91
ASSESSING THE IMPACT OF REMITTANCES: A CASE STUDY OF THE PHILIPPINES by Mustafa Zia A thesis submitted to the Faculty of the University of Delaware in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the degree of Master of Science in Economics Spring 2011 Copyright 2011 Mustafa Zia All Rights Reserved

Mustafa Zia Thesis - University of Delaware

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

ASSESSING THE IMPACT OF REMITTANCES:

A CASE STUDY OF THE PHILIPPINES

by

Mustafa Zia

A thesis submitted to the Faculty of the University of Delaware in partial fulfillmentof the requirements for the degree of Master of Science in Economics

Spring 2011

Copyright 2011 Mustafa ZiaAll Rights Reserved

ASSESSING THE IMPACT OF REMITTANCES:

A CASE STUDY OF THE PHILIPPINES

by

Mustafa Zia

Approved: __________________________________________________________Peter Schnabl, Ph.D.Professor in charge of thesis on behalf of the Advisory Committee

Approved: __________________________________________________________Saul Hoffman, Ph.D.Chair of the Department of Economics

Approved: __________________________________________________________Rick L. Andrews, Ph.D.Interim Dean, Lerner College of Business & Economics

Approved: __________________________________________________________Charles G. Riordan, Ph.D.Vice Provost for Graduate and Professional Education

iii

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

Falaris, Evangelos, Laurence Seidman for all of their advice and guidance.

Peter Schnabl, my advisor who was there to help me on a daily basis. Without hisimmense help this paper would not have been possible.

My mother, Hajera Zia, for her love and support.

iv

TABLE OF CONTENTS

LIST OF TABLES ........................................................................................................ viABSTRACT ............................................................................................................... ix

Chapter

1 INTRODUCTION.............................................................................................. 1

1.1 The Philippines Background .................................................................. 51.2 When did it Begin?................................................................................. 51.3 Who Are The Overseas Filipinos? ......................................................... 71.4 Characteristics of Overseas Filipinos: (The Latest year 2008) .............. 9

2 LITERATURE REVIEW................................................................................. 11

2.1 Remittances and GDP Growth ............................................................. 112.2 Remittances and Human Capital .......................................................... 132.3 Remittances and Health........................................................................ 172.4 Remittances and Inequality .................................................................. 192.5 The Multiplier Effect............................................................................ 22

3 THE DATA ...................................................................................................... 25

3.1 The Variables ....................................................................................... 28

4 METHODOLOGY........................................................................................... 33

4.1 Models 1-A & 1-B................................................................................ 344.2 Models 2-A & 2-B................................................................................ 364.3 Our Expectations from the Equations .................................................. 384.4 Inequality Analysis............................................................................... 40

5 RESULTS......................................................................................................... 42

5.1 Model 1-A & 1-B. ................................................................................ 425.2 Model 2-A & 2-B. ................................................................................ 435.3 Yearly Models 1, 2, 3, & 4 ................................................................... 45

v

5.4 Expenditure Results.............................................................................. 475.5 Inequality Analysis:.............................................................................. 49

6 SUMMARY & CONCLUSION ...................................................................... 51REFERENCES............................................................................................................. 54

AppendixA MODEL 1-A (REGIONAL) ............................................................................ 57B MODEL 1-B (PROVINCIAL)......................................................................... 60C MODEL 2-A (REGIONAL) ............................................................................ 63D MODEL 2-B (PROVINCIAL)......................................................................... 66E 1999 (REGIONAL).......................................................................................... 69F 2004 (REGIONAL).......................................................................................... 72G 2007 (REGIONAL).......................................................................................... 75H 2008 (REGIONAL).......................................................................................... 78I MODEL 3-A(REGIONAL/PROVINCIAL) .................................................... 81J MODEL 4-A (REGIONAL/PROVINCIAL) ................................................... 82

vi

LIST OF TABLES

Table 3.1 Table of Variables ................................................................................ 29

Table A.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................... 57

Table A.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittanceson Fraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 .................................... 58

Table A.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures ............ 58

Table A.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effect of Remittanceson Education & Medical Expenditures ................................................ 59

Table B.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................... 60

Table B.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................... 61

Table B.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures ............ 61

Table B.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effect of Remittanceson Education & Medical Expenditures ................................................ 62

Table C.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................... 63

Table C.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittanceson Fraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................... 64

Table C.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures ............ 64

Table C.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effect of Remittances onEducation & Medical Expenditures ..................................................... 65

vii

Table D.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed: For Ages7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................................... 66

Table D.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittanceson Fraction of Years Completed: For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................................................................... 67

Table D.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures ............ 67

Table D.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effect of Remittances onEducation & Medical Expenditures ..................................................... 68

Table E.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed: For Ages7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................................... 69

Table E.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed: For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................................................................... 70

Table E.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures ............ 70

Table E.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance IncomeEffect of Remittances onEducation & Medical Expenditures ..................................................... 71

Table F.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed: For Ages7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................................... 72

Table F.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittanceson Fraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................... 73

Table F.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures ............ 73

Table F.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effect of Remittances onEducation & Medical Expenditures ..................................................... 74

Table G.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed: For Ages7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................................... 75

Table G.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed: For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................................................................... 76

viii

Table G.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures ............ 76

Table G.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance IncomeEffect of Remittances onEducation & Medical Expenditures ..................................................... 77

Table H.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................... 78

Table H.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24 ..................................... 79

Table H.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures ............ 79

Table H.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effect of Remittances onEducation & Medical Expenditures ..................................................... 80

Table I.1 Regional Effects of Remittances on Different Percentile Ratios ......... 81

Table I.2 Provincial Effects of Remittances on Different Percentile Ratios ....... 81

Table J.1 Inequality Analysis: Gini Decomposition (Regional) Total IncomeVariable: TOTINC ............................................................................... 82

Table J.2 Inequality Analysis: Gini Decomposition (Provincial) Total IncomeVariable: TOTINC ............................................................................... 82

ix

ABSTRACT

In recent years, there has been a plethora of literature written on

remittances. While disagreements exist on the exact impact of remittances,

nevertheless, the overwhelming view paints that of a positive picture. According to the

World Bank, the amount of remittance received for 2010 amount to $325 billion. This

is particularly the case in middle and low income countries. In this paper, I examine

the impact of remittances on education, health, and inequality using the Annual

Poverty Indicator Survey from the Philippines. This paper uses the Philippines as the

country of choice since ten percent of its GDP is comprised of remittances. The

analysis is done using regional/provincial fixed-effects, Gini decomposition, and ratios

of different expenditure per capita percentiles. The results indicate a positive impact of

remittances on education and health. However, the effect of remittances on inequality

is not conclusive, and suggests additional research.

1

Chapter 1

INTRODUCTION

A friend of mine once told me — had it not been for the financial help

from his brother abroad, his family would not have been able to survive financially.

Like many others looking for a better opportunity, his brother was able to find his way

into Europe. In a month’s time, he was able to find a job and send money back home.

The remittances sent by him went a long way in improving and meeting the financial

needs of his family. My friend stopped working as a street vendor, and started going

back to school. A similar pattern followed with the rest of his siblings, all of whom

were working to support the family. In a couple of years, the family had gone from

struggling to meet daily needs to a financially stability. This isn’t an isolated case. In

fact, there are many individuals living in developing as well as underdeveloped

countries who rely heavily on overseas remittances as a source of income. According

to recent estimates by the World Bank, the amount of remittances received for the year

2010 amount to $325 billion, an increase of 6 percent from the previous year. And the

amount of people living outside of their country of birth is estimated to be around 215

million individuals, accounting for 3 percentage of the world’s population (a majority

of them from the developing nations). The overwhelming consensus among

academics, researchers, and general public is that remittances provide a boost to the

2

economy (especially if the economy is that of a developing country) (e.g. Ang 2007,

Taylor 1995, 2003, Yang 2008, etc). One positive aspect of remittances is that it can

provide countries with access to funds without them having to go into debt. Many of

the organizations that provide money for developing countries often require the

receiving country to direct the funds towards achieving goals that the providing

organization sees as appropriate. The World Bank often has certain priorities and

requirements as to where the funds given must be spent. Not following the goal of the

desired organization can have negative consequences for the fund-receiving country.

Among many, one obvious consequence is the denial of current and future funds for

the country. Remittances on the other hand provide countries with an indirect form of

assistance through their citizens. It is not surprising then, that many of the developing

countries include remittances as a big portion of their GDP. The Philippines is a

leading example, with remittances accounting for 10 percent of its GDP. Even at a

micro level, remittances received by households enable them to spend the money at

their own discretion—unlike other forms of financial aid. In this way, remittances

allow for freeing up of some of the money for the households. The households can

now meet their basic needs easily, leaving extra money to be spent on education,

healthcare and other areas. Some have argued remittances to be a form of safety net.

During economic crisis, remittances tend to stay stable, and thus provide a much

needed help during economic downfalls (although the current crisis challenges this

theory). They also provide a transfer channel for skills and technology from abroad,

especially of those individuals living in highly developed countries such as the United

3

States and the Europe. An example of this transfer channel includes a Filipino IT

student in the United States who builds a computer learning school back home. The

list of positive impacts is quite exhaustive, but the point remains, remittances play a

vital role in the developing nations. Nevertheless, there are critics who seem to paint

a negative picture of the impact of remittances (e.g. Chami 2003, Haskar, Burges

2005, etc)

One criticism is that heavy reliance on remittances as a source of income

is problematic if there was a halt to the remittance sending and receiving system. A

halt could be due varying factors that either make it impossible or expensive to send

money back (e.g. high cost of transaction). This issue could be disastrous for a

country like the Philippines. For example, if a family relies heavily on assistance from

overseas for education expenses, then a sudden halt in that process could lead to the

discontinuation of educational attainment. If it persists, then this will obviously have

long-term negative direct and indirect external effects on the society (especially when

aggregated across households).

Another major criticism of remittances has been centered on the argument

that the money does not reach the neediest of individuals. Critics argue that only the

well off individuals have the ability to go abroad, and therefore those who benefit

most from these remittances aren’t the really needy ones. Additionally, the banking

system in developing nations makes it very hard for poor people to have an account,

which leads the poor to choose other alternatives. This could not only result in costs

for the poor in terms of transfer of the money, but also leads to the remittances not

4

being accounted for in the overall economy—creating an underground economy in the

process.

While there seem to be two opposing views of remittances on many socio-

economic factors, in this paper I will examine the effects that remittances have on

education, healthcare, and inequality. The reason for using the Philippines as a country

of interest is because the Philippines is famous for its export of workers. According to

the World Bank, the Philippines is the fourth largest recipient of remittances.

