30
OUT TO SEA: THE DISMAL ECONOMICS OF OFFSHORE WIND REPORT | August 2020 Jonathan A. Lesser Adjunct Fellow

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

OUT TO SEA: THE DISMAL ECONOMICS OF OFFSHORE WIND

REPORT | August 2020

Jonathan A. LesserAdjunct Fellow

Page 2: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

2

About the AuthorJonathan A. Lesser is an adjunct fellow at the Manhattan Institute. As president of Continental Economics, Lesser has more than 30 years of experience working for regulated utilities, for government, and as a consultant in the energy industry. He has addressed economic and regulatory issues affecting energy in the U.S., Canada, and Latin America. Those issues include gas and electric utility structure and operations, generating asset valuation under uncertainty, cost-benefit analysis, mergers and acquisitions, cost allocation and rate design, resource investment-decision strategies, cost of capital, depreciation, risk management, incentive regulation, economic impact studies, and energy and environmental policies.

Lesser has prepared expert testimony and reports for utility commissions in numerous states; for the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission; for international regulators; and for commercial litigation cases. He has testified before Congress and many state legislative committees on energy

policy and regulatory issues. Lesser is the author of numerous academic and trade-press articles and is a contributing columnist and editorial board member of Natural Gas & Electricity.

He earned a B.S. in mathematics and economics from the University of New Mexico and an M.A. and a Ph.D. in economics from the University of Washington.

Page 3: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

3

Contents Executive Summary ..................................................................5

I. The Rise of Offshore Wind .....................................................7

II. Offshore Wind Contracts .......................................................9

III. The Claimed Benefits of Offshore Wind Development .........12

IV. The Reality: Offshore Wind’s Costs Will Far Exceed Its Benefits .................................................................14

V. Claims of Economic Development Benefits of Offshore Wind Are Misleading ................................................21

VI. Adverse Environmental Impacts .........................................21

VII. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations ........................23

Appendix. The Mathematics of Calculating Levelized Cost for a PPA ........................................................................24

Endnotes ................................................................................26

Page 4: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

4

Page 5: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

5

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

Executive SummaryThe generation of electricity by onshore wind turbines has benefited from federal subsidies and state renewable energy mandates for decades. More than 100,000 megawatts (MW) of generating capacity have been construct-ed in the lower 48 states,1 9,000 MW of which came online in 2019. Onshore wind capacity has now surpassed installed nuclear capacity (although because of its “always-on” nature, total electricity generated from nuclear plants far exceeds that of onshore wind) and is exceeded only by natural gas- and coal-fired generating capacity.2

But from an economic perspective, the future of onshore wind is unfavorable. The federal production tax credit (PTC)—which was created in 1992 and today pays qualifying wind plant owners about $23 per MWh of electricity generated for 10 years—began to phase out in 2017. The PTC has decreased by 20% per year, and wind projects whose construction begins after January 1, 2021, will no longer be eligible.3

The demise of the PTC is not, however, the source of onshore wind power’s troubling future. Instead, given the remote location of many wind farms, expensive transmission lines are necessary to bring the electricity to cities and towns; perhaps most significant, local opposition has intensified over the past few years and stymied the development of new projects.4

In response to local pushback, some states are pushing back. In March of this year, for example, New York enacted legislation to overturn the state’s traditional “home rule” deference, which allows local governments to have final say over the types of facilities that can be built. Now, under the Accelerated Renewable Energy Growth and Community Benefit Act, almost all renewable energy development in the Empire State will be approved by a new Office of Renewable Energy Siting. Locations will be denied only if there are valid and substantive reasons; local opposition, however, no longer will be considered a valid reason.5

Nevertheless, the opposition to additional onshore wind turbines, as well as the decreasing availability of high-quality “windy” locations, has led politicians and policymakers to shift their focus to offshore projects. In January 2019, New York Governor Andrew Cuomo called for developing 9,000 MW of offshore wind capacity by 2035, up from his previous order that 2,400 MW be developed by 2030.6 In January 2018, New Jersey Gover-nor Phil Murphy signed an executive order requiring 3,500 MW of offshore wind capacity by 2030.7 A 2016 law in Massachusetts requires that the state’s electric distribution companies procure 1,600 MW of “cost-effective” offshore wind capacity by June 2027 and 3,200 MW by 2035.8 Similarly, Maryland’s Offshore Wind Energy Act of 2013 calls for 480 MW of offshore wind capacity to be developed.9

Proponents of offshore wind energy tout its clean energy bona fides and rapidly decreasing costs (as evidenced by recent competitive solicitations), which will enable states to meet ambitious targets to eliminate greenhouse gas emissions and reliance on fossil fuel and nuclear power. Advocates also see offshore wind as an avenue to create a manufacturing and economic renaissance in their respective states, one that will create thousands of construc-tion jobs and generate billions of dollars of new economic activity.10

As this paper will show, the arguments made on behalf of offshore wind are invalid.

Key Findings Offshore wind is not cost-effective, and the forecasts of rapidly declining costs through increasing economies of

scale are unrealistic. Absent continued subsidies—such as state mandates for offshore generation and renew-able energy credits, which force electric utilities to sign long-term agreements with offshore wind developers at above-market prices—it is unlikely that any offshore wind facilities will be developed. These subsidies, along with the need for additional transmission infrastructure and backup sources of electricity, will increase the cost of elec-tricity for consumers and reduce economic growth.

The actual costs of offshore wind projects borne by electric ratepayers and taxpayers are likely to be greater than advertised. Experience in Europe over the previous decade demonstrates that the performance of offshore wind turbines degrades rapidly—on average, 4.5% per year. As output declines and maintenance costs increase, proj-ect developers will have a growing economic incentive to abandon their projects before the end of their contracts to supply power. In contrast to the strict requirements for nuclear power plants, it is unclear whether offshore

Page 6: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

wind project owners will be required to set aside sufficient funds to decommission their facilities. This will likely mean that electricity ratepayers and state taxpayers will pay to decommission offshore wind turbines or pay high-er prices to keep the projects operating.

The cumulative environmental impacts of multiple offshore wind projects along the Atlantic Coast—including on fisheries and endangered species—may be significant and irreversible. Also, mining the raw materials of offshore wind turbines, especially rare-earth minerals, has significant environmental impacts because those materials primarily are mined overseas, where environmental regulations are less stringent than in the United States. Dis-missing environmental impacts that occur outside the U.S. while championing offshore wind’s alleged worldwide climate-change benefits is hypocritical.

The justification of subsidies for offshore wind based on increased economic growth, new industries, and state job creation is an appeal to “free-lunch” economics. The subsidies will benefit the well-connected few while im-posing economic costs on consumers and businesses at large.

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

Page 7: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

7

OUT TO SEA: THE DISMAL ECONOMICS OF OFFSHORE WIND

I. The Rise of Offshore WindThe first offshore wind facility was constructed in 1991, about one and a half miles off the shore of Denmark, near the town of Vindeby.11 The facility consisted of 11 450-kilowatt (kW) turbines—a total generating capacity of just under 5 MW. Another 10 years would pass until the first utility-scale offshore wind facility was built, at Middel-grunden, off the Danish coast, which consisted of 20 1.5-MW turbines.12 By the end of 2018, the total offshore wind capacity in Europe was about 18,500 MW. Of that total, Britain and Germany accounted for 14,600 MW.13

Utility-scale offshore wind turbines in Europe and the U.S. today are far larger than the 1.5-MW turbines of two decades ago. The largest currently operating turbines are 8.5-MW units manufactured by Vestas. Still-larger turbines are on the horizon: General Electric’s 12-MW turbine, the Haliade-X, is scheduled to begin commercial operation in 2021.14 (A prototype unit, which was installed onshore, began operation in the Netherlands in late 2019.) Haliade-X stands 853 feet high and has turbine blades that are about 350 feet long. In March 2020, Sie-mens-Gamesa announced a 15-MW turbine, with 110-meter blades, which the company hopes to have available by 2024. It will be used by Dominion Energy’s 2,600-MW Coastal Virginia Offshore Wind Project.15 However, it is unlikely that wind turbines can gain further significant cost reductions by exploiting economies of scale: the manufacture of wind turbine components and foundations, as well as their installation, is reaching the limits of current technology.16

The first offshore wind facility in the U.S., Rhode Island’s 30-MW Block Island Wind Farm, was completed in 2016. Located about 4 miles south of Block Island (which is about 9 miles off the coast), the project consists of five 6-MW turbines. The power purchase agreement (PPA) for the project specified that utilities pay a first-year price of $245/MWh for the electricity it generates; that price escalates at 3.5% each year. (By comparison, in 2016, the average wholesale price of electricity in New England was less than $30/MWh; in 2019, the average wholesale price of electricity was $30.67/MWh, reflecting continued low natural gas prices.)17 In 2035, the last year of the Block Island Wind Farm PPA, the contract price will be more than $470/MWh.

The Rhode Island Public Utilities Commission (RIPUC) initially rejected the Block Island Wind Farm because of its high cost and the resulting adverse impacts on electric utility ratepayers.18 RIPUC’s findings were consistent with traditional regulatory principles for electric utilities, which emphasize providing consumers with the low-est-cost power (see sidebar, How State Regulations Favor Renewable Energy). However, the state legis-lature changed the applicable regulatory laws, which then required RIPUC to approve the project.19 (Owing to an exposed underwater transmission cable, the project will be shut down this fall to rebury the cable. It is expected to reopen sometime in May 2021.)

A much larger project, Cape Wind, first proposed in 2005, was to be built off the coast of Martha’s Vineyard (an island off the coast of Massachusetts). That project envisioned 130 3.6-MW turbines, totaling 468 MW of capac-ity. The project attracted bitter opposition, including by many residents of Martha’s Vineyard who complained that the location would spoil their ocean views. Concerns were also raised about adverse impacts on fisheries habitat and endangered species.20 Eventually, unable to obtain financing in a timely fashion, the developer aban-doned the project in 2017.

Page 8: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

8

Nevertheless, the demise of Cape Wind did not stop efforts to promote offshore wind. Currently, seven states have laws or executive orders mandating, col-lectively, about 22,000 MW of offshore wind capacity. An eighth state, Maine, has an Offshore Wind Initiative but no specific capacity mandate (Figure 1).21

In autumn 2019, the New York State Energy Research and Development Authority (NYSERDA) signed 20-year PPAs for two offshore wind projects, totaling about 1,700 MW of capacity: the 880-MW Sunrise Wind Project, to be located off the eastern shore of Long Island; and the 816-MW Empire Wind Project, to be located off the southern shore of Long Island.22 Both projects are slated to be operational by 2024. Sunrise Wind will rely on 110 8.0-MW turbines manufac-tured by Siemens. Empire Wind has not identified any specific turbines, except to state that the project will consist of 60–80 turbines having an installed capacity “of more than 10 MW each.”23 New York also intends to conduct a solicitation for an additional 2,500 MW of offshore wind capacity sometime later this year. More-over, in June of this year, NYSERDA issued a white paper recommending that it procure the entire 9,000 MW of offshore wind by 2035, as set forth under the state’s Climate Leadership and Community Protection Act.24

In October 2019, the Massachusetts Department of Public Utilities (DPU) approved long-term agreements to purchase power from two proposed offshore wind projects: the 84-turbine, 800-MW Vineyard Wind

Project, to be located about 15 miles off Martha’s Vine-yard; and the 804-MW Mayflower Wind Project, to be located about 20 miles south of Nantucket Island.25

(The number of turbines for Mayflower is not known, as it will depend on the size of the turbines that the developers install.) Although construction on the first phase of the Vineyard Wind Project was supposed to begin in autumn 2019 and be completed in 2022, the project has been held up because the Bureau of Ocean Energy Management (BOEM) has not yet issued a final environmental impact statement (EIS).26 Construction on Mayflower Wind is supposed to begin in 2022, with the project operational by December 2025.

