than that o the

    50 states (6.6 percent).

    Corporate income tax revenue declined

    in all seven states rom scal year 2008

    to scal year 2009. Te largest declines

    were in Kentucky (44.4), Illinois (22.0percent) and Missouri (21.1 percent). O

    the seven states, Indiana experienced the

    smallest decline in corporate income tax

    revenue (9.7 percent). For the seven states,

    corporate income tax revenue decreased by

    a greater percentage (20.3 percent) than

    did sales tax revenue (3.8 percent) and

    personal income tax revenue (5.1 per-

    cent). In addition, the decline in corporate

    income tax revenue or the seven states was

    about 33 percent greater than that o the 50

    states (20.3 percent versus 15.2 percent,

    respectively).

    otal tax revenue (dened here as sales

    tax revenue + personal income tax revenue

    + corporate income tax revenue) or each

    state is shown in the last three columnso able 1. All seven states experienced a

    decline in total tax revenue between scal

    year 2008 and scal year 2009, with the

    declines ranging rom a high o 9.6 percent

    in Illinois to a low o 2.2 percent in Missis-

    sippi. Te decline in total tax revenue or

    the seven states (6.0 percent) was slightly

    less than that o the 50 states (6.1 percent).

    Differences across the States

    Although the majority o Eighth District

    states experienced a decline in revenue romthe three major taxes, the magnitude o

    the decline across states is quite dierent.

    One reason is that various tax bases may be

    more aected by an economic slowdown

    than others, and this eect may be dierent

    across states. For example, a reduction in

    retail sales will reduce sales tax revenues,

    whereas a reduction in employment will

    more likely infuence personal income tax

    revenue and corporate income tax revenue.

    Tus, the degree to which an economic con-

    traction aects consumption, employmentand income in each state can explain part

    o the dierence in the perormance o the

    three tax revenue sources across the states.

    A related reason is the degree to which

    each state relies on, as a percentage o total

    tax revenue, each source o revenue. As

    seen in able 2, the seven states each rely on

    each source o revenue to varying degrees.

    For example, 25 percent o total tax revenue

    in Missouri is rom the states sales tax,

    Th eghth fdal rsv Dstct is

    composed of four zones, each of whichis centered around one of the four main

    cities: Little Rock, Louisville, Memphis

    and St. Louis.

    MISSOURI

    ILLINOIS

    ARKANSASTENNESSEE

    KENTUCKY

    MISSISSIPPI

    INDIANA

    Memphis

    Little Rock

    Louisville

    St. Louis

    By omas A. Garrett

    The Regional Economist | www.stloisfed.org 19

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    20/24

    whereas over 78 percent o total tax revenue

    in ennessee is rom the states sales tax.

    Similarly, 69 percent o total tax revenue in

    Missouri is rom the personal income tax,

    compared with only 3.3 percent in ennes-

    see. Tus, equal drops in retail sales activity

    (assuming constant tax rates and exemptions)

    will infuence total tax revenue much more in

    ennessee than in Missouri.

    Looking Ahead

    States will continue to ace budget pres-

    sure until economic conditions improve.

    Improvement in revenue streams rom the

    sales tax, the personal income tax and the

    corporate income tax is dependent upon,

    broadly speaking, increased consumer

    spending and greater employment and busi-

    ness investment. Slow or stagnant growth

    in one or more o these areas will hinder

    growth in total tax revenue, especially in

    those states that generate the majority o

    their tax revenue rom only one or two taxes.

    Certainly, there are actors other than

    the three major taxes that will infuence a

    states scal health. Increased ederal money

    to state governments as a result o the

    American Recovery and Reinvestment Act(the stimulus package) may provide a tem-

    porary boost to state government revenue.

    Reductions in expenditure on various state-

    unded programs, such as higher educa-

    tion, social services and corrections, have

    occurred in dozens o states in scal year

    2009, with urther cuts likely in the next year

    or two. Finally, many states are considering

    tax increases in scal year 2010 and scal

    year 2011.

    E N DN O T E S

    1 All tax data presented here are rom National

    Governors Association and the National

    Association o State Budget Ocers.2 State governments obtain revenue rom sources

    other than sales ta xes, personal income taxes

    and corporate income taxes. Tese sources

    include excise taxes, user ees, ederal govern-

    ment transers, license ees and selective sales

    taxes (sales taxes on specic goods, such as

    tobacco). About 40 percent o general und

    revenue is rom the personal income tax, 33

    percent is rom the sales tax and 8 percent is

    rom the corporate income tax. 3 Te scal year or most states, including all o

    those in the Eighth District, ends June 30. Te

    exceptions are: Alabama and Michigan, Sept. 30;

    Nebraska and exas, Aug. 31; and New York,

    March 31.

    R E F E R E N C E S

    National Governors Association and the National

    Association o State Budget Ocers. e Fiscal

    Survey of States, June 2009. See www.nasbo.

    org/Publications/PDFs/FSSpring2009.pd.

