31
Comparative Political Studies 45(12) 1624–1654 © The Author(s) 2012 Reprints and permission: sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/0010414012463904 http://cps.sagepub.com 63904CPS 45 12 10.1177/0010414012463904Co tical StudiesGingrich and Ansell s) 2011 ermission: ournalsPermissions.nav 1 University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN, USA Corresponding Author: Ben Ansell, Department of Political Science, University of Minnesota, 1414 Social Sciences, 267 19th Ave. S, Minneapolis, MN 55455, USA Email: [email protected] Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts, and the Demand for Social Policy Jane Gingrich 1 and Ben Ansell 1 Abstract Political economists have increasingly looked to understand social welfare policy as a product of individual-level demand for social spending. This work hypothesizes that individuals with riskier jobs demand more social spending and that large welfare states emerge where there are more of such individu- als. In this article we build on the “policy feedback” literature to argue that existing welfare institutions condition how individual-level factors affect social policy preferences. Specifically, we argue that institutions directly alter- ing the risk of unemployment (employment protection legislation) and those that delink benefits from the labor market create a more uniform system of social risk that reduces the importance of individual-level risk in shaping policy preferences. We test these propositions using multilevel analysis of 19 advanced industrial countries in 2006.We find that individual risk matters for social policy preferences only where employment protection is low and welfare benefits are dependent on employment. Keywords policy feedback, risk, welfare state, public opinion

Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    22

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Comparative Political Studies45(12) 1624 –1654© The Author(s) 2012Reprints and permission:sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.navDOI: 10.1177/0010414012463904http://cps.sagepub.com

463904 CPS451210.1177/0010414012463904Comparative Political StudiesGingrich and Ansell© The Author(s) 2011

Reprints and permission: sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav

1University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN, USA

Corresponding Author:Ben Ansell, Department of Political Science, University of Minnesota, 1414 Social Sciences, 267 19th Ave. S, Minneapolis, MN 55455, USA Email: [email protected]

Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts, and the Demand for Social Policy

Jane Gingrich1 and Ben Ansell1

Abstract

Political economists have increasingly looked to understand social welfare policy as a product of individual-level demand for social spending. This work hypothesizes that individuals with riskier jobs demand more social spending and that large welfare states emerge where there are more of such individu-als. In this article we build on the “policy feedback” literature to argue that existing welfare institutions condition how individual-level factors affect social policy preferences. Specifically, we argue that institutions directly alter-ing the risk of unemployment (employment protection legislation) and those that delink benefits from the labor market create a more uniform system of social risk that reduces the importance of individual-level risk in shaping policy preferences. We test these propositions using multilevel analysis of 19 advanced industrial countries in 2006. We find that individual risk matters for social policy preferences only where employment protection is low and welfare benefits are dependent on employment.

Keywords

policy feedback, risk, welfare state, public opinion

Page 2: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1625

Why do some individuals support spending on social programs more than other people? There has been a resurgence of interest in this question as schol-ars have looked to differences in popular support for social policy to explain differences in the origins and persistence of welfare states (Brooks & Manza, 2007). Many of these “bottom-up” approaches to explaining welfare state variation rest on deductively derived claims about how individuals’ economic positions shape their attitudes toward the welfare state (Cusack, Iversen, & Rehm, 2005; Iversen & Soskice, 2001; Rehm, 2009, 2011). In this work, wel-fare states largely work to insure against individual risks. Thus, individuals in jobs with high unemployment risks or with skills specific to that particular job are more likely to support social spending as a hedge against their own labor market risks. Where such jobs proliferate, the state develops more extensive social insurance: bigger welfare states follow the distribution of individual preferences.

Although this work has advanced a number of crucial insights explaining public support for the welfare state, it hinges on strong assumptions about the nature of individual risk and preferences. For these scholars, individual risk comes from the inherent riskiness of one’s job or skills. However, this claim raises the question of whether individual risk and thus individual spending preferences exist prior to welfare state institutions. Both labor market institu-tions and the benefits that individuals receive from the state can substantially modify the inherent riskiness of a given job. If systems of social protection shape how much economic risk individuals face, then they should also matter for determining individual demand for social welfare.

The claim that policies powerfully shape public preferences has a long his-tory in the study of comparative welfare states (Jaeger, 2009; Jordan, 2010; Korpi & Palme, 1998; Larsen, 2008; Linos & West, 2003; Rothstein, 1992). These “policy feedback” approaches argue that welfare policies alter the cost–benefit calculus for individuals. Larger welfare states, in offering more gener-ous benefits, tie more citizens to the state and increase support for it (Korpi & Palme, 1998). Although cross-national variation in levels of support for social spending provides some evidence for these arguments, empirical analyses of the distribution of individual opinion produce more mixed results (Bleckesaune & Quadagno, 2003; Svallfors, 1997). These ambiguous empirical findings raise questions about the precise connection between the distribution of indi-vidual support for the welfare state and existing policy structures

In this article, we build on both the feedback and the risk-based literatures to present a new understanding of how individuals’ policy contexts affect their social policy preferences. We argue that what citizens want from the government depends on how existing policies shape their experience of

Page 3: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1626 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

individual risk. Different social policy institutions create different systems of social risk. Social risk refers to the baseline risk citizens have of needing social benefits provided by the state, regardless of individual characteristics. Where welfare policies create a more uniform system of social risk, they reduce the importance of individual risk in preference formation.

Uniform systems of social risk can emerge for two reasons. First, existing institutions can alter the underlying risk of unemployment for a given group by making it harder for employers to fire and hire employees. Many countries have significant employment protection legislation that reduces differences across employees in terms of the risks of both unemployment and reemploy-ment. Second, some countries provide benefits to individuals independent of the labor market. Countries that provide individual benefits based on citizen-ship or residence, rather than employment status, make all citizens equally reliant on the state, and varying individual economic risk does not translate into varying risk of needing public benefits. In both cases, policies create more uniformity across citizens in the risks they face; thus, preferences should accordingly also become more homogenous.

We test the connection between individual attributes and social policies by examining individual spending preferences over health care, unemployment benefits, and industrial aid. We look at spending preferences across contexts that directly modify individual labor market risk (varying levels of employ-ment protection legislation) and those that do so indirectly by modifying the link between employment and benefits (employment dependent and indepen-dent health care benefits). We show that where institutions create more uni-form social risk, they decrease the importance of individual risk in determining spending preferences and increase overall support for spending.

This finding has important implications for both the risk-based literature and work on policy feedback. First, it shows that the individual-level factors purported to explain support for large welfare states actually have a weaker causal impact in large welfare states than in smaller ones. Second, it presents a new argument about how policies affect public preferences. Institutions affect preferences not only directly—by creating new groups of recipients—but also indirectly—by modifying the way individuals experience risk and thus the importance of risk in shaping overall preferences.

We start in the second section with a brief overview of the existing litera-ture on micro preferences and macro welfare regimes and then develop our argument about how these forces interact with one another. The third section describes our empirical approach and data. In the fourth section we examine the determinants of preferences over social insurance spending (unemploy-ment, industrial aid, and health care). The fifth section concludes.

Page 4: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1627

Connecting Macro and Micro Theories of Social Policy Preferences

The idea that welfare states not only play a redistributive role but also insure against the risk of income loss is well accepted in the social policy literature (Baldwin, 1990; Moene & Wallerstein, 2001). In recent years, scholars examining popular support for the welfare state have applied this insight to understand individual demand for social insurance. This research investi-gates how an individual’s position in the labor market helps shape his or her preferences over spending, with the basic finding that individuals with more inherent labor market risk support more public social spending (Iversen & Soskice, 2001; Rehm, 2009, 2011).