Moreover, in 2010, the Philippines received $21.3 billion dollars in remittances, right

behind Mexico ($22.6 billion), China ($51 billion), and the top remittances receiving

country, India ($55 billion). This paper is divided into six main sections. The first

section deals with some background information on the Philippines, its migration

pattern, and the characteristics of the Filipino migrants. The second section discusses

some of the literature related to the impact of remittances on various facets of the

economy. In the third section, more attention is given to the data sets relevant for this

paper. This part discusses some of the data sets specifications, as well as the variables

relevant for this paper. The next two sections, four and five, deal with methodology,

and the results found in this paper. That is, the fourth section discusses some

specifications of the fixed-effects regressions, the decomposition of total income, and

different expenditures per capita ratios to examine inequality. Section five pertains to

the results attained after running the regressions. I will discuss about the significance

as well as the magnitude of some of the coefficient estimates achieved. The last

5

section concludes the paper with a review of the results and some recommendations

for future analysis.

1.1 The Philippines Background

Located in the Western Pacific Ocean of Southeast Asia, the Philippines is

considered one of the biggest exporters of labor. The Philippines is estimated to have

the highest rates of outmigration to population compared to any other countries in East

or South East Asia (Lucas, 2001). The remittances are quite pronounced—currently

constituting 10% of the entire Philippines GDP. According to the Commission on

Filipinos Overseas, in 2009 there were 8.6 million Filipinos overseas. Of this 8.6

million, 4.1 million of them were permanent migrants, 3.9 million of them were

temporary migrants, and there were more than 6 hundred thousand irregular migrants.

It is vital to look at the history of when migration became important for the

Philippines.

1.2 When did it Begin?

In 1974 the government of the Philippines instituted international

migration as policy to combat the temporary problem of unemployment. The

Presidential Decree number 442 (a Labor Code of the Philippines) was the reason

behind the creation of the Overseas Employment Development Board. A department

created to foster Filipino employment overseas, as well as to register and monitor

Filipinos overseas. However, since its inception, there has been a concerted effort to

6

facilitate the export of labor overseas, not merely on temporary basis, but as a long-

term revenue generator for the Philippine economy. Due to an increase in the number

of Filipinos migrating to other countries, the President had to create an independent

department—solely responsible for dealing with Filipinos leaving overseas. To that

effect, in 1978, the President ordered the creation of the Office of Emigrant Affairs

(Decree number 1412). This wasn’t to be the last expansion of the office, as the

outflow of Filipino migrants grew.

The high volume of migrants resulted in the formation of Batas Pambansa

Blg. 79 (established on June 16th of 1980)—which replaced the Office of Emigrant

Affairs (OEA). The latter expanded its functions to include the welfare and interest of

migrants leaving the Philippines. The four main functions of Batas Pambansa Blg. 79

are as follows:

“Provide assistance to the President and the Congress of the Philippines

in the formulation of policies and measures concerning or affecting

Filipinos overseas;

Develop and implement programs to promote the interest and well-

being of Filipinos overseas;

Serve as a forum for preserving and enhancing the social, economic,

and cultural ties of Filipinos overseas with the motherland; and

7

Provide liaison services to Filipinos overseas with appropriate

government and private agencies in the transaction of business

and similar ventures in the Philippines” (Overseas Filipinos

Website).

The gradual transformation of the offices dealing with overseas migrants

is an indicator of the vital role that overseas Filipinos play in the local Philippines

economy. Going from a policy that didn’t “promote overseas employment as a means

to sustain economic growth and economic development (Section 2c, Republic Act

8042)”, to considering the employment of overseas Filipinos as a “legitimate option

for the countries work force”—forcing the government to “fully respect labor

mobility, including the preference for overseas employment.”(Go Undated). In

addition to the history of labor migration, it is also important to know a little about the

overseas Filipino migrants.

1.3 Who Are The Overseas Filipinos?

Filipinos living overseas can be divided into three groups. The groups are

classified as permanent migrants, temporary or non-migrants, and lastly irregular

migrants.

-Permanent Migrants: These are the migrants who have left the

Philippines on the premise that they will reside abroad, and have no intention of

8

coming back to live in the Philippines. As indicated earlier, these migrants constitute

the largest bulk of the overall Filipinos abroad (4.1 million out of the 8.6 million).

-Temporary or non-migrant: These are migrants who have left the country

primarily to work, and have the intention of coming back once their work contract is

over. The duration of time for temporary migrants is usually more than 6 months. This

group constitutes the second largest bulk of Filipino migrants, amounting to 3.9

million of the total migrants abroad.

-Irregular migrants: The smallest portion of Filipinos living abroad is

those who have left the Philippines with or without any proper authorization, or

documentation, but due to legal issues lost their status abroad. These immigrants may

have lost their status due to legal issues or because they have overstayed their time in

the foreign country (Asis.). There is also a difference in terms of where most Filipinos

are attracted to migrate.

The top destination countries as of 2010 are United States, Saudi Arabia,

Canada, Malaysia, Japan, Australia, Italy, Qatar, the United Arab Emirates, and the

United Kingdom. However, the top region in terms of Filipino migration has

consistently been the Middle East. There is however a distinction between the top

destination, and the top source countries. The top source countries provide the largest

percentage of remittances as a source of income for the Philippines. As expected, the

top source country is the United States, followed by China, United Kingdom, Bahrain,

Japan, Antigua and Barbuda, Indonesia, India, Brazil, and Angola. It should also be

noted that since the 1970s the pattern and trend of Filipino workers have changed. For

9

example, during the 1970s many of the overseas Filipinos were unskilled workers,

who mainly went to the Middle East. However, as the decades went by, the demand

for high skilled and in particular service industry has increased substantially. The

United States, and many other developed countries are in high demand for service

industries such as Nursing and Information Technology. Thus, we have seen an ever-

increasing number of Filipinos specializing in medical and information technology

fields. It is also important to point out that the male to female disparity of migrants

has also diminished as the demand for more service oriented jobs increased. Many of

the Nursing jobs are particularly suited towards women, and thus we have seen an

increasing drop in the male to female ratio of workers and immigrants abroad. It is

also vital to mention some information on the characteristics of these overseas

Filipinos.

1.4 Characteristics of Overseas Filipinos: (The Latest year 2008)

This section, based on the Overseas Filipinos Survey conducted by the

National Statistics Office provides data on the Filipinos living abroad. It includes

individuals who are 15 years and older, have left the country within the last five years,

and are working or had worked abroad during the past six months. According to the

survey, there were an estimated 2 million Overseas Filipinos Workers (OFWs) who

worked abroad. The portion of male compared to female workers was slightly higher

(51.7% male to 48.3% female), and more than ¼ of the workers were between the ages

of 25 and 29 (25.7%). The ages of male workers seemed to be smoother in terms of

10

distribution, as compared to females. Of the total number of female workers abroad,

28.8 percent belonged to the age group 25-29, and 20.3 percent belonged to the age

group 30-34.

About one third (34.7percent) of the total of OFWs belonged to the

laborers and unskilled workers group. This group included workers in cleaning,

manufacturing, and domestic helping. 15 percent of the workers belonged to the trade

and other trade related workers, while service workers and shop market sales workers

constituted 14.3 percent of the total number of workers. Finally, plant and machine

operators and assemblers made up the last big bulk of the OFWs.

The top five regions that constituted most of the OFWs are

CALABARZON (14.7 percent), National Capital Region (12.8 percent), Central

Luzon (11.8 percent), Llocos Region (8.3 percent), and finally Cagayan Valle (7.3

percent). These five regions amount to about 50 percent of the Filipinos workers

overseas. The next section sheds some light on the literature related to remittances. In

particular, the literature relating remittances to education, health, inequality, and the

multiplier effect of remittances. (National Statistics Office)

11

Chapter 2

LITERATURE REVIEW

Remittances have several impacts on the economy. This paper will only

showcase some of the most important linkages between remittances and factors that

are paramount to a developing nation. In this section I will converse some of the

literature written about the impact of remittances on various economic factors. I will

try to mention both sides of the argument; that is literature that does not have a

favorable view of remittances, and literature that shows deems remittance impact

positive. One of the most important areas in which remittances may play an important

role is the overall GDP of a country. Remittance growth has long been related with

GDP growth.

2.1 Remittances and GDP Growth

Several countries such as Bulgaria, Philippines, Pakistan, India to name a

few, consider remittances to be a vital part of their overall economy. There has been a

plethora of literature written on this subject matter, with most of the academic

consensus being that remittances have a positive impact on GDP. Nevertheless, there

are those who negate the view that remittances have a positive impact on GDP.

Several authors such as Chami et al (2003), Burgess and Haksar (2005) have found a

negative correlation between remittances and economic growth. Burgess and Haksar

12

find that the growth rate of remittances is inversely correlated with the per capita GDP

growth, using data from the mid-1980s. They use Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) as

well as Instrument Variable (IV) methods to come up with their conclusion. Using

OLS, they regress the log of real GDP per capita on the investment to the GDP ratio,

and the log of worker remittances to GDP. In their OLS analysis they find a negative

correlation between per capita GDP and the growth rate of remittances. However, due

to the possibility of an endogeniety problem (between per capita growth in real income

and remittances) they conduct an Instrument Variable regression. Using the IV

method, their regressions yield inconclusive results. They attribute their coefficient

estimates for both methods to data problems (in particular the 1998 dataset). When

the authors include the 1998 data set, they get a negative correlation compared to

when they do not include the 1998 observation for remittances. Therefore, they do not

find empirical evidence to support that remittances have a positive effect on the GDP.

Burgess and Haskar base most of their study on Chami’s paper. Chami also found a

negative relation between GDP and remittances.

In his paper, Chami creates a unified model to examine the outcome of

remittances on the economy. He finds remittances to have negative impact on real

growth in per capita incomes, due to the problem of adverse incentive. That is, since

the whole remittance process takes place in an uncertain economic environment, it

leads to a reduction of economic activity. However, his findings are most likely

convoluted as he aggregates cross-country data to make a unified model. This is a

problem, since each country has distinct characteristics. Therefore, the effects of

13

remittances on GDP growth will also depend on country specific characteristics (i.e.

political stability, level of corruption, etc). This is the case with a study done by Alvin

P. Ang. In his paper, “Workers’ Remittances and Economic Growth in the

Philippines”, Ang (2007) concludes that the relationship between GDP growth and

remittance growth is positive and statistically significant. Ang’s study is based on a

country per country analysis, while Burgess-Haskar and Chami use cross-sectional

analysis and a unified model respectively. That is a problem, since country

characteristics and factors affecting migration and remittances change over time and

do not tend to stay constant. Thus, the unified model suggested will not be able to

account for those factor changes and will yield inconclusive results. In that sense, a

country by country analysis is vital in order to clearly understand the impact of

remittances in GDP and overall development. Although Ang does acknowledge the

possibility of an endogeneity problem in the study, nevertheless, the results seem to

confirm the anecdotal evidence among many Filipinos—remittance growth does have

a positive effect in the GDP growth. GDP is one side of the coin—remittances affect

other socio-economic factors. This impact is very pronounced in the field of

education.