    Sals Tax rvn Psonal incom Tax rvn Copoat incom Tax rvn Total Tax rvn

    Stat FY2008 FY2009 % Change FY2008 FY2009 % Change FY2008 FY2009 % Change FY2008 FY2009 % Change

    Arkansas 2,111 2,135 1.14 2,345 2,271 3.16 318 258 18.87 4,774 4,664 2.30

    Illinois 7,215 6,674 7.50 10,320 9,417 8.75 1,860 1,450 22.04 19,395 17,541 9.56

    Indiana 5,534 5,426 1.95 4,838 4,726 2.32 910 822 9.67 11,282 10,974 2.73

    Kentucky 2,878 2,878 0.00 3,483 3,365 3.39 435 242 44.37 6,796 6,485 4.58

    Mississippi 1,947 1,950 0.15 1,542 1,548 0.39 501 403 19.56 3,990 3,901 2.23

    Missouri 1,931 1,860 3.68 5,210 5,084 2.42 459 362 21.13 7,600 7,306 3.87

    Tennessee 6,851 6,475 5.49 292 204 30.14 1,620 1,328 18.02 8,763 8,007 8.63

    7 State Total 28,467 27,398 3.76 28,030 26,615 5.05 6,103 4,865 20.29 62,600 58,878 5.95

    50 States 214,217 207,358 3.20 276,155 257,805 6.64 50,772 43,034 15.24 541,144 508,197 6.09

    SOURCE: National Governors Associat ion and the National Association of State Budget Ofcers (2009). Total tax revenue is the sum of the three individual taxes.

    Tbe 1

    Stat Sals Tax % Psonal incom Tax % Copoat incom Tax %

    Arkansas 44.2 49.1 6.7

    Illinois 37.2 53.2 9.6

    Indiana 49.1 42.9 8.1

    Kentucky 42.3 51.3 6.4

    Mississippi 48.8 38.6 12.6

    Missouri 25.4 68.6 6.0

    Tennessee 78.2 3.3 18.5

    50 States 39.6 51.0 9.4

    NOTE: Percentages are computed using the data in Table 1. Numbers may not add up to 100 percent due to rounding.

    Tbe 2

    Regardless o the actions taken by state

    governments to shore up their balance

    sheets, only an economic recovery will

    provide or growth in state tax revenue. As

    long as state governments rely on revenue

    sources that are linked to economic peror-

    mance and ail to adequately save during

    prosperous times, it is certain that states

    will once again nd themselves acing

    budget shortalls during the next economic

    slowdown.

    omas A. Garrett is an economist at theFederal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. For moreon his work, see http://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/garrett/.

    Tax Collections, Eighth District States ($ millions)

    Tax Revenue as Percentage of Total Tax Revenue (2008)

    20 The Regional Economist | October 2009

  • 8/9/2019 Regional Economist - October 2009

    21/24

    B o o K r V W

    By Kevin L. Kliesen

    (e authors book review of In Fed We rust

    takes the place of our usual National Overview

    feature, which will return in the next issue.)

    he nations economic policymakers areentrusted with helping to ensure eco-nomic and nancial stability. Oen, though,

    a policymakers thought process is clouded

    by the storm and stress o the crisis. In his

    bookIn Fed We Trust: Ben Bernankes War

    on the Great Panic (published in August 2009by Crown Business), the Wall Street Journals

    David Wessel walks us through a detailed,

    behind-the-scenes narrative that attempts to

    portray the diculties acing Federal Reserve

    policymakers (and those in the ederal

    government) as they ormulated an evolving

    response to the nancial crisis that roughly

    began in August 2007.

    From Page 8:

    Tis is the story o the Bernanke Fedabandoning ailed paradigms in

    order to do what needed to be done.

    It is a story o what the Fed saw and

    what it missed, what it did and what

    it didnt, what it got right and what

    it got wrong. It is a story about Ben

    Bernanke deciding to do whatever it

    takes. Above all, it is a story about

    a handul o peopleoverwhelmed,

    exhausted, beseeched, besieged, con-

    stantly second-guessedwho ound

    themselves assigned to protect the U.S.economy rom the worst economic

    threat o their lietimes.

    Heading into the last ew months o 2009,

    it appears that these eorts have produced

    some tangible benets: Te economic and

    nancial headwinds that have hammered

    the U.S. economy over the past year or so

    appear to be calming. Indeed, a majority

    o economists believe the recession that

    ocially began sometime in December

    2007 has nally ended.

    Riders on the Storm

    As the books subtitle suggests, much

    o the narrative is ocused on the Federal

    Reserves response to the nancial cri-

    siswhat Wessel calls the Great Panic.

    Te design and implementation o these

    policy responses are seen mainly through

    the lens o Chairman Ben Bernankeand his key colleagues on the Federal

    Open Market Committee. Wessel also

    added a second subtitle to the book: How the

    Federal Reserve Became the Fourth Branch

    of Government. By this, Wessel has in mind

    the Federal Reserves special lending powers

    that were invoked under Section 13(3) o the

    Federal Reserve Act. Under the auspices o

    unusual and exigent circumstances, the

    Federal Reservevia the three special lend-

    ing acilities named Maiden Lane I, II and

    IIIhelped to nance the purchase o BearStearns by JPMorgan Chase and to prevent

    the ailure o American International Group

    (AIG). Wessel also relates how Bernanke

    and other Federal Reserve ocials urged the

    governments other key economic players

    to take aggressive actions at key moments

    in the Great Panic. Tese included policies

    designed to stabilize the nations 19 largest

    depository institutions deemed too systemi-

    cally important to ail.

    In Fed We Trustis an entertaining read,

    but it is generally written rom a Washington,D.C., and New York City perspective. Indeed,

    the key Federal Reserve ocials in the nar-

    rative are Bernanke, Govs. Don Kohn and

    Kevin Warsh, and then-New York Fed Presi-

    dent im Geithner. Wessel reers to them

    as the our musketeers.