Off the coast of New Jersey, the nation’s single largest offshore wind facility—the 1,100-MW Ocean Wind facility—is scheduled to begin construction in 2021 and be online in 2024.27 More offshore wind development is likely as states seek to increase renewable generation. As of December 2019, according to AWEA, solicitations for offshore wind energy in six states totaled almost 6,300 MW of capacity.28 A 2018 report issued by the National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL), which is part of the U.S. Department of Energy (DOE), cited industry forecasts predicting 11,000 MW–16,000 MW of U.S. offshore wind-generating capacity by 2030.29

The most recent long-term forecast of the U.S. Energy Information Administration (EIA) is less bullish, predicting 10,000 MW of offshore wind capacity by 2030, and just over 18,000 MW by 2035.30 That sounds like a lot; but by comparison, EIA projects that, in 2050, coal-fired power plants will generate some 700

Beginning in the early 1980s, state utility regulators required the electric utilities they oversee to perform a detailed economic analysis to determine how best to meet the growing consumer demand for electricity. Although much of that analysis, called “least-cost planning” (LCP) and then “integrated resource planning” (IRP), was designed to promote energy conservation as an alternative to building more generating resources, the ultimate goal was to meet the demand for electricity at the lowest possible cost.

Competitive wholesale electric markets work the same way, but instead of utility regulators determining whether a generating resource will be built, the lure of profitability drives resource choice: the lowest-cost generating re-sources, providing the greatest economic value to the bulk power system, will provide their owners with the most profits.

However, environmental concerns, especially climate change, have changed resource-selection objectives. Rather than lowest cost, regulators and policymakers have imposed mandates forcing consumers and utilities to use the “right” types of electricity, with direct costs given secondary consideration.

The surge in offshore wind mandates in East Coast states is the most recent example of this trend. Although states are adopting competitive solicitations for offshore wind, and although the prices offered in response to these solicitations have fallen, those prices nevertheless are far higher than average prices in wholesale electricity markets. Moreover, the prices offered by offshore wind developers encompass only direct costs of the resources themselves—that is, the costs to build, operate, and maintain the generators. They exclude the costs associated with providing backup power for times when the wind does not blow.

How State Regulations Favor Renewable Energy

Page 9: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

9

terawatt-hours (TWh) of electricity and natural gas plants will generate over 1,600 TWh, compared with 74 TWh for offshore wind.31

II. Offshore Wind ContractsMost states have adopted a system of competitive so-licitations to secure offshore wind projects. However, given that there are only a few offshore wind devel-opers, the level of actual competition is unclear. Suc-cessful bidders sign contracts called power purchase agreements (PPAs), which include annual pricing, performance guarantees, and numerous other factors. Many of the contract terms are kept confidential under the rubric of “competitive market information.”32 As such, the actual costs to build and operate these wind facilities are unknown. This secrecy matters because, as discussed below, developers may well abandon facil-ities that are no longer profitable to operate or demand changes to their contractual agreements.

As of this writing, a total of 13 offshore wind projects have signed PPAs. Only one of them, Coastal Virginia

Offshore Wind, will be built and operated by a regulated electric utility (Figure 2). Although the utilities must purchase the output from offshore wind generators, the contract terms are not approved by them. In Mas-sachusetts, the contracts are approved by that state’s DPU. In New York, the contract terms with regulated utilities have been agreed to by NYSERDA, except for two contracts signed by the Long Island Power Author-ity (LIPA), itself a government-run utility.

In Figure 2, the column labeled “PPA Type” reflects the types of contracts. The simplest PPAs sell the energy generated by the offshore wind farm to the buyer at the contract price. This reflects the agreements for the 30-MW Block Island Wind Farm off the coast of Rhode Island, which began operating in 2016, as well as the proposed Maine Aqua Ventus Project.

The second type of PPA involves the sale of electric-ity and offshore renewable energy credits (ORECs). ORECs are a specific type of renewable energy credit (REC) that can be used by utilities in lieu of actually owning renewable energy generating resources or con-tracting for their output. For example, suppose that a utility expects to sell 100 million MWh of electricity

FIGURE 1.

States with Offshore Wind Mandates

Source: American Wind Energy Association (AWEA), U.S. Offshore Wind Industry, “Status Update,” June 2020

ME

MA

MD

DC

RI

DE

NJ

NY

VTNH

CT

VAWV

OH

KY

TN

AL GA

SC

NC

FL

PA

MN

WI

MO

IL IN

AR

LA

MI

TX

OK

KS

SD

ND

NE

AZ

MT

NM

CO

WY

WA

OR

CA

NV

ID

UT

AK

IA

MS

HI

Page 10: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

10

FIGURE 2.

U.S. Existing and Announced Offshore Wind Projects

State Project Name Capacity (MW) On-Line Year PPA Type PPA Duration (years)

CT, RI Revolution Wind 300 2023 Energy, ORECs 20

MA Mayflower Wind 804 2025 Energy, ORECs 20

MA Vineyard Wind Phase 1 400 2022 Energy, ORECs 20

MA Vineyard Wind Phase 2 400 2023 Energy, ORECs 20

MD Skipjack Wind 120 2023 Energy, ORECs 20

MD US Wind 248 2023 Energy, ORECs 20

ME Maine Aqua Ventus 12 2022 Energy 20

NJ Ocean Wind 1,100 2024 Energy, ORECs 20

NY Sunrise Wind 880 2025 Energy, ORECs 25

NY Empire Wind 816 2025 Energy, ORECs 25

NY South Fork Wind 130 2023 Energy 20

RI Block Island (Deepwater Wind) 30 2016 Energy 20

RI Revolution Wind 400 2023 Energy, ORECs 20

VA Coastal Virginia Offshore Winda 12 2020 na na

Total Capacity 6,150

to its customers next year, of which 20%—20 million MWh—must come from renewable energy resources. Of that 20 million MWh, suppose the regulator man-dates that at least 25% (5 million MWh) be sourced from offshore wind and another 25% from solar photo-voltaics (PV) (Figure 3).

If the utility does not own any renewable generating plants or have existing contracts with renewable gen-erators, it can use RECs to meet the renewable energy mandate. Typically, an offshore (or onshore) wind project creates one REC for each MWh of electrici-ty that it generates. As renewable energy mandates become more specific (e.g., X% of solar, Y% of offshore wind, etc.), they further restrict the ability of an electric utility to reduce the cost of the electricity that it sells to consumers.33

Almost all the East Coast states shown in Figure 1 mandate that their electric utilities purchase increas-ing quantities of offshore wind generation over time. Hence, the utilities must purchase offshore electricity directly or purchase ORECs in the marketplace that are “produced” by these wind projects. The market value of ORECs depends on supply-and-demand conditions. If the demand for ORECs increases faster than the

supply, the price for ORECs will increase. If the supply of ORECs increases faster than the offshore wind man-dates, the price of ORECs will decrease.

To address the potential volatility of future OREC prices, long-term PPAs fix their price, regardless of market conditions. This provides developers with a guaranteed income stream that they can use to secure financing for their projects.

PPA terms vary significantly. For example, in January 2017, LIPA signed a PPA for New York’s first offshore wind project, the 90-MW South Fork Wind project.34

Subsequently, in November 2018, LIPA signed an additional PPA for a 40-MW expansion of that project. But it was not until October 2019 that LIPA released the pricing for the project, with the high costs of the contract surprising some.35 Specifically, the 90-MW project’s initial price will be $160 per MWh, escalating at 2.0% per year over the 20-year contract life.36 The 40-MW expansion project will have a first-year price of $86 per MWh, also escalating at 2.0% per year. Both are expected to begin commercial operation in December 2022. The resulting “levelized” costs in real 2019$ are $142.48 per MWh for the 90-MW project and $87.00 per MWh for the expansion project (for

Source: Individual state utility regulatory commissions and project websites. U.S. wind initially be 248 MW, with a planned build-out to 750 MW.

aProject to be built and operated by Dominion Energy, placed into ratebase.

Page 11: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

11

an explanation of levelized costs, see pp.11–12 and Appendix, pp.24–25).

By contrast, New Jersey’s 1,100-MW Ocean Wind Project will sell ORECs to state electric utilities at an initial contract price of $98.10 per OREC. The two other, much larger, New York offshore wind projects—Empire Wind and Sunrise—are less costly but have very different, and more complex, pricing structures.

The Coastal Virginia Offshore Wind Project (Figure 2) will be developed by Dominion Energy, a utility. In contrast to the other projects in Figure 2, Dominion will recover the costs of the project from its custom-ers under traditional utility cost-of-service regulation. This means that Dominion will earn a regulated return on its capital investment and recover all operating ex-penses of its offshore wind farm.

Comparing Project CostsOffshore wind projects have different start dates, different contract lengths, and different price structures. For example, the Mayflower Wind PPA specifies that all the electricity that the project generates will be purchased by Massachusetts electric utilities at a constant $77.76 per MWh over the entire 20-year contract term, which is expected to begin operations in late 2025. The Bay State’s Vineyard Wind has a different deal. Phase 1, scheduled to be operating sometime in 2022, has a first-year price of $74.00 per MWh, which will escalate 2.5% annually over the entire 20-year contract life. Phase 2, scheduled to be operating sometime in 2023, has an initial price of $68.45 per

MWh, which also escalates at 2.5% annually over its 20-year contract life. New York State’s Empire Wind, scheduled to begin operation in 2025, has a 25-year PPA. The first-year price will be $99.08 per MWh, escalating at 2% per year. LIPA’s two Deepwater Wind projects—a 90-MW project and a 40-MW expansion facility—are supposed to be operational sometime in 2023. They have first-year costs of $160 per MWh and $86 per MWh, respectively, escalating at 2% per year. However, unlike Empire Wind, the Deepwater Wind Project PPAs have 20-year terms.

Because these projects have different pricing terms, contract lengths, and start dates, PPA costs cannot be compared directly. Moreover, comparisons are made more difficult because the products being sold differ. Thus, a PPA selling ORECs cannot be compared direct-ly with one that sells only energy. Nevertheless, one can compare the costs of the 10 projects selling energy and ORECs, using their LCOE, or “levelized cost of electric-ity” (or energy), and LACE “levelized avoided cost of electricity.” EIA provides a simple explanation of these standard metrics:

The levelized cost of electricity (LCOE) rep-resents the installed capital costs and ongoing op-erating costs of a power plant, converted to a level stream of payments over the plant’s assumed fi-nancial lifetime. Installed capital costs include construction costs, financing costs, tax credits, and other plant-related subsidies or taxes. Ongoing costs include the cost of the generating fuel (for power plants that consume fuel), expected maintenance costs, and other related taxes or subsidies based on the operation of the plant.

FIGURE 3.