2.2 Remittances and Human Capital

Anecdotal evidence shows that remittances have long been seen as a

positive factor in education attainment. The list of scholars analyzing the various

relations between remittances and education is quite exhaustive. A few of them will

14

be mentioned in this paper. Among many scholars, Dean Yang is the one who has

written some important papers on this subject matter. Yang (2008) examines the role

that an exchange rate shock plays in remittances, which in turn affects various

household investments such as child schooling, child labor, and entrepreneurial

activity. He uses the exchange rate shocks as an instrument for remittances in his

Instrument Variable regression. The idea is that an exchange rate shock appreciates

the value of the currency, and thus the remittances sent back are worth more than they

were before the exchange rate changed. He estimates the Philippines-peso remittance

elasticity with respect to exchange rate to be around .60, which is quite large. He

rejects the notion that remittances are primarily consumed. Rather his results indicate

that remittances play an investment role in the Philippines, in particular on education.

Accordingly, families who were affected by the exchange rate shock were able to raise

their non-consumption investment (i.e. human capital investment). Moreover, those

families tended to keep their children longer in school, reduced the responsibility of

the child in terms of providing for the family (reduce child labor), and embark on

entrepreneurial activities (start capital-intensive enterprises).

In, “Accounting for Remittance and Migration Effects on Children’s

Schooling”, Dorantes and Pozo (2010) find mixed results. Using data from the

Dominican Republic, the authors study the effects of remittances on school

attendance. Dominican Republic is one of the countries that has experienced an

extensive amount of migration, in particular to the United States. According to the

15

2009 estimates of the World Bank, 12 percent of the population has already emigrated,

and remittances amount to approximately 10 percent of the country’s total GDP.

The study distinguishes between two kinds of households, those with a

member of the family who has migrated to the United States (migrant households),

and those who do not have a migrant member of the family in the United States (non-

migrant households). The authors opt to choose the non-migrant households to

conduct their analysis, because non-migrant households’ children constitute 88 percent

of their entire sample. Thus, non-migrant households become a more reliable sample

to utilize. However, the study claims that 52 percent of children who receive

remittances reside in non-migrant households. Their results suggest that remittances

do have a positive impact on the children’s school attendance. In addition to a 3

percent point increase in the likelihood of attending school (due to a 10 percent

increase in the likelihood of receiving remittances), girls’ attendance as well as the

secondary school age children and younger siblings seem to reap a large chunk of the

benefits from remittances in terms of school attendance. However, they get a different

result when they expand their datasets to include migrant households. In other words,

their study shows that the migration of a family member tends to have a negative and

disruptive effect on school attendance of children. For instance, male member of the

family (usually father) is the head of the household. Having a big influence in the

households, the absence of the father will surely have a negative impact on the family.

This is most certainly the case if the children in the household are young.

Nevertheless, the study does not see a negative impact of remittances, rather, a

16

disruptive effect on school attendance due to migration. Thus the study confirms the

general notion of a positive feedback from remittances on human capital investment.

There were also several other studies done, which examine other types of

correlations between remittances and education. Edwards and Ureta use El-Salvador to

study the effects of remittances on school retention— they find the relation to be

significant. In particular, they examine the effects on school retention rates from

different income sources. They find remittances to have a bigger impact on the school

retention rate, compared to other sources of income. The study was done using a Cox

proportional hazard model. (Edwards –Cox and Ureta 429-461)

Needless to say, there has been an overabundance of literature written on

the subject matter—all the same, the overwhelming majority paint a positive picture of

the effect of remittances on education attainment.

Aside from educational attainment, remittances sometimes provide a good

source of income to be expended on healthcare. The impact of remittances on

healthcare is difficult to explain. Remittances can have a consumption effect on

healthcare. For example, a family can ameliorate an immediate medical problem due

to remittances (e.g. going to the dentist). On the other hand, remittances might

provide a continuous stream of income that enables a family to improve its overall

health (e.g. seeing a dentist on a regular basis). This impact of remittances can then be

categorized as human capital investment effect. There have been attempts by some

scholars to shed light on this phenomenon.

17

2.3 Remittances and Health

Studying the effects of remittances on health expenditure in Mexico, Jorge

(2008) uses a Tobit model with fixed-effects. In particular, the author wants to see if

the share of household health expenditure in total expenditure is affected by

remittances. The study finds a significant link between the level of remittances and

health expenditure. For individuals in households who lacked medical care, and were

not covered by any other type of insurance, the effect of remittances on their level of

health expenditure was significant. This means that remittance do in fact increase non-

consumption activities. The authors found a 10 percent of changes in remittances to be

associated primarily with health expenditure. The results were also verified using both

a Tobit as well as a Generalized Least Squared (GLS) model. Both of the models

confirmed the theory, that remittances positively affect a household’s health

expenditure (Jorge). A similar effort to study the effects of remittances on health was

produced by Hildebrandt and McKenzie (2005).

Hildebrandt and McKenzie look at the effect of migration on child health

in Mexico. Using various econometric methodologies (OLS, IV, Probit), the authors

investigate this issue with the 1997 nationally representative demographic survey.

Overall the authors’ find a linear relation between migration and child health. In

particular, the authors note a decrease in the incidence of child mortality and increase

in higher birth weights—the two indicators used as proxies for health outcome.

Although the authors find the effects of migration to be larger than remittance, they

nevertheless contend that remittances do have positive impact on health outcomes.

18

Using a Grossman production function, they label remittances as a positive channel of

migration on health outcomes. Alternatively, migration influences health outcomes

through the wealth mechanism. That is, individuals who receive remittances are more

capable, and possibly likely to spend on health related activities. There is also a

possibility of remittances affecting health outcomes indirectly through consumption.

Although farfetched, it is possible for households to increase their overall food

consumption, which could result in better health. This will specially be the case if the

food purchased is of high nutrients such as vegetables and fruits. Again, the evidence

in the case of health outcomes seems to follow anecdotal evidence—that remittances

have positive effect on health (Hildebrandt, and McKenzie 257-289).

A different, yet theoretically similar approach was taken by Chauvet,

Gubert, and Somps (2008) to see if remittances are more effective than aid in

improving child health.

They measure it by looking at child and infant mortality rates, as well as

stunting incidence. The analysis examines the effects of aid, remittances, and medical

brain drain has on health outcomes. According to the authors, both aid as well as

remittances have a positive impact on health outcomes, albeit aid is more helpful for

the poor than remittances. Medical brain drain, which occurs when those individuals

in the medical field migrate to other countries, seems to have a negative impact on

health outcomes. Medical brain drain also results in aid becoming less effective, due to

a decrease in the number of qualified medical professionals who serve as a

compliment to aid. Nevertheless, in terms of remittances, the impact on health

19

outcomes seems to be positive, even if it is mainly for the children of the richer

portion population. This most likely exacerbates inequality, which is another

important factor that needs attention. (Chauvet, Gubert, and Somps)

2.4 Remittances and Inequality

There has been some argument to whether the remittances sent back

increases the income distribution gap. The premise is that most of the well-off

families are capable of migration, and thus remittances sent back only magnifies the

inequality gap. There have been several studies conducted to clarify this topic.

According Ang (2007), while remittance growth might lead to GDP growth,

remittances also seem to exacerbate the inequality issue. According to the study, most

of the OFWs comes from certain regions (Regions I, III, IV, VI, XI, and NCR), which

are regions that already have lower rates of poverty. This also goes to prove Taylor’s

(2006) point that most of the immigrants are not from poor families, and thus the

migration might actually exacerbate the poverty issue. Ang further emphasizes that

the regions with highest rates of migration are more urbanized compared to other

regions. A different approach to examine this issue is taken by Jones (1998).

This is a study done with the 1998 household survey of central Zacatecas

state, Mexico to find the effect of remittances on inequality. The study suggests that

previous studies of the effect of remittances on inequality have been inconclusive. He

offers a “spatiotemporal perspective” which uses migration stages and spatial scale

(interregional, interurban, rural-urban, and interfamilial). They are conceptualized as

20

controls which measure inequalities. With regards to the stage of migration, he finds

that the inequalities decrease with migration up to a point, after which it increases. At

the geographical scale, he finds the advantage going to the richer families, at the

expense of poorer families. Furthermore, he believes that at a regional and familial

level, remittances can play an important role if these regions are being introduced to

liberalized trade. While the richer regions might be affected by “foreign exchange-

generation activates”, it is only the poorest regions that seem to have a higher benefit

from remittances. Remittances seem to play a vital role in maintaining these regions,

which otherwise would have disappeared. The rural households are able to maintain

their “rural roots” while coping with the modern age. Moreover, the migrants seem to

invest more in non-consumption activities which makes them less likely to migrate.

Investments in human capital, health, and agriculture are some of the most important

ones made in these rural communities. Therefore, remittances according to Richard do

not exacerbate inequality, but rather provides an essential option for the poor in the

rural regions. The author provides a broader approach of looking at the inequality

issue than the existing literature. Another approach to looking at the impact of

remittances on inequality is conducted by Chimhowu, Piesse, and Pinder.

The Socioeconomic Impact of Remittances on Poverty Reduction is one of

the chapters of a book organized by the World Bank to have a comprehensive study of

remittances. The authors, Chimhowu, Piesse, and Pinder (2005), examine the

socioeconomic impact of remittances on poverty reduction. They conclude that

remittances have different effects based on different time horizons. First and

21

foremost, the authors believe that there needs to be a medium to long range horizon,

during which the full effect of remittances on poverty can be assessed. While in short

time, it is possible that it could increase a household’s consumption. However, the

long term implications are unclear. For example, a household might use the

remittances as a source of education or health expenditure, which can have a positive

future effect. Therefore, in the short-term remittances is very unlikely to lift a family

out of poverty, and medium to long term horizon is needed to fully count for the

effects of remittances on poverty. Nevertheless, the authors show that empirical

studies have shown that remittances “make a powerful contribution to reduction

poverty and vulnerability in most households and communities”.

Remittances might lead to inequality at a local level, but they might also

decrease it at an international level with the transfer of resources and knowledge from

developed to developing nations. On the national level, remittances could have a

negative impact if the country of interest has lower GDP and higher migration rate.

The studies indicate an increase in poverty for the families who do not have remitting

migrants, especially if a macroeconomic crisis is caused due to remittances inflows.

Although, according to the authors if a country has an organized system of migration

and remittances (such as the Philippines), then the impact of remittances is

significantly positive. In addition, they seem to have a negative outlook of what they

regard as “medical brain drain”, in which the individuals who have some sort of

degree in the healthcare field (nurses, physicians) will have a negative impact on the

overall healthcare system if these individuals decide to migrate. The idea is that while

22

the aid might be available to the country in focus, the lack of individuals who know

how to best utilize the aid will make the aid useless. Their results however are cross-

sectional, and there have been several studies which recommend focusing on a country

by country basis to have a solid analysis of the impact of remittances (e.g. Ang’s

analysis). Regardless of positive or negative impact, remittances seem to have a

multiplier effect on many socio-economic factors—and a mention of this effect is vital

in understanding the effects of remittances.