One particularly influential line of argument focuses on the risks associated with possessing different types of skills. Iversen and Soskice (2001) argue that individuals with specific skills are more likely to support social spending. Specific skills are skills that are used in only one industry or firm and are not transferable across different types of jobs. Broadly, those with specific skills face more risk of losing income should they become unemployed as they face greater difficulty in finding new work that is equally remunerative. According to this logic, because social insurance programs protect workers’ income during unemployment, those with specific skills should support them as a compensa-tory measure. Rehm (2011), conversely, argues that individuals’ occupationally specific unemployment risk determines their policy preferences, with risk again underpinning support for social policy.

These “bottom-up” models draw a line between individual economic attri-butes, support for social spending, and ultimately the size of the state itself. Estevez-Abe, Iversen, and Soskice (2001) suggest that individual skills aggregate to national outcomes: “[T]he greater the significance of a specific skill system . . . the greater the number of workers who possess the ‘key skills,’ and the more likely it is the median voter would be someone with an interest in supporting generous social protection” (p. 161). Rehm (2011) argues that countries with more homogeneity in individual-level occupa-tional risk have a larger coalition in favor of social spending. In each case, the distribution of risks at the micro level shapes the distribution of popular atti-tudes toward the welfare state, ultimately producing different types of macro-level social programs.

Casting the micro–macro link along these lines is potentially problematic. The theory and empirical analysis of individual preference formation focus only on individual risk. Yet, although citizens face risk that is “individual-ized,” they demand institutions that will socialize risk. If these institutions

Page 5: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1628 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

already exist and work to moderate risk, a question emerges as to why indi-vidual risk should be abstracted from its institutional context. Indeed, a core assumption of the “varieties of capitalism” literature that this work draws on is that some societal institutions do shape the risks and choices individuals face in the labor market. But if societal institutions already moderate risk, how can we abstract individuals from those same institutions to determine their preferences?

Many scholars studying the welfare state argue that institutions do indeed affect individual preferences. Work studying “policy feedback” argues that welfare states not only are the product of political struggles but also are cru-cial determinants of welfare politics in their own right. Drawing on the insights of “historical institutionalist” scholars, this research sees institutional structures as constructing individual social policy preferences. This work suggests two mechanisms that create policy feedback. Some scholars see welfare structures as either tying together or dividing class loyalties by pro-ducing benefits that are universalistic or residual (Esping-Andersen, 1990; Korpi & Palme, 1998). Individuals belonging to different classes will have social policy preferences reflecting the structure of welfare benefits. Others scholars argue, instead, that policies do not create class divisions but rather their own specific constituencies of “policy takers” who become its chief supporters (Pierson, 1996). In both cases, the underlying argument is that citi-zens support programs or policy regimes that benefit them, thus more exten-sive programs construct more extensive political support.

These claims, though highly influential, have met both empirical and theo-retical hurdles. Although cross-national surveys do show systematically varying levels of support for spending across countries, the hypothesis that individual preferences should mirror institutionally produced class cleavages has found mixed support (Bleckesaune & Quadagno, 2003; Jaeger, 2009; Svallfors, 1997). The “policy-taking” hypothesis has also met mixed results in empirical studies. Soss and Schram (2007) and Lynch and Myrskala (2009) find little evidence that policies of, respectively, cash welfare provision and public pensions have reshaped public opinion or created strong support bases among their recipients. Thus, questions remain about the mechanisms linking individual attributes and macro-level institutions.

An emerging literature has begun to resolve these empirical and theoreti-cal dilemmas by moving beyond broad regime or programmatic effects and looking at the way policies condition individual preferences in narrower terms. Studies such as those by Linos and West (2003), Larsen (2008), and Jordan (2010) examine how particular programs or “social policy regimes” condition how individual attributes such as gender, attitudes toward others,

Page 6: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1629

and class matter for policy preferences. Here macro regimes alter the impact of specific micro mechanisms, offering a clearer causal mechanism underly-ing public support for the welfare state. However, this literature does not engage with the insurance function of the welfare state or directly connect with the literature focusing on individual risk, leaving open questions as to how institutions interact with individual-level characteristics in shaping demand for social insurance.

We argue that social policy contexts matter because they modify the degree to which individuals experience direct labor market risk and thus the impor-tance of this risk in shaping individual preferences. The core mechanisms shaping individual preferences in the risk-based literature are (a) underlying differences in unemployment risks associated with a particular job or (b) underlying differences in the risk of needing public benefits because of prolonged unemployment. Where individuals face higher risks of becoming unemployed or of prolonged unemployment, they are more likely to support extensive social spending than their fellow citizens in less risky jobs. We argue that these individual-level mechanisms are likely to matter where social policy compensates for these underlying individual-level risks but does not directly modify them. However, where institutions alter the incidence of risk in the labor market or the risk of needing public benefits, we expect they will have a feedback effect by reducing the importance of individual risk (occupational or skill differences) in shaping preferences. We focus on two ways institutions can do this.

First, social policy institutions can directly affect the distribution of unem-ployment risk. Many countries have labor market institutions designed to protect employment for existing workers. These institutions are alleged to encourage more investment in specific skills because they modify the inher-ent riskiness of such investment (Estevez-Abe et al., 2001). One particularly important set of institutions is employment protection legislation (EPL). EPL makes it harder for employers to fire existing workers, reducing the risk of unemployment for the already employed. EPL should thus make differences in individual risk less important in determining the risk of unemployment and thus the need for social insurance.

These same institutions, however, are also associated with problems of job creation—and more controversially unemployment (Lazear, 1990; Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development [OECD], 2004). Although scholars debate whether EPL causes high aggregate unemploy-ment, there is evidence that EPL disrupts both the flow out of and the flow into employment (Blanchard & Portugal, 2001; Nickell, 1997). In countries with high unemployment and high EPL, even those with general skills can

Page 7: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1630 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

have trouble entering or reentering the labor market. This problem, dubbed as an “insider–outsider” problem, creates a logic of social risk that counteracts individual labor market risk (Lindbeck & Snower, 1989; Rueda, 2005). Regardless of skill specificity, individuals with jobs face a lower likelihood of becoming unemployed, but these same individuals face a uniformly higher risk of prolonged unemployment if they do become unemployed.

Second, social programs can indirectly alter individual-level risks by changing the likelihood that individuals will need public benefits. Where benefits are provided to people as citizens, rather than employees, higher than average risks of prolonged unemployment do not translate into higher risk of needing public spending, and vice versa. For instance, all individuals have guaranteed access to health care in Sweden, meaning that both those with high and those with low risks of unemployment in Sweden depend on the state for benefits, whereas in the United States those with a higher risk of long-term unemployment also have a higher risk of losing access to health insurance (and thus demanding public spending). Although no welfare states truly “decommodify” people, some go much further than others in how far they base benefits on labor market activity (Esping-Andersen, 1990). Where institutions provide benefits independent of the labor market, citizens with risky and nonrisky jobs are at equal risk of needing social benefits.

Taken together, we see that social policy institutions can, but do not neces-sarily, homogenize both the risk of prolonged unemployment and the costs of unemployment. Where institutions modify social risk by creating more uni-formity across the population, they reduce the importance of individual risk in determining individual preferences. Given that differences in risk exposure are crucial to Iversen and Soskice (2001) and Rehm’s (2009, 2011) claims about differences in individual preferences, this contextual effect is poten-tially important. Indeed, for Rehm (2011), risk homogeneity is crucial to determining spending outcomes—populations with more homogenous risks tend to be more supportive of the welfare state, thus causing larger welfare states. However, if policies themselves construct risk homogeneity, rather than it being inherent in particular economies, this complicates the idea that micro preferences seamlessly drive macro policy outcomes. Our theoretical approach suggests that by changing the level of social risk, and thus modify-ing the impact of individual risk, national welfare institutions have powerful feedback effects on individual preferences over welfare spending.