Illustration of Renewable Generation Mandate

Fossil, 80% Offshore Wind, 5%

Solar, 5%

Renewables, 20%

Other Renewables, 10%

Page 12: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

12

The levelized avoided cost of electricity (LACE) represents that power plant’s value to the grid. A generator’s avoided cost reflects the costs that would be incurred to provide the electricity displaced by a new generation project as an esti-mate of the revenue available to the plant. As with LCOE, these revenues are converted to a level stream of payments over the plant’s assumed fi-nancial lifetime.37

Levelized costs can also be adjusted by inflation. As-suming that the annual generation from the projects remains constant, the “real levelized costs” of elec-tricity are straightforward to calculate.38 The result-ing cost can be viewed as a fixed mortgage payment in inflation-adjusted dollars. For example, the Vineyard Wind 1 Project has a first-year PPA cost of $74.00/MWh, which escalates each year of the 20-year con-tract at a rate of 2.5% (Figure 4). Using EIA assump-tions,39 the real levelized cost (2019$) is $70.14/MWh, and the nominal levelized cost is $89.68/MWh.

Figure 5 compares the real levelized costs in 2019$ for all 10 projects whose PPAs will sell ORECs to util-ities. To be consistent with EIA’s LCOE and LACE es-timates, the levelized costs are all adjusted to reflect an online year of 202540 and assume that there will be no reduction in output from the projects over time. As this figure shows, the levelized costs range between

$55.52/OREC (Mayflower Wind) and $179.27/OREC (US Wind).

The three energy-only projects—Maine Aqua Ventus, South Fork Wind, and the Block Island Wind Farm Project that came online in 2016—have real levelized costs ranging between $138.68/MWh and $327.70/MWh (2019$).

III. The Claimed Benefits of Offshore Wind DevelopmentSeveral drivers are pushing offshore wind development. Onshore wind development is, for one, becoming more difficult, as local opposition to siting massive new wind farms has increased, owing to concerns about health impacts associated with low-frequency noise emitted by turbines,41 loss of productive farmland,42 and adverse impacts on the scenic landscape.43 Moreover, in several East Coast states, there is not enough suitable land on which to site industrial-scale wind farms.

Another reason: the wind offshore is steadier and more frequent than onshore, which means lower costs. This

FIGURE 4.

Levelized Costs of the Vineyard 1 PPA

Source: Author’s calculations

$140.00

$120.00

$100.00

$80.00

$60.00

$40.00

$20.00

$0.00

$/MWh

2022 2025 2028 2031 2034Year

2037 2040

Annual PPA Cost ($MWh)

Levelized Nominal Cost $89.68/MWh

Real Levelized Cost (2019$): $70.14/MWh

Page 13: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

13

is why offshore wind facilities are expected to have higher capacity factors (representing the percentage of time the turbines will be generating electricity) than onshore turbines. Between 2015 and 2019, EIA calcu-lated that the average capacity factor for onshore wind energy in the U.S. was just under 35%.44 For offshore wind, EIA assumes capacity factors of 50%–58%.45

Proponents also see the decreasing PPA costs as ev-idence of rapidly declining costs for offshore wind, which will lead to lower electricity prices. However, as discussed below, PPA prices resulting from compet-itive solicitations likely suffer from what economists call the “winner’s curse”; and the actual costs of these projects are likely to be higher than predicted.

States also tout the economic development benefits of offshore wind, especially new manufacturing indus-tries and jobs. For example, a 2018 study prepared by Bristol Community College, the UMass Dartmouth Public Policy Center, and the Massachusetts Maritime Academy for the Massachusetts Clean Energy Center (MassCEC) estimated that constructing and operating 1,600 MW of offshore wind turbines in the Bay State could create 2,279–3,171 direct job-years. Taking into account the “indirect impacts” of the supply chain, as well as “induced impacts” from employees spending their earnings could bring the total to 6,878–9,852 in-direct job-years.46 A report for the 800-MW Vineyard

Wind Project estimated that it would support 974 con-struction job-years in Massachusetts, along with 80 job-years for each year of operation and maintenance of the project, totaling 3,180 job-years.47

Similarly, a 2017 report commissioned by NYSERDA estimated that the state’s commitment to installing 2,400 MW of offshore wind would create 5,000 new jobs in manufacturing, installation, and operation.48 Not to be outdone, in approving the 1,100-MW Ocean Wind Project in June 2019, the New Jersey Board of Public Utilities (NJBPU) cited estimates that the project would create $1.17 billion in economic benefits and create 15,000 jobs over the project’s 20-year ex-pected life.49 Massachusetts cited claims that the May-flower Wind Project would create more than 10,000 job-years over its lifetime, creating an additional $690 million in gross earnings for the state.50

In September 2019, Virginia Governor Ralph Northam issued an executive order to develop at least 2,600 MW of offshore wind by 2026 and to develop an “energy workforce plan.”51 That executive order subsequently was codified into legislation as the Virginia Clean Economy Act (VCEA), which calls for the state’s two largest electric utilities—Dominion Energy and Appalachian Power—to provide power solely from renewable generating resources by 2045 and 2050, respectively. VCEA includes a requirement that no less

FIGURE 5.

Levelized Costs for Offshore Wind PPAs Selling ORECs

Source: Author’s calculations

$200

$180

$160

$140

$120

$100

$80

$60

$40

$20

$0RevolutionWind - CT

Mayflower Wind

Vineyard Wind 1

Vineyard Wind 2

Skipjack Wind

Levelized 2019$/OREC

$76.07

$55.52

$83.01$71.96

$155.24

$179.27

$98.36

$76.54$85.54

$138.68

US Wind Ocean Wind

Sunrise Wind

Empire Wind

Revolution Wind - RI

South Fork Wind

$75.25

Page 14: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

14

than 5,200 MW of offshore wind power be developed.52 According to its backers, VCEA will create up to 13,000 new jobs per year and $69.7 billion in net benefits for Virginians.53

Thus, states promoting offshore wind development claim that offshore wind development will create thou-sands of new, high-paying jobs and lead to new man-ufacturing industries. All are competing to gain a so-called first-mover advantage because, as one booster claimed, “Whichever states get out ahead and do the best job of managing the early growth and development of their offshore wind projects are going to garner the most investment from the industry.”54 (Of course, only one state can gain a first-mover advantage, which may well turn out to be a “first-mover disadvantage,” as dis-cussed below.)

Finally, states claim that the environmental benefits of offshore wind will advance them along the path to a future free of greenhouse gas emissions. NYSERDA says that the first 2,400 MW of offshore wind will reduce greenhouse gas emissions in New York by more than 5 million short tons per year and provide an annual benefit of $1.9 billion, based on estimates of the social cost of carbon.55 In January 2020, New Jersey Governor Phil Murphy released his Energy Master Plan, which calls for 100% clean energy by 2050. His November 2019 executive order calls for 7,500 MW of offshore wind by 2035 to reduce that state’s approxi-mate 100 million metric tons of greenhouse gas emis-sions.56 Maryland’s 248-MW US Wind Project and the 120-MW Skipjack Project claim to reduce carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions by about 24 million tons over the entire 20-year project life, or about 1.2 million tons per year.57 A 2016 report by DOE claimed nationwide benefits from reduced greenhouse gas emissions worth $50 billion in avoided global damages through 2050 if 96,000 MW of offshore wind were installed, along with $2 billion in avoided costs associated with air pollution emissions and reduced water consumption, among other benefits.58

IV. The Reality: Offshore Wind’s Costs Will Far Exceed Its BenefitsThe combination of lower electricity costs, new man-ufacturing industries and thousands of new jobs, and reduced greenhouse gas and air pollution emissions makes offshore wind sound like a dream. It is a dream: in reality, offshore wind will result in higher electrici-

ty costs, less economic growth, and significant adverse environmental impacts.

The High Cost of Offshore WindAlthough offshore wind development costs and PPA prices have certainly decreased in the last decade, claims that the costs to construct and operate offshore wind fa-cilities will decrease significantly are likely unrealistic. For example, a report by DOE projects that the real level-ized costs for offshore wind projects will fall below $50/MWh (2018$) by 2030.59 That same report projects that the capital cost of the turbines themselves (which con-stitute 30%–45% of total capital costs) will decline to about $1,000/kW by 2030.60 These forecasts are almost surely too optimistic and are inconsistent with EIA’s forecasts, as discussed below. (EIA falls within DOE.) Since the 2008 financial crisis, the cost of capital has been at historical lows, with interest rates even declining to negative values in some countries, such as Germany and Switzerland. Financing costs cannot go much lower.

As the size of offshore wind projects increases, more of the costs are devoted to related infrastructure—foundations, cables, and such. These are mature industries. It is unlikely that increasing the size of cement manufacturers will result in lower per-unit costs; they have likely captured most economies of scale. Increasing the demand for offshore wind facilities will increase the demand for these underlying materials—such as the concrete and steel needed for turbine foundations—and is more likely to increase prices than it is to decrease prices. To the extent that those materials require the use of fossil fuels, efforts to impose carbon taxes or other policies to increase the costs of fossil fuels will increase the cost of manufacturing and transporting the materials needed to develop turbine sites.

Furthermore, as discussed previously,61 the size of wind turbines is close to its physical limits. Hence, opportuni-ties for continued exploitation of economies of scale in turbine technology are also limited.

As part of its Annual Energy Outlook, which provides a long-term forecast of U.S. energy demand, EIA pub-lishes an accompanying report on the projected costs of different types of generating resources. In its most recent report, EIA estimated the real LCOE for offshore wind facilities beginning service in 2025 as between $102.68/MWh and $155.55/MWh, with an average price of $122.25/MWh (2019$).62 EIA estimates that the costs for offshore wind installed in 2040 will be about one-third less, with levelized costs between $74.47/MWh and $105.39/MWh, with an average price of $85.53/MWh (2019$).63

Page 15: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

15

By comparison, the levelized cost of gas-fired com-bined-cycle generating units entering service in 2025 is between $33.35/MWh and $45.31/MWh, with an average price of $38.07/MWh (2019$). For 2040, EIA projects levelized costs for combined-cy-cle units to range between $34.27/MWh and $72.32/MWh, with an average levelized cost of $42.89/MWh (2019$). (The higher real levelized costs in 2040 are the result of higher projected prices for natural gas.)

So, even in 2040, EIA projects that the levelized costs of gas-fired combined-cycle units will still be half the levelized cost of offshore wind generation.

Because offshore wind is intermittent, its LACE value is less than that of reliable resources such as natural gas or coal. EIA estimates the real LACE value for a combined-cycle generating unit to be between $29.32/MWh and $45.22/MWh in 2025, with a capacity-weighted average value of $37.15/MWh (2019$), slightly higher than the capacity-weighted LCOE. For offshore wind, EIA’s estimate of LACE is between $25.36/MWh and $42.76/MWh, with a capacity-weighted average value of $37.29/MWh (2019$). For a combined-cycle generating unit, LACE exceeds LCOE. Hence, for offshore wind, EIA estimates the average LCOE to be more than three times greater than the average LACE.

The upshot: from a strictly economic standpoint, EIA estimates that the economic costs of offshore wind resources will be three times larger than the cor-responding economic benefits, in terms of avoided costs. As such, the more offshore wind that is added, the greater will be the net economic cost to society.

Worse, new research on European offshore wind turbine performance over the last decade shows that performance degrades rapidly over time, especial-ly for newer and larger wind turbines; that means higher operating costs and reduced economic life-times. As more offshore wind is integrated onto the bulk power grid, the costs of addressing wind power’s inherent intermittency will also increase, further increasing the costs borne by electricity con-sumers and requiring new gas-fired generating units to operate on standby or highly expensive battery storage systems.

