25
Principal - Agent Games Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help, since they are only effective at separating types before signing a contract The classic example – an owner of a firm hires a manager and wants the manager to maximize the profits of the firm There are two main sources of asymmetric information (1)the owner cannot observe the manager’s effort (2)the manager might obtain better information about firm’s opportunities than owner Problems of this type are known as principal agent problems - the principal hires the agent and wants the agent to take actions that maximize the principal’s welfare, - but the agent’s preferences might differ from the principal - the agent might be more risk averse and dislike

Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Principal - Agent Games Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been

signed

In this case, signaling and screening do not help, since they are only effective at separating types before signing a contract

The classic example – an owner of a firm hires a manager and wants the manager to maximize the profits of the firm

There are two main sources of asymmetric information (1)the owner cannot observe the manager’s effort(2)the manager might obtain better information about firm’s

opportunities than owner

Problems of this type are known as principal agent problems - the principal hires the agent and wants the agent to take actions that maximize the

principal’s welfare, - but the agent’s preferences might differ from the principal

- the agent might be more risk averse and dislike effort

Page 2: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Information problems The two parties attempt to design a contract that deals with these

problems

(1)Hidden action – the principal does not observe the agents actions - ex: in the firm, the action is work effort

- in insurance, the action is safe driving - this is known as the moral hazard problem

(2) Hidden information – the agent acquires better information - ex: new investment opportunities

Suppose an owner wants to hire a manager for a one-time project

Suppose that the project’s profits are affected by the manager’s actions - if the manager’s actions are observable, both to the owner and to a third party enforcer, then the contract could be quite simple: it would specify the manager’s actions and corresponding wage

The contract would be a forcing contract, where the manager is paid only if actions are performed.

Page 3: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Hidden Action Even if the P and A can observe actions,

this is not enough as they must be verifiable by a third party.

If the manager’s actions cannot be observed, then the contract cannot specify particular actions, since they cannot be verified.

In this case, the manager’s compensation can only be based on observable variables

Profits may or may not be observable and verifiable, but we will assume that they are

This may be more appropriate for the top managers than anyone else - as they affect the profits of the whole company and these profits might be public - or good proxies like share price are public

For regular workers involved in team production, this only provides a rough guide.

Page 4: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Let π denote the project’s profits -observable and verifiable. Let e denote the manager’s effort – usually e is assumed as a one-

dimensional real number, - but it could also be a vector

If profits are a deterministic function of e and presumably a monotonic function,

- then e could be inferred perfectly just by observing profits.

This case is then no different from the case where effort can be observed.

More realistically, Shocks can affect π -we cannot perfectly infer e

from observing π

Hidden Action Model

e1 e

π(e)π

π1

Page 5: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

To add to the model, assume that , and that there is a conditional density fn

e such that e 0 e and ,

Given any e, we

ff

H L

H

can observe any in the interval , (some levels more likely)

Assume that the manager only has 2 possible effort choices e , e

We will assume that the distribution of conditional on e fir

L

H L

st order stochastically dominates the distribution of conditional on e

So e e at all ,

with the inequality being strict for some open set ,

F F

Shocks

Page 6: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

High profits are more likely with eH

H Le e F is the CDF (cumulative density function)

- so it gives the probability of getting profit levels less that or equal to .

The inequality says that low profit levels are more likely wit

F F

L H

H

H L

h e than with e .

This implies that expected profits are higher when the manager chooses e .

e ef d f d

Page 7: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Manager’s expected utility fn

Assume that the manager maximizes expected utility

Given a utility function ( , e) defined over certain outcomes ( , e).

Assume that: ,e 0 so that higher wages are preferred

,e 0 at al

w

ww

U w w

U w

U w

H L H L

L

l ,e diminishing marginal utility of money (weak risk aversion)

,e ,e at all effort e is more costly then e and e is preferred holding constant

,

w

U w U w ww

U we

additively separable in and e this simplifies the analysis - the first assumption implies that 0, 0 and that H L

V w g e wV w V w g e g e

Page 8: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Assume that the owner receives the profits minus the wages. - assume that the owner is a risk neutral expected payoff maximizer. - owners can diversify, so they are less risk averse than the manager is

Consider a game where, 1- the owner moves first and chooses a contract to offer the manager 2- then the manager observes the contract and either accepts or rejects 3- if the manager accepts, then he chooses an effort level 4- then shocks are realized 5- payoffs are determined.

Initially, suppose that effort is observable, then the contract would specify - manager’s effort level and manager’s wage as a function of profits w(π) - Assume that the manager has a reservation utility level .- So the owner must provide manager with an expected utility of at least . - or the manager will not accept the contract. .

Owner maximizes net revenue (π-w)

L He e ,e

UU

Page 9: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

. .

