Part IV Bubble, Bubble, Toil, And Trouble Keynes and Financial Instability

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/17/2019 Part IV Bubble, Bubble, Toil, And Trouble Keynes and Financial Instability

    1/2

    I ShareThis

    This is a web-only article.

    Subscribe Nowat a 30% discount.

    The General Theory  and the Current Crisis: A Primer on Keynes’ Economics

    Intro | Pt. I | Pt. II | Pt. III | Pt. IV

    Part IV: Bubble, Bubble, Toil, and Trouble: Keynes and Financial Instability

    B Y A L E J A N D R O R E U S S

    n recent years, the United States has experienced major “bubbles”—

    increases in asset prices fueled by nothing more than the expectation

    that in the future others will be willing to pay even more—in the stock

    market and in real-estate markets. The S&P Composite Index, a broad

    index of stock prices, stood at less than 850 in early 2003, after the

    “dot.com” crash. By 2007, it had ballooned to over 1500. The real-estate

    bubble saw the Case-Shiller 20-City Housing Price Index, the main index

    of U.S. housing prices, more than double from 100 at the beginning of 

    2000 to over 206 in the middle of 2006. Both have crashed since then.

    The Case-Shiller Index fell to less than 150 by January 2008. The S&P

    lost about half its value, down to a little more than 750, between its 2007 peak and March 2009.

    Sources of Market VolatilityIn the words of former Federal Reserve chair Alan Greenspan, a wave of “irrational exuberance” fueled the

    stock market boom. It is easy to believe that daredevil risk-taking, an unreasoning faith that prices will

    keep rising and rising, and possibly testosterone intoxication, are responsible for asset “bubbles.” That

    may not be entirely false, but we chalk up bubbles exclusively to irrational behavior at the peril of ignoring

    the element of individual rationality in joining into a bubble and fueling its growth. In The General Theory ,

    Keynes argued that financial-market instability, in particular, was due not merely to some “wrong-headed

    propensity” on the part of the individuals involved, but to the organization of financial markets themselves.

    Conventional economic theory of asset markets is dominated by the “efficient markets hypothesis.” Proponents of this view argue that the

    price of a financial asset at any given moment reflects all the available information about its true value (e.g., stock prices at any given

    moment reflect all the available information about the value of  a company, or real-estate prices about the value of those properties). When

    new information becomes available, either about a particular asset or about the national or world economy, this causes market participants

    to revalue the asset, and the price goes up or down accordingly. If it were possible to know now that a stock’s price would, say, go up to a

    specific level the next day, people would buy it now in anticipation the rise, bidding up the price today. We would not have to wait untiltomorrow to get to the new, higher price. In this view, stock prices reflect the real values of the assets being traded, so far as the available

    information allows, and price fluctuations on the stock market and other asset markets originate from outside the markets themselves.

    Critics of the efficient markets hypothesis have argued that it underestimates the instability generated within asset markets. Price

    fluctuations are caused not only by newly available information, but by market participants’ reactions to previous price fluctuations and

    prediction of how other participants will react to those fluctuations. Market participants are concerned, in Keynes’ view, not with correctly

    ascertaining the long-term value of an asset, but primarily with guessing what others will be willing to pay for it in the short-run. They buy

    and sell, Keynes argued, not on the basis of “what an investment is really worth to [someone] who buys it ‘for keeps’,” but on the basis of 

    “what the market will value it at ... three months or a year hence.”

    Keynes’ Beauty Contest

    Keynes famously compared financial markets to a strange sort of beauty pageant run by London newspapers in his time. The papers

    published an array of photos, and readers could enter a contest in which the winner was the reader who guessed which faces would be

    chosen by the most other participants. As Keynes pointed out, it would not do to simply choose the photo that one found most attractive,for one’s own tastes might not match those of other entrants. Neither, however, should one choose the photo that one thought other 

    entrants would find most attractive (for they would not themselves be choosing the one they found most attractive). Each entrant would,

    rather, be trying to guess what other entrants would guess about which photos most other entrants would choose.

    In the same way, participants in the stock market, Keynes argued, did not generally attempt to estimate the likely returns from a

    company’s investments (often referred to these days as its “fundamentals”), but to “guess better than the crowd how the crowd will

    behave.” If other market participants are, for whatever reason, buying a particular kind of asset and driving up its price, rational participants

    would decide to buy as well (to benefit from the short-run increase in prices) as long as they expected that the price would continue to rise.

    This makes sense, from the standpoint of an individual buyer, even if the buyer, in some sense, knows better— that is, believes that the

    company in question has bad long-term prospects, that “the market” has overpriced the stock, that other buyers are acting unwisely, and

    so on. For example, I may not think that Springfield Nuclear Power is a very well-run company, but as long as I think other people are

    (unwisely) going to buy its stock, pushing up the stock price, it makes sense for me to buy the stock and profit from these future price

    increases. As more people buy in to take advantage of a crowd-induced rise in prices, of course, they further fuel the growth of the bubble.These price increases, in turn, may induce still others to buy the stock in anticipation of further increases, and so on.