Our claim raises a second question. If institutions homogenize the experi-ence of risk across individuals, do they work to make low-risk individuals behave more like high-risk individuals or vice versa? We argue that either pathway is theoretically possible, but, in line with existing empirical work

Page 8: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1631

(Finseraas, 2008; Rehm, 2011), the former seems more likely. The homoge-nization of risk through social programs makes all individuals equally depen-dent on the state for benefits. In an unmodified market, low-risk individuals, such as those with general skills, are (a) able to find new jobs easily and (b) less reliant on the public sector because they receive many occupationally provided benefits (e.g., health care). As institutions homogenizing risk come into place, these same individuals face a different environment. First, where EPL not only modifies the distribution of unemployment risk but also increases barriers to entry into jobs—as in countries with insider–outsider labor markets—general-skilled individuals now face an equivalent risk to specific-skilled individuals of prolonged unemployment if they lose their jobs. Thus, as in Saint-Paul (2000), EPL will become associated with higher aggregate demand for unemployment insurance as all citizens now face lon-ger spells of unemployment.

Second, where benefits are provided independent of employment, public spending now benefits low-risk individuals directly and their lower level of labor market risk does not translate into lower risk of needing the public sys-tem. Indeed, rather than having private occupational benefits, they must now rely on the public sector for benefits. As such, they should support spending. In both cases, as risk is decoupled from inherent features of an individual’s job and cast at a societal level, those who are “winners” in a less regulated labor market are now more dependent on the state for their well-being, mak-ing them more similar to their colleagues in inherently risky jobs.

These claims suggest a very different take on the micro–macro connection than much of the literature. We are arguing that societal institutions can either reflect or modify individual risk. Where these institutions modify risk, they tend to reduce individual differences based on risk and increase the likeli-hood of overall support for the welfare state. It is problematic to argue that large welfare states exist today because of current individual demands based on risk—the structure and impact of individual risk is at least partly endoge-nous to existing institutions. Indeed, individual risk should matter least in generating demand for higher spending in countries that already have high spending and a more homogenous system of social risk. By contrast, where social protection is lacking, individuals do face substantial risk based on their labor market position. Consequently, we expect individual risk to be most important as a predictor of support for public spending in countries where social protection is comparatively low. In the long run, it is true that macro-level institutions may be endogenous to public opinion. Nonetheless, in the medium run, when citizens form social policy preferences they are partly doing so in response to a fixed policy environment.

Page 9: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1632 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

Equally, the argument here contributes to the policy feedback literature. Our argument is broadly congruent with the existing literature, but it specifies the micro–macro connection differently. Although the core mechanism link-ing policies to individual preferences in the existing feedback literature is benefit receipt, we argue that risk modification is more important with regard to social insurance preferences. Institutions such as EPL that do not directly affect what an individual receives from the state can still have a feedback effect by modifying labor market risk.

To test these claims, we examine two mechanisms of social risk modifica-tion: the extent of EPL and the existence of employment independent bene-fits. EPL directly modifies the distribution of individual labor market risk, and thus is likely to matter for spending on programs directly related to the labor market, such as unemployment insurance and industrial aid. We expect the effect of individual risk factors such as skill specificity on support for unemployment insurance and industrial aid to be much smaller in countries with robust EPL. We further expect that since EPL is often associated with a higher aggregate risk of lengthy unemployment, general skills individuals will look more like their specific skilled colleagues and thus demand more spending. Controlling for unemployment levels should remove this effect.

Hypothesis 1a: Higher levels of EPL will reduce the importance of individual risk factors such as skill specificity in determining indi-vidual social insurance spending preferences.

Hypothesis 1b: EPL will tend to increase the overall level of support for social insurance. This effect should be reduced once unemployment levels are taken into account.

Employment-independent benefits indirectly alter individual risk. Here we focus on the risk of losing job-related benefits, for example health care, rather than income. Some countries provide health care to all citizens, regard-less of their employment status (Hacker, 2004). These countries may provide universal health insurance through a “single payer” (as in Canada) or a national health service where the government actually produces health care (as in Sweden and the United Kingdom). In each case, benefit receipt is not tied to work and thus is unaffected by spells of unemployment. By contrast, other countries have a connection between work and health benefits. Although very few OECD countries (the United States is an exception) tie health ben-efits directly to work, the extent of this coverage and the associated contribu-tions are tied to employment in many Continental European countries, Japan, and Ireland. Skill specificity should thus matter more in determining

Page 10: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1633

spending preferences where benefits are dependent on employment and less where they are not.1 Because employer-independent systems make individu-als equally dependent on the state, we expect they will increase the overall level of support. Since individual health risks are not dependent on the level of unemployment, this outcome should not be affected by aggregate unemployment.

Hypothesis 2a: Employment independent benefits will reduce the importance of individual risk factors such as skill specificity in determining individual spending preferences.

Hypothesis 2b: Employment independent benefits will tend to increase the overall level of support for the welfare state. This effect should not be affected by aggregate unemployment.

In summary, welfare institutions create a system of social risk that directly modifies individual risk. Tracing the interaction between an individual’s labor market position and spending preferences requires taking this social risk into account.

Data and Statistical ApproachIn this section we describe the data and statistical techniques we use in our empirical tests of the propositions developed above. The data set we use is the 2006 Role of Government International Social Survey Programme (ISSP 2006), which asks a variety of questions about whether individuals would prefer the government to increase or decrease spending on a series of social policies. Our sample covers between 18 and 19 countries and around 15,000 individuals. The previous iteration of the Role of Government survey—the ISSP 1996 data set—was key to the development of hypotheses about skill specificity and policy preferences (Iversen & Soskice, 2001). The ISSP 2006, also used by Rehm (2011), covers a broader range of countries than the ISSP 1996, producing greater variation among national social policies.2

Unlike most cross-national surveys, the ISSP asks questions about govern-ment spending on specific social programs. Although previous authors have typically combined these disparate measures into single or multiple dimen-sions of aggregate spending preferences, we retain the disaggregated mea-sures since our interest is in how specific national-level policy institutions affect individual preferences about specific policies.3 The dependent variables

Page 11: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1634 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

we examine are unemployment benefits, support for declining industries, and health care spending.4 Individuals are asked the following question:

Listed below are various areas of government spending. Please show whether you would like to see more or less government spending in each area. Remember that if you say “much more,” it might require a tax increase to pay for it.

Thus, this survey question directly addresses the issue of fiscal trade-offs—individuals are asked to compare increased spending with increased taxes. Respondents are provided with the following choices: spend much more, spend more, spend the same, spend less, and spend much less. Following Rehm (2011), we use a binary scale of 0 for spend much less, spend less, and spend the same, and 1 for spend more and spend much more.5

As independent variables we employ individual-level variables, national-level variables, and the cross-level interactions of individual- and national-level variables. Our chief individual-level independent variable is a measure of individual risk: skill specificity. We use the measure of skill specificity developed by Iversen and Soskice (2001) and Cusack et al. (2005). This mea-sure derives the specificity of an individual’s skills from his or her occupa-tion, using the 1988 International Standard Classification of Occupations (ISCO88)—a hierarchical categorization of occupations that produces occu-pational codes one to four digits long. The skill-specificity index uses the number of four-digit occupation subcategories in each two-digit category as a proxy for the specialization of skills. For example, ISCO code 82, “machine operators and assemblers,” has 36 subcategories, whereas ISCO code 52, “models, salespersons, and demonstrators,” has only 3 subcategories. Yet both groups account for around 5% of the workforce. Iversen and Soskice (2001) argue that the former group has much more specific skills than the latter. We use the occupational categories provided in the ISSP 2006 and fol-low the instructions provided in Cusack et al. (2005) to produce a measure of their s1 skill specificity index, which ranges from 0.48 to 4.11. In the online appendix (available at http://www.polisci.umn.edu/~ansell/papers.htm), as a cross-validation measure we also examine Rehm’s (2011) individual occupa-tional risk variable, coded as the national unemployment rate for each of the 9 one-digit ISCO codes.