When effort is observable

, ,the firm's expected profits net of wages the manager's exected utility must be at leas

The optimal contract for the owner solves the following problem.

max . . L He e e w

w f e d st V w f e d g e U

t

Since there are only 2 possible levels of , can solve this max problem by:

(1) set , solve for given

(2) set , solve for given

(3) choose or and the as

U

L L

H H

L H

e

e e w e e

e e w e e

e e

sociated optimal depending on which one results in a higher payoff for the owner

w

Page 10: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

. .

Transform optimization problem

To solve, we can first transform the optimization problem

Since, in (1) and (2) we hold e fixed and choose , we can ignore

The problem becomes min w

w f e d f e d w f e d

w f e d

w f e d s

1

1 n

,..

. .

We can solve this problem by choosing the optimal for each possible . It is more intuitive if you think in terms of a finite # of possible profit levels ( , ... )

minw

t V w f e d g e U

w

.

1 1

Prob . . Probn

n n

i i i iwi i

w e st V w e g e U

Page 11: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

. .

Lagrangian

1,... ,

1 1

To solve min Prob Prob

And we would get a FOC for each

Prob Prob =0

In the case where , , we would get a similar FOC

The wage at ea

n

n n

i i i iw wi i

i

i i i

w e V w e g e U

w

e V w e

w

a positive constant

ch level of , must satisfy =0

1Divide by and rearrange to obtain ( <0, when minimized)

f e V w f e

f eV w

Page 12: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Risk Sharing result

From this condition, we know that if the manager is strictly risk averse 0 the optimal is a constant wage that does not depend on

This is just a risk sharing

V ww

result, - since the contract specifies an effort level and there is no need to provide incentives, - the optimal contract has the less averse party bearing all of the risk.

By paying the mana

ger a constant wage, - the owner insures the manager against fluctuations in income.

The owner will offer a fixed wage *, s. t. the manager receives his reservation utility level

*

e

e

w

V w g

or *

Since , the manager's wage will be higher if the contract specifies .

e

H L H

e U V w U g e

g e g e e

Page 13: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

If manager is risk neutral

Suppose the manager is risk neutral 1

then 1 and always holds ( -1)

There is no need for insurance because both the and the are risk neutral

So any wage funciton that r

V w

V wV w

P A

w

1

esults in any expected wage of is optimal

Regardless, in equilbrium the expected wage satisfies

Given the expected wage, the maximizes expected profits minus expeced

g e U

E V w E w g e U

w V g e U

P

1

,

wage payments by choosing e

maxL He e e

f e d V g e U

Page 14: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

When effort is not observable

1

When effort is observable it is easy to get the A to choose the desired effort - just use a contract ( , ) where - and e is chosen to maximize expected profits minus expected wage

w e w V g e U.

- the agent is insured against income risk

When effort cannot be observed, the contract cannot specify e. - the only way to make the agent choose the desired e is to make the wage a fn of

.

- since is random, the agent is no longer fully insured against income risk. There is a conflict between providing incentives and having an efficient allocation of risk. - If the age

nt is risk neutral, then there is no need to insure the agent at all - in this case, the principal can end up with the same payoffs are before.

Risk neutrality , we established tV w w

,

this is the principal's payoff

hat in the observable effort case,

e would be chosen to solve maxL He e e

f e d g e U

Page 15: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Optimal contract w/unobservable effort We have the following result for the case with unobserved effort.

Prop: In the PA model with unobservable effort and a risk neutral A, an optimal contract

generates the same effort choice and expected utilities for the manager and the owner as when e is observable.

Proof:: Note that the P can always do at least as well when e is observable as when it is not, since the P could always ignore e in choosing a contract. So if we find a contract when e is unobservable that generates the same expected payoffs as the optimal contract when e is observable, then the contract must be optimal. This is the plan.

Consider , where is a constant.

This contract is like selling the firm to A, - because A pays and in return gets whatever profits are generated.

w

Page 16: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Risk neutral agent

If A accepts , then A will choose e to solve

max

Note that the e that maximizes this is the same e that maximizes max (which is what was maxed when e

w

w f e d g e f e d g e

f e d g e U

was obs)

So the optimal e under ( ) is the first best optimal e (fully observable case).

A accepts the contract as long as it pays at least his residual utility, . * *

Now

w

Uf e d g e U

this is what the P gets

this is the P's payoff when e is observablewhen e is unobservable

choose so that this constraint binds, then we get * * *

So both the P and t

f e d U g e

he A get the same payoff as before. .QED

Page 17: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Risk adverse agent The intuition for the prior result is since A is risk neutral, there is no

need for risk sharing. - Efficient incentives can be provided by selling the A the firm. - Then the A gets the full marginal return from e.

With a risk adverse agent, proceed by taking 2 steps

1) characterize the optimal contract for each effort level2) choose the effort level to maximize the P’s payoff

In solving 1), the P’s problem reduces to the wage minimization problem discussed above;

the difference is now there is an added constraint because the contract cannot specify e.