    This process can dramatically unhitch the price of an asset from its “fundamentals,” at least for a time. To show that the price of a stock,

    of houses, or of some other asset has grown out of all due proportion, however, we must have some basis for estimating the “correct”

    value. For stocks, one comparison is the “price-earnings (P/E) ratio” (the ratio of the stock price to the corporation’s profits, on which

    stocks ultimately are a claim). For housing, one can use a ratio between housing prices and “owner’s equivalent rent” (how much it would

    Home

    Subscribe

    ArchiveBack issues

    Reprints

    Recent issues

    2016 archive

    2015 archive

    2014 archive

    2013 archive

    2012 archive

    2011 archive

    2010 archive

    2009 archive

    2008 archive

    2007 archive

    2006 archive

    2005 archive

    2004 archive

    2003 archive

    2002 archive

    2001 archive

    2000 archive

    1999 archive

    1998 archive

    1997 archive

    1996 archive

    D&S books

     About D&S

    For instructors

    Get involved

    D&S blog

     Advertise

    Donate

    Please note our

    new address:

    Dollars & Sense

    95 Berkeley St.Suite 305

    Boston, MA 02116 USA

    Phone: (617) 447-2177

    Fax: (617) 447-2179

    Email us.

    © 2016

    Search  

    converted by Web2PDFConvert.com

    http://www.dollarsandsense.org/subscriptions.htmlhttp://void%280%29/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/promote.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/examcopies.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/1997/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/1999/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2002/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2004/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2009/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2011/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2016/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/reprint.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/subscriptions.htmlhttp://www.web2pdfconvert.com/?ref=PDFhttp://www.web2pdfconvert.com/?ref=PDFmailto:[email protected]://www.dollarsandsense.org/donate.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/advertise.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/bloghttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/promote.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/examcopies.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/about4.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/bookstore.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/1996/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/1997/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/1998/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/1999/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2000/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2001/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2002/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2003/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2004/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2005/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2006/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2007/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2008/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2009/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2010/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2011/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2012/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2013/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2014/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2015/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/year/2016/http://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/reprint.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/back_issues.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/subscriptions.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/index.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/subscriptions.htmlhttp://void%280%29/http://dollarsandsense.org/archives/2009/0809reusskeynespartIII.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/2009/0509reusskeynespartII.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/2009/0509reusskeynespartI.htmlhttp://www.dollarsandsense.org/archives/2009/0509reusskeynesintro.html

  • 8/17/2019 Part IV Bubble, Bubble, Toil, And Trouble Keynes and Financial Instability

    2/2

    cost to rent a similar house), or the “price-rent ratio.” By these measures, U.S. stocks and housing have been grossly overvalued during

    the bubbles of recent years. Economist Robert Shiller, a leading authority on asset bubbles, notes that price-earnings ratios in the mid 20s

    are above historical norms. In 2007, the P/E ratio peaked over 27. (It had peaked at over 44 in late 1999, during the dot.com bubble.) The

    price-rent ratio, likewise, went way above historical norms in 2007. The national average for the 15 preceding years was less than 17. In

    mid 2007, it was nearly 23.

    Bubbles and the Real Economy

    Some people will profit in any bubble. But bubbles do not go on forever. Some end with a fizzle (prices stop rising, and inflation gradually

    erodes the value of the asset); others, with a dramatic crash, as in the U.S. stock market and housing markets did in 2008. As a bubble

    bursts, however, the price may not simply return to the “right” level. Instead, market participants may believe that price declines now mean

    that prices are likely to continue to fall in the future (in effect, this is a bubble in reverse, known as a “panic selloff”). As the price of an

    asset declines, more and more people sell to avoid getting stuck with it, fueling a further decline, and so on. Falling asset prices may, inshort, overshoot the mark in the other direction.

    Keynes was concerned that the “daily revaluations of the Stock Exchange ... inevitably exert a decisive influence of the rate of current

    investment,” that fluctuations in stock prices affect real economic activity. Rising stock prices, which make it possible for a company to

    raise capital cheaply by issuing new shares, have the same effects as falling interest rates. Some investment projects, which would be

    unprofitable if the cost of capital were greater, will be undertaken. Plummeting stock prices, on the other hand, are like increasing interest

    rates. They make it more expensive for companies to raise capital, and may therefore result in decreased real investment.

    The collapse of the stock and housing bubbles reverberated on real economic activity in at least two more ways.