To capture general skills, we use the ISSP’s 7-point scale of formal educa-tion to ascertain whether individuals have received a university degree, which is the highest category included. We create a dummy variable measuring

Page 12: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1635

whether individuals have attained a university education: We refer to this vari-able as degree. This variable is an important control in our analysis of social insurance since the risk-based literature predicts individuals with general skills will be less supportive of social insurance spending. We use this variable because countries in the sample differ dramatically in the structure of second-ary education. Only when we turn to university degrees do we see a clear com-monality and thus a comparable indicator of high general skills. Nonetheless, our results are very similar if the 7-point education scale is used.

At the national level, our core variables are EPL and health care structure. Our EPL index is taken from the OECD (2006) and is produced by aggregating measures of (a) regulation on temporary employment, (b) specific requirements for collective dismissal, and (c) protection of regular workers against dismissal.6 The EPL measure varies between 0.65 (United States) and 3.5 (Portugal). For our analysis of the health care spending question, the national policy we exam-ine is whether the country has an employment-independent health care system. We code Australia, Canada, Denmark, Finland, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom as employment-independent systems and France, Germany, Ireland, Israel, Japan, the Netherlands, Switzerland, and the United States as employment-dependent systems.7 To create our cross-level interaction variables, we multiply our individual-level variables skill specificity and degree by the relevant national variable (EPL for unemployment and indus-trial aid preferences, health care system for health preferences).8 In Table 4 below, we also examine the effects of other national variables: Here we use the national unemployment level in 2005, taken from OECD (2006), the proportion of secondary school students in vocational education from OECD (2008), and the Gini coefficient for occupational unemployment from Rehm (2011). The online appendix provides descriptive statistics and correlations among these variables.

We also include a battery of control variables, following the specifications used in Iversen and Soskice (2001) and Rehm (2011). We begin with a mea-sure of income. The ISSP does not provide a direct interval measure of family income but instead uses a 10-point scale.9 We also include a series of employ-ment and demographic variables: age, gender (1 = male), and dummy vari-ables for unemployment, nonemployment, self-employment, part-time work, and whether the individual belongs to a trade union. We also include a vari-able measuring political information to control for exposure to pro- or anti-spending arguments in the media. To control for the anti-redistribution effect of religiosity hypothesized by Scheve and Stasavage (2006), we use an 8-point measure of religious attendance. Finally, we use a 5-point scale of

Page 13: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1636 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

partisanship ranging from far left to far right, drawn from party identifica-tion. This latter variable dramatically reduces the size of the data set since independents and nonvoters are excluded. Like Iversen and Soskice (2001), we impute partisanship through multiple imputation to retain individuals who would otherwise drop out of the analysis.10

We now turn to our estimation techniques. We perform three different types of multilevel binary dependent variable analysis: a logit model with country fixed effects, a logit model with random effects, and a two-step model with random intercepts and coefficients. All estimations use heterosce-dasticity-robust standard errors clustered by country.11 The models presume that observed survey answers reflect an unobserved variable y*

ij, measuring

underlying support for the policy, with i indexing individuals and j indexing countries. The equation for the fixed effects model is,

y = + s + d + z s + z d + + u +ij*

0 1 ij 2 ij 3 j ij 4 j ij j ijα β β β β εW bij

This equation has an intercept α0, the skill specificity variable for each indi-

vidual sij and its coefficient β

1, the university degree variable for each indi-

vidual dij and its coefficient β

2, the interaction of skill specificity with the

national policy zj and the coefficient β

3, the same for the degree variable with

coefficient β4, the matrix of remaining controls and their coefficients W

ijb, a

country fixed effect uj, and an individual error term ε

ij. By contrast, the equa-

tion for the random effects model is,

y = + s + d + z s + z d + z + + +ij*

0 1 ij 2 ij 3 j ij 4 j ij 5 j j ijα β β β β β ν εW bij

This equation differs in two ways. First, we directly estimate the effect of the national policy z

j, and, second, the country-specific error term υ

j is randomly

drawn from a normal distribution, with mean zero and variance σ2

v.

These two multilevel techniques, used in Tables 1 through 3, have comple-mentary properties. The fixed effects model, also used in Iversen and Soskice (2001) and Hellwig (2001), controls for cross-country heterogeneity in responses and for variation in spending preferences related to the existing level of spending, a potentially important omitted variable. However, since the national-level pol-icy z

j is invariant within countries, we cannot estimate the level effects of national

policies on aggregate spending preferences. Conversely, the random effects approach, also used in Finseraas (2008) and Solt (2008), permits the estimation

Page 14: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1637

of the effects of national policies such as EPL. What the random effects approach loses in its ability to control for national-level idiosyncrasies it gains in its ability to examine cross-sectional variation at the national level.

The effects of social risk policies on policy preferences can be seen in two ways. First, in the random effects models the direct level effect of a policy can be read off its coefficient as the average effect of the policy on spending pref-erences across all citizens. Second, in both techniques, the policy-conditional effect of individual-level variables can be understood as the coefficient of the individual-level variable when the national-level variable equals zero plus the coefficient on the interactive variable multiplied by the value taken by the national-level variable.

Ideally, one would test a feedback model of preference formation using panel data, but unfortunately no cross-national panel survey with appropriate questions currently exists, and, moreover, we would need information on preferences before and after changes in EPL and health care policy and such changes are rather rare. Nonetheless, if policy feedback arguments are cor-rect, then cross-sectional analyses should show that contextual effects come only through the relevant policy and not other national-level variables. We take this approach in Table 4 by estimating a series of “two-stage” models. This technique allows us to compare the relative importance of a variety of different national contextual variables—EPL, health care structure, unem-ployment, skills profile, and occupational unemployment inequality. Accordingly, we can show it is the social risk policy specific to the spending question that drives our results, not the national composition of the labor market nor the composition of skills.

At the “first stage” we run a separate logit analysis within each country, and then at the “second stage” we use coefficients from the first stage as the dependent variable and national-level variables as predictors. This is equiva-lent to running a model with both random intercepts and random coefficients for all independent variables. In the second stage analyses we adjust for the fact that the dependent variable, being a regression estimate, is measured with error, using the technique and code developed by Lewis and Linzer (2005). We compare the effects of relevant national policy variables on the coefficient for skill specificity and that for the constant term.

Individual Risks, Social Risk, and Support for Social SpendingWe begin our empirical analyses by examining the role of EPL in shaping individual preferences over unemployment spending (Table 1) and aid to

Page 15: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1638 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

Table 1. Unemployment Preferences and Employment Protection Legislation (EPL)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