2.5 The Multiplier Effect

So far proponents of remittances seem to suggest that remittances have

multitude of effects in a country. Remittances given in a household might have

secondary or even tertiary effects on the entire economy. For example, remittances

sent back might result in the household investing more in education and healthcare.

This can have a big impact on children especially, since better health allows the

children to focus more on school. A multitude of literature has shown that more

schooling leads to higher income and lifestyle in the future.

In one study done by Glytsos (1993), the effects of international

remittances on production, imports, and employment on the Greek economy in 1971 is

examined. According to the author, the remittances have a multiplier effect of 1.71 on

GDP, with the biggest effect of remittances being on machinery and construction

industries. This means that a $2 million increase of remittances will lead to a $3.5

million increase in total GDP. Similar analysis has been done by other scholars.

23

Taylor has done several studies in which his analysis sheds some light on

the multiplier effects of remittances. In his 1995 analysis of international remittances

on a Mexican village, he finds a multiplier effect of 1.6. Similar to the Glytsos study,

a $2 million increase in remittances would lead to $3.2 million in the villages’ value

added output.

In 2003 Taylor conducted another study in which he examined the effects

of remittances on crop and household income. While the study found a negative effect

(lower crop yields and income) of migrants leaving the household, there was a positive

effect of remittances received by households. For example, the households tended to

substitute capital for labor as they were able to buy more inputs. Overall, the

remittances lead to an income increase of between 16 to 43 percent for members of the

rural households in China.

Finally, during the 2008 period, another study on Mexico was done by

Taylor and Dyer, in which they found a 52 percent increase in marginal human capital

investment and 5 percent increase in rural wages in the short run (due to an increase of

10 percent in remittances). The same was true for the long-term, except the effects

were even greater in terms of human capital investment. Overall the indirect effects of

remittances exceeded the direct effects of remittances. And this seems to confirm to

the notion that remittances do more than increasing household consumption. It affects

human capital and health investments which all have been proven to have positive

external effects.

24

Even though there have been some conflicting views on the effect of

remittances; the general notion seems to point towards a positive outcome. In recent

years, the United Nations has written several papers, and has spent considerable

resources in trying to understand fully, the effects of remittances. The United Nations

and many other international organizations, such as the International Monetary Fund

(IMF) all seem to think of remittances as having a positive effect on the developing

nations. It is to that effect, that many of the recent surveys run by the United Nations

include gather data on remittances. That is also the case in the Annual Poverty Report

survey of the Philippines. A survey conducted to measure several poverty indicating

variables. Abbreviated as APIS, this dataset was also used for this paper.

25

Chapter 3

THE DATA

The data collected for this paper are for four different years. The years in

interest are 1999, 2004, 2007, and 2008. The data used for this paper is cross-

sectional for each individual year, and it was originally collected by the National

Statistics Office in the Philippines. Although different sorts of survey were conducted

for each individual year, the survey from which the variables are taken is called

Annual Poverty Indicator Survey (for all four years), which is funded by the United

Nation and the Asian Europe Meeting (ASEM) organization.

The Annual Poverty Indicators Survey of 1999 was conducted using

40,922 households. Of the 40,992 sample households, 37,454 households were

successfully interviewed using the APIS. This means that the response rate was 91.4

percent successful. Those individuals who were not interviewed either refused to be

interviewed, or were not available during enumeration. It should be noted that the

sampling method used was similar to the one used for the 1995 Census of Population.

The purpose of the survey was to provide impact indicators that could be used as

inputs to monitor and analyze poverty indicators. Statistics on poverty for the

Philippines are presented in the Family and Income Expenditure Survey (FIES) which

was conducted on a three years basis since its introduction in 1995. Other than the

26

poverty indicators, the FIES also provides data on spending pattern by income class,

income deciles, etc. However, if there is no FIES survey conducted, then the National

Statistics Office of Philippines conducts the APIS. For this reason, the paper uses

APIS rather than FIES, since no FIES was conducted during the years of interest.

Additionally, FIES was not available from their databank. The sample also covered

82 provinces and 16 regions, including cities and municipalities. Included are also

3416 sample enumeration areas (EAs) or barangays with an approximately 41000

sample families. The weighting for the sample was conducted in three stages. The first

stage involves adjusting the weight at the stratum level (domain city, urban or rural,

within province). The adjusted factors were based on a division of sample EAs in the

stratum by the sample EAs actually enumerated. The second stage was adjusted for

non-interview households at the level of sample EA. Finally, in order to reflect the

change in population overtime, a weight adjustment factor based on population

projection was conducted. The adjustment factor was applied at the domain level, and

was based on best population projections for the survey year. The 2004 survey is more

or less similar to the 1999 survey.

Conducted in 2004, the survey has 48115 sample households, of which

42789 were successfully interview. The survey yielded a significant response rate of

88.9 percent at the national level. The sampling procedure for 2004 uses the Master

Sample from the 2003 year. The Master Sample utilizes a multi-stage sampling design

which involves three stages of evaluation. For example sample barangays are selected

with probability proportional to size in the first stage. Similar to the 1999 census, the

27

2004 census provides information not only on a country level, but at a regional level

as well (17 administrative regions included in this survey). A similar weighting

method as that of 1999 was used to ensure that the data is a good representative of the

whole country as well as its regions. The 2007 follows a similar pattern as the 1999,

and 2004 surveys.

The 2007 census has approximately 43107 household samples, of which

40239 were successfully interviewed (a response rate of 93.3 percent). Aside from not

being available or refusing to be interviewed, those who were in critical areas were

also excluded from this survey. Therefore, regions with political instability comprised

smaller percentage of the survey. This issue is prevalent throughout all the years in

this survey. That is, regions with political instability, such as the Autonomous Region

in Muslim Mindanao have lower response rates compared to the stable ones (e.g.

National Capital Region). In fact, the Autonomous Region in Muslim Mindanao is the

only region that has its own separate local government. The 2007 sample used the

2000 Census of Population and Housing survey as its master sample. The survey was

conducted in all of the 17 regional levels, and it was weighted similar to other years

(goes through three separate weighting stages) to ensure that the data is a good

representation of the country and its regions.

Following similar pattern as that of the previous 3 surveys, the 2008

APIS was conducted due to the absence of the Family Income and Expenditure Survey

(FIES). The APIS provide critical poverty statistics for the whole country as well as

the 17 different regions. Funded by the government of the Philippines, the survey

28

covered 43020 sample households of which 40613 households were successfully

interviewed. This translates to a response rate of 94.4 percent at the national level.

Although there is a visibly similar pattern among all the years of survey mentioned in

the paper, there are some notable variations that need mentioning. First of all, aside

from regional poverty statistics, the 1999 and 2004 APIS surveys include data on

provincial level analysis as well. This is not the case for the 2007 and 2008 APISs.

Secondly, there is no Region IV in the 2004, 2007, and 2008 surveys. Region IV was

split into two regions in 2002, resulting in Region IV-A (Calabarzon), and Region IV-

B (Mimaropa) which are included in the other years.

3.1 The Variables

There were a total of 17 variables selected from the different years. Some

variables were available for some years, but not for others (e.g. Visit to Health

Facility, Province). However, not all variables were used for this analysis, and

therefore the missing variables for certain years do not play a significant role in the

overall analysis. There was also a set of variables created by manipulating the

variables attained from the datasets. The following table provides the names and

description variables used and created for this paper:

29

Table 3.1 Table of Variables

Variables Description

Region

This variable shows the 17 different regions to which thehouseholds belong to. The 17 regions in no particular order are,llocos, Cagayan Valley, Central Luzon, Bicol, Western Visayas,Central Visayas, Eastern Visayas, Zamboanga Peninsula,NorthernMindanao, Davao, Soccsksargen, National Capital Region,Cordillera Administrative Region, Autonomous Region in MuslimMindanao, Caraga, Calabarzon, and Mimaropa.

ProvinceThis variable was only available for the 1999 and the 2004 years.They are approximately 80 provinces which are separated basedon political and administrative divisions.

Family Size

As indicated by the name, this variable shows the enumeratedmembers of the household. Aside from the household head, otherfamily members enumerated in this variable are, spouse, father,mother, son, daughter, son-in law, daughter in-law, sister, brother,granddaughter, grandson, and other close relatives.

SexShows whether the gender of the family member is male orfemale

Salaries & WagesThis variable shows the income generated from salaries andwages from employment.

30

Table 3.2 (continued)Variables Description

Total FamilyIncome

It includes primary income received by the family. The primaryincome includes salaries and wages, commissions, bonuses,family and clothing allowances, transportation and representationallowances, and other sources of income which make up the totalincome of the family.

Total FamilyExpenditure

This refers to any expenses of disbursements mainly for personalconsumption. Therefore, expense that related to farming, business,investments, and other purchases which are not for the purposesof personal consumption are not included in this variable.

Total EducationExpenditure

It is based on the expenditures made (either in case or king) foreducation.

Total MedicalExpenditure

This is similar to the education Expenditure variable; this variablealso shows the disbursements and expenditures for medicalpurposes.

Contributionfrom Abroad

\This includes salaries and wages received other sources ofincome of a family member who is a contract worker abroad. Italso includes cash received from a family member who has adifferent status than that of a contract worker (immigrant, tourist,and those with student visa). It also includes 3 other items such aspensions received from foreign government, rental fromproperties and income, and cash received from foreign aid, whichmake a small portion of the variable. For example, foreign aidusually does not come in form of cash, but through other means.

31

Table 3.2 (continued)

Highest GradeCompleted

Refers to the highest education attainment. It refers to the highestgrade completed in school, college or university.

Reason NotAttending School

Refers to different reasons given for not attending any sort ofschool. Some of the reasons given for not attending school aresickness, high cost, distance, etc.

Age Shows the age of the individuals in the households.

Created Variables

Variable Description

Years of Education

This variable shows the years of education fordifferent grade years. It is consistent with theinformation taken from the PhilippinesDepartment of Higher Education.

Expenditure Per Capita

This shows the disbursement per person. It wascreated by dividing the Total ExpenditureVariable by the Family Size. This variable wascreated to examine inequality in terms of ratios ofexpenditure for the 90th percentile (high income),50th (middle income) percentile, and 10th

percentile (low income). These variables will beused to show case how difference in remittancesrelated to regional inequalities in the 90th/10th,90th/50th, and 50th/10th percentile income rations.

32

Table 3.2 (continued)

Expected Years of Education

This variable was created by subtracting6(usual age in which individual starts school)from the Age variable. It should be noted that thisvariable is for individuals 24 years and younger.