More offshore wind turbines (as well as increased requirements for batteries for electric vehicles and storage of intermittent wind-generated power) means more rare-earth elements, which historically have come overwhelmingly from China.64 That in-creased demand will likely bring higher prices and higher turbine manufacturing costs.65

Page 16: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

16

The Bureau of Ocean Energy Management (BOEM) has specific requirements for decommissioning offshore wind turbines.a The bottom line is that all turbine com-ponents, from the blades to the foundation, must be removed to a depth of 15 feet below the mud line (what happens to the power cables is unclear).

As no offshore wind facilities have been decommis-sioned in the U.S., the costs to do so are uncertain. One recent article estimated the cost of decommis-sioning Britain’s offshore wind turbines to be £80,000–£300,000 per MW, or about $102,000–$384,000 per MW at current exchange rates.b

Several studies have estimated decommissioning costs for U.S. offshore projects. A 2010 study estimated the cost of decommissioning the canceled Cape Wind Project at $63.8 million for the project’s 130 3.6-MW turbines, which translates into a cost of $136,000 per MW.c A detailed 2014 study for the Cape Wind Project estimated a decommissioning cost of $71 million–$126 million, with an expected cost of $103 million and a salvage value of $23 million.d The net expected cost, $80 million, is equivalent to $171,000 per MW. A 2017 study of decommissioning eight offshore wind farms off the British coast estimated an average cost of over £200,000 per MW.e Because the larger turbines to be built off the Atlantic Coast will be more difficult and costly to remove and dispose of, the per-MW costs are likely to be higher, perhaps much more so. For example, the 12-MW GE Haliade-X turbine, which will be used for the Ocean Wind and Skipjack Projects, has 325-foot-long blades, longer than a football field. Disposal of smaller, onshore wind turbine blades, which today cannot be recycled, is already a problem.f GE admits that the installation of these turbines represents the limits of existing technology;g removal of the tur-bines likely will pose similar challenges.

The approved PPAs for the projects shown in Figure 1 provide little detail regarding decommissioning costs and, especially, the funds that the developers are re-quired to set aside for ultimate decommissioning. This is in marked contrast to nuclear power plants, which

have strict decommissioning requirements and regula-tions governing how much money nuclear plant owners must set aside each year for decommissioning.

BOEM regulations do not specify dollar amounts for decommissioning funds. PPAs typically require some bonding for the projects, especially during the con-struction phase, but the details regarding decommis-sioning funds are sparse and, in some cases, confidential.

Except for the Coastal Virginia Offshore Wind Project to be built and operated by Dominion Energy, all the other offshore wind projects will be owned by single-purpose entities. For example, Mayflower Wind will be devel-oped by Shell New Energies and EDPR Offshore North America, two large multinational companies. However, the actual project owner is Mayflower Wind Energy, LLC, a single-purpose entity. The only assets owned by these companies will be the turbines and undersea cables connecting them to the shore. The same is true for Vineyard Wind, a joint venture of Avangrid and CIP, as well as many of the other projects in Figure 2. Once the projects are no longer economical to operate, the companies can simply walk away, leaving electric ratepayers and U.S. taxpayers to pay the decommis-sioning costs.h

a The requirements can be found at 30 CFR § 585.9–585.913.

b Elaine Maslin, “£10 billion+ Offshore Wind Decommissioning Bill,” Offshore Engineer, Dec. 16, 2019.

c Mark Kaiser and Brian Snyder, “Offshore Wind Energy Installation and Decommissioning Cost Estimation in the U.S. Outer Continental Shelf,” BOEM, November 2010, p. 215, table 12.14. The authors estimated lower costs for an alternative deconstruction alternative, “felling the turbine like a tree, rather than removing it piece-by-piece.”

d PCCI, “Decommissioning Cost Estimation for the Cape Wind Project,” report prepared for BOEM, December 2014.

e Eva Topham and David McMillan, “Sustainable Decommissioning of an Offshore Wind Farm,” Renewable Energy 102, part B (March 2017): 470–80.

f See, e.g., “Electric Power Research Institute, “Wind Turbine Blade Recycling” 2020 Technical Report,” Apr. 17, 2020. In February 2020, the Wyoming House of Representatives passed two bills that would ban the disposal of wind turbine blades in landfills and allow base materials to be buried in abandoned coal mines. See Brendan LaChance, “Bills Aim to Require Recycling of Wind Turbine Blades, Disposal in Abandoned Coal Mines,” Oil City News, Feb. 24, 2020.

g Tomas Kellner, “The X Factor: Here’s What It Takes to Build the Tower for the World’s Most Powerful Offshore Wind Turbine,” GE Reports, May 25, 2018.

h For a discussion of this issue as it relates to onshore wind farms, see William Stripling, “Wind Energy’s Dirty Word: Decommissioning,” Texas Law Review 95 (2016): 123–51.

Who Will Pay to Decommission Offshore Wind Turbines?

Page 17: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

17

Nevertheless, some regulators claim that offshore wind will reduce ratepayers’ electric bills. For example, in its letter recommending approval of the Mayflower Wind Project, Mass DOER claimed that the project’s cost would be below the cost of wholesale market power and provide an average of 2.4 cents/kWh (in real 2019 dollars) of direct savings to ratepayers.66

These claims are overblown; they are also an example of “free-lunch” economics. First, Mass DOER assumptions about real levelized wholesale cost of electricity appear to be overstated. Over the same period as the Mayflower PPA (2026–45), EIA’s Annual Energy Outlook 2020 forecasts declining inflation-adjusted wholesale electric prices in New England, with a levelized generation cost of 5.6 cents/kWh (2019$), one-third lower than the 8.4 cents/kWh value in the Mass DOER letter.67 These far lower forecast wholesale energy prices belie the Mass DOER’s claims of cost savings for consumers.

Second, it is true that adding more high-cost wind and solar resources is likely to drive down wholesale power prices. That sounds like an unambiguous win for consumers. It is not; those lower prices are the result of subsidies that will drive out unsubsidized generators, which I call “Gresham’s Law of Green Energy.”68 Here is how this “law” plays out.

First: in its current Annual Energy Outlook 2020 (AEO 2020), EIA projects greater quantities of wind and solar power and lower real (inflation-adjusted) average wholesale generation prices than its pre-vious forecast (AEO 2019). AEO 2020 projects that average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to an average $48/MWh in 2050.69 AEO 2020 also shows an increase in renewable gen-eration, when compared with its 2019 forecast, and lower generation prices (Figure 6).

Second: as more offshore wind generation is added, the effect will be to lower wholesale prices while tending to drive out unsubsidized generation. Indeed, analyses of offshore wind PPAs often tout the indirect price-suppression benefits of offshore wind power to electric consumers—that is, the benefits to consumers from suppressing wholesale generating prices. Proponents of such price suppression effects argue that the increase in the supply of offshore wind will decrease market-clearing prices by more than the cost of the plant. Supposedly, everybody wins, except for competitive generators that invested their capital. This argument is wrong.

Third: by artificially driving down market prices through subsidies and mandates, states drive out legitimate competitive generators, including

FIGURE 6.

AEO 2020 vs. AEO 2019 Average Wholesale Generation Prices and Change in Renewable Generation

Source: Annual Energy Outlook 2019 and 2020

70

65

60

55

50

45

40

35

30

25

20

2019 $/MWh

2024 20292019 2034 2039 2044 2049

1,000

900

800

700

600

500

400

300

200

100

0

GWh

Increase in Renewable Generation AEO 2019 Avg. Generation Cost AEO 2020 Avg. Generation Cost

Page 18: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

18

renewable generators that operate without the benefit of subsidies and mandates. Thus, any price reductions are temporary. The long-term damage to markets is worse. By driving out legitimate competitors, these policies increase financial risk, as investors don’t know if the plant that they finance will be forced out of business in the future by some other state policy action.

Finally, subsidies reduce the incentive to innovate and lower costs. Thus, in the long run, because competitive generators will be more hesitant to invest and because investors will demand higher returns to compensate for the additional financial risk, electric prices paid by consumers will end up higher than they otherwise would be.

Hidden CostsThe levelized costs estimated by EIA in its Annual Energy Outlook, as well as the levelized PPA prices shown in Figure 5, do not provide a complete account-ing of offshore wind’s costs. A more accurate picture must account for at least three factors: (i) output deg-radation—the tendency for offshore wind turbines to produce less electricity as they age, owing to unexpect-ed equipment failures, which may lead to premature abandonment of offshore wind facilities; (ii) the costs of ensuring that the bulk power system can provide reliable electricity supplies, which becomes more diffi-cult and costly, the greater the amount of intermittent generation like wind is integrated onto the system; and (iii) future decommissioning costs, which are unlikely to be fully accounted for by developers.

Output Degradation The levelized costs published by EIA in its Annual Energy Outlook, as well as the levelized PPA prices shown in Figure 5, all assume that there is no reduction in the amount of power generated by an offshore wind project as its turbines age. In reality, output tends to decrease as generating units age. This can be caused by the need for additional downtime for maintenance. Or, as in the case of solar photovoltaics, by breakdowns in the solar cells themselves. For example, the electric conversion efficiency of solar photovoltaics decreases on average 0.8% per year.70

The output degradation in offshore wind turbines has two key economic impacts. First, the more a project’s output declines over time, the higher its levelized cost. Second, as costs increase as output declines, the relative benefit of continued operation decreases. Eventually, the expected costs of maintaining a project

will exceed its expected revenues, at which time the rational economic response for the project’s owner is to shut down.

The first large-scale study of changes in wind turbine output over time was in 2012 by Gordon Hughes, an economics professor at the University of Edinburgh.71 He examined the performance of onshore wind farms in Britain and Denmark, as well as the performance of offshore wind farms in Denmark. Hughes’s anal-ysis found that the average load factor (i.e., the ratio of a generator’s average annual output to its rated ca-pacity) for offshore wind farms in Denmark fell from over 40%, when the units were new, to less than 15% after nine or 10 years.72 The performance degradation of onshore wind farms in Denmark was much less, but the performance of onshore wind farms in Britain fell rapidly. (Hughes’s onshore turbine findings in Britain were confirmed in a 2014 study that found that the average annual output loss from installed facilities was about 1.6%.)73

In 2020, Hughes published an update of his 2012 study, taking advantage of the much larger quantity of available data.74 This updated analysis found that the performance of larger offshore wind turbines decreased an average of 4.5% per year for turbines installed after 2011. In other words, after 10 years, the average output of these newer offshore wind turbines was just over half the initial output. Hughes’s analysis also showed that the performance of newer, much larger, turbines was far worse than that of older ones. His findings are relevant for the U.S. offshore wind projects because they will be relying on a newer generation of still-larger turbines, including GE’s 12-MW Haliade-X turbines.

Hughes’s study also noted another, less well-recog-nized, problem with offshore turbines: subsea trans-mission lines “are notorious for the severity and length of their outages.” (As noted earlier, the Block Island Wind Farm’s offshore cable was exposed because of erosion. Repairs and reburying of the cable are antici-pated to take at least six months to complete.)

Finally, Hughes’s study shows that the likelihood of major outages lasting at least one month increases by at least 10% per year. In other words, in the first year of operation, a turbine has a 10% likelihood of a major outage. In its second year of operation, that probabil-ity increases to 20%, then 30% in the third year, and so forth, increasing to about an 80% probability of a major outage by the time a turbine is eight years old.

Not only are major outages costly to repair for the owners, but the lost output must be replaced. Given the propensity for major outages, this means that there

Page 19: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

19

will be a greater need for the bulk power systems to increase the quantity of generating capacity held in reserve, as well as higher costs paid by consumers.