FE RE FE RE FE RE

Individual Income −0.461*** −0.486*** −0.417*** −0.446*** −0.417*** −0.446*** (0.047) (0.034) (0.049) (0.036) (0.048) (0.036) Skill specificity 0.309*** 0.335*** 0.278*** 0.320*** 0.323*** 0.360*** (0.064) (0.080) (0.070) (0.082) (0.098) (0.103) Univ. degree −0.148 −0.109 −0.179 −0.167 −0.110 −0.125 (0.187) (0.150) (0.178) (0.153) (0.245) (0.199) Unemployed 0.969*** 0.887*** 0.962*** 0.875*** 0.964*** 0.876*** (0.189) (0.111) (0.188) (0.120) (0.188) (0.120) Nonemployed −0.000 0.007 0.028 0.039 0.029 0.039 (0.107) (0.061) (0.103) (0.065) (0.103) (0.065) Self-employed −0.350*** −0.345*** −0.339*** −0.331*** −0.339*** −0.332*** (0.078) (0.071) (0.067) (0.075) (0.068) (0.075) Part-time 0.118 0.103 0.106 0.091 0.108 0.092 (0.103) (0.069) (0.105) (0.073) (0.105) (0.073) Age 0.006** 0.005*** 0.006** 0.005*** 0.006** 0.005*** (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) (0.003) (0.002) Gender −0.095* −0.080* −0.092 −0.071 −0.092 −0.071 (0.055) (0.045) (0.064) (0.048) (0.064) (0.048) Religiosity 0.016 0.015 0.008 0.005 0.008 0.005 (0.014) (0.011) (0.013) (0.011) (0.013) (0.011) Union member −0.175*** −0.166*** −0.128** −0.121*** −0.128** −0.121*** (0.050) (0.029) (0.052) (0.031) (0.052) (0.031) Political info. 0.057 0.060*** 0.064 0.071*** 0.064 0.072*** (0.039) (0.021) (0.039) (0.023) (0.039) (0.023) Partisanship −0.211*** −0.213*** −0.211*** −0.213*** (0.061) (0.021) (0.061) (0.021)National EPL 0.523* 0.455* 0.239 (0.267) (0.259) (0.312) EPL × skill spec. −0.101*** −0.117*** −0.082*** −0.108*** −0.059* −0.088* (0.026) (0.036) (0.031) (0.037) (0.036) (0.049) EPL × univ. −0.133 −0.140** −0.126 −0.117 −0.099 −0.100 (0.098) (0.071) (0.095) (0.073) (0.119) (0.089) Unemployment 0.129 (0.109) Unemp. × skill spec. −0.015 −0.013 (0.017) (0.021) Unemp. × univ. −0.021 −0.013 (0.051) (0.039) Constant −1.167*** −2.557*** −0.616*** −1.803*** −0.606*** −2.142*** (0.147) (0.596) (0.216) (0.585) (0.213) (0.636) N 14,432 14,432 13,120 13,120 13,120 13,120 Countries 18 18 18 18 18 18

Standard errors in parentheses. Models 3 through 6 use multiple imputation.*p < .10. **p < .05. ***p < .01.

Page 16: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1639

Table 2. Industrial Aid Preferences and Employment Protection Legislation (EPL)

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

FE RE FE RE FE RE

Individual Income −0.339*** −0.344*** −0.304*** −0.307*** −0.303*** −0.306*** (0.044) (0.032) (0.041) (0.034) (0.041) (0.034) Skill specificity 0.387*** 0.361*** 0.397*** 0.361*** 0.390*** 0.363*** (0.091) (0.086) (0.091) (0.089) (0.103) (0.104) Univ. degree −0.642*** −0.722*** −0.689*** −0.763*** −0.499*** −0.612*** (0.125) (0.126) (0.145) (0.129) (0.175) (0.162) Unemployed 0.136 0.098 0.129 0.117 0.127 0.115 (0.136) (0.121) (0.133) (0.129) (0.131) (0.129) Nonemployed 0.096* 0.085 0.104* 0.096* 0.106* 0.097* (0.054) (0.055) (0.056) (0.057) (0.056) (0.057) Self-employed −0.294*** −0.282*** −0.259*** −0.242*** −0.258*** −0.242*** (0.098) (0.059) (0.089) (0.062) (0.089) (0.062) Part-time 0.060 0.077 0.042 0.061 0.044 0.063 (0.073) (0.060) (0.073) (0.062) (0.073) (0.062) Age −0.009*** −0.010*** −0.009*** −0.010*** −0.009*** −0.010*** (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) (0.002) (0.001) Gender −0.603*** −0.580*** −0.560*** −0.543*** −0.559*** −0.543*** (0.043) (0.040) (0.041) (0.042) (0.041) (0.042) Religiosity −0.012 −0.019* −0.023** −0.030*** −0.023*** −0.030*** (0.009) (0.010) (0.009) (0.010) (0.009) (0.010) Union member −0.126*** −0.115*** −0.091*** −0.078*** −0.090*** −0.078*** (0.030) (0.026) (0.029) (0.027) (0.029) (0.027) Political info. 0.180*** 0.170*** 0.194*** 0.184*** 0.194*** 0.184*** (0.025) (0.020) (0.027) (0.021) (0.027) (0.021) Partisanship −0.111*** −0.117*** −0.111*** −0.117*** (0.028) (0.022) (0.028) (0.022)National EPL 0.463** 0.416** 0.317 (0.191) (0.187) (0.227) EPL × skill spec. −0.100*** −0.092** −0.104*** −0.088** −0.114** −0.091* (0.038) (0.041) (0.039) (0.043) (0.047) (0.053) EPL × univ. −0.014 0.032 0.006 0.043 0.075 0.101 (0.098) (0.071) (0.095) (0.073) (0.119) (0.089) Unemployment 0.061 (0.079) Unemp. × skill spec. 0.004 0.000 (0.018) (0.019) Unemp. × univ. −0.059* −0.047 (0.034) (0.030) Constant −0.006 −1.160*** 0.306* −0.705 0.307* −0.871* (0.167) (0.433) (0.177) (0.431) (0.177) (0.473) N 14,376 14,376 13,082 13,082 13,082 13,082 Countries 18 18 18 18 18 18

Standard errors in parentheses. Models 3 through 6 use multiple imputation.*p < .10. **p < .05. ***p < .01.

Page 17: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1640 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

Table 3. Health Care Preferences and Single-Payer Systems

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

FE RE FE RE FE RE

Individual Income −0.163*** −0.163*** −0.132*** −0.132*** −0.132*** −0.132*** (0.039) (0.038) (0.044) (0.040) (0.044) (0.040) Skill specificity 0.247*** 0.220*** 0.265*** 0.218*** 0.235* 0.148 (0.053) (0.054) (0.082) (0.058) (0.129) (0.124) Univ. degree −0.177** −0.177** −0.183** −0.172* −0.258 −0.213 (0.088) (0.084) (0.094) (0.090) (0.310) (0.185) Unemployed 0.156 0.101 0.230 0.174 0.229 0.173 (0.170) (0.141) (0.194) (0.157) (0.193) (0.157) Nonemployed 0.076 0.081 0.097 0.105 0.097 0.105 (0.064) (0.066) (0.067) (0.070) (0.067) (0.070) Self-employed −0.318*** −0.285*** −0.290*** −0.248*** −0.289*** −0.246*** (0.093) (0.065) (0.096) (0.069) (0.094) (0.069) Part-time 0.066 0.045 0.079 0.051 0.078 0.049 (0.053) (0.070) (0.052) (0.074) (0.051) (0.074) Age 0.000 −0.001 0.000 −0.001 0.000 −0.001 (0.003) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.002) Gender −0.420*** −0.391*** −0.376*** −0.348*** −0.376*** −0.348*** (0.071) (0.047) (0.077) (0.050) (0.077) (0.050) Religiosity 0.044*** 0.045*** 0.042*** 0.042*** 0.042*** 0.042*** (0.013) (0.011) (0.015) (0.012) (0.015) (0.012) Union member −0.115*** −0.129*** −0.088** −0.103*** −0.088** −0.103*** (0.035) (0.030) (0.036) (0.032) (0.036) (0.032) Political info. 0.137*** 0.132*** 0.165*** 0.161*** 0.165*** 0.161*** (0.035) (0.023) (0.033) (0.025) (0.032) (0.025) Partisanship −0.098** −0.113*** −0.098** −0.113*** (0.040) (0.021) (0.040) (0.021)National Single payer (SP) 0.995*** 1.085*** 1.061*** (0.317) (0.305) (0.302) SP × skill spec. −0.241*** −0.232*** −0.227** −0.197** −0.224** −0.194** (0.064) (0.073) (0.094) (0.079) (0.088) (0.079) SP × univ. −0.314** −0.320*** −0.307** −0.328*** −0.303* −0.326*** (0.137) (0.107) (0.146) (0.113) (0.159) (0.113) Unemployment −0.063 (0.069) Unemp. × skill spec. 0.005 0.012 (0.025) (0.018) Unemp. × univ. 0.013 0.007 (0.046) (0.028) Constant 0.374* −0.010 0.574** 0.165 0.589** 0.551 (0.208) (0.283) (0.261) (0.293) (0.250) (0.515) N 15,064 15,064 13,350 13,350 13,350 13,350 Countries 19 19 18 18 18 18

Standard errors in parentheses. Models 3 through 6 use multiple imputation.*p < .10. **p < .05. ***p < .01.