Fraction of Years Completed

Fraction of Years

This variable is created by dividing theYears of Education variable by Expected Years ofEducation. Furthermore, this will be divided intothree sub sections each limited by different ageratios. For example, I will have the Fraction ofYears Completed for individuals who arebetween the ages of 7-12(primary education), forthose between ages of 13-19 (secondary) andlastly the for individuals between the ages of 19-24(tertiary)

33

Chapter 4

METHODOLOGY

In this paper I will do several analyses to see the effects of remittances on

education and healthcare, as well as analyzing inequality by means of the Gini-

decomposition—and by regressing different percentile ratios on remittances. There are

several sets of equations that are being analyzed—all at regional and some of the

equations at the provincial level. The analysis in this paper is divided into three

distinct models. Models 1-A and 1-B look at the collapsed regional and provincial

level analysis respectively. Models 2-A and 2-B pertain to non-collapsed household

level data for both regional and provincial level analysis correspondingly. The Yearly

Models 1, 2, 3 and 4 will look at each individual year separately, while merely

focusing at the regional level. Models 3-A and 3-B look at the impact of remittances

on different percentile ratios at regional and provincial levels respectively. Finally,

Model 4-A (Table J.1 & J.2) pertain to the inequality analysis. In particular, Model 4-

A looks at the Gini-decomposition at a regional as well as provincial level for the

collapsed dataset. The equations for this paper are provided in the beginning of each

subsection. The Gini-Decomposition analysis does not require running a regression.

Instead, the analysis is contingent upon a user-written program (i.e. descogini). By

34

utilizing the “descogini” syntax in STATA, Lerman and Yitzhaki’s inequality

measurement is acquired. Following is some information related to the Models.

4.1 Models 1-A & 1-B

The equations relevant to Model 1-A & 1-B are as follows:

1. Yi=β0+β1REMIT+β2 (K) + β3Year + ui .

2. Yi=β0+β1REMIT+ B2 NRI+β3 (K) + β4Year + ui .

Here, Yi is a generic dependent variable. It takes the value of FYC for

different age groups, expenditure variables (Medical and Education), as well as

different percentile ratios (90th/10th, 10th/50th, and 50th/10th). Moreover, K is a general

term for Regions and Provinces. Equation 2 maintains the same values for the generic

terms; expect here we are also controlling for non-remittance income (NRI). As

mentioned earlier, it should be noted that this is the only occasion in which the

percentile ratios have been regressed.

Originally, the data pertaining to each year were cross-sectional. The data

related information about several regions and province, but at a single point in time.

Analyzing across regions with a single time reference could have an endogeniety (in

the form of omitted variable bias) problem. For example, looking at the 1999 data—

there is a possibility of an omitted variable that varies across regions or provinces, yet

correlated with remittances. A good example would be the migration patterns. A

poorer region might have a lower migration rate than that of a middle or high income

region. In doing so, I am not taking into account other factors that might influence

migration (better opportunity to migrate) more from certain regions, or the quality of

35

education in certain region might be higher than others. Therefore, I am omitting

factors such as education quality as well as better opportunities of migration from my

analysis. This will yield unconvincing and problematic results for the reasons

discussed earlier.

However, if I add the regions for different Years, then I can conduct a

cross-section/time-series analysis (pool the data), which will give me a better

representation of the effects of remittances on education. With this method, I will be

able to examine two different types of variations—interregional as well as

intratemporal. The interregional variation will give me the variation in average

education from one region to the next. The intertemporal will give me variation within

each region over time. Therefore, by having different observations about each region,

and looking at the effects of remittances within each region, we can hope to have rid

our analysis of omitted variable bias. There is however one catch. With the fixed-

effects regression one has to assume that other unobserved factors that might

simultaneously affect years of education and remittances of the regression are time-

invariant. This means that any shocks that could affect the level of migration (and

remittances), or the quality of education, if not accounted for could yield inadequate

results. To conclude, running a simple Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) might yield

incorrect results due to unobservable factors that are correlated with education, or

remittances in the regressions. Assuming the unobservable factors to be time-

invariant, the fixed-effects model will yield more consistent, and eliminate omitted

variable bias. The fixed-effects model pertains to Models 1-A and 1-B in this paper.

36

Models 1-A is essentially a difference-in-difference analysis of variation in

remittances across different and over span of 4 different years. The same is true for 1-

B, except using provinces and only 2 years (1999 and 2004) to examine the variation

in remittances. This isn’t the case with Models 2-A and 2-B.

4.2 Models 2-A & 2-B

Model 2-A compares household variations in remittances in the same year

and region. This is also the case for Model 2-B, except that it analyzes household

variations in remittances in the same year (only 1999 and 2004) and province (instead

of region). The equations relevant to Model 2-A & 3-B are as follows:

1. Yi=β0+β1REMIT+β2 (K) + β3Year + ui .

2. Yi=β0+β1REMIT+ B2 NRI+β3 (K) + β4Year + ui .

Here, Yi is a generic dependent variable. It takes the value of FYC for

different age groups and expenditure variables (Medical and Education). Moreover, K

is a general term for region and provinces. Equation 2 maintains the same values for

the generic terms; expect here we are also controlling for non-remittance income

(NRI). There are no percentile ration regressions done with Model 2.

There is one advantage that Model 2 has over Model 1. Model 2 accounts

for regional and yearly changes (i.e. shocks) which are also correlated with

remittances. For example, if there was a natural catastrophe (e.g. flooding) in a

specific region or province, then it will undoubtedly affect migration, which in turn

will influence remittances. This sort of a shock is absorbed by the analysis in Model

37

2. Nevertheless, Model 2 is not immune from omitted variable bias. There are strong

cultural differences among different households in the Philippines that certainly affect

their characteristics and are difficult to control. For example, in the mostly Muslim

populated region of ARMM, religious factors are taken into account when looking at

schooling. While the region is comprised of different religions, the vast majority of

them are Muslims. There is a vast number of Madaris (Islamic schools) in ARMM that

encourage emphasis on Islamic literature and Arabic studies. One of the major

migrant destinations for the Filipino migrants is the Middle East. It is very highly

likely the case that those who have knowledge of Arabic and are of the Muslim faith

will mostly be the ones who migrate. Thus, the likelihood of migration for the

Muslim household is higher than that of the non-Muslim family (especially if it is

migration to the Middle East). Furthermore, households differ by income. The

wealthier families will most have greater opportunities to migrate than the low income

families. Not only will the wealthier section of the population be able to migrate, but

are also most likely to have higher education (although not always the case). Thus, it is

very difficult to account for all these different household characteristics to get a better

measurement. For that reason, this is one disadvantage that Model 2 has over Model 1.

Model 2 cannot account for different household characteristics within regions and

provinces that could affect migration, and thus remittance patterns.

38

4.3 Our Expectations from the Equations

As mentioned earlier, for both of the Models, Yi represents a generic term

for the dependent variable. Thus there are several dependent variables for which

regressions were conducted. The first 5 regressions conducted look at the effects of

remittances on fraction of years completed for different ages. The next set of 5

regressions analyzes the same effect, although controlling for non-remittance income.

The next set of 4 regressions is related to education and health expenditures. These

regressions are pertinent to both Models 1 (collapsed) and 2 (non-collapsed

household), covering regional and provincial level analysis. Finally, we have 3

additional regressions to look at the impact of remittances on different percentile

rations (both regional and provincial level), but not accounting for non-remittance

income.

The expectations from the first 10 equations are one of an optimistic one.

Economic theory/anecdotal evidence suggest a positive impact of remittances on

education, even when controlling for non-remittance income. Remittances sent back

home should help the households in human capital investment. The Fraction of Years

Completed Per Capita (FYC) variable was selected as the dependent variable, since it

provides a better measurement of education attainment compared to Years of

Education. The FYC variable is further divided into 5 sub equations to account for

different age variations. Therefore, we will examine the effect of remittances on FYC

for individuals between the ages of 7 to 24 (Primary-Tertiary), 7 to 12(Primary), 13 to

18(Secondary), and finally 19 to 24(Tertiary).

39

We should see a positive relation between remittances and the FYC

variable for each age variation. Moreover, we should see a stronger relation between

remittances and primary level of education (ages 7 to12), as some studies have shown

(Dorantes and Pozo 2010). We should see a similar result, even when accounting for

non-remittance income. Moreover, the last four expenditure equations should further

clarify the impact of remittances (at least in terms of consumption). We should expect

remittances to have a positively linear relationship with education and healthcare

expenditures.

One would expect that a family receiving remittances will enable them to

buy school related supplies, or free up their income to be spent on education. This is

also similar in the case of healthcare. Remittances can affect health expenditures in

two ways. In the first instance, a family member might be in dire need of money for an

urgent medical issue, and thus the money sent from abroad could alleviate that

problem. This does not necessarily have to always be the case. Remittances sent back

could also be spent for normal medical expenditures, like buying drugs; although

drugs are not always bought to cure a sickness per se. Vitamins are also a form of

drug, yet they are mostly used to improve health and not necessarily cure sickness. In

this manner remittances can have both consumption and investment effects on health.

This is just to clarify that medical expenditures are not confined to one single activity.

Most of the equations pertain to the impact of remittances on education--with the

exception of equations 12 and 14. To account for the effect of remittances on

inequality, two methodologies have been used.

40

4.4 Inequality Analysis

The first analysis follows the Lerman and Yitzhaki (1985) measurement of

inequality. The Gini coefficient has been widely used to measure inequality in the

distribution of income, wealth, and expenditure. Using this literature, one can

decompose this measure to better understand the determinants of inequality.

According to Lerman and Yitzhaki, the Gini coefficient for total income, G, can be

shown as G=∑ R G S . Here Sk represents the share of component k in total

income, Gk shows the source Gini, which corresponds to the distribution of income

from source k, and Rk is the Gini correlation of income from source k with the

distribution of total income. There are three important issues to take into consideration

according to Stark, Taylor and Yitzhaki (1986). That is, the influence of any income

component on total income inequality depends upon:

1. The importance of income source with respect to total income (Sk)

2. The inequality distribution of the income source (Gk)

3. The correlation of income source with total income (Rk) (Taylor,Adams, Mora, and Lopez-Feldman 110-111)

In our case one of the income sources with respect to total income is

remittances, with the other one being salaries and wages. The 3 mechanisms discussed

earlier make it easy to estimate the influence of any income component (remittance in

our case) on total income inequality.

For instance, if I happen to have a large value for the remittances, so that

it constitutes a large share of the total income, then it may be possible that remittances

41

have a large impact on inequality. Conversely, if remittances constitute a small portion

of the total income, then it can be deduced that remittances do not have a large impact

on inequality. Although, if remittances is distributed equally (Gk=0), then regardless of

Sk, remittances will not affect inequality. If Sk and Gk happen to be large, that is

remittances are large and unequally distributed, remittances may either increase or

decrease inequality. For example, if the remittances are unequally distributed, and

flow towards household that are the top portion of income distribution, then

remittances will increase inequality. The inverse is also true. If the remittances are

unequally distributed, but tend to flow towards household that are in the lower portion

of the income bracket, then the remittances will have an equalizing affect.