The wage function w(π) must be chosen so that when the A chooses e to max

- the optimal e is the effort level the P is trying to get A to choose.

maxe

v w f e d g e

Page 18: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

So the Principal’s problem is

participation constraint

incentive constraint

min . . (1)

and (2) solves max

To implement , P optimally offers the A

w

e

L

w f e d st v w f e d g e U

e v w f e d g e

e

1a fixed wage * - where * is the same wage that P would pay if was observable

Since effort is costly and , if the wage is fixed then the A will choose - contract result

e L

e L

H L L

w v u g ew e

g e g e e

s in the same payoffs to P and A as in the case when effort is observable

- so it is optimal.

To implement is more challengingHe

Page 19: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Implementing high effort

A's expected payoff given and the choice of

In order to induce the A to choose the more costly effort level, wage must depend on profit.

Rewrite constraint (2) as

H

H H L L

w e

v w f e d g e v w f e d g e

A's expected payoff given and the choice of

P's problem max . . (1) 0

(2) 0

As before, choose optimal

Lw e

H Hw

H H L L

w f e d st v w f e d g e U

v w f e d g e v w f e d g e

w

multiplier on multiplier on constraint (1) constraint (2)

for each a FOC must be satisfied at every ,

0

1where 0 , 0 rearranging, we get

H H H Lf e v w f e f e f e v w

v w

1 L

H

f e

f e

Page 20: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Proof that constraints bind

Claim: In any solution to P's problem when P implements , both 0 and >0.

So, both constraint (1) and (2) are binding at the optimal wage.

1Proof: Suppose =0. Then 1

He

f

v w

.

Because first order stochastically dominates , there must exist

an open set of profit levels , such that at all .

This implies that 1

L

H

H L

L H

L

H

e

f e

F e F e

f e f e

f e

f e

at all , which, along with the fact that 0,

implies that 0 at all .

But by assumption, A always

v w

strictly prefers more money to less, so 0, which leads to a contradiction. Therefore 0.

v w

Page 21: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Optimal contract when P chooses eH

1

Now suppose that =0. Then & the optimal contract specifies a fixed wage

- we know that A strictly prefers to when the wage is fixed, - so this contract cannot implement

L H

H

v we e

e

. Therefore, 0.

More details on the optimal contract when P chooses .

1 - we know that 1

1ˆ - as a benchmark, let be the wage that sets

- optimal

H

L

H

QED

e

f e

f ev w

wv w

ˆ ˆ satisfies: > if 1 ; < if 1 L L

H H

f e f ew w w w w

f e f e

Page 22: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Likelihood ratio

The optimal pays relatively more for levels of that are relatively more likely to occur when A chooses .

is a likelihood ratio as it corresponds to a ratio of probabilities in the

H

L

H

we

f e

f e

discrete case

By paying A more for outcomes that are more likely to occur when is chosen, - P ensures that A chooses .

This suggests P should pay more for higher , but doesn't have to be i

H

H

ee

w

ncreasing in .

- if is decreasing in , then it is optimal for to be increasing in .

- but otherwise the optimal would be non-monotonic in .

L

H

f ew

f e

w

Page 23: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Monotone likelihood ratio property

Often economists assume that is decreasing in .

If has this property, then said to have the monotone likelihood ratio property.

- Note that the monotone LRP is not implied by fir

L Hf e f e

f e

st order stochastic dominance.

- So ( ) is not monotonic in general; even when it is it is not linear in general w

w

0 1

F

1

0 1

HeF

LeF

H Le stochastically dominates eF F

f

0 1

Hf e Lf e

0 1

H

Middle values of , ,

are relatively more likely with e

0 1

H

pays more for ,

(values relatively more likely with e )

w

Page 24: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Principal’s payments

Because the A is risk averse, and the P needs to make vary with , - the expected wage payment is strictly higher than the fixed wage payment made in the case where effort is observable.

w

Jensen's inequality

- A must be compensated in utility terms for taking the extra risk.

Strict risk aversion 0 implies

Sin

H Hv E v w e v E w e

ce, , we must have

Since, when effort is observable, * , and since 0,

We must have *

H

H

H H H H

e H

H e

E v w e U g e v E w e U g e

v w U g e v w

E w e w

Page 25: Principal - Agent Games. Sometimes asymmetric information develops after a contract has been signed In this case, signaling and screening do not help,

Summing Up The wage payment for implementing eL is exactly the same as when

effort is observable.

The expected wage payment for implementing eH is strictly larger in the non-obs. effort case.

So, non-observable effort raises the cost of implementing eH and does not change the cost of implementing eL . This could lead to an inefficiently low level of effort being implemented.

When eL is optimal under obs, it is still optimal under non-obs, and non-obs causes no losses.

If eH would be optimal under observability, then under non-observability either

1) could still be optimal to implement, but A must bear risk and the expected wage rises

2) the risk bearing costs may be high enough that P decides that it is better to implement eL

In either case, non-observability causes a welfare loss to P. - A gets an expected utility equal to his reservation utility no matter what.

Note: a social planner can’t improve welfare unless the planner can observe effort when P can’t