Page 18: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1641

declining industries (Table 2) before turning to the role of employment-independent benefits in shaping health-spending preferences (Table 3). In each case we are focusing on the effect of individual risk—proxied by skill specificity—conditional on the national level of social risk. We argue that where EPL is high, or benefits are employment-independent, social risk is more uniform and individual-level risk will hence matter less in determining social insurance preferences. This implies a negative coefficient on the inter-action between skill specificity and EPL (or employment independent bene-fits). We also expect that EPL and employer independent benefits will be associated with a higher aggregate level of support for spending.

Tables 1 through 3 all contain six models. Models 1 and 2 are baseline fixed and random effects models. Models 3 and 4 add a control for partisan-ship and accordingly use multiply imputed data sets. Models 5 and 6 further add a national-level measure for unemployment and its interaction with both skill specificity and degree. These final models control for an important con-ditioning variable that is strongly correlated with EPL (at .59) and that might affect the salience of individual skills (as in Iversen & Soskice, 2001, who examine this specification). We examine other potential conditioning national effects in Table 4.

Table 1 examines the interactive effect of EPL and skill specificity on preferences over unemployment spending. In Models 1 and 2 skill specificity has a statistically significant positive direct effect on unemployment spend-ing preferences—as in Iversen and Soskice (2001)—but also a statistically significant negative coefficient for its interaction with EPL. This implies that as EPL increases, skill specificity has less of a positive impact on support for unemployment spending.12 This is true whether we control for country-specific effects (Model 1) or include cross-sectional variation and the direct effect of EPL (Model 2).13 The direct effect of EPL is positive and statistically significant, implying average support for unemployment spending is higher in countries with greater EPL. Finally, we see statistically significant nega-tive effects of income and of self-employment and positive effects of unem-ployment, age, union membership, and being female. In the online appendix, we show that this pattern holds up when we use the 5-point version of the dependent variable and if we replace skill specificity with Rehm’s (2011) measure of occupational unemployment risk.

Figure 1a presents the estimated probability of supporting increased spend-ing on unemployment benefits for different levels of skill specificity, using the random effects specifications from Model 2.14 Two predicted probabilities (with 95% confidence intervals) are plotted, one for a country with a low EPL of score of 0.65—for example, the United States—and one for a country with a high EPL score of 2.89—for example, Germany. Only in the low EPL case

Page 19: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1642 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

Table 4. Two-Stage Analyses

Unemployment spending

Skill specificity Skill specificity Skill specificity Skill specificity Skill specificity

Control — Single payer Unemployment Vocational Rehm Gini

Corr. with EPL — .09 .59 .42 −.36EPL −0.095*** −0.105*** −0.070* −0.083** −0.081** (0.030) (0.034) (0.039) (0.033) (0.030)Control 0.039 −0.016 −0.001 0.620 (0.059) (0.016) (0.001) (0.617)Constant 0.292*** 0.289*** 0.339*** 0.300*** 0.112 (0.067) (0.068) (0.081) (0.075) (0.188)N 18 18 18 17 15

Constant Constant Constant Constant Constant

Control — Single payer Unemployment Vocational Rehm Gini

EPL 0.528* 0.582** 0.366 0.628** 0.672* (0.258) (0.244) (0.322) (0.266) (0.318)Control −0.671* 0.096 −0.017 7.358 (0.377) (0.113) (0.010) (6.284)Constant −2.057*** −1.780*** −2.308*** −1.427** −4.167** (0.558) (0.545) (0.635) (0.579) (1.882)N 18 18 18 17 15

Health Care Spending

Skill specificity Skill specificity Skill specificity Skill specificity Skill specificity

Control — EPL Unemployment Vocational Rehm Gini

Corr. with single payer (SP) — .09 −.10 .04 −.12SP −0.170** −0.157** −0.158** −0.180** −0.184*** (0.065) (0.068) (0.067) (0.068) (0.059)Control −0.026 0.009 0.000 2.084** (0.046) (0.015) (0.002) (0.848)Constant 0.171*** 0.212** 0.109 0.155* −0.331 (0.047) (0.098) (0.107) (0.084) (0.210)N 19 18 18 17 15

Constant Constant Constant Constant Constant

Control — EPL Unemployment Vocational Rehm Gini

SP 0.589** 0.821*** 0.808*** 0.862*** 0.878*** (0.279) (0.249) (0.249) (0.250) (0.271)Control −0.030 −0.025 −0.007 7.622* (0.179) (0.057) (0.006) (3.783)Constant 1.111*** 0.934** 1.022** 1.202*** −1.034 (0.206) (0.405) (0.398) (0.358) (0.932)N 19 18 18 17 15

EPL = employment protection legislation. Standard errors in parentheses.*p < .10. **p < .05. ***p < .01.

Page 20: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1643

Figure 1. Unemployment spending preferences and employment protection legislation (EPL)

Page 21: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1644 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

is there a robust positive effect of skill specificity on unemployment spending preferences. In the high EPL case, the effect is indistinguishable from zero. The level effect of EPL is also apparent: General-skilled citizens are much more supportive of increased unemployment spending in high EPL countries than they are in low EPL countries. By contrast, specific-skilled individuals have similarly high levels of support across both systems. Figure 1b shows the declining effects of skill specificity as EPL increases: Once EPL exceeds 2 (its median), skill specificity ceases to have a significant effect. Substantively, we see it is only where social risk is less uniform that individual risk matters in determining unemployment spending preferences.

Models 3 and 4 add partisanship, using the multiply imputed data sets. We see a strong negative effect of right-wing partisanship on spending prefer-ences, but the effects of skill specificity and its interaction are consistent. Models 5 and 6 add the national level of unemployment and its interactions with skill specificity and degree. Here we do find a somewhat reduced coef-ficient for the interaction of skill specificity and EPL, unsurprising given the correlation of .59 between EPL and unemployment. The interaction remains significant at the 10% level, and, moreover, the interaction of unemployment with skill specificity has no effect: It is EPL not unemployment that condi-tions the effects of skill specificity. We do, however, find that including the level of unemployment wipes away the level effect of EPL. Since we hypoth-esized that general skills citizens support unemployment spending in high EPL countries because EPL makes reemployment more difficult, this finding is reassuring.

In Table 2 we examine the industrial support question. With regard to the interactive effect of skill specificity and EPL, we find very similar results to the previous analysis. Across all the models there is a robust negative effect of this interactive variable. Figures 2a and 2b show that when EPL is low, a 1-point shift in skill specificity is estimated to produce a 7% increase in sup-port for industrial aid. However, this effect declines rapidly, and when EPL is high, there is no statistically discernable effect. Again, individual risk matters less, if it all, when the government creates more uniform social risk—here, by propping up declining industries that might otherwise make workers with specific skills redundant.

In Table 3 we examine the demand for social protection from a different angle: preferences over health spending. We distinguish between countries with employment-independent health care systems (single-payer systems) and those where health benefits are partially tied employment (multipayer systems). We expect skill specificity to matter for health spending prefer-ences only where benefits are tied to employment—that is, in multipayer not

Page 22: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1645

Figure 2. Industrial aid preferences and employment protection legislation (EPL)

Page 23: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1646 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

single-payer systems. We also expect higher aggregate support for health spending in single-payer systems: Where the government is the only “game in town,” all citizens must rely on it regardless of their employment risk.