Thus, according to Stark, Taylor and Yitzhaki, using the decomposition of

the Gini coefficient, one can estimate the effect that a 1 percent change in income

from remittances (source k), will have on total income inequality. The effect is given

by (SkRkGk/G)-Sk, where Sk, Rk, and Gk denote the source k share of income, Gini

correlation, and source Gini. An additional analysis of inequality was conducted by

regressing the different percentile ratios on remittances. This will allow for a

comparision of the top 90th percentile and the bottom 10th percentile, top 90th

percentile to median (50th percenilte), and finally 50th percentile to to the bottom 10th

percentile. The coefficeint estimates should provide some insight into the disparity

among different income distributions based on remittances. It should be noted that this

analysis has only been done for the collapsed data set for both regions (Model 3-A)

and provinces (Model 3-B). The following are the we get for the different models.

42

Chapter 5

RESULTS

5.1 Model 1-A & 1-B.

In the first ten equations, I examine the effects of remittances on the FYC

variable for different age groups. In Model 1-A, the sign of remittances is negative—

not the relationship we initially expected. The expectation was that of a positive

correlation between remittances and FYC. However looking at Model 1-A Table A.1,

coefficient estimate of remittances is negative (-10.6). This means that a 10 percent

increase in remittances above the mean (5908), will result in .63 percent decrease in

FYC for those between the ages of 7-24. But since the coefficient estimate is not

statistically significant at any level, we can conclude that regional remittances really

do not have any effect on regional changes in education. This is true across the board

for all FYC variables both at regional and provincial analysis. This is the case even

when controlling for non-remittance income. For example, in the provincial analysis

(Model 1-B) the coefficient estimate of FYC for ages 7 to 24 is (-

0.0000106*1,000,000=-10.6) is negative, although not statistically significant. This

means that even when growth of remittances differed across regions, growth of FYC

did not, at least statistically speaking. The FYC for all ages however, does not do a

fair job of explaining the impact of remittances on different age groups. Regardless,

43

remittances seem to have insignificant impact across the board for all the FYC

variables. Therefore, statistically speaking, remittances have not had a big impact on

education since 1999 (a very bold claim). However, when looking at the confidence

interval, we see that the value of 0 is bounded by the two extreme ends. For example,

looking at the extreme left (-50.6) and right (29.3) of the confidence interval (Model

1-A) for FYC (ages 7 to 24), a 10 percent increase in remittances lead to a decrease

and increase of -2.9 percent and 1.73 percent respectively. A similar pattern follows at

the provincial analysis. This means that Model 1 does not estimate a precise zero

effect.

5.2 Model 2-A & 2-B.

The coefficient estimates for the un-collapsed Models 2-A and 2-B are all

positive. This means that remittances have a positive impact on FYC for all the ages,

both at a regional and provincial level. For example a 10 percent increase in

remittances above the mean (688) will lead FYC (ages 7-24) to increase by .12 percent

for Model 2-A. Although positive, the dependent variable here includes a bigger age

range, and a better analysis would be to look at different age groups. This will enable

us to better examine the impact of remittances on FYC completed by looking in

specific age groups that usually attain education. The following are the results of the

effects of remittances on fraction of years completed for three sets of schooling: 7-24

(Primary-Tertiary) Primary (ages 7-12), Secondary (ages 13-18), and Tertiary (ages

19-24). The regressions in Model 2-A/2-B give us some expected results.

44

In Model 2-A, for individuals between the ages of 7-24, a 10 percent

increase in remittances will lead to an increase of .13 percent increase for FYC ages 7

to 24, a bit large compared to the regional (.12 percent). They are both significant at

99 percent level (p value of 0.00). Furthermore, at the regional level, a 10 percent

increase in remittances seem to have a larger affect on primary education compared to

secondary and tertiary (.22 percent primary vs. .06 percent secondary and .005 percent

tertiary). The results indicate that remittances sent back home are largely spent on

primary education. Remittances seem to have little if any pronounced effect on

tertiary schooling. This seems to conform to anecdotal evidence. Most of the

households that attain tertiary education will most likely be the households who can

afford it, and thus rely less on remittances and more on other sources of income.

These households tend to be in the upper-middle to higher part of the income

distribution. A similar pattern follows the provincial analysis, with primary education

being the prime recipient of remittances (.20 percent primary vs. .047 percent

secondary and .038 percent tertiary). Although the results seem to be congruent with

economic theory it is nevertheless important to control for non-remittance income.

This way we can truly get a good measure of the effects of remittances.

Again, the collapsed regional and provincial provide overwhelmingly

insignificant results—even when controlling for non-remittance income. Some

coefficient estimates for remittances are positive, while some are negative. Regardless,

they all exhibit a similar pattern—they are all insignificant. It should however be

mentioned that the two extremes of the confidence interval do have 0 bounded within

45

the interval. This means that the coefficient for remittance might have an impact on

different FYC variables, or it might have zero affects. This all depends on the value of

the extreme confidence interval. However, that is not the case with Model 2. Both at

the regional and provincial levels, controlling for non-remittance yield positive and

significant effects of remittances. As expected, the impact of remittances on all FYC

variables is not as pronounced when controlling for non-remittance income, except in

the case of primary education. For instance, the effect of remittances on FYC

variable for those between the ages of 13 and 18 is a bit lower when controlled for

non-remittance income (.06 percent vs. .05 percent increase) at the regional level. This

is also the case at the provincial level. Thus, overall we should also see a positive

impact on FYC from non-remittance income—and we do. A 10 percent increase in

non-remittance above the mean (14019) will lead to an astounding 21.1 percent

increase in primary education (ages 7-12), while it only increases tertiary education by

3.9 percent for Model 2-A. This further proves our point—in terms of education, most

of the remittances seem to flow towards primary education.

5.3 Yearly Models 1, 2, 3, & 4

The 2004 dataset is the only dataset that seems to give inconclusive results

for the non-expenditure equations. Although most of the signs of the coefficient

estimates are negative (except FYC 7-24), nevertheless, they are all insignificant. But

similar to Model 1, the confidence intervals range from -10 to 10. There is a possible

explanation for these uncommon effects. First of all, 2004 saw a very hotly contested

46

election year, in which for the first time the Overseas Absentee Voting Act of 2003

enabled overseas Filipinos to vote. Secondly, there was a huge tsunami in South Asia

which crippled the economies of many of the neighboring island countries (notably

Indonesia and Malaysia). This could very possibly have had a negative impact on the

Philippines economy as well. A 10 percent increase in remittances for 1999, 2007, and

2008 above mean (4340, 7866, 8453) will lead to increases of percent, .22 percent, and

.056 percent, and .48 percent for primary education—with all of the coefficients being

highly significant. Comparing the primary education with tertiary for each year, we

see an analogous trend as that of Model 2-A. The increase in tertiary education due to

remittances is lower than that of primary education; .0389 (1999), .0585 percent

(2007), .067 percent (2008), except for the year 2007. The results for the 2008 year do

look a little suspicious. It is very unlikely for remittance to have such a big impact on

primary education. The secondary education also seems to be a bit higher than tertiary,

but lower than primary. This is also the case when controlling for non-remittance

income.

Controlling for non-remittance income, a 10 percent increase in remittance

above mean for 1999, 2007, and 2008 years will lead to an increase of .21 (primary),

.056 percent (secondary), .051 percent (primary), .0347 percent (secondary), .45

percent (primary), and .12 percent (secondary) respectively. It is interesting to note

that aside from the 2004 year, remittances seem to have an increasingly positive effect

on education as the years progressed. A large volume of remittances seem to have

been spent on education in 2008, compared to 1999 (even when controlling for non-

47

remittance income). Of course, the regression does not take into account other

variables that could have affected education or remittances. Even so, the results seem

quite logical.

It is also important to see the effects of remittance on education and

healthcare expenditures to get a better perspective. The expenditure results will

include the results for collapsed (Models 1-A & 1-B), non-collapsed (Models 2-A &

2-B), and yearly datasets (1999, 2004, 2007, 2008). The regional and provincial

analysis will only be limited to Models 1 (collapsed dataset) and Models 2 (non-

collapsed household dataset), and not the yearly datasets.

5.4 Expenditure Results

For Model 1-A, remittances seem to have a positive effect on education

expenditure and medical expenditure. This is also the case when non-remittance

income is used as a control independent variable. However, only the education

expenditure coefficient is significant in both cases (.413 & .166 when controlling for

non-remittance income). Thus, we see a lesser impact of remittances on education

expenditure when controlling for non-remittance income. This is however only in the

regional analysis. For Model 1-B (provincial level), the opposite seems to be true.

Although the effect of remittances is positive and significant for both the education

and medical expenditure (.219 & .0765 respectively), the medical expenditure is the

only one that remains significant when controlled for non-remittance income (.061).

Thus, we have mixed effects of remittances on education and medical expenditures

48

when using the collapsed dataset. The results from Model 2-A and 2-B are more

consistent.

For Model 2-A, each peso of remittances results in increase of 8.5 percent

expenditure on education at the margin. Similarly each peso of remittances results in a

.0836 peso increase in education expenditure when controlling for non-remittance

income. This is also true for the medical expenditure. A 10 percent increase in

remittances will lead to an increase of approximately 3628 percent in health

expenditure for both controlled and uncontrolled effect of remittances. There seems to

be consistency in terms of the effects of remittances on education and medical

expenditures. This tendency is also seen in the yearly data sets, looking across

different regions.

In terms of regional analysis, 1999, 2004, 2007, and 2008 all show a

positive effect of remittances on education and medical expenditure. For example for

the year 1999, the education and medical expenditures have positive and significant

coefficients (.0284, .0229 respectively). That is also the case when controlling for

non-remittance income (.028 for education, .0224 for medical). For 2004, 2007, and

2008, education and expenditure coefficient estimates are positive and highly

significant for both controlled and uncontrolled non-remittance income. Tables E.3,

E.4, F.3, F.4, G.3, G.4, H.3, and H.4 provide the coefficient estimates of the

expenditure regressions. Aside from the regression analysis, it is also important to

take a look at the effect of remittances in terms of inequality. While remittances might

have a positive impact on education and health, it is important to see who benefits the

49

most from this impact. If most of the remittances help the higher income class, then

remittances do little in reducing poverty and inequality. The inequality

decomposition and regression of different percentile ratios give us a glance into the

inequality issue.

5.5 Inequality Analysis:

The two components of Total Income in a household in this paper are

given by salaries and wages, and remittances. The Gini coefficient for the remittances

component of total income is larger than that of the salaries and wages (.36 vs. .23).

One could conclude that remittances have a large impact on inequality. However, the

share of total income comprised by remittances is only 9 percent (Sk=.084). In

addition the correlation of remittances with total income is lower for remittances

compared to salaries and wages. In this case Sk and Rk are small, but Gk is large for

remittances compared to salaries and wages. The remittances could have an

inequality-reducing effect if the flow of remittances is geared towards the poor, and

not towards the wealthy households. The second analysis of inequality is done by

comparing different expenditure percentile ratios.

