Real Versus Nominal

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/7/2019 Real Versus Nominal

    1/2

    Real versus nominal, constant price versus current price: A comment

    on some terminology that is used in economic statistics

    In a recent critique of this paper by Dr Andrew Leigh and Dr Chris Ryan, Dr David Zyngier has

    suggested that a time series on education expenditure that is constructed by Leigh and Ryan is

    wrong. One of Zyngier's reasons for making this claim is his belief that Leigh and Ryan (2008) did

    not adjust for inflation. While it is true that Leigh and Ryan did not adjust the educationexpenditure data in Appendix Table 2 of their paper to account for inflation, they did not claim to

    do so. Indeed, the title of that table is "Nominal education expenditure (Spending per child per

    year, in current dollars)". Zyngier appears to have confused nominal data with real data.

    Specifically, he has interpreted "current dollars" to mean "constant 2003-2004 dollars". I suspect

    that this confusion may have been caused by a lack of familiarity with the terminology of economic

    statistics on the part of Zyngier. While Leigh and Ryan (2008) are correct to use the term "current

    dollars" to refer to nominal data, it is not difficult to see why someone who is unfamilar with the

    terminology employed in economic statistics might misinterpret this to mean "constant prices for

    this year" or maybe "constant prices for the most recent year in the data set". Such a mistake is

    understandable. After all, the everyday meaning of "current" is "now", not each of many previous

    points in time. Nonetheless, while such a mistake is understandable, it still renders this aspect of

    Zyngier's criticism of Leigh and Ryan (2008) invalid.

    In economic statistics, current dollar figures refer to nominal values. These are valued in terms of

    the dollars of the year in which the expenditure took place. On the other hand, constant dollar

    figures refer to real values. These are valued in terms of particular years dollars. I suspect that

    misinterpreting "current dollars" to mean "constant dollars of the most recent year in the time

    series" is probably an easy and understandable mistake to make for people who are not familiar

    with the terminology employed in economic statistics.

    The distinction between nominal (or current price) data and real (or constant price) data exists

    because time series data on pure quantities is sometimes unavailable in circumstances where time

    series data on expenditure and time series data on prices is available. In these circumstances, it is

    possible to obtain an index that represents the implicit time series data on quantities by:

    1. Constructing an expenditure index from the nominal expenditure time series;

    2. Constructing a price index from the price time series; and

    3. Deflating (that is, dividing) the nominal expenditure index by the price index.

    4. Renormalising the resulting quantity index so that it has a base year.

    The result of this is an index of the underlying quantities. If the time series of nominal expenditure

    itself is deflated by the price index, then the resulting data will be a time series of real

    expenditure. This is simply actual expenditure valued at the prices that prevailed in whatever year

    is chosen as the base year.

    When it comes to actual data, things are, of course, much more complicated. In particular, it is

    necessary to deal with both aggregation and quality changes when constructing the underlying price

    index. There are also other techniques for constructing volume (or quantity) indices, including the

    use of chain weights. There is a large literature on the properties of various different types of

    indices. An overview of this literature can be found at this website for a course on index

    numbers that is taught by Professor Erwin Diewert at the University of British Columbia in Canada.

  • 8/7/2019 Real Versus Nominal

    2/2

    Note 1. The full reference for Leigh and Ryan (2008) is: Leigh, A and C Ryan (2008), "How has school

    productivity changed in Australia?", mimeo The Australian National University, Canberra.

    Note 2. Dr Zyngier's criticisms of Leigh and Ryan (2008) appear in three places. The first place they

    appear is in this article in the online version of the Australian's Higher Education Supplement from

    Wednesday 19 March 2008. The second place they appear is ina letter to the editor of the online

    version of the Age from Tuesday 1 April 2008. However, it should be noted that this letter does notexplicitly mention the current doolar versus constant dollar issue. The third place in which it

    appears is in this comment on this post at Dr Leigh's blog site. Andrew addresses a different aspect

    of Dr Zyngier's critiques in the post mentioned above.

    Note 3. While Leigh and Ryan (2008) privide a time series of nominal education expenditure in their

    Appendix Table 2, they also provide three alternative time series of real education expenditures in

    their Appendix Table 4. The real data is presumably based on the nominal expenditure data in their

    Appendix Table 2 and three alterenative price indices that are provided in their Appendix Table 3.

    Update: I have made some edits to this post, including the addition of point four in the section of

    the post that discusses the construction of a quantity index from a time series on nominal

    expenditures and a time series on prices.