Output degradation over time will increase the actual levelized costs of PPAs shown in Figure 5. For example, if output degrades an average of 2.5% per year, the re-sulting increase in a project’s levelized cost is 22% for a 20-year PPA.75 At the 4.5% average annual degradation rate calculated in the Hughes study, the increase in levelized cost is 58%, and, after 10 years, the expected output will be about half the initial output (Figure 7).

Output degradation over time is likely to cause another hidden cost for consumers and taxpayers: the cost of project abandonment.

Project Abandonment and the “Winner’s Curse”

The levelized costs of many of the PPAs shown in Figure 5 are lower than EIA’s levelized cost estimates for offshore wind turbines—in some cases, much lower. For example, as shown in Figure 5, the levelized PPA price of the Mayflower Wind Project is $55.52/MWh, versus the EIA’s average forecast for offshore wind of

$122.25/MWh. This would seem to mean that EIA’s levelized cost estimates are too high. In fact, EIA’s lev-elized cost estimate is likely to be too low.

As discussed previously, EIA estimated a weighted-average LCOE for offshore wind turbines installed in 2025 of $115.04/MWh (2019$). That LCOE estimate is based on an assumed lifetime of 30 years. However, offshore wind turbines are designed only to withstand the elements for 20–25 years.

Using more favorable financing assumptions,76 NREL estimates a lower LCOE cost, $89/MWh (2018$), based on projects installed in Europe and a study of a representative 5.5-MW turbine. Contra Hughes, NREL estimates assume that a wind turbine will never suffer any extended outages.77 Even so, many of the levelized PPA costs are below NREL’s LCOE estimate as well.

This would seem unlikely, especially as most of the cost estimates are based on data from Europe, which has an extensive history of offshore wind, while the only functioning offshore wind farm in the U.S. is the 30-MW Block Island Wind Farm Project. Yet, as discussed previously, the relatively low-cost PPAs are seen as evidence of rapidly declining costs to construct and operate offshore wind projects.

FIGURE 7.

Effect of Output Degradation on Levelized Cost (20-Year PPA)

Source: Author’s calculation

70%

60%

50%

40%

30%

20%

10%

0%0.5% 1.0% 1.5% 2.0%

Relative Increase in Levelized Cost, 20-year PPA (%)

2.5% 3.0% 3.5% 4.0% 4.5%Average Annual Output Degradation Percentage

Page 20: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

20

The apparent contradiction can be resolved by noting two factors. First, as Hughes (2020) points out, the costs of offshore wind projects have declined, owing to economies of scale and low interest rates, but neither trend is likely to continue to any great extent. Second, Hughes (2020) notes that the growing discrepancy between estimated costs and PPA bids may be ascribed to what economists call the “winner’s curse,” a familiar concept in auction theory.78 In brief, auction winners tend to overpay. In the context of one-off wind power projects, “winners” tend to underestimate costs and overestimate benefits, a phenomenon known as “optimism bias.”79

Coupled with the observed annual output degradation rates for offshore wind projects in Denmark, which have been especially acute for the newer generation of large turbines, if the lower-cost PPA auction winners in Figure 5 above have underestimated construction and, especially, ongoing operation costs, they will be more likely to abandon the projects as uneconomic before the full terms of their contracts.80

Abandoned ProjectsMost proposed offshore wind projects in the U.S. are structured as limited-liability, single-purpose entities. This means that the only assets of the company will be the turbines and related equipment. If a project becomes uneconomic to operate under the terms of its PPA, the company can declare bankruptcy. Utility ratepayers and the state’s taxpayers will have no recourse to recover the costs to cover decommissioning the turbines and removing them from the ocean.

Thus, if a project with a 20-year PPA is abandoned after 10 years, the available alternatives will be to renegotiate the PPA and pay more for the project’s output; or decommission the project prematurely. If the former option is chosen, electric utility ratepayers lose. If the latter option is chosen, moneys set aside for decommissioning are unlikely to cover the actual decommissioning costs. These costs will have to shouldered by electricity consumers and, possibly, the state’s taxpayers (see sidebar, Who Will Pay to Decommission Offshore Turbines?).

None of the publicly reviewable portions of the approved PPAs provides specific information about the moneys that project owners will be required to set aside for eventual decommissioning. Although PPAs include discussions of performance bonds when the projects are under construction, discussions about decommissioning requirements are absent.

Ensuring Bulk Power System Reliability

As with all large generators in New England, New York, and the Mid-Atlantic states, the electricity produced by offshore wind farms must be integrated onto the bulk power system that provides electricity to local electric utilities and their ultimate customers. To provide safe and reliable electricity, the supply and demand must be matched continuously by a Regional Transmission Or-ganization (RTO).81 The reason is that electricity-con-suming devices—lightbulbs, motors, the computer I am using to write this report, etc.—are all designed to operate within a narrow band of voltage and frequency. If those bands are breached, the effects can range from flickering lights to a large-scale blackout.

Consequently, power systems have different types of reserves that can respond to changes in supply or demand. For example, many gas-fired generators have the ability to “load-follow”—to have their output ramped up or down to match instantaneous changes in electricity demand (called “automatic generation control”). Other generators are kept on hot standby, equivalent to a car that is running in neutral gear. At a moment’s notice, the generator can be engaged (put into gear) to meet demand.

Unlike fossil-fuel and nuclear plants, wind and solar are inherently intermittent, generating electricity only when the wind blows or the sun shines. Their output cannot be controlled and can change from moment to moment. This inherent intermittency must be compen-sated for by relying more on natural gas-fired generators that can be brought online quickly, on pumped-storage hydroelectric plants, or, thanks to additional mandates and subsidies,82 on expensive battery storage.83

Although small quantities of intermittent wind and solar energy can be accommodated on the bulk power systems at a relatively low cost, these costs increase as greater quantities of these resources are integrated onto the bulk power system. A 2012 study prepared for the Organisation of Economic Co-operation and Devel-opment (OECD) examined grid-related costs for differ-ent types of generating resources in different countries. It estimated that if offshore wind accounted for 10% of the total electricity supply, the resulting grid-support costs would be $20.51/MWh. At 30%, the costs would be $28.26/MWh. For onshore wind, the study estimat-ed the costs to be $16.30/MWh and $19.84/MWh for the 10% and 30% cases, respectively. By comparison, the study estimated the grid-support costs of natural gas-fired generators to be $0.51/MWh.84

Page 21: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

21

Grid-support costs will not be paid by offshore wind developers. Instead, they will be socialized across all electricity consumers through electric transmission rates that are charged by grid operators that coordinate the bulk power system. For the East Coast states with offshore wind mandates, these grid operators are ISO New England, the New York Independent System Op-erator, and PJM Interconnection. Offshore wind pro-ponents (and wind and solar proponents in general) either downplay these costs as de minimus85 or ignore them altogether.

V. Claims of Economic Development Benefits of Offshore Wind Are Misleading As noted earlier, a 2017 NYSERDA report claimed that developing 2,400 MW of offshore wind in New York State would create nearly 5,000 new jobs associated with manufacturing, installation, and ongoing operations, as well as $6.3 billion of new infrastructure spending.86 In March 2020, AWEA claimed that offshore wind power would create 19,000–45,000 new jobs by 2025, and 45,000–83,000 jobs by 2030.87 Offshore wind development, according to the report, would also increase economic output by $12 billion–$25 billion by 2030: “Economic benefits extend beyond initial project expenditures as project spending circulates throughout the economy, delivering additional spending and job support. Capturing the initial and subsequent impacts stemming from offshore wind projects provides a full picture of the economic contributions the offshore wind industry can deliver to the U.S.”88

In approving PPAs for the US Wind and Skipjack offshore wind projects, Maryland imposed specific minimum in-state employment requirements. For US Wind, the state mandated the creation of 1,298 direct construction-period jobs and 2,282 direct operating-period jobs in the state during the project’s 20-year operational contract life, along with a $51 million investment in a new steel fabrication plant. Skipjack will be required to create a minimum of 913 direct construction-period jobs and 484 direct operating-period jobs, plus a minimum $25 million investment in the steel fabrication plant. Skipjack will be required to create a minimum of 913 direct construction-period jobs and 484 direct operating-period jobs, plus a minimum $25 million investment in the steel fabrication plant.89

It is certainly true that subsidizing offshore wind energy development will create jobs for energy developers. It may also lead to new businesses serving the offshore wind industry, especially if, as in Maryland, developers are required to create minimum numbers of jobs and contribute to the development of new manufacturing facilities. When the entire economic ledger is tallied, however, the net impact of renewable energy subsidies necessarily will be lower economic growth and a citi-zenry that is worse off.

The fundamental error is to confuse economic benefits with economic transfers. In effect, claims of enhanced economic growth assume that the money that pays for offshore wind development drops out of the sky. In reality, the money is transferred from ratepayers and taxpayers to developers—there is no improvement in overall well-being. Ignoring or whistling past this reality leads to a preposterous outcome: if one ignores the economic impacts of forcibly transferring dollars from consumers and taxpayers to developers of renew-ables, then the most costly—and least cost-effective—renewable resources will be seen to create the greatest economic “benefits.”90

Given its cost relative to wholesale electric prices, off-shore wind energy will lead to higher electricity prices. Many public utility commissions that have approved offshore wind PPAs acknowledge the cost increases but opine that they will be insignificant. For example, NYSERDA claimed that the average bill impact for res-idential customers from the Empire Wind and Sunrise Wind Projects would be $0.73/month.91 Similar claims by offshore wind proponents based on such cost break-downs (sometimes called the “cup-of-coffee” pricing fallacy) are disingenuous: they ignore the cumulative economic impacts of those higher costs. A $3 cup of coffee sold by Starbucks may not sound like much, but in 2019, Starbucks’ revenues were $26.5 billion and the company’s profits exceeded $5.7 billion.92

VI. Adverse Environmental ImpactsOf the 13 projects in Figure 2, only Vineyard Wind has a completed Draft Environmental Impact Statement (EIS).93 (A supplement to this EIS was issued on June 12, 2020.)94 The Draft EIS discusses impacts on a variety of resources, classifying those impacts as “negligible,” “minor,” “moderate,” or “major.”95 In some instances, the EIS also noted potentially beneficial impacts, such as the creation of artificial reefs for finfish from foundations and scour protection,96 although these

Page 22: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

22

claimed benefits have been challenged by fisheries representatives.97 (Scour refers to the erosion of the seabed surrounding a wind turbine foundation, effectively creating a hole around the foundation.) However, for this category, the Draft EIS also noted potentially moderate long-term impacts from habitat disruption and moderate to major adverse impacts on commercial fisheries and recreational fishing. One key concern: the proposed spacing between the turbines will be too small to allow commercial fishing. Another: the underground cable delivering electricity to the shore may be exposed because of strong tidal currents, as happened with the Block Island Wind Farm Project cable in August 2019.