This analysis is done by regressing different percentile ratios on

remittances across regions and provinces (Models 3-A & 3-B). In another sense, this is

similar to Model 1-A and 1-B, in that it uses the collapsed dataset. Looking at Table

I.1 of Model 3-A, one can see that the disparity between the top 90th and the bottom

10th percentile is bigger than the other percentile ratios. The 90th to 10th percentile ratio

50

seems to be increasing by .07. This increase is less dramatic when looking at the 90th

to 50th percentile (.031 differences in 90th to 50th percentile ratio). The effect of

remittances further lessens when looking at the middle to bottom percentile ratios

(.0025 differences in 90th to 50th percentile ratio). The coefficient estimates are all

significantly different from zero, so our estimates are accurate. We see a big gap

between the top and the bottom portion of the income distribution, while the middle to

bottom is not as dramatic. We see an almost similar pattern in Model 3-B (provincial).

While the gap between the top and the bottom is even bigger than that of

the regional analysis (.072 increases in the percentile ratio difference), the gap

between top and the middle is smaller (.0282 increase in the percentile ratio

difference). It is interesting to look at the 50th to 10th percentiles. The negative

coefficient means that remittances actually decrease inequality between the middle

and the bottom class of the income distribution. The 50th to 10th percentile ratio seems

to be decreasing by .004. As expected, there exists a gap between the top and the

bottom portion of the income distribution, and remittances do seem to favor those who

are above the bottom percentile of the income distribution.

51

Chapter 6

SUMMARY & CONCLUSION

Most of the literatures related to remittances seem to paint a positive

picture of its effects on development. While remittances might not constitute a large

portion of a developed country’s economy, it plays a vital role in a developing nation’s

economy. In this paper the results indicate a positive impact of remittances on human

capital investment. That is particularly the case for individuals between the ages of 7-

12, who are earning primary education. The bulk of remittances seem to be directed

toward primary education as compared to secondary or tertiary. This is the case even

when controlling for non-remittance income. The 2004 Year dataset seems to yield

negative or insignificant coefficients estimates, which also affects the collapsed

datasets (both at a regional and provincial level). However, with the non-collapsed

datasets, the coefficient estimates seem to follow economic theory. The remittances

are positively correlated with education attainment with both uncontrolled and

controlled non-remittance regressions. Model 1 yields insignificant p-values.

Therefore, one cannot with certitude claim the validity or the invalidity of the

coefficient estimates in Model 1. Nevertheless, Model 1 is less biased than Model 2.

Model 1 takes into account any characteristics that could affect remittance variations

52

across regions, while Model 2 cannot account for household factors that are correlated

with remittances.

Additionally, when remittances are available, they seem to increase

education and medical expenditures, although not by a big magnitude. For example

for Model 2-A and 2-B,coefficient estimates for medical and education expenditures

are all positive and significant as shown in Tables C.3, C.4, D.3, and D.4. However,

there seems to be a disparity when it comes to inequality. The percentile ratios suggest

inequality among the top and the bottom income distribution. The income

decomposition seems to also suggest the same (Gini coefficient of remittances is

high), although the remittance share of total income seem to be less than salaries and

wages.

The results obtained from Models 2-A and 2-B also seem to be in line

with the studies done by Dorantes and Pozo. Most of the benefactors of remittances

seem to be younger siblings who are attending primary school. Additionally, the

analysis of percentile ratios suggests disparities among different distributions of

income, both at a regional and provincial level. This is also similar to the findings by

Taylor, that most of the remittances do not reach the poor families.

Overall remittances seem to play an important role in the Philippines, and

most likely many other developing nations. Remittances are a more stable form of

financial inflow, and tend to be immune to economic shocks. Although the paper

paints a positive picture of remittances on various factors of the Philippine society, we

still have to be cautious. The datasets for the regions and provinces are not consistent.

53

The lack of data for certain regions, such as Autonomous Region in Muslim

Mindanao, Caraga and Cordillera Administrative Region make it difficult to be

completely conclusive about the results. Additionally, there are many channels

through which remittances are sent and received. The actual amount of remittances is

most likely more than what is reported. Furthermore, as Skeldon (1997) points out

that most of the migrants do not belong to the poorest income distribution. In addition

to aspiration for a better life, migration involves physical, financial, and social risks

that many of the poorest in the least developed nations would most likely not

undertake. Thus, most of the migrants seem to come from lower-middle to upper-

middle incomes who have the necessary motivation, as well as the financially ability

to migrate. Thus remittances do not seem to help the poorest section of the society. In

fact most of the countries with high rates of emigration (Turkey, Mexico, and

Philippines) are no longer categorized as least developed. The fact is that migration

and remittance by themselves do not lead to development. To better exploit the full

potential of remittances, other constraints to development such as corruption, market

failures, access to credit, access to human capital (education, health), trade barriers, etc

need to be addressed. Over the years, the Philippines has addressed many of these

constraints, and have had significant improvements. Nevertheless, there is still room

for improvement in order to provide a suitable environment to fully exploit the

potentials of remittances.

54

REFERENCES

Amuedo-Dorantes, Catalina, and Susan Pozo. "Accounting for Remittance andMigration Effects on Children's Schooling." (2010): Print.

Ang, Alvin P. "Workers." DEGIT, Conference Papers. (2007): Print.

Asis, Maruja M.B. "The Philippines." Asian and Pacific Migration Journal.17.3-4 (2008): Print.

Burgess, R. and Haksar, H. (2005). “Migration and Foreign Remittances in thePhilippines.” IMF Working Paper WP/05/

Chami, Ralph, Connel Fullenkamp, and Samir Jahjah. "Are ImmigrantRemittance Flows a Source of Capital for Development?" PalgraveMacmillan Journals 52.1 (2005): 55-81. Web. 2 Jun 2011.<http://www.jstor.org/stable/30035948 .>.

Chauvet, Lisa, Flore Gubert, and Sandrine Mesle-Somps. "Are RemittancesMore Effective than Aid to Improve Child Health? An EmpiricalAssessment Using Inter and Intra-country Data." Annual BankConference on Development Economics. (2008): Print.

Chimhowu, Admos, Jenifer Piesse, and Caroline Pinder. The SocioeconomicImpact of Remittances on Poverty Reduction. Remittances:Development Impact and Future Prospects. Washington DC: The

Docquier, Frederic, Ousmane Faye, and Pierre Pestieau. "Is Migration a GoodSubstitute for Education Subsidies?" World Bank DevelopmentResearch Group. (2008): Print.

Edgar R., Rodriguez. "International Migrants' Remittances in the Philippines."Canadian Journal of Economics 29.Special (Apr 1996): S427-S432.Web. 2 Jun 2011. <http://www.jstor.org/stable/136081>.

Eduardo T., Gonzalez. "Does international migration induce human capitalinvestment and knowledge transfer? Evidence from the Philippines."Asian Center: University of the Philippines. (Undated): Print.

Edwards Cox, Alejandro, and Manuelita Ureta. "International migration,remittances, and schooling: evidence from El Salvador." Journal ofDevelopment Economics 72. (2003): 429-461. Web. 2 Jun 2011.<www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase>.

55

Fajnzylber, Pablo, and J. Humberto Lopez. Remittances and Development.Print.

Fayissa, Bichaka, and Christian Nsiah. "Can Remittances Spur EconomicGrowth and Development? Evidence from Latin American Countries(LACs)." (2010): Print.

Go, Stella P. "Remittances and International Labour Migration: Impact on thePhilippines." Philippine Migration Research Network. (Undated): Print.

Hildebrandt, Nicole. David J. McKenzie. “The Effects of Migration on childHealth in Mexico.” Economia: Project Muse. 6. (2005): 257-289.

International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 83-99. Print.

Jorge, Valero-Gil. "Remittances and the household's expenditures on health."Munich Personal RePEc Archive. (2008)

Margarita R., Songco. "International labor migration and remittances in thePhilippines." National Economic and Development Authority. (Dec2009): Print.

McKenzie, David, and Marcin J. Sain. "Migration, Remittances, Poverty, andHuman Capital: Conceptual and empirical challenges." World BankPolicy Research Working Paper. (2007): Print.

Overseas Filipinos Workers. <http://overseasfilipinos.com/>.

Republic of Philippines National Statistics Office.<http://www.census.gov.ph>

Richard C., Jones. "Remittances and Inequality: A Question of Migration Stageand Geographic Scale." Economic Geography 74.1 (Jan 1998): 8-25.Web. 2 Jun 2011. <http://www.jstor.org/stable/144341 .>.

Skeldon, R (1997) Migration and Development: A Global Perspective(Harlow: Longman).

Stark, J., Edward, and Shlomo Yitzhaki. "Remittances and Inequality."Economic Journal 96.383 (Sep 1986): 722-740. Web. 2 Jun 2011.<http://www.jstor.org/stable/2232987>.

Taylor, J.Edward, Richard Adams, Jorge Mora, and Alejandro Lopez-Feldman."Remittances, Inequality and Poverty: Evidence from Rural Mexico."(2005): 110-111.

56

W. Stahl, Charles, and Fred Arnold. "Overseas Workers' Remittances in AsianDevelopment." International Migration Review 20.Temporary Worker(Winter 1986): 899-925. Web. 2 Jun 2011.<http://www.jstor.org/stable/2545742 >.

Yang, Dean, and Claudia A. Martinez. "Remittances and Poverty in Migrants'Home Areas: Evidence from the Philippines." Print.

Yang, Dean. (2008). International migration, remittances, and householdinvestment: Evidence from Philippine migrants’ exchange rate shocks,Economic Journal 118

57

Appendix A

MODEL 1-A (REGIONAL)

Table A.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 FYC_7_24

REMIT 2.2100 -0. 695 2.21 -10.6(26.900) (7.03) ( 2.80) (18.9)

Constant 3.710*** 1.000*** 0.581*** 2.114***

(0.188) (0.0492) (0.0223) (0.134)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term.

58

Table A.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 FYC_7_24

NRI -26 - 4.72 -1.10 -17.7(33.7) (6.53) (5.19) (15.5)

REMIT 12.3 1.93 2082 -0. 794(30.7) (6.65) (3.72) (20.9)

Constant 3.837*** 1.023*** 0.586*** 2.200***

(0.276) (0.0636) (0.0363) (0.144)* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term.

Table A.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)EDU_EXP MED_EXP

REMIT .4130* .0976(.1510) (.555)

Constant -1757.2 403.7(1395.9) (466.8)

Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

59

Table A.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance IncomeEffect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)EDU_EXP MED_EXP

REMIT .166 * .0606(.734) (.0709)

NRI .443** .0665(.132) (.047)

Constant -3911.3** 80.63(1054.8) (374.2)

Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

60

Appendix B

MODEL 1-B (PROVINCIAL)

Table B.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 FYC_7_24

REMIT 5.69 -3.23 -1.19 -0. 250(40.9) (4.60) (5.30) (16.1)

Constant 3.790*** 1.069*** 0.607*** 2.101***

(0.435) (0.0482) (0.0564) (0.172)* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term.