Across all six models there is a strong and statistically highly significant conditional effect of skill specificity and type of health system. In employment-dependent multipayer systems, skill specificity is positively associated with health care spending preferences, whereas in employment-independent single-payer systems there is no estimated effect of skill specificity on health spending preferences. Moreover, in the online appendix we show that this remains true when using the 5-point preference scale as a dependent variable and if indi-vidual occupational unemployment risk is used instead of skill specificity. Finally, in the random effects models we see a sizable and statistically signifi-cant direct positive effect of single-payer health care systems on support for health spending, as hypothesized.

Figures 3a and 3b show the estimated effects of skill specificity on the probability of supporting increased health spending in single versus multi-payer systems. Although all individuals, regardless of skill specificity, have an average probability of support of 83% in single-payer systems, in multi-payer systems individuals with low levels of skill specificity have a support probability of 60% compared to 80% for those with high skill specificity. Finally, as hypothesized above, unlike the case of unemployment and indus-trial aid, Models 5 and 6 show that the unemployment rate affects neither the interactive nor direct effects of single-payer health systems.

In Table 4 we provide further confirmation that it is the specific policies that condition social risk that affect the importance of individual skill speci-ficity rather than other national institutions discussed in the comparative political economy literature. We conduct a series of two-stage analyses, first running logit models for the dependent variables for each country and then using the coefficient estimates as dependent variables. In the second stage analysis we examine the effects of a variety of national policy and economic variables on two sets of coefficients. First we examine the estimated coeffi-cients on individual skill specificity—that is the effect of individual risk on policy preferences. Second we examine the constant term—which measures the “level” effects of the context variables—when all continuous individual-level independent variables are mean centered and all categorical variables to are set to zero, thereby reflecting the preferences of a “typical” citizen.15 We do this process in turn for unemployment insurance and health care spend-ing.16 By adding a variety of differing context variables, we are able to deter-mine whether the effects of EPL and of health care system are the national

Page 24: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1647

Figure 3. Health spending preferences and health systems

Page 25: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1648 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

factors driving our results, or if other contexts have an important role in shap-ing individual risk and “typical” support for social spending.

Beginning with unemployment insurance, we see that EPL on its own is a strong and statistically significant negative predictor of the coefficient on skill specificity (as we found in Table 1) and that EPL has a positive direct effect on “typical” support for unemployment spending (using the constant term as the dependent variable). When we include single-payer health care system as a control, it has almost no impact on EPL’s estimated effect on either the skill specificity coefficient or the constant. This is not surprising given the low correlation of .09 between EPL and health care system, but it is reassuring that these policy institutions are not interchangeable and that health policies do not affect unemployment preferences. When we add the level of unemployment as a context variable, it does somewhat reduce EPL’s affect on skill specificity, but it is significant at conventional levels, whereas unemployment has no effect on the skill specificity coefficient. As in Table 1, we see that the direct effect of EPL is, however, reduced dramatically—consistent with our hypothesis that EPL’s level effect is through its relation-ship with aggregate unemployment.

Estevez-Abe et al. (2001) argue that the aggregate level of vocational training will produce increased demand for social insurance. Accordingly, we examine the proportion of secondary students in vocational streams to see if the composition of skills in the economy is driving our results. However, despite a high correlation of .42 with EPL, once again we see a significant effect for EPL and no effect of the vocational control, either on the coefficient for skill specificity or on the “typical” level for unemployment spending.17 Finally, Rehm (2011) argues that the inequality of unemployment across occupations produces varied demand for social insurance. Although we do have a reduced sample, we find no effect of Rehm’s “unemployment Gini” on either the effect of EPL on the skill specificity coefficient or the level effect.18

Table 4 repeats these analyses with health care spending as the dependent variable and single-payer health care as the main independent variable. Single-payer health care remains a significant predictor of both the skill spec-ificity coefficient and the “typical” level of support, regardless of whether EPL, the unemployment rate, vocational education profile, or the unemploy-ment Gini is included as a “rival” context variable. In the final model, there is some evidence that unemployment inequality accentuates the role of skill specificity in determining support for health care spending: This is consistent with our account of the interplay between individual and social risk since unemployment inequality heightens rather moderates the role of individual labor market status.

Page 26: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1649

In summary, these results suggest a powerful conditioning effect of social risk on individual policy preference formation. Both EPL and employment independent benefits, by creating more uniform social risk, attenuate the importance of individual risk in shaping demands for social protection. Although we cannot entirely discount the role of endogeneity, the results in Table 4 showing that only the relevant policy context variable affected indi-vidual preferences, along with the fixed effects results, suggest that our results are not being driven by some unobserved national sentiment for social policy. Policy supply fundamentally shapes policy demand.

In ConclusionThe turn to examining the relationship between individual preferences and the structure of the welfare state has been a foundational step in comparative political economy. Although earlier works—for example Esping-Andersen (1990)—focused on the role of group action in demanding and securing social policies, research over the past decade has provided a salutary opening of the “black box” of preferences that lay implicit in many of these classic works. This literature provides an account of how national-level institutions might have emerged from the aggregation of individual characteristics such as skill specificity or occupational risk. However, something has been lost in this new program—the important conditioning effect of national policies on individual preferences. The “policy feedback” literature, for its part, reminds us that welfare states are not inert products but themselves shapers of politi-cal identification and policy demands.

The findings in this article provide a new way to link together the micro and macro literatures of policy preferences. We show that that national-level institutions affect preferences by altering the degree to which individuals experience economic risk. Where national institutions create more unifor-mity in risks and more dependence on the state, individual risk matters less in shaping preferences, and even those with low levels of individual risk are more supportive of the welfare state.

The article leaves open questions about the dynamic story of preference formation and welfare state change. We have argued that existing welfare regimes condition the importance of individual attributes in determining preferences. Indeed, we find that less extensive systems of social protection regimes accentuate the importance of individual risk in determining policy preferences. Given enough individuals with specific skills, this pattern could in the long run lead to realized demands for greater social protection. Or,

Page 27: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1650 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

conversely, as highly regulated labor markets reduce EPL, the politics of individual risk might become more salient in countries where it plays a more limited role today. Accordingly, scholars of institutional change might them-selves want to turn to examine the micro dynamics of preference formation.

Acknowledgments

We would like to acknowledge Teri Caraway, Kathleen Collins, Silja Hausermann, Lisa Hilbink, David Rueda, Phil Shively, and the editors and reviewers of Comparative Political Studies for their extremely helpful comments, critiques, and clarifications. We would also like to thank Philipp Rehm for his comments and for his generosity in giving us access to his data.

Declaration of Conflicting Interests

The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article.

Funding

The author(s) received no financial support for the research, authorship, and/or pub-lication of this article.

Notes

1. Jordan (2010) also examines the conditional effect of health care system on indi-vidual spending preferences, though he focuses on social class as the key determi-nant of preferences, rather than the interplay between individual and social risk.

2. We conducted a similar set of tests on the 1996 data set, producing comparable results.

3. Iversen and Soskice (2001) use factor analysis to combine several questions into two dimensions.

4. We do not examine questions on culture, the environment, or law and order since they are tangential to individual-level theories about skill specificity.

5. We also estimated ordered logit analyses with the 5-point scale that produced results with equivalent magnitudes and levels of statistical significance. Results are available in the online appendix.

6. Comparing employment protection legislation (EPL) submeasures aimed at regu-lar workers versus temporary workers, we find both are statistically significant but that the effects of the former on the skill specificity coefficient are stronger, as we would expect given that workers with specific skills are likely to be labor market insiders.