The Draft EIS ignored the environmental impacts associated with decommissioning. For example, BOEM stated that undersea cables could be retired in place but did not evaluate the potential long-term impacts of deactivated cables, or how such impacts would be monitored.98

The major adverse cumulative impacts determined by BOEM help explain the intense opposition to offshore wind projects by many commercial fishermen. The turbines for the proposed South Fork Wind Farm, off the eastern tip of Long Island, will not be visible from the shore, but fishermen are concerned that the under-water cable will permanently disrupt fishing efforts.99

There is no research on cumulative impacts on benthic (seafloor) species from electromagnetic fields, under-water noise, and potential habitat changes that will encourage the proliferation of nonnative species.100

Nor is there evidence for BOEM’s claim that there will be beneficial “reef effects” from turbine foundations. Perhaps the greatest direct environmental concern, however, is the cumulative impacts of all the proposed offshore wind development along the Atlantic Coast. If all these projects are developed, “temporary” dis-ruption of marine habitats and fisheries for each proj-ect’s construction will mean long-term disruptions for decades.101 This is the primary reason that BOEM has delayed the issuance of a final EIS for the project.102

The Vineyard Wind Supplemental EIS issued by BOEM in June 2020 examined these cumulative impacts of developing 22,000 MW of offshore wind along the Atlantic Coast, which “would result in the construction of about 2,000 wind turbines over a 10-year period.”103 It emphasized the uncertainty of many findings because of lack of data; however, it concluded that there would be “moderate” adverse impacts on bottom fish, finfish, fish habitat, marine mammals (including whales), and sea turtles. It also found that there would be “major” adverse impacts on commercial fisheries, as well as on coastal navigation, scientific research, and military uses.

Unfortunately, as the Supplemental EIS notes, there is little research on such long-term impacts.104 For example, it is not known how construction up and down the East Coast for many years will affect how fish migrate. There is no research on how construction will affect the migration of whales, especially the North Atlantic right whale, of which only about 400 remain.105 Similarly, there is no research on the potential cumulative impacts on migratory seabirds.

Indirect Environmental ImpactsAmong other environmental concerns, perhaps the most significant are the rare-earth minerals required to manufacture turbines. Currently, almost all rare-earth minerals are supplied by China, from mines in Mongolia. China’s environmental laws are far less stringent than those in the West. Hence, by promoting “clean” wind energy, U.S. states are, in effect, outsourcing adverse environmental impacts, including toxic lakes where radioactive material—primarily thorium bound up in mineral deposits—is dumped;106 and high levels of air pollution, “the deadly and sinister side of the massively profitable rare-earths industry that the ‘green’ companies profiting from the demand for wind turbines would prefer you knew nothing about.”107

Moreover, as my Manhattan Institute colleague Mark Mills’s most recent report discusses, the raw materi-als needed to manufacture and install wind turbines dwarf those needed to manufacture and install gas-fired combined-cycle turbines.108 Other than fiberglass blades, which currently cannot be recycled and are already creating disposal issues for landfills because of their size,109 wind turbines are primarily made from steel (70%–80% of the total mass).110 Steel, of course, is made from coal. The largest monopile foundations, upon which about 80% of all offshore wind turbines have been built, weigh over 1,300 tons.111 Each 12-MW GE Haliade-X turbine weighs 2,800 tons, including the 2,000-ton steel monopile foundation.112 To make one ton of steel solely from raw materials requires about 1.4 tons of iron ore and 0.8 tons of coal,113 so each foundation implies about 2,800 tons of iron ore and 1,600 tons of coal. Concrete gravity foundations, the other major alternative to monopile foundations, also require large amounts of materials. A gravity base foundation for a single 6-MW turbine in the North Sea requires more than 5,000 tons of concrete and more than 700 tons of steel.114

The materials requirements for offshore (and onshore) wind turbines to become a major source of electricity in the U.S. will be staggering, especially as states seek to electrify their economies toward the stated goals

Page 23: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

23

of eliminating all greenhouse gas emissions. Along with damage to fisheries, the environmental costs associated with mining and manufacturing rare-earth elements and the vast quantities of raw materials to manufacture and install—compared with other, far more energy-dense, generating resources such as gas-fired generators and nuclear units—mean that states mandating thousands of MW of offshore wind capacity thus will create their own set of environmental problems. Yet offshore wind proponents respond to these environmental issues either by dismissing them as insignificant or ignoring them altogether.115

Ultimately, the environmental benefits of offshore wind, in terms of reduced air pollution and greenhouse gas emissions, are likely overstated, for two reasons. First, to the extent that the intermittent output of offshore wind plants is backstopped with gas-fired generators, the latter will operate less efficiently, producing more emissions and less output, much as a gasoline-powered car operates less efficiently in stop-and-go traffic than on a highway.

Second, offshore wind will tend to displace onshore wind. In a 2017 review, the Maryland Public Service Commission’s independent evaluator, Levitan and Associates, found that the state’s Skipjack and US Wind projects would reduce gas-fired generation in the eastern part of the PJM region (e.g., Delaware, Maryland, Pennsylvania) but tend to reduce electricity generated from onshore wind in the western portion (e.g., Illinois, Ohio).116 The reason: offshore wind will increase the supply of ORECs and offset Maryland util-ities’ need for RECs from other resources, primarily onshore wind. Hence, REC prices will tend to fall, re-ducing the economic value of onshore wind generation.

This Levitan review also projected that with less onshore wind, more coal-fired generation would take place in the western PJM, offsetting emissions reduc-tions. The estimated net emissions reductions would be only about 19,000 tons per year because of these offset-ting impacts on other electric generating plants, versus the projected 1.2 million tons per year claimed by the projects’ developers.117 The Skipjack Project, accord-ing to the review, would result in an average decrease in sulfur dioxide (SO2) emissions of a mere 1.6 tons/year and reduce emissions of oxides of nitrogen (NOx) by only 3.4 tons/year over the project’s lifetime.118 By comparison, U.S. emissions of SO2 and NOx from elec-tric generating plants in 2018 were 1.26 million tons and 1.02 million tons, respectively. Finally, the Levitan review estimated that the project would reduce CO2 emissions an average of 6,384 tons/year.119 By compar-ison, total U.S. energy-related CO2 emissions in 2019 were estimated to be 5.1 billion tons.120 Even if one ac-

cepted the estimated annual reduction of 1.2 million tons of CO2 from the US Wind and Skipjack Projects, that represents 0.02% of 2019 U.S. energy-related CO2 emissions.

VII. Conclusions and Policy RecommendationsAs in the popular game show Jeopardy!, offshore wind is an “answer” in search of a policy question. The current projects slated to be built off the Atlantic Coast will raise the cost of electricity and reduce the grid’s reliability, forcing bulk power systems to invest ad-ditional resources in backup generation resources or high-cost battery storage. Claims that offshore wind costs are declining rapidly, based on PPA prices, fail to consider that the winning bidders may be seriously underestimating their costs over time. The experience with offshore wind projects in Europe over the last decade has demonstrated that newer, larger turbine technologies have been accompanied by significant re-liability and maintenance issues, causing the amount of electricity that these turbines generate each year to decline by almost half over 10 years.

The likely declines in output will reduce the revenues and profitability of these facilities over time. This may lead developers to abandon the facilities before the term of their PPAs, leaving ratepayers and taxpayers to pay for decommissioning and dismantling the units. Even if the units do operate for their full claimed economic lifetimes, it is unclear whether they will be required to set aside sufficient funds to pay for decommissioning.

Claimed environmental benefits from reduced pollution and reduced greenhouse gas emissions fail to account for offsetting impacts in wholesale electricity markets and fail to account for the increase in pollution from more inefficient use of gas-fired generators that will be required to provide backup power to compensate for the inherent intermittency of wind power. In any event, offshore wind development will make no meaningful contributions to reductions in U.S. emissions of greenhouse gases, nor will it have any measurable impacts on world climate.

The claimed economic development benefits of offshore wind are also overstated, as proponents ignore the adverse economic impacts on existing consumers and businesses from higher electricity costs. Forcing offshore wind developers to hire minimum numbers of workers and contribute to the construction of new manufacturing facilities, as Maryland has done, is

Page 24: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

24

absurd. Ultimately, the economic benefits of subsidized offshore wind development will accrue to the few, at the expense of the many.

In view of all the shortcomings, this report recommends that states:

• End subsidized development of offshore wind facilities, including the requirement that electric utilities purchase increasing quantities of offshore wind renewable energy credits. Developers that wish to construct and operate offshore wind facilities should bear the investment risks, rather than be allowed to transfer those risks to electricity consumers.

• Require offshore wind developers to provide full information to the public about anticipated decommissioning costs and post surety bonds that will fully fund those costs. As decommissioning cost estimates change over time, project developers should be required to adjust their contributions to

decommissioning funds, as is done for nuclear power plants and for individual pipelines that are subject to asset retirement obligations.

• Require offshore wind developers to pay for the additional costs of backup generating resources needed to compensate for the inherent intermittency of their wind facilities. These developers should also be required to pay for the costs to interconnect their projects to the bulk power system, rather than having those costs be paid for by electricity customers.

• Focus on ensuring that electricity demand is met with the most efficient resources possible, rather than resources that will create set numbers of jobs. States that wish to emphasize clean energy resources should ensure that reliable nuclear power generat-ing units can be constructed, especially new modular technologies that will reduce financial risks and use natural forces such as gravity to bring a reactor to a safe shutdown.121

Calculating the levelized cost of a PPA involves three steps:

1. Estimate the overall stream of annual nominal or real costs associated with the PPA.

2. Determine the net present value of that annual stream of costs.

3. Calculate the LCOE as the value that, when multiplied by each year’s output, equals the net present value of the stream of annual costs.

Assume a PPA that will last T years. The output to be sold in each year t is Qt at a nominal price Pt. The dis-count rate, i, is just the weighted average cost of capital.

Item (3) implies that:

(A-1)

Solving equation (A-1) for LCOE, we have:

(A-2)

Appendix. The Mathematics of Calculating Levelized Cost for a PPA

Page 25: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

25

There are two cases to consider.

Note that, if d = 0, that is, there is no output degradation over time, then (A-7) simplifies to the denominator in (A-3).

Case 2: Qt degrades at a constant percentage rate, d, such that:

(A-4)

where l = (1 - d) / (1 + i). Applying a bit of algebra, it turns out that

(A-6)

Case 1: The annual output level, Qt, is constant. If so, then equation (A-2) simplifies as follows:

(A-3)

where CRF is the “capital recovery factor.” Hence, in the case of constant annual output, the LCOE is just the annualized “mortgage payment” divided by the annual output.

Hence, we can rewrite the denominator of (A-2) as follows:

(A-5)

Hence, we can rewrite (A-5) as:

(A-7)

Page 26: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

26

1 American Wind Energy Association (AWEA), Wind Facts at a Glance, accessed July 27, 2020.2 U.S. Energy Information Administration (EIA), “Electricity Monthly Update,” Apr. 24, 2020. EIA’s electricity data browser shows net generation by source.3 On Dec. 20, 2019, the president signed the Taxpayer Certainty and Disaster Relief of 2019, which extended PTC eligibility for new wind facilities that

begin construction by Dec. 31, 2020, but need not be operational until Jan. 1, 2023. There have been repeated efforts by some in Congress to extend this deadline further. Those efforts are sure to continue.

4 See, e.g., Robert Bryce, “Wind Power Is an Attack on Rural America,” Los Angeles Times, Feb. 23, 2017; “Angry U.S. Landowners Are Killing Off Renewable Energy Projects,” New York Post, Mar. 7, 2020.

5 New York Governor Andrew Cuomo signed emergency budget legislation to create a new Office of Renewable Energy Development within the Department of Economic Development. Under this legislation, local municipalities will no longer be able to oppose development of industrial-scale wind and solar projects. See New York State Energy Research and Development Authority (NYSERDA), “New York State Announces Passage of Accelerated Renewable Energy Growth and Community Benefit Act as Part of 2020–2021 Enacted State Budget,” Apr. 3, 2020; Jonathan Lesser, “Andrew Cuomo’s Bid to Ram Industrial Wind, Solar Plants Down Locals’ Throats,” New York Post, Mar. 30, 2020.