    First, people’s consumption spending is affected not only by their current income, but also their wealth (the value of the assets they own,

    minus their debts, at any given time). As people’s wealth increases, they spend more freely; if their wealth decreases, they curtail their 

    spending. This is known as the “wealth effect.” Keynes described this phenomenon in The General Theory , writing that the “consumption of 

    the wealth-owning class may be extremely susceptible to unforeseen changes in the money-value of its wealth.” The stock-market andreal-estate bubbles certainly fueled increased consumption. Many people simply spent more freely because they felt financially secure.

    Some borrowed against the rising values of their homes, often for consumption spending. As the values of these assets have plummeted,

    people have cut back dramatically on consumption.

    Second, the collapse of the housing market detonated a major financial crisis. Banks had bet heavily on the continued rise in real-estate

    prices. They extended mortgage loans indiscriminately. They bought enormous amounts of mortgage-backed securities (which pay returns

    to their owners based on payments made on an underlying set of mortgages). When real-estate prices plummeted and mortgage defaults

    skyrocketed, banks were left holding assets that were plummeting in value and were basically unsellable. Many curtailed their lending

    dramatically, trying to build their cash reserves as a guard against bankruptcy. The resulting tightening of credit made it difficult for 

    consumers and firms to borrow, further dragging down spending and contributing to the deepening recession.

    Is Regulation the Answer?

    In the parts of The General Theory  focused on financial instability, Keynes argued that the speculative short-term speculative buying and

    selling of securities disconnected financial markets from any real evaluation of the long-term prospects of different investments. While thiswas, in Keynes’ view, harmless enough if the speculation existed on the surface on a “steady stream of enterprise,” it could be very

    harmful if enterprise became the surface on top of a “whirlpool of speculation.”

    It’s easy to see the relevance of this analysis to the current economic crisis. From the 1940s to the 1970s, banks, insurance companies,

    and other financial institutions were highly regulated, and financial crises were relatively rare. Since the deregulation of finance, in the

    1980s, the nonregulation of ever-more-exotic financial securities, and the creation of a vast world of “shadow banking,” they have become

    much more frequent. Enterprise (that is, the real economy) seems to have been dragged down, as Keynes foresaw, into the whirlpool.

    The chain-reaction of excessive financial risk-taking, the eruption of the financial crisis, and the deepest recession since the 1930s has

    resulted in calls for renewed financial regulation. As of yet, only partial and inadequate measures have been adopted, and the largest

    banks are flying higher than ever. Even if there were robust new financial regulation, however, that would not solve the problems that cause

    the Great Recession in the first place—since these problems went way beyond just excessive financial speculation or risk-taking.

    Economic growth in capitalist economies depends on growing demand for goods and services to match the growing productive capacity of an economy. From the late 1940s to the early 1970s, growth in productivity was matched by growth in real wages. Ordinary workers, then,

    created the demand for the goods that they were producing in ever-greater abundance. Since then, however, real wage growth has

    stagnated, while productivity and total output have kept right on rising. The demand for these goods and services had to come from

    somewhere. In part, it came from the wealthy who, enjoying a growing share of the total income, spent more. In part, it came from working

    families that made up for stagnant wages with more hours of paid work (especially by women) and more and more debt. In large measure,

    though, it also came from bubbles! Remember, growing asset prices encourage people to spend more. Unsustainable asset bubbles are

    not just a way that the U.S. economy has failed over the last few decades—they are a way that it has worked .

    This way of structuring a capitalist economy, however, is prone to periodic crises that inflict an enormous human toll. Creating an economy

    that does not depend on the next bubble, however, requires much more than just an overlay of financial regulation.

     A L E J A N D R O R E U S S is co-editor of Dollars & Sense.

    Sources: S&P/Case-Shiller Home Price Indices; Stock Market Winners Get Big Payoff—In Testosterone, Scientific American; RobertShiller, Online Data; Robert Shiller, Irrational Exuberance, 2nd ed.; Where Housing is Heading, Fortune.

    Did you find this article useful? Please consider supporting our work by donating or subscribing.

    Economic

     Affairs

    Bureau,

    Inc.

    converted by Web2PDFConvert.com

    http://www.web2pdfconvert.com/?ref=PDFhttp://www.web2pdfconvert.com/?ref=PDFhttp://dollarsandsense.org/subscriptions.htmlhttp://dollarsandsense.org/donate.htmlhttp://money.cnn.com/magazines/fortune/price_rent_ratios/http://www.econ.yale.edu/~shiller/data.htmhttp://www.sciam.com/podcast/episode.cfm?id=71A2DE32-A0B3-D4CC-9589E741CCEC9431http://www2.standardandpoors.com/portal/site/sp/en/us/page.topic/indices_csmahp/0,0,0,0,0,0,0,0,0,1,1,0,0,0,0,0.html