61

Table B.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 FYC_7_24

NRI 19.9 2.87 2.88 10.6(28.8) (5.22) (3.51) (14.0)

REMIT -2.06 -4.34 -2.31 -4.36(47.8) (5.34) (6.14) (18.9)

Constant 3.692*** 1.055*** 0.592*** 2.049***

(0.376) (0.0510) (0.0492) (0.158)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term.

Table B.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)EDU_EXP MED_EXP

REMIT 0.219* 0.0765*

(0.0957) (0.0307)

Constant 246.8 670.0*

(1054.9) (321.6)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

62

Table B.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effect of Remittances onEducation & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)EDU_EXP MED_EXP

REMIT 0.0903 0.0615*

(0.0795) (0.0307)

NRI 0.332*** 0.0385(0.0595) (0.0450)

Constant -1390.1 480.2(835.9) (419.3)

Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

63

Appendix C

MODEL 2-A (REGIONAL)

Table C.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed: For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 For Ages 7 to 24

REMIT 3.30*** 0.852*** 0. 0739*** 1.68***

(.337) (0. 0567) (0. 0408) (.155)

Constant 3.675*** 1.007*** 0.603*** 2.1167***

(0.075862) (0.014208) (0.011406) (0.03806)

Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term.

64

Table C.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed: For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 For Ages 7 to 24

NRI 15.1*** 3.74*** .278*** 7.39***

(0. 490) (0. 0802) (0. 0610) (0. 226)

REMIT 3.0*** 0. 810*** 0. 727*** 1.59***

(0. 336) (0. 0560) (0. 040) (0. 154)

Constant 3.529*** 0.970*** 0.574*** 2.0428***

(0.07562) (0.01404) (0.01122) (0.03804)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term.

Table C.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)EDU_EXP MED_EXP

REMIT 0.0859*** 0.07044***

(0.00044) (0.000586)

Constant 1023.266*** 654.27***

(110.364) (145.69)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

65

Table C.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance IncomeEffect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)EDU_EXP MED_EXP

REMIT 0.08369*** 0.06905***

(0.000432) (0.000583)

NRI 0.11277** 0.06932**

(0.000597) (0.000806)

Constant -99.568 -35.949(107.444) (145.042)

* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

66

Appendix D

MODEL 2-B (PROVINCIAL)

Table D.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 FYC 7_ 24

REMIT 3.03*** 0. 685*** 0. 552*** .185 ***(0. 787) (0. 143) (0.110) (.0383)

Constant 3.288*** 1.020*** 0.602*** 1.9758***

(0.28565) (0.061638) (0.03854) (0.14650)

Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term.

67

Table D.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 For Ages 7 to 24

NRI 20.6*** 3.98*** 2.88*** 9.928***

(1.04) (0.000000163) (0. 0124) (0. 466)

REMIT 2.74*** 0. 664*** 0. 554*** 1.78***

(0. 783) (0. 141) (0. 108) (0. 383)

Constant 3.130*** 0.987*** 0.578*** 1.90095***

(0.28424) (0.06106) (0.038087) (0.146229)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term.

Table D.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)EDU_EXP MED_EXP

REMIT 0.0423*** 0.02665***

(0.00076) (0.001244)

Constant 1692.307*** 722.79(298.398) (488.159)

Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

68

Table D.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance IncomeEffect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)EDU_EXP MED_EXP

REMIT 0.041883*** 0.0262836***

(0.000754) (0.0012413)

NRI 0.05749** 0.04954**

(0.0009299) (0.0015304)

Constant 1219.686*** 315.5909(296.047) (487.2147)

* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

69

Appendix E

1999 (REGIONAL)

Table E.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 For Ages 7 to 24

REMIT 5.28*** 1.33*** 0.897*** 3.05***

(1.25) (0. 238) (0. 163) (0. 735)

Constant 3.661*** 1.004*** 0.602*** 2.106***

(0.00964) (0.00196) (0.00133) (0.00587)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term.

70

Table E.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed:For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)

FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 For Ages 7 to24

NRI 26*** 4.91 3.96** 11.7*

(4.81) (2.50) (1.27) (4.13)

REMIT 4.82*** 1.30*** 0. 879*** 2.93***

(1.11) (0. 199) (0. 153) (0. 662)

Constant 3.407*** 0.954*** 0.561*** 1.989***

(0.0475) (0.0264) (0.0132) (0.0427)Standard errors are in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term

Table E.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)EDU_EXP MED_EXP

REMIT 0.0284*** 0.0229***

(0.00487) (0.00299)

Constant 1470.0*** 1023.6***

(37.84) (23.21)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

71

Table E.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effect of Remittances onEducation & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)EDU_EXP MED_EXP

REMIT 0.0280*** 0.0224***

(0.00464) (0.00323)

NRI 0.0458** 0.0517**

(0.0140) (0.0128)

Constant 1010.7*** 505.0***

(163.5) (114.0)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

72

Appendix F

2004 (REGIONAL)

Table F.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed: For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 For Ages 7 to 24

REMIT -.0068 -0. 414 -.00598 .00889(0. 530) (0.209) (0. 231) (0. 375)

Constant 4.191*** 1.134*** 0.663*** 2.234***

(0.00505) (0.00170) (0.00179) (0.00322)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term

73

Table F.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed: For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 For Ages 7 to 24

NRI 2.84 0. 112 -0. 196 1.31(2.26) (0. 293) (0. 269) (1.05)

REMIT -0.000000116 -0. 416 -.00589 7.06e-08(0.000000535) (0. 211) (0. 231) (0.000000375)

2.219***

Constant 4.155*** 1.133*** 0.665*** (0.0133)(0.0296) (0.00300) (0.00397) (2)

Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term

Table F.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)Education Medical Care

REMIT 0.0665*** 0.0334***

(0.00415) (0.00663)Constant 1628.4*** 962.5***

(38.50) (61.42)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

74

Table F.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effect of Remittances onEducation & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)Education Medical Care

REMIT 0.0652*** 0.0328***

(0.00444) (0.00648)

NRI 0.0935*** 0.0413***

(0.0103) (0.00799)

Constant 487.5** 458.2**

(151.2) (141.5)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

75

Appendix G

2007 (REGIONAL)

Table G.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed: For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)

FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 FYC_7_24REMIT 0. 718*** 0. 463*** 0. 743*** 0. 319**

(.00789) (.00644) (.00894) (.00870)

Constant 1.934*** 1.188*** 0.875*** 1.399***

(0.000892) (0.000761) (0.00129) (0.00107)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term

76

Table G.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed: For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 For Ages 7 to 24

NRI 4.94*** 2.06** 1.99* 0. 560(1.01) (0. 553) (0. 690) (0. 440)

REMIT 0. 642*** 0. 441*** 0.739*** 0. 313**

(.00828) (.00567) (.00748) (.00832)

Constant 1.887*** 1.165*** 0.846*** 1.393***

(0.00955) (0.00634) (0.0101) (0.00554)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term

Table G.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)Education Medical Care

REMIT 0.110*** 0.0633***

(0.0148) (0.00923)

Constant 1855.8*** 1034.7***

(185.3) (115.9)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

77

Table G.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effect of Remittances onEducation & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)Education Medical Care

REMIT 0.107*** 0.0622***

(0.0153) (0.00947)

NRI 0.146*** 0.0677***

(0.0131) (0.0146)

Constant 52.84 200.3(300.8) (216.8)

Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

78

Appendix H

2008 (REGIONAL)

Table H.1 Effects of Remittances on Fraction of Years Completed: For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 For Ages 7 to 24

REMIT 5.73*** 1.52*** 0. 797*** 3.09***

(1.18) (0. 182) (.00882) (0. 513)

Constant 4.253*** 1.160*** 0.691*** 2.224***

(0.0129) (0.00198) (0.00110) (0.00578)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term

79

Table H.2 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effects of Remittances onFraction of Years Completed: For Ages 7-1213-1819-247-24

(Primary) (Secondary) (Tertiary) (Primary-Tertiary)FYC_7_12 FYC_13_18 FYC_19_24 For Ages 7 to 24

NRI 14.0** 4.04** 3.58** 8.82***

(4.08) (1.15) (0. 986) (1.95)

REMIT 5.37*** 1.46*** 0. 772*** 2.94***

(1.11) (0. 159) (.00834) (0. 466)

Constant 4.062*** 1.102*** 0.643***

(0.0603) (0.0174) (0.0131) 2.103***

Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeCoefficients & Standard errors have been multiplied by 1 million, except for theConstant term

Table H.3 Effect of Remittances on Education & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)Education Medical Care

REMIT 0.0907*** 0.105***

(0.00558) (0.0182)

Constant 2643.3*** 1013.5***

(62.84) (204.7)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

80

Table H.4 Controlling For Non-Remittance Income Effect of Remittances onEducation & Medical Expenditures

(1) (2)Education Medical Care

REMIT 0.0868*** 0.103***

(0.00605) (0.0177)

NRI 0.130*** 0.0855***

(0.0108) (0.0187)

Constant 885.2*** -138.5(168.0) (270.9)

Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From AbroadNRINon-Remittance IncomeEDU_EXPEducation ExpenditureMED_EXP Medical Expenditure

81

Appendix I

MODEL 3-A (REGIONAL/PROVINCIAL)

Table I.1 Regional Effects of Remittances on Different Percentile Ratios

(Top-Bottom) (Top-Middle) (Middle-Bottom)90th to 10thPercentile

90th to 50thPercentile

50th to 10thPercentile

REMIT 119* 52.7** 4.07(41.7) (17.0) (1906)

Constant 4.161*** 2.099*** 1.995***

(0.350) (0.155) (0.167)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From Abroad

Table I.2 Provincial Effects of Remittances on Different Percentile Ratios

(Top-Bottom) (Top-Middle) (Middle-Bottom)90th to 10thPercentile

90th to 50thPercentile

50th to 10thPercentile

REMIT 122.9 *** 47.9 *** -6.81***

(36.3) (14.3 ) (1.88)

Constant 5.303 *** 2.734*** 0.381***

(.6397) (.252) (0.033)Standard errors in parentheses* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001REMITRemittances Received From Abroad

82

Appendix J

MODEL 4-A (REGIONAL/PROVINCIAL)

Table J.1 Inequality Analysis: Gini Decomposition (Regional) Total IncomeVariable: TOTINC

Source Sk Gk Rk Share % Change

SALWAG 0.4370 0.2351 0.9441 0.5351 0.0981REMIT 0.0843 0.3574 0.9117 0.1515 0.0672Total income 0.1813

Table J.2 Inequality Analysis: Gini Decomposition (Provincial) Total IncomeVariable: TOTINC

Source Sk Gk Rk Share % ChangeSALWAG 0.4408 0.2610 0.8986 0.5537 0.1129REMIT 0.0782 0.4447 0.7529 0.1402 0.0620Total income 0.1867