6 Joshua Hill, “New York Governor Cuomo Announces Mammoth Offshore Wind & Distributed Solar Increases,” Clean Technica, Jan. 16, 2019. 7 Executive Order No. 8, Jan. 31, 2018. 8 The 2016 legislation is called “An Act to Promote Energy Diversity.” It was followed in 2018 by “An Act to Advance Clean Energy.” See Massachusetts

Clean Energy Center, Offshore Wind, undated. 9 “Offshore Wind Energy in Maryland,” Maryland Energy Administration. 10 A 2014 report prepared for the U.S. Department of Energy (DOE), for example, estimated that construction of 16,000 MW of offshore wind capacity

by 2030 would create more than 18,000 full-time-equivalent jobs (FTEs) and that operating and maintaining that capacity would create more than 8,600 FTEs. See DOE, “Economic Impacts of Offshore Wind,” January 2014, table 3; E2, “Offshore Wind: Generating Economic Benefits on the East Coast,” August 2018. A report prepared by AWEA predicts 45,000–83,000 jobs by 2030. See AWEA, “U.S. Offshore Wind Power Economic Impact Assessment,” March 2020.

11 European Wind Energy Association (EWEA), “Wind in Our Sails,” 2011, p. 11.12 The Vindeby facility was decommissioned in 2017. 13 WindEurope, “Offshore Wind in Europe—Key Trends and Statistics 2018,” February 2019.14 The 138-MW Skipjack Wind Project, to be located off the Delaware coast, will use these turbines.15 Eize de Vries, “How SGRE Upped the Offshore States with 14MW+ Turbine and 222m Rotor,” Windpower Monthly, May 19, 2020; Adnan Durakovic, “15

MW Siemens Gamesa Turbines for Offshore Wind Farm,” OffshoreWIND.biz, May 26, 2020.16 Vaclav Smil, “Wind Turbines Just Keep Getting Bigger, but There’s a Limit,” IEEE Spectrum, Oct. 22, 2019.17 ISO New England (ISO-NE), “New England Power Grid 2019–2020 Profile,” Feb. 27, 2020.18 Rhode Island Public Utilities Commission, In Re: Review of Proposed Town of New Shoreham Project Pursuant to R.I. Gen. Laws § 39-26.1-7, Docket

No. 4111, Report and Order, Apr. 2, 2010, at 65. 19 State of Rhode Island and Providence Plantations Public Utilities Commission, In Re: Review of Amended Power Purchase Agreement Between

Narragansett Electric Company D/B/A National Grid and Deepwater Wind Block Island, LLC Pursuant to R.I. Gen. Laws § 39-26.1-7, Docket No. 4185, Report and Order, Aug. 16, 2010.

20 Kathryn Seelye, “After 16 Years, Hopes for Cape Cod Wind Farm Float Away,” New York Times, Dec. 19, 2017. In 2010, I testified on behalf of the Alliance to Protect Nantucket Sound regarding the economics of the project and the specific costs of the proposed PPAs between Cape Wind and Massachusetts electric utilities.

21 AWEA, “U.S. Offshore Wind Industry—Status Update,” October 2019. In June 2019, Maine Governor Janet Mills signed legislation requiring the Maine Public Utilities Commission to approve a power purchase contract for Maine Aqua Ventus, an (up to) 12-MW floating offshore wind farm. The governor also announced the Offshore Wind Initiative to investigate opportunities for offshore wind development in the Gulf of Maine. See Office of Governor Janet Mills, “Governor Mills Signs Bill to Advance Offshore Wind Demonstration Project, Announces Maine Offshore Wind Initiative,” June 19, 2019.

22 Maps of the locations for the Sunrise and Empire projects can be downloaded from NYSERDA’s Map Library.23 Equinor, “Equinor Offshore Wind Bid Wins in New York State,” press release, July 18, 2019. Currently, the only wind turbine with an installed capacity

greater than 10 MW is the GE Haliade X-12, with an installed capacity of 12 MW. That turbine is not yet in service.24 NYSERDA, “White Paper on Clean Energy Standard Procurements to Implement New York’s Climate Leadership and Community Protection Act,” Case

No. 15-E-0302, June 18, 2020.25 Colin Young, “Mayflower Wind Picked for 800-Megawatt Project Off of Nantucket Island, Martha’s Vineyard,” WBUR, Oct. 30, 2019.26 Senator Sheldon Whitehouse (D., RI), who in July 2019 cosponsored legislation for a nationwide carbon tax, is a vocal critic of Vineyard Wind. See

Benjamin Storrow and Heather Richards, “Top Climate Hawk Bashes First Big Offshore Wind Project,” E&E News, Nov. 15, 2019.27 In the Matter of the Board of Public Utilities Offshore Wind Solicitation for 1,100 MW—Evaluation of the Offshore Wind Applications, Docket No.

QO18121289, Order, June 21, 2019.28 AWEA, “U.S. Offshore Wind Industry—Status Update,” June 2020.29 DOE, “2018 Offshore Wind Technologies Market Report,” 2018, p. xi.30 EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020, table 16. Curiously, the EIA forecast shows no additional offshore wind capacity after 2035.31 Ibid., table 8. 32 E.g., see PPA between NStar Electric Company and Mayflower Wind, Jan. 10, 2020.33 In states with restructured electric industries, competitive firms are allowed to sell electricity directly to retail consumers. REC mandates also apply to

these firms.34 LIPA Fact Sheet, “LIPA Procures Energy from New York’s First Offshore Wind Farm,” Oct. 28, 2019.35 Mark Harrington, “South Fork Wind Farm More Costly than Larger State Projects, LIPA Says,” Newsday, Oct. 28, 2019.

Endnotes

Page 27: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

27

36 Ibid.37 EIA, Today in Energy, “EIA Uses Two Simplified Metrics to Show Future Power Plants’ Relative Economics,” Mar. 29, 2018.38 The Appendix to this report provides the mathematics for calculating levelized costs.39 For its analysis, EIA assumes a real weighted average cost of capital (WACC) of 4.30%. The agency also assumes an average annual inflation rate of

2.3%.40 The calculation is performed by converting all annual contract prices to 2019$ and then adjusting the present value of those prices to reflect an assumed

start date of 2025. EIA’s offshore wind LCOE estimates are based on the agency’s estimates of project costs, not actual PPA contract prices. As discussed below, the lower PPA contract prices do not mean that EIA’s cost figures are too high. Rather, they may be evidence of what economists call the “winner’s curse.”

41 A discussion of the health impacts associated with low-frequency sound emitted by wind turbines is beyond the scope of this report. For a discussion, see Robert McCunney et al., “Wind Turbines and Health: A Critical Review of the Scientific Literature,” Journal of Occupational and Environmental Medicine 56, no. 11 (November 2014): 108–30; Alice Freiberg et al., “Health Effects of Wind Turbines on Humans in Residential Settings: Results of a Scoping Review,” Environmental Research 169 (February 2019): 446–63.

42 For examples of opposition in upstate New York, see Sara Jerving, “Proposed Wind Turbines Generating Conflict,” Investigative Post, Feb. 13, 2019; Joseph Goldstein, “A Climate Conundrum: The Wind Farm vs. the Eagle’s Nest,” New York Times, June 25, 2019.

43 See, e.g., Jenna Portnoy, “After Coal, Appalachia to Wind Farm Proposal: ‘It Is Insulting, Really,’ ” Washington Post, Aug. 20, 2015; Scott McFetridge, “New Rebellion Against Wind Energy Stalls or Stops Projects,” Seattle Times, Feb. 21, 2018; Robert Bryce, “Hawaii Protests Show Why Wind Energy Can’t Save Us from Climate Change,” The Hill, Nov. 13, 2019; Samantha Gross, “Renewables, Land Use, and Local Opposition in the United States,” Brookings Institution, January 2020.

44 EIA, Electric Power Monthly, May 2020, table 6.07.B.45 EIA, Assumptions to AEO 2020, Renewable Fuels Module, January 2020, p. 7.46 Paul Vigeant et al., “2018 Massachusetts Offshore Wind Workforce Assessment,” report prepared for MassCEC, May 2018, p. v. One job-year equals

one year of full-time equivalent employment.47 David R. Borges et al., “Proposed Vineyard Wind Offshore Wind Energy Project: Estimated Contribution to Employment and Economic Development

(800MW),” UMass Dartmouth, March 2018. 48 NYSERDA, “The Workforce Opportunity of Offshore Wind in New York,” Report No. 17-25t, December 2017. 49 State of New Jersey, Governor Phil Murphy, “New Jersey Board of Public Utilities Awards Historic 1,100 MW Offshore Wind Solicitation to Ørsted’s

Ocean Wind Project,” June 21, 2019. The actual award is: In the Matter of the Board of Public Utilities Offshore Wind Solicitation for 1,100 MW-Evaluations of the Offshore Wind Applications, Docket No. Q018121289, Order, June 21, 2019.

50 “Project Selected to Increase Offshore Wind Energy in the Commonwealth,” Mass.gov, Oct. 10, 2019.51 Commonwealth of Virginia, Office of the Governor, Executive Order 43, Sept. 17. 2019.52 Commonwealth of Virginia, HB 1526.53 Virginia Clean Economy, undated.54 Frederick Hewett, “Massachusetts Could Win Big in Offshore Wind Energy,” WBUR, Cognoscenti, Mar. 5, 2018.55 NYSERDA, “Benefits of Offshore Wind,” undated.56 State of New Jersey, Office of the Governor, Executive Order 92, Nov. 19, 2019. 57 In the Matter of the Applications of U.S. Wind, Inc., and Skipjack Offshore Energy, LLC for a Proposed Offshore Wind Project(s) Pursuant to the Maryland

Offshore Wind Energy Act of 2013, Order No. 88192, May 11, 2017, Appendix A (US Wind) and Appendix B (Skipjack). US Wind will eventually build out to 750 MW.

58 DOE, “National Offshore Wind Strategy,” September 2016, p. viii.59 DOE, “2018 Offshore Wind Technologies Market Report,” August 2019, p. 57.60 Ibid., p. 60. A proprietary forecast by Bloomberg cited in this report shows far more aggressive cost reductions for turbines, to less than $700/kW by

2025. The Bloomberg forecast is not supported by EIA’s cost forecast.61 Smil, “Wind Turbines Just Keep Getting Bigger.”62 EIA, “Levelized Cost and Levelized Avoided Cost of New Generation Resources,” January 2020, p. 8, table 2. 63 Ibid., p. 20.64 USA Rare Earth is currently developing a project to extract rare earths from Round Top Mountain, located east of El Paso, Texas; see Jim Vinoski, “The

U.S. Needs China for Rare Earth Materials: Not for Long, Thanks to This Mountain,” Forbes, Apr. 7, 2020.65 Jan Dodd, “Rethinking the Use of Rare-Earth Elements,” Windpower Monthly, Nov. 30, 2018.66 Re: Petitions for Approval of Proposed Long-Term Contracts for Offshore Wind Energy Pursuant to Section 83C of Chapter 188 of the Acts of 2016,

D.P.U. 20-16, 20-17, 20-18, Letter from Robert Hoagland, Attorney for Massachusetts DOER to Mark Marini, Secretary, Department of Public Utilities, Feb. 11, 2020, p. 4.