Page 28: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1651

7. We categorize Australia, Spain, and Portugal as employment-independent, despite the presence of a sizeable private insurance sector, because these coun-tries provide uniform benefits to citizens within the public system at the state or national level. The categorization of Australia breaks with that of Jordan (2010), who categorizes it as decentralized and equivalent to the multipayer systems. However, his definition differs from ours, which stresses employment indepen-dence. Our empirical results are robust to the exclusion of these countries.

8. Our results are robust to the exclusion of the interactions with degree. 9. We take the log of income relative to its country mean to normalize the distribu-

tion. Using measures of self-reported class (with or without income) produces very similar results for the contextual impact of individual risk, although the United Kingdom is dropped from the analysis. The results are also robust to using the Erikson–Goldthorpe indicator for class (created from ISCO occupations) and its interactions with EPL and health care system.

10. We use Stata 11’s multiple imputation suite to create five imputed data sets used in Models 2 through 6.

11. We use the sample population weights provided by the International Social Sur-vey Programme in the fixed effects regressions. Stata’s random and mixed effects suites do not permit the use of weights, but cross-checking with results drawn from GLLAMM shows little appreciable difference to their inclusion for the ran-dom effects models.

12. The interaction of EPL and degree by contrast is significant in only one model in the Tables 1 and 2.

13. Both this result and those that follow are robust to removing each country one at a time from the sample.

14. We produce Figures 1 through 3 by adapting Brambor, Clark, and Golder’s (2006) code for the cross-national random effects approach, setting our represen-tative countries to an error of zero.

15. Thus, the constant measures the national average preference of a full-time employed woman of mean age, income, religiosity, union membership, and polit-ical information.

16. We omit industrial aid for the sake of space. The results are similar but slightly weaker, as in Table 2.

17. Our results are similar if we use the mean skill specificity or its coefficient of variation as context variables. However, these indicators are drawn from the sample and potentially measured with error. Our results are also robust to using income inequality and public employment as context variables.

Page 29: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1652 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

18. In regressions excluding EPL, unemployment inequality accentuates the impor-tance of individual risk. This conforms with our understanding that aggregate social risk exacerbates individual risk.

References

Baldwin, Peter. (1990). The politics of social solidarity: Class bases of the European welfare state 1875–1975. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Blanchard, Olivier, & Portugal, Pedro. (2001). What hides behind an unemploy-ment rate: Comparing Portuguese and U.S. labor markets. American Economics Review, 91, 187-207.

Bleckesaune, Morten, & Quadagno, Jill. (2003). Public attitudes toward welfare state policies. European Sociological Review, 19(5), 415-427.

Brambor, Thomas, Clark, William, & Golder, Matt. (2006). Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis, 14, 63-82.

Brooks, Clem, & Manza, Jeff. (2007). Why welfare states persist: The importance of public opinion in democracies. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Cusack, Thomas, Iversen, Torben, & Rehm, Philipp. (2005). Risks at work. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(3), 365-389.

Esping-Andersen, Gøsta. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Estevez-Abe, Margarita, Iversen, Torben, & Soskice, David. (2001). Social protection and the formation of skills: A reinterpretation of the welfare state. In P. Hall & D. Soskice (Eds.), Varieties of capitalism (pp. 145-183). New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

Finseraas, Henning. (2008). Income inequality and demand for redistribution. Scandi-navian Political Studies, 32(1), 94-119.

Hacker, Jacob. (2004). Dismantling the welfare state? Political institutions, public policies and the comparative politics of health reform. British Journal of Political Science, 34, 693-724.

Hellwig, Timothy. (2001). Interdependence, government constraints, and economic voting. Journal of Politics, 63(4), 1141-1162.

Iversen, Torben, & Soskice, David. (2001). An asset theory of social policy prefer-ences. American Political Science Review, 95, 875-893.

Jaeger, Mads Meier. (2009). United but divided: Welfare regimes and the level and variance in public support for redistribution. European Sociological Review, 25(6), 723-737.

Jordan, Jason. (2010). Institutional feedback and support for the welfare state: The case of national health care. Comparative Political Studies, 43, 862-885.

Page 30: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

Gingrich and Ansell 1653

Korpi, Walter, & Palme, Joakim. (1998). The paradox of redistribution and strategies of equality. American Sociological Review, 63(5), 661-687.

Lazear, Edward. (1990). Job security provisions and employment. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(3), 699-726.

Larsen, Christian Albrekt. (2008). The institutional logic of welfare attitudes: How wel-fare regimes influence public support. Comparative Political Studies, 41, 145-168.

Lewis, Jeffrey B., & Linzer, Drew A. (2005). Estimating regression models in which the dependent variable is based on estimates. Political Analysis, 13(4), 345-364.

Lindbeck, Assar, & Snower, Dennis. (1989). The insider-outsider theory of employ-ment and unemployment. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Linos, Katerina, & West, Martin. (2003). Self interest, social beliefs, and attitudes to redistribution. European Sociological Review, 19(4), 393-409.

Lynch, Julia, & Myrskala, Mikko. (2009). Always the third rail? Pension income and policy preferences in European democracies. Comparative Political Studies, 42, 1068-1097.

Moene, Karle Ove, & Wallerstein, Michael. (2001). Inequality, social insurance, and redistribution. American Political Science Review, 95, 859-874.

Nickell, Stephen. (1997). Unemployment and labor market rigidities: Europe versus North America. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 11(3), 55-74.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. (2004). Employment out-look. Paris, France: Author.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. (2006). Employment out-look. Paris, France: Author.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. (2008). Education at a glance. Paris, France: Author.

Pierson, Paul. (1996). The new politics of the welfare state. World Politics, 48(2), 143-179.

Rehm, Philipp. (2009). Risks and redistribution: An individual-level analysis. Com-parative Political Studies, 42, 855-881.

Rehm, Philipp. (2011). Social policy by popular demand. World Politics, 63(2), 271-299.

Rothstein, Bo. (1992). Labor-market institutions and working-class strength. In Sven Steinmo, Kathleen Thelen, & Frank Longstreth (Eds.), Structuring poli-tics: Historical institutionalism in comparative analysis (pp. 33-56]). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

Rueda, David. (2005). Insider outsider politics in industrial democracies. American Political Science Review, 99(1), 61-74.

Saint-Paul, Gilles. (2000). The political economy of labour market institutions. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

Page 31: Preferences in Context: Micro Preferences, Macro Contexts

1654 Comparative Political Studies 45(12)

Scheve, Kenneth, & Stasavage, David. (2006). Religion and preferences for social insurance. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 1(3), 255-286.

Solt, Frederick. (2008). Economic inequality and democratic political engagement. American Journal of Political Science, 52(1), 48-60.

Soss, Joe, & Schram, Sanford. (2007). A public transformed? Welfare reform as pol-icy feedback. American Political Science Review, 101(1), 111-127.

Svallfors, Stefan. (1997). Worlds of welfare and attitudes to redistribution: A compari-son of eight Western nations. European Sociological Review, 13, 283-304.

Bios

Jane Gingrich is assistant professor of political science at the University of Minnesota. Her work focuses on comparative political economy and governance, particularly in Western Europe. She is the author of Making Markets in the Welfare State: The Politics of Varying Market Reforms (Cambridge University Press, 2011) and coeditor of Social Policy in the Small European States, forthcoming with Berghahn Books.

Ben Ansell is associate professor of political science at the University of Minnesota. His work broadly covers issues of inequality in comparative politics. He is the author of From the Ballot to the Blackboard: The Redistributive Political Economy of Education (Cambridge University Press, 2010) and articles on education policy in World Politics and International Organization. Together with David Samuels he has written on inequality and democracy, including an article published in Comparative Political Studies. He is also coeditor of Social Policy in the Small European States, forthcoming with Berghahn Books.