67 The calculation is based on the forecast generation price (energy and capacity) for New England, as shown in table 54.7 of AEO, less EIA’s forecast of retail level taxes on electricity.

68 Jonathan Lesser, “Gresham’s Law of Green Energy,” Regulation (Winter 2010–11): 12–18.69 EIA, Annual Energy Outlook 2020, table 8.70 Dirk Jordan and Sarah Kurtz, “Photovoltaic Degradation Rates—An Analytical Review,” NREL, June 2012.71 Gordon Hughes, “The Performance of Wind Farms in the United Kingdom and Denmark,” Renewable Energy Foundation, London, 2012, p. 11.72 Hughes’s results were challenged in 2013; see David Milborrow, “No Big Drop in Performance as Turbines Get Older,” Windpower Monthly, Mar. 4, 2013.

Milborrow speculated that the decline in observed offshore wind performance was the result of less wind, not more breakdowns of equipment. Another challenge to Hughes’s findings is Chris Goodsall, “Wind Turbines—Going Strong 20 Years On,” The Ecologist, Jan. 3, 2014. Hughes responded, arguing that Goodsall did not perform any statistical analysis and considered a narrow subset of wind resources. See Gordon Hughes, “Response from Professor Gordon Hughes to Previous Posting,” Carbon Commentary, Jan. 5, 2014.

Page 28: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind

28

73 Iain Staffell and Richard Green, “How Does Wind Farm Performance Decline with Age?” Renewable Energy 66 (2014): 775–86.74 Gordon Hughes, “The Performance of Wind Generation in Denmark Revisited,” Renewable Energy Foundation, London, forthcoming October 2020.75 The Appendix to this report provides the underlying mathematics that determine the change in levelized cost relative to a decrease in output.76 EIA’s real weighted average cost of capital, 4.3%, implies a capital recovery factor of 6.6% for a 25-year life, whereas NREL assumes a slightly lower

6.5% capital recovery factor. NREL also assumes a 5.01% nominal discount rate, equivalent to a 2.65% real discount rate (based on EIA’s average inflation rate of 2.31%), whereas EIA’s real discount rate is 4.30%. The lower the real discount rate, the lower the levelized cost.

77 Tyler Stehly and Philipp Beiter, “2018 Cost of Wind Energy Review,” NREL, December 2019.78 For a discussion, see Richard Thayer, “The Winner’s Curse,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 2, no. 1 (Winter 1988): 191–202.79 See, e.g., Bent Flyvbjerg, “Survival of the Unfittest: Why the Worst Infrastructure Gets Built and What We Can Do About It,” Oxford Review of Economic

Policy 25, no. 3 (Autumn 2009): 344–67. It may also be the case that PPA developers have assumed that the production tax credit (PTC), which is scheduled to expire on Dec. 31, 2020, will be renewed ad infinitum by Congress.

80 Hughes (2020) provides a detailed financial analysis of the Kriegers Flak project, which is expected to be operational by the end of 2021. Vattenfall, the developer, bid a flat nominal price of €49.9/MWh (about US$58/MWh, at the current exchange rate), equivalent to a real levelized cost of $39/MWh. Hughes concludes that the break-even price for the project is at least one-third too low and, if the project’s output declines at an average rate of 4.5%/year, two-thirds too low.

81 RTOs coordinate generating facilities and operate the high-voltage transmission grid; together, this is referred to as the “bulk power system.” The PJM Interconnection (PJM) encompasses 13 Mid-Atlantic states, plus the District of Columbia; ISO-NE, which oversees the bulk power system for the New England states; and the New York ISO, which does the same for New York State. All have separate markets for energy, capacity, and what are called “ancillary services.” Capacity can be thought of as a measure of “iron in the ground” that is available to meet electricity demand. Ancillary services include other components of the bulk power system, such as reserves of generation that can be available on a moment’s notice, ensuring that the system operates safely, reliably, and within specific voltage and frequency parameters. For simplicity, I refer to the combined products of electric energy (measured in MWh), capacity (measured in MW), and ancillary services as “energy.” For an additional, nontechnical discussion, see Jonathan Lesser and Leonardo Giacchino, Fundamentals of Energy Regulation, 3rd ed. (Reston, VA: Public Utilities Reports, 2019), chap. 18.

82 E.g., in 2018, NYSERDA approved a battery storage goal of 1,500 MW by 2025 (NYSERDA, “Governor Cuomo Announces Dramatic Increase in Energy Efficiency and Energy Storage,” Dec. 13, 2018). That same year, Massachusetts approved legislation mandating 1,000 MWh of battery storage by Dec. 31, 2025 (“Energy Storage Initiative,” Mass.gov). California’s 2013 battery storage mandate calls for 1,325 MW by the end of 2020 (CPUC, Decision Adopting Energy Storage Procurement Framework and Design Program, Decision 13-10-1040, Oct. 17, 2013). In total, six states have such mandates.

83 Current estimates of the capital costs for utility-scale battery storage are about $400/MWh for four hours of storage, with forecast costs decreasing to about $150/MWh (2018$) by 2050. Those costs far exceed current and projected wholesale prices of electricity. See Wesley Cole and A. Will Frazier, “Cost Projections for Utility-Scale Battery Storage,” NREL, June 2019.

84 Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, “Nuclear Energy and Renewables: System Effects in Low-Carbon Electricity Systems,” 2012, p. 18. See also Lion Hirth, Falko Ueckerdt, and Ottmar Edenhofer, “Why Wind Is Not Coal: On the Economics of Electricity Generation,” Energy Journal 37, no. 3 (July 2016): 1–27, which includes a literature review of grid integration costs.

85 E.g., NYSERDA estimated that the increased cost for the average residential customer would be $0.68/month. 86 NYSERDA, “The Workforce Opportunity of Offshore Wind in New York,” Report 17-25t, December 2017.87 AWEA, “U.S. Offshore Wind Power Economic Impact Assessment,” March 2020.88 Ibid., p. 6.89 In the Matter of the Applications of U.S. Wind, Inc., and Skipjack Offshore Energy, LLC for a Proposed Offshore Wind Project(s) Pursuant to the Maryland

Offshore Wind Energy Act of 2013, Order No. 88192, May 11, 2017, Appendix A (US Wind) and Appendix B (Skipjack).90 For additional discussion, see Jonathan Lesser, “Renewable Energy and the Fallacy of Green Jobs,” Electricity Journal 23, no. 7 (August/September

2010): 45–53.91 NYSERDA, “Launching New York’s Offshore Wind Industry: Phase 1 Report,” October 2019, p. ii.92 Starbucks Corporation, FY19 Annual Report, p. 24.93 BOEM, “Vineyard Wind Offshore Wind Energy Project Draft Environmental Impact Statement,” December 2018. 94 BOEM, “Vineyard Wind 1 Offshore Wind Energy Project: Supplement to the Draft Environmental Impact Statement,” June 2020 (Vineyard Wind

Supplemental EIS). BOEM states that it intends to issue a final decision on project approval by December 2020.95 Vineyard Wind Draft EIS, pp. ES-6–ES-8.96 Ibid. 97 Letter from Annie Hawkins, Responsible Offshore Development Alliance (RODA), to Dr. Walter Cruickshank, BOEM, Feb. 22, 2019 (RODA letter, Feb.

22, 2019), p. 12 (a copy of this letter is available on request from the author). For a discussion of scour, see “Offshore Wind Farm Developments and Scouring Effects,” Hydro International, Oct. 15, 2008.

98 RODA letter, Feb. 22, 2019, p. 8. 99 Thomas Zambito, “Energy Ratepayers Bankrolling Offshore Wind Farm Opposed by the Long Island Fishing Community,” Rockland/Westchester Journal

News, Sept. 12, 2018.100 RODA letter, Feb. 22, 2019, pp. 4–5.101 Alex Kuffner, “Troubling Questions, Concerns Raised About Offshore Wind Farms,” Providence Journal, Aug. 21, 2019. 102 As of this writing, there are no published EIS documents for the other offshore wind projects listed in Fig. 2.103 Vineyard Wind Supplemental EIS, p. ES-2.104 BOEM has published an approach to evaluate cumulative impacts of offshore wind projects. See National Environmental Policy Act Documentation for

Impact-Producing Factors in the Offshore Wind Cumulative Impacts Scenario on the North Atlantic Outer Continental Shelf; OCS Study, BOEM 2019-036, May 2019.

105 Telephone interview with Adam Lipsky, National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, May 19, 2020.106 Mike Ives, “Boom in Mining Rare Earths Poses Mounting Toxic Risks,” YaleEnvironment360, Jan. 28, 2013.107 Simon Parry, “In China, the True Cost of Britain’s Clean, Green Wind Power Experiment: Pollution on a Disastrous Scale,” Mail Online, Jan. 26, 2011.

Page 29: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

29

108 Mark Mills, “Mines, Minerals, and ‘Green’ Energy: A Reality Check,” Manhattan Institute, July 2020. 109 Christina Stella, “As Wind Energy Thrives, So Does Its Waste Problem,” Harvest Public Media, Sept. 1, 2019.110 NREL, “2015 Cost of Wind Energy Review,” May 2017, p. 62.111 A monopile foundation is a single large-diameter steel or concrete tube driven into the seafloor. The weight figure is for the Veja Mate offshore wind farm,

with 6-MW turbines, located in the North Sea. See Vicente Negro et al., “Monopiles in Offshore Wind: Preliminary Estimate of Main Dimensions,” Ocean Engineering 133 (March 2017): 253–61.

112 Tomas Kellner, “The X Factor: Here’s What It Takes to Build the Tower for the World’s Most Powerful Offshore Wind Turbine,” GE Reports, May 25, 2018.

113 World Steel Organization, “Fact Sheet: Steel and Raw materials,” February 2019. In 2017, about 70% of all steel was manufactured this way, while the remaining 30% was made in electric arc furnaces from recycled steel. An electric arc furnace requires about 0.15 tons of coal per ton of steel manufactured.

114 Vicente Negro et al., “Gravity-Based Foundations in the Offshore Wind Sector,” Journal of Marine Science and Engineering 7, no. 3 (March 2019): 64–77.

115 See Matt Ridley, “More Gas, Less Wind,” The Spectator, May 13, 2017.116 Levitan and Associates, “Evaluation and Comparison of US Wind and Skipjack Proposed Offshore Wind Project Applications,” revised version, Mar. 17,

2017.117 Ibid., p. ES-39, table 6. In its order approving PPAs for the two projects, the Maryland Public Service Commission rejected these estimates. In the

Matter of the Applications of U.S. Wind, Inc. and Skipjack Offshore Energy, LLC for a Proposed Offshore Project(s) Pursuant to the Maryland Offshore Wind Energy Act of 2013, Case No. 9431, Order No. 88192, May 11, 2017, pp. 63–70.

118 Levitan and Associates, “Evaluation and Comparison,” pp. 159–60. As discussed in n. 117, the Maryland Public Service Commission rejected the Levitan analysis because it questioned the market response (i.e., less onshore wind in lieu of more offshore wind).

119 Ibid.120 U.S. EIA, Monthly Energy Review, May 2020, table 11.1.121 See Jonathan Lesser, “Is There a Future for Nuclear Power in the United States?” Manhattan Institute, July 2019.

Page 30: Out to Sea: The Dismal Economics of Offshore Wind ... · average wholesale market electric generating prices will decline by 20% between 2019 and 2050, from an average $61/MWh